7 Options and limitations for enhancement of

advertisement
Options for livelihoods in Java
77
7
Options and limitations for enhancement of
livelihoods in marginal upland areas of Java
Junko Goto
Independent Regional Planning Researcher,
4-9-25, Higiriyama, Konan-ku, Yokohoma, Japan
Introduction
The period of late 1990s is often viewed as a transition phase
in the modern history of Indonesia. Hard hit by the currency crisis
and drought of 1997, Indonesia tumbled into a political, social, and
economic uncertainty after 30 years of dictatorship. After nearly ten
years of neglect, agriculture is now getting more attention, but the
road to agricultural development is not smooth (McBeth, 1998).
Farming Systems Research (FSR) has a long history in Indonesia
(Goto and Mayrowani, 2001). Starting as cropping systems research
led by International Rice Research Institute (IRRI) during 1970s, the
78
Goto
1980s was a boom period for FSR. Several research efforts have
been made to understand organization and function of integrated
smallholder farming systems in different ecoregions of the country
(Huszar, 1997).
In April 1995, Assessment Institutes for Agricultural Technology (AIATs) were established throughout the country (17 units in
total) as part of research and development set-up of the Ministry of
Agriculture. Responsibility of supervision of these Institutes was
vested in Center for Agro-Socio-Economic Research and Development (CASERD). AIATs carry out applied research and support
local government and farmers in their respective regions. Decentralization and regionalization became the leading concepts in FSR
programs in the late 1990s.
Livelihoods in uplands
Portrayal of livelihoods presented here is based on a household survey undertaken in Sukamekar village, Cibinong District,
Cianjur Regency during 1998-1999 period. During mid-1990s, southern Cianjur was identified as the target area for small farmer development because this area had been excluded in previous development programs that had benefited northern Cianjur. Northern Cianjur
is well known for its high quality rice and vegetables. Southern
Cianjur, in contrast, is characterized by hilly topography, poor soil
and water conditions together with ill-developed infrastructure. Located far away from major consumption centers of Jakarta and
Bandung, farmers in southern Cianjur grow rice and other food crops
for subsistence, and clove, banana and durian (Durio zibethinus).
Production of perishable fruits and vegetables demanded in market
is, however, limited to the places connected by motorable roads.
Farmers in Sukamekar village was integrated with market in
the year 1997 after the initiation of the Ministry of Agriculture’s
small farmer programs called P2RT and SPAKU. P2RT was one of
the major agricultural development programs of the Ministry of Agriculture during the 1990s. The program P2RT (Pengembangan
Pertanian Rakyat Terpadu which means integrated smallholders
agricultural development) aimed to provide guidance to small farmers to form cooperative groups and to optimize use of available resources to improve their well-being. The program SPAKU (Sentra
Options for livelihoods in Java
79
Pengembangan Agribisnis Komoditi Unggulan which means
agribusiness development center for superior commodity) tried to
develop institutions and mechanisms favoring economic interests of
farmers. Agribusiness development for small farmers was one of
the most important concern of planners during 1990s and P2RT and
SPAKU were considered to be complementary and often implemented
together. This project in southern Cianjur covered 200 ha of agricultural land falling villages Sukamekar and Cikangkarent. Farmers
selected banana as the key commodity for agribusiness development.
Village roads were improved to enable automobile access, and farmers were organized so as to benefit from agricultural subsidies and
information provided by the government. AIAT-Lembang was invited to support technology dissemination and to conduct assessment of banana-based farming systems (SUP-pisang project; AIATLembang, 1997).
The banana project brought a significant change in this remote
upland area. Earlier, villagers could earn daily at best Rp 3,000 (US
$ 1 = roughly 3,000 Indonesian Rupiah in 1997; 10,000 in 1998)
from plantation work. When this job opportunity ceased, many families resorted to sending women to work far away from home to earn
money. Tenaga Kerja Wanita (TKW), a local phrase, literally means
female work force. Saudi Arabia and Malaysia are two major destinations for Indonesian migrant workers (Hugo, 2002). Often not
registered as overseas contract workers, these women are subjected
to a high risk of exploitation and abuse. To improve the household
income situation, the project encouraged farmers to adopt a systematic approach to produce banana and other commodities for marketing. According to the village chief at the time of our interview in
1998, selling banana brought farmer a daily gross cash income of Rp
7,000-10,000.
Development projects and rural economy
Our survey of fifty-one households in the year 1998/99 (Table
1) revealed that the smallest farm measured 0.04 ha and the largest
one 3.32 ha. On average, a farmer operated 0.20 ha of lowlands split
in 1.35 plots, and 0.72 ha of uplands in 2.06 plots (Figure 1). Average land holding of surveyed households (0.92 ha) is slightly larger
than the national average (0.8 ha in 1993 Census). Farmers owned
80
Goto
about 81% of lowland and 85% of upland of the village. Most farmers owned sheep (4.3 heads household -1 ) and chicken (7.1 household-1). Water buffalo is used for land preparation for rice because a
hand tractor is not only too expensive but also too difficult to operate
in small, irregular, terraced and scattered fields. Farmers in the study
village brought buffalo on rent from a farmer who owns and operates buffalo.
Table 1. Basic features of surveyed households
SUP cooperator
(14 house
holds)
0.80
Upland area
under cultivation (ha)
Family size (number
4.14
of individuals)
Household expenditure 378
-1
(‘000 Rp month )
Non- cooperator
(10 house
holds)
0.38
P2RT cooperator
(27 house
holds)
0.81
Average of
all categories
(51 house
holds)
0.72
3.1
4.22
3.98
286
367
354
Source: CASER-JIRCAS collaborative farm household survey, 1998.
Lowlands requires about 40% of total labor input. Land preparation in rice fields is usually the task of men and planting/weeding
of women. Hired labor was used to a greater extent in lowlands
compared to uplands (Figures 1 and 2). Gotong royong, the traditional system of mutual help (labor exchange without payment), was
no longer practiced. Rp 5,000 were paid as daily wage to men and
Rp 4,000 to women. Lowland farming was important for achieving
local production based food self-sufficiency (it provided nearly 2/
3rd of family requirement), while upland farming was largely for
income. The average rate of commercialization was 78.9% in upland farming, while it was 15.1% in lowland (Figure 3). Among upland crops, banana was the most dominant and rewarding crop.
An average family has 4 members indicating dominance of
nuclear families. A few cases of older couples residing with grandchildren were found. The parent(s) of these children were working
away from home. Monthly expenditure per household amounted to
Rp 354,000. This level was well above (higher than) the poverty
Options for livelihoods in Java
81
Laborinput--lowland
18.00
16.83
16.71
16.00
14.09
14.00
11.91
12.00
9.83
10.00
HOK
8.00
6.00
5.34
4.00
2.00
0.00
family
labor
0.40
nonfamily
labor
landpreparation
3.94
2.69
2.34
2.26
1.43
1.20
5.14
4.57
3.74
0.97
0.29
family
labor
nonfamily
labor
planting
family
labor
nonfamily
labor
weeding
0.74
0.37 0.34
family
labor
nonfamily
labor
fertilizing
0.00 0.17
0.00
family non- family
labor family
labor
labor
pest & disease
control
nonfamily
labor
harvest
Figure 1. Annual labor input in lowland cultivation by an average
household (n=35). HOK (hari orang kerja) means “man
(woman) days engaged.”
Laborinput--upland
18.00
16.00
16.75
14.88
14.00
12.00
10.00
HOK
8.00
6.10
6.00
3.90
3.37 3.59
4.00
2.00
0.00
6.00
1.65
1.25
3.04
1.29 1.33
3.59
3.04
1.29 1.33
2.08
1.70
3.88
2.56
0.14
0.12 0.16
0.00
family non-family family non-family family non-family family non-family family non-family family non-family
labor labor labor labor labor labor labor labor labor labor labor labor
landpreparation
planting
weeding
fertilizing
pest&disease
control
harvest
Figure 2. Annual labor input in upland cultivation by an average
household (n=51). HOK as in figure 1.
82
Goto
Crop production summary
30,000,000
100.0
90.0
25,000,000
70.0
Production (Rupiah)
20,000,000
60.0
15,000,000
50.0
40.0
10,000,000
30.0
Rate of commercialization (%)
80.0
20.0
5,000,000
10.0
0
0.0
banana
chili
palm
sugar
clove
petai cassava maize jengkol peanut coconut soybean
lowland upland
rice
rice
Figure 3. Crop production summary of 51 farmers 1 year (1997-98).
Rate of commercialization (for each crop) = amount sold /
total production x 100 (shown by curve); total production =
production for market + production for home consumption
(shown by histogram (sum of 51 farmers) of crops listed in
Rupiah).
line at the time of the survey in 1998. More than half of the surveyed
households had some earnings from local non-farm occupations or
remittances from family members working away from home.
Small farmer typology
Based on the survey results, we realized that focusing solely
on market-oriented farming was certainly not an ideal solution for
every household to improve its income. There were other means of
household sustenance. In order to understand these means, we developed small farmer typology based on income from farm and nonfarm activities (Figure 4):
A. farming households relatively well-to-do and progressive
(n=5)
B. farming households poor but subsistent (n=6)
C. farming households barely subsistent (n=28)
D. part-time farming households with a steady non-farm income
(n=8)
E. farming households well-to-do with remittance incomes (n=4)
Options for livelihoods in Java
TKW (Saudi Arabia,
Malaysia, JKT, …)
local non-farm
jobs
?
nonag
income
part-time D
multiple-job
holder C-1
C-2
better-off
with
E
remittances
Market
generous employer C-3
Subsistent
starter
farmer
83
B
progressive
successful profit -maker A
agricultural income ?
Figure 4. Household options: niches in the local economy. Details of
farmer categories A-E given in Table 2 and also in the text.
TKW (tenaga kerja wanita): simple translation is “women
work force”, but means family members working away from
home, often abroad (including male members).
Barely subsistent farmers represented more than 50% of families and were further classified based on per capita rice produced at
home and income from sale of upland crops:
C-1. small multiple job holders: almost no rice produced at home,
earning cash and/or rice by working as agricultural
laborers, spending a small amount of money for farming
their own land and selling upland crops (n=8).
C-2. small to medium size starter farmers: with some rice production in upland and/or lowland, no or very little offfarm income, spending a lot of money for farming their
own land with a poor record of sale of upland crops (n=12).
C-3. medium to large scale farmers: more than sufficient production of rice for self-consumption, a high level of farm
production and an equally high level of farm cash expenditure (including payment for non-family labor), some
such farmers record a large cash deficit (n=8).
84
Goto
Table 2 shows the key indicators and distribution of each farm
type. The overall average per capita annual rice production was 170
kg. This amount of dry unhusked rice equals 100 kg of milled rice,
which could be enough to meet the family need given the availability of other food crops such as corn and cassava. Relatively betteroff farmers belonging to types A and E stated above had a large
reserve of rice for home, while those categorized as C-1 farmers had
none. There were a good number of small farmers who took part in
this development project. This could be a good relief for agricultural program officers afraid of a possibility of government projects
favoring large and progressive farmers only. There were two sources
of income from outside the region: remittances and sale of cash crops.
Almost all types of households benefit directly from crop sales. Income should somehow be redistributed from wealthier households
to others, because quite a few relied on local wage jobs (farm and
non-farm) as their major means of survival. In addition, some farmers held part-time non-farm jobs as carpenters, motorbike drivers,
tailors, or local clerks.
Conclusions
In promoting upland crops for marketing, AIAT officers found
that it was difficult to keep villagers focused on upland crops once
the busy ‘rice’ cycle began. Lowland rice occupied a very important
position in securing food self-sufficiency. Most villagers were not
much concerned about the necessity of soil and water conservation
for sustainable farming in the uplands. Realistically, options for these
households to improve their income and livelihoods are not many.
One may choose one of the following: (a) become a successful market-oriented farmer (small but progressive); (b) have a stable parttime job in or near the village (skill required); (c) earn significant
income by sending a family member away from home; (d) earn income from miscellaneous sources in or near the village; (e) stay selfcontent, subsistence-oriented, producing enough to eat at home.
Should we, researchers and extensionists, feel powerless and
lost, because there were only a few good candidates for market-oriented farming? I would argue that diversity in livelihoods, although
difficult to understand and rationalize, is a strength and safety net in
marginal hill areas. Income from cultivation of banana and chili
7,314
2,796
274
555
2,593
1,826
3,046
2,152
282.7
251.3
3.8
92.4
251.1
130.7
385.4
169.7
A.
B.
C-1.
C-2.
C-3.
D.
E.
78.9
86.3
84.9
77.7
34.1
76.4
51.1
68.4
4.0
5.4
3.5
4.0
4.0
4.3
3.4
3.5
(14)
2
2
0
3
3
2
2
(10)
1
1
2
4
0
2
0
(27)
2
3
6
5
5
4
2
Upland
Family size SUP
Non-cooperator P2RT
commercialization (persons)
cooperator
cooperator
rate (%)
Source: CASER-JIRCAS collaborative farm household survey, 1998; * farm production from September 1997 until August
Note: Upland commercialization rate = upland crops marketed (in values)/ upland total production (in values) x 100.
Progressive
Subsistent
Multiple job holder
Starter farmer
Local employer farmer
Part-time farmer
Rich with remittance
income
Average (Total)
Rice at home Total farm
(kg/ person)* production
(‘000 Rp)*
Type
Table 2. Characteristics of farm types
Options for livelihoods in Java
85
86
Goto
boosted the local economy, although profit making from crop sales
was an uphill struggle for traditional subsistence farmers in a remote
place. Responding to our questionnaire, 90% farmers remarked that
they were not satisfied with their farming system. Reasons for their
dissatisfaction included: (a) high and rising prices of inputs viz., fertilizers, chemicals and seeds; (b) poor harvest because of pest and
diseases; and (c) low prices of farm products (Figure 5). Because of
continued recession and oversupply, farm gate price of banana declined sharply during the first half of 1999. Prices of chili and other
cash crops also plunged.
Frequently cited reasons (51 respondents)
The numbers below correspond with choices in Form C, Question 2.
6) prices of fertilizers, chemicals, seeds, keep rising
4) poor harvest because of pest and diseases
7) prices of farm product low
2) lack of water sources for farm use
1) rainfall inadequate, etc.
8) poor infrastructure for marketing (road)
5) lack of farm labor for peak seasons
3) soil conditions not favorable
9) lack of middlemen for marketing
Figure 5. Reasons of farmer dissatisfaction. Note: Respondents gave
ranks to the options (reasons) provided in the question. There
are eleven reasons provided. To show the overall ranking in
a simple graph, the scores of 51 respondents added first,
then subtracted from 500 (because the largest sum was 460).
The graph shows the top nine reasons.
It is hard for the late-starters located in remote villages to compete in market. Farm input prices are going-up, while commodity
prices are getting depressed. Lack of capital, knowledge and experience delimits economic benefits to small farmers. A more labor-intensive upland operation (for a better quality product) is not realistic
because of diversion of labor to secure food security in lowlands and
high cost of non-family labor. Even though a successful migrant
worker might bring back good fortune to his/her family, it means
shortage of labor required for farming and related activities as well
as a big risk for the family.
Options for livelihoods in Java
87
Local people are very often well aware of the options and limitations better than anybody else. A government project may open a
new option, but its adoption by people is determined by a variety of
factors. It is often reported that farmers follow guidance as long as
subsidies last. Researchers and extension workers should not be disappointed when they observe that not everybody is a progressive
farmer. Instead, such diversity in livelihood may be viewed as a
strength and safety net in marginal areas.
References
AIAT-Lembang. 1997. Monograf Sistem Usaha Tani Berbasis Pisang
Pada Lahan Kering di Jawa Barat. AIAT-Lembang, Lembang,
Indonesia (in Indonesian).
Booth, A. 1988. Agricultural Development in Indonesia. Allen &
Unwin Australia Pty Ltd, Sydney, Australia.
Goto, J. and Mayrowani, H. (Eds.). 2000. Learning from the Farming Systems Research Experiences in Indonesia: Proceedings
of Center for Agro-Socio-Economic Research-Japan International Research Center for Agricultural Sciences International Workshop 3-4 March, 1999, Bogor, Indonesia, JIRCAS
Working Report No. 18, JIRCAS, Tsukuba, Ibaraki, Japan.
Goto, J. and Mayrowani, H. 2001. Revisiting the farming systems
research in Indonesia: How to interpret the past twenty-five
years of history and how to move forward from here? Jurnal
Penelitian dan Pengembangan Pertanian (Indonesian Agricultural Research and Development Journal) 20: 113-124.
Goto, J. and Mayrowani, H. (Eds.). 2002. Potentials and Constraints
of Banana-based Farming Systems: A Case of an Upland
Village in West Java. JIRCAS working report No. 29,
JIRCAS, Tsukuba, Ibaraki, Japan.
Hayami, Y. and Kikuchi, M. 1981. Asian Village Economy at the
Crossroads: An Economic Approach to Institutional Change.
University of Tokyo Press, Tokyo.
Hugo, G. 2002. Indonesia’s Labor Looks Abroad. Migration Policy
Institute,
http://
hyperlink
“http://
www.migrationinformation.org/ Feature/display.cfm?ID=53”
www.migrationinformation.org/ Feature/display.cfm?ID=53
(viewed on July 9, 2003).
88
Goto
Husken, F. and White, B. 1989. Java: social differentiation, food
production and agrarian control. In: Hart, G., Turton, A. and
White, B. (Eds.). Agrarian Transformations: Local Processes
and the State in Southeast Asia, University of California Press,
Berkeley, pp. 235-265.
Huszar, P.C. 1997. Indonesia’s upland soil sprouts seeds of change.
Forum for Applied Research and Public Policy 12: 125-128.
McBeth, J. 1998. Return to roots: Indonesia could revive its battered
economy by funneling more resources into an old stand-by
food production. Far Eastern Economic Review 161: 64-65.
Thorbecke, E. 1992. Adjustment and Equity in Indonesia. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.
Van der Eng, P. 1996. Agricultural Growth in Indonesia: Productivity Change and Policy Impact since 1880. MacMillan Press
Ltd., London.
Download