MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change The Impact of Climate Policy on U.S. Aviation Niven Winchester, Christoph Wollersheim, Regina Clewlow, Nicolas C. Jost, Sergey Paltsev, John Reilly and Ian A. Waitz Report No. 198 May 2011 The MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change is an organization for research, independent policy analysis, and public education in global environmental change. It seeks to provide leadership in understanding scientific, economic, and ecological aspects of this difficult issue, and combining them into policy assessments that serve the needs of ongoing national and international discussions. To this end, the Program brings together an interdisciplinary group from two established research centers at MIT: the Center for Global Change Science (CGCS) and the Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research (CEEPR). These two centers bridge many key areas of the needed intellectual work, and additional essential areas are covered by other MIT departments, by collaboration with the Ecosystems Center of the Marine Biology Laboratory (MBL) at Woods Hole, and by short- and long-term visitors to the Program. The Program involves sponsorship and active participation by industry, government, and non-profit organizations. To inform processes of policy development and implementation, climate change research needs to focus on improving the prediction of those variables that are most relevant to economic, social, and environmental effects. In turn, the greenhouse gas and atmospheric aerosol assumptions underlying climate analysis need to be related to the economic, technological, and political forces that drive emissions, and to the results of international agreements and mitigation. Further, assessments of possible societal and ecosystem impacts, and analysis of mitigation strategies, need to be based on realistic evaluation of the uncertainties of climate science. This report is one of a series intended to communicate research results and improve public understanding of climate issues, thereby contributing to informed debate about the climate issue, the uncertainties, and the economic and social implications of policy alternatives. Titles in the Report Series to date are listed on the inside back cover. Ronald G. Prinn and John M. Reilly Program Co-Directors For more information, please contact the Joint Program Office Postal Address: Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change 77 Massachusetts Avenue MIT E19-411 Cambridge MA 02139-4307 (USA) Location: 400 Main Street, Cambridge Building E19, Room 411 Massachusetts Institute of Technology Access: Phone: +1(617) 253-7492 Fax: +1(617) 253-9845 E-mail: g lob a lch a n g e @mit.e d u Web site: h ttp ://g lob a lch a n g e .mit.e d u / Printed on recycled paper The Impact of Climate Policy on U.S. Aviation Niven Winchester*,†, Christoph Wollersheim‡, Regina Clewlow§, Nicolas C. Jost‡, Sergey Paltsev*, John Reilly* and Ian A. Waitz‡,** Abstract We evaluate the impact of an economy-wide cap-and-trade policy on U.S. aviation taking the American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 (H.R.2454) as a representative example. We use an economywide model to estimate the impact of H.R. 2454 on fuel prices and economic activity, and a partial equilibrium model of the aviation industry to estimate changes in aviation carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions and operations. Between 2012 and 2050, with reference demand growth benchmarked to ICAO/GIACC (2009) forecasts, we find that aviation emissions increase by 130%. In our climate policy scenarios, emissions increase by between 97% and 122%. A key finding is that, under the core set of assumptions in our analysis, H.R. 2454 reduces average fleet efficiency, as increased air fares reduce demand and slow the introduction of new aircraft. Assumptions relating to the sensitivity of aviation demand to price changes, and the degree to which higher fuel prices stimulate advances in the fuel efficiency of new aircraft play an important role in this result. Contents 1. INTRODUCTION...................................................................................................................... 1 2. MODELING FRAMEWORK.................................................................................................... 2 3. SCENARIOS.............................................................................................................................. 4 4. RESULTS .................................................................................................................................. 6 5. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS ..................................................................................................... 10 5.1 Aircraft Retirement Decisions .......................................................................................... 11 5.2 New Aircraft Fuel Efficiency ........................................................................................... 11 5.3 Income and Price Elasticities ............................................................................................ 12 6. CONCLUSIONS ...................................................................................................................... 12 7. REFERENCES ......................................................................................................................... 13 APPENDIX: LITERATURE REVIEW ....................................................................................... 16 1. INTRODUCTION Worldwide aviation is expected to grow by just under 5% per year for the next two decades (Airbus, 2009; Boeing, 2010). This growth will have environmental consequences via noise, air quality and climate impacts (Mahashabde et al., 2010). Potential mitigation methods include regulations and standards, technological improvements involving aircraft and engine performance and/or the development of alternative fuels, operational improvements, and marketbased policies. In regard to market-based policies, the House of Representatives recently passed the American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 (H.R. 2454, also known as Waxman* Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change, MIT, Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S.A. Department of Economics, University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand. ‡ Department of Aeronautics and Astronautics, MIT, Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S.A. § Engineering Systems Division, MIT, Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S.A. ** Corresponding author: Ian Waitz (Email: iaw@mit.edu) † 1 Markey Bill). H.R. 2454 proposes an upstream cap-and-trade policy to curtail greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. Such a policy would affect all U.S. industries, as refineries would be required to purchase allowances for each potential ton of carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions. In the long run, refiners will pass on these increased costs to consumers, such as airlines. Based on the specifications of H.R. 2454, this study analyzes the impact of climate policy on aviation operations, financial outcomes and emissions. The impact of cap-and-trade programs on aviation has been examined by several studies, which are summarized in Appendix 1. Most analyses focus on the emissions and economic impacts of the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS).1 Other studies, also with an EU-ETS focus, examine legal issues associated with including aviation in cap-and-trade programs (Oberthuer, 2003; Haites, 2009; Peterson, 2008), or the impact of climate policy on airline competition (Albers et al., 2009; Scheelhaase et al., 2010; Forsyth, 2008). To our knowledge, Hofer et al. (2010) is the only study to focus on the impact of a U.S. cap-and-trade policy. Hofer et al. (2010) uses a partial equilibrium model to simulate the environmental impacts of an assumed airfare increase. We contribute to this literature by analyzing the impact of a cap-and-trade policy on U.S. aviation using an economy-wide model and a detailed partial equilibrium model of the aviation industry. We use our economy-wide model to estimate the impact of a cap-and-trade policy (taking H.R. 2454 as a representative example) on the fuel price, the price of emissions allowances and the overall level of economic activity. Given these predictions, a partial equilibrium model is employed to estimate changes in aviation emissions and operations. To our knowledge, we are the first to analyze the impact of climate policy on aviation by combining a climate policy model and a detailed aviation model. This paper has five further sections. Our modeling framework is detailed in Section 2. Section 3 outlines the scenarios we consider. Modeling results are presented in Section 4. A sensitivity analysis is detailed in Section 5. The final section provides a short summary and conclusions. 2. MODELING FRAMEWORK Our analysis employs version 4 of the Emissions Prediction and Policy Analysis (EPPA) model (Paltsev et al., 2005) and version 4.1.3 of the Aviation Environmental Portfolio Management Tool for Economics (APMT-E, MVA Consultancy, 2009). EPPA is used to determine the economy-wide impacts of climate policy and, given predicted changes in key variables simulated by EPPA, APMT-E calculates the impact of climate policy on aviation emissions and operations. EPPA is a recursive dynamic, computable general equilibrium (CGE) model of the global economy that links GHG emissions to economic activity. The model is maintained by the Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change at the Massachusetts Institute of 1 See, for example, Anger (2010), Boon et al. (2007), Ernst & Young (2007), Hofer et al. (2010), Mayor and Tol (2010), Mendes (2008), Morrell (2007), Scheelhaase and Grimme (2007), Vespermann and Wald (2010) and Wit et al. (2005). 2 Technology, and has been widely used to evaluate climate policies (see, for example, Paltsev et al., 2007, 2009). EPPA models the world economy and identifies the U.S., 15 other regions and nine sectors, including electricity and refined oil. Reflecting EPPA’s focus on energy systems, electricity can be produced using conventional technologies (for example, electricity from coal and gas) and advanced technologies (for example, large scale wind generation and electricity from biomass). Advanced technologies enter endogenously when they become economically competitive with existing technologies. Refined oil includes refining from crude oil, shale oil, and liquids from biomass, which compete on an economics basis and can be used for transportation. EPPA is calibrated using economic data from the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) database (Dimaranan, 2006), energy data from the International Energy Agency (IEA, 2004), and non- CO2 GHG and air pollutant from the Emission Database for Global Atmospheric Research (EDGAR) 3.2 database (Olivier and Berdowski, 2001) and Bond et al. (2004). The model is solved through time, in five-year increments, by imposing exogenous growth rates for population and labor productivity. APMT-E is one of a suite of models developed by the Office of Environment and Energy at the Federal Aviation Administration (FAA) for assessment of aviation-related environmental effects. The model is designed to examine aviation industry responses to policy measures. APMT-E is a global model that determines operations for country pair-stage length combinations, known as schedules. Most country pairs have one stage length, but some country pairs involving large countries have more than one stage length. For example, the U.S.-UK country pair has five stage lengths, reflecting geographic disparity in U.S. points of departure or disembarkation. AMPT-E also identifies six world regions (North America, Latin America and the Caribbean, Europe, Asia and the Pacific, The Middle East and Africa), 23 route groups (for example, North Atlantic, Domestic U.S., North America-South America and Europe-Africa), nine distance bands (for example, in kilometers, 0-926, 927-1853, and 6483-8334), 10 aircraft seat classes defined by the number of available seats (for example, 0-19, 20-50 and 211-300) and two carrier types (passenger and freight). Aviation operations are determined in each year by retiring old aircraft based on retirement functions. The surviving fleet is then compared to forecast capacity requirements to determine capacity deficits by carrier region, distance band and carrier type. Potential new aircraft, which are combinations of available airframes, engines and seat configurations, are evaluated by calculating operational costs (including fuel, depreciation, finance and maintenance costs, and route and landing charges) per seat hour over the life of the aircraft. Once new aircraft are purchased to meet fleet deficits and added to the surviving aircraft, the fleet is deployed across schedules and operating costs are calculated. Assuming a constant cost markup, cost calculations are used to derive airfares, which are combined with route group price elasticities to compute demand. The constant markup assumption implies that all costs associated with a cap-and-trade policy are passed on to consumers. Although airlines may absorb some short-run cost increases, it is difficult to imagine an industry repeatedly absorbing cost increases to continue to operate, so a full pass-through assumption is commonly used in long-run assessments of the impact of cap3 and-trade policies on aviation (see, for example, Anger and Köhler, 2010). APMT-E price elasticities, sourced from Kincaid and Tretheway (2007), represent the average response of business and leisure travelers and vary by route group. Price elasticities range from -0.36 for the Transpacific route group to -0.84 for the Intra-European route group. After a solution is found, differences between actual and forecast demands are used to update demand projections for the next period. Our APMT-E reference scenario mainly follows ICAO/GIACC (2009). Traffic and fleet forecasts are from the Forecast and Economic Analysis Support Group (FESG) at the International Civil Aviation Organization (ICAO), adjusted by the short-term FAA Terminal Area Forecast (TAF). Aircraft fuel efficiency rises by 1% per year. Airspace management improvements driven by Next Generation (NextGen) High Density Analysis are first implemented in the U.S. and then in other regions with a five-year lag. NextGen improvements are assumed to result in detour reductions relative to great circle distances in the U.S. of 3% in 2015 and 10% in 2025. Corresponding decreases for non-U.S. regions occur in 2020 and 2030. Load factors, average stage lengths and aircraft retirement schedules are consistent with FESG forecasts used for the eighth meeting of the Committee on Aviation Environmental Protection (CAEP/8). The main influence of H.R. 2454 on aviation is likely to occur via the bill’s impact on the fuel price and the overall level of economic activity. Accordingly, in our policy scenarios, using output from EPPA, we change fuel prices and demand forecasts used by APMT-E. Guided by Gillen et al. (2002), we assume an income elasticity of demand of 1.4 to convert GDP changes estimated by EPPA into changes in aviation demand. As EPPA has a five-year time step and APMT-E is solved for each year, we use linear interpolation to generate annual series for EPPA predictions. 3. SCENARIOS We model climate policy in the U.S. using H.R. 2454 as representative cap-and-trade policy. The first major action by the U.S. Congress to address climate change, H.R. 2454 sets an economy-wide target for GHG emissions, measured in CO2 equivalent (CO2-e) units, released between 2012 and 2050.2 The chief emissions reduction instrument in H.R. 2454 is a cap-andtrade system that would cover between 85% and 90% of all U.S. emissions. Other provisions, such as efficiency programs, target emissions from uncovered sectors. Following Paltsev et al. (2009a, Appendix C), we simplify analysis of the policy by assuming that the cap-and-trade program applies to all sectors. The cap is gradually tightened through 2050. It is 80% of 2005 emissions (5.6 gigatons, Gt, of CO2-e) in 2020, 58% (4.2 Gt) in 2030, and 17% (1.2 Gt) in 2050. Under H.R. 2454, U.S. emissions may exceed the above targets if carbon offsets are used. Offsets allow businesses to support eligible offset projects, as determined by the Environmental 2 CO2-e units measure concentrations of other GHGs, such as methane and nitrous oxide, relative to the climate impacts of one unit of CO2 over a specified time period, usually 100 years. 4 Protection Agency (EPA), in lieu of turning in allowances. Offsets are restricted to 2 Gt – 1 Gt from domestic sources and 1Gt from international sources – per year. We consider two offset scenarios to capture uncertainties concerning the evolution of the market for offsets and the impact of competition from foreign cap-and-trade programs. In a “full offsets” scenario, 2 Gt of offsets are available each year at a specified cost. In a “medium offsets” case, we assume that the quantity of offsets available increases linearly from zero in 2012 to 2 Gt in 2050. Another provision in H.R. 2454, allowance banking, allows firms to over-comply in early years and bank the excess of allowances for use in later years. As the stringency of the emissions constraint increases over time in H.R. 2454, banking reduces compliance costs. When firms can bank allowances, optimal behavior will equate the discounted price of CO2 allowances across years. We assume a discount rate of 4%. We model climate policies in other regions following a recent Energy Modeling Forum scenario (EMF, Clarke et al., 2009). In the EMF scenario, developed nations (excluding the U.S.) gradually reduce emissions to 50% below 1990 levels by 2050, and China, India, the Former Soviet Union, and South America begin curtailing emissions in 2030. A difference between H.R. 2454 and climate policy in the EU is that H.R. 2454 requires energy producers, such as oil refineries, to turn in allowances while end users, such as airlines, are required to submit allowances in the EU-ETS. However, as we assume that costs are passed through to consumers, “upstream” and “downstream” policies produce identical results. Additionally, although allocation rules have distributional effects, in our analysis the value of emissions allowances represent windfall gains or losses, so allocation rules do not influence operating decisions. A contentious issue in the application of climate policy to aviation is how a nation’s climate policy will influence foreign carriers flying to and from that nation, as is evident from court action by the Air Transport Association (ATA) challenging the legality of requiring flights by U.S. airlines to and from the EU to purchase allowances under the EU-ETS. In our analysis, airlines pay carbon charges embedded in fuel prices, so airlines are influenced by foreign capand-trade programs when they uplift fuel abroad. For example, a U.S. airline flying to the EU pays the U.S. CO2-e price when uplifting fuel in the U.S. and the EU CO2-e price when refueling in the EU. In addition to CO2 emissions, aviation operations may influence climate via emissions of nonCO2 gases and soot and sulfate particles which alter the atmospheric concentration of GHGs. Although some additional effects contribute to warming and others to cooling, non- CO2 effects are believed to contribute to warming in aggregate (Penner et al., 1999; Lee et al., 2009). Aviation climate impacts from non- CO2 sources are sometimes characterized by a metric – known as a multiplier – that divides the total impact of aviation on climate by the CO2 impact. Although proposals requiring airlines to purchase allowances for non- CO2 effects have been discussed in policy circles, such as the European Parliament, it remains uncertain whether such measures will be applied. To capture these uncertainties, we consider multiplier coefficients of one and two. When the multiplier is one, non- CO2 effects are not considered, while a multiplier 5 of two is used to capture non- CO2 effects in our analysis. We refer to simulations employing a multiplier of one as “no aviation multiplier” scenarios and simulations with a multiplier of two as “aviation multiplier” scenarios. To reflect the increased scarcity of allowances in multiplier scenarios, we reduce economy-wide emissions caps based on estimates of the contribution of aviation to aggregate GHG emissions from Lee et al. (2009). To consider alternative offset and multiplier combinations, we implement four scenarios: full offsets with no aviation multiplier (F1), full offsets with an aviation multiplier (F2), medium offsets with no aviation multiplier (M1), and medium offsets with an aviation multiplier (M2). These scenarios capture a wide range of possible outcomes. The cap on cumulative emissions between 2012 and 2050 is 17% lower in full offset scenarios than in medium offset scenarios, and policy-induced aviation fuel price increases in multiplier scenarios are more than twice as large as fuel price increases in no multiplier scenarios. 4. RESULTS Table 1 reports per ton CO2-e prices ($/t CO2-e), measured in 2005 dollars, and proportional changes in GDP due to climate policy in three years: 2015, 2030 and 2050. In the F1 scenario, the emissions price is $7 in 2015 and rises by 4% (our assumed discount rate) per year so that the price reaches $13 by 2030 and $29 by 2050. In the medium offsets scenario without an aviation multiplier, M1, CO2-e prices are around three times larger than in the F1 scenario. In the two multiplier scenarios, F2 and M2, increased demand for allowances increases CO2-e prices relative to the corresponding no multiplier scenarios but only slightly (for example, in the medium offsets case, including an aviation multiplier increases the 2015 CO2-e price from $21.31 to $22.25). The treatment of the aviation multiplier also has a small impact on GDP changes, which range from -0.11% to -0.33% in 2015 and from -0.95% to -1.95% in 2050. As noted above, H.R. 2454 will result in income-induced aviation demand changes and raise fuel prices. Income-induced demand changes are estimated by multiplying GDP changes by 1.4, to reflect an underlying income elasticity of demand. The largest income-induced demand change, which occurs in scenario M2 in 2050, is 2.73%. Therefore, this effect is modest compared to the impacts on demand of changes in fuel prices. Proportional change in aviation fuel prices reflect the price of CO2-e emissions and the number of allowances that must be purchased per ton of emissions. In scenario F1, the price of aviation fuel increases by 4.7% in 2050 relative to the reference scenario, while the corresponding price increase in the M1 scenario is 26.7%. Fuel price changes in multiplier scenarios are more than twice as large as in corresponding non-multiplier scenarios, as the multiplier is applied to a higher CO2-e price than in no-multiplier scenarios. 6 Table 1. U.S. CO2-e prices (in 2005 dollars) and aviation fuel price and demand changes relative to the reference scenario. CO2-e price ($/t CO2-e) Scenario 2015 GDP-induced demand change (%) 2030 2050 2015 2030 2050 Fuel price change (%) 2015 2030 2050 F1 $7.27 $13.09 $28.69 -0.11% -0.43% -0.95% 5.83% 4.60% 4.74% F2 $7.79 $14.03 $30.74 -0.12% -0.48% -1.15% 12.50% 9.20% 18.10% M1 $21.31 $38.39 $84.07 -0.31% -1.01% -1.83% 17.50% 17.82% 26.72% M2 $22.25 $40.07 $87.08 -0.33% -1.09% -1.95% 36.67% 41.38% 65.09% How do changes in fuel prices influence aviation emissions and operations? Estimated annual aviation CO2 emissions for the period 2012-2050 under our reference and four policy scenarios are presented in Figure 1. In the reference scenario, CO2 emissions increase from 250 million metric tons (Mt) in 2012 to 580 Mt in 2050, a 130% increase. In policy scenarios, emissions trajectories are lower than in the reference case but absolute emissions continue to increase substantially over the policy period, by between 97% in the most stringent scenario (M2) and 122% in the least stringent scenario (F1). Thus, airlines respond to H.R. 2454 primarily by paying higher fuel prices rather than changing operations. This finding is consistent with other studies of the impact of climate policy on aviation emissions (see Anger, 2010; Mendes and Santos, 2008; Vespermann and Wald, 2010). Three explanations emerge for the small impact of H.R. 2454 on aviation emissions. First, the results indicate that aviation emissions mitigation options are more expensive than mitigation operations elsewhere. This is because, as fuel costs are a significant share, around 26% (IATA, 2010), of total aviation costs, airlines already operate closer to the fuel efficiency frontier than other industries. There is also limited scope for airlines to switch to alternative, low-emitting fuel sources compared to industries such as electricity, where coal can be replaced by several relatively inexpensive, low-carbon energy sources. In our EPPA simulations, the largest proportional reduction in sectoral emissions is observed for electricity in all scenarios. In the M1 scenario, electricity emissions fall by 60% relative to reference 2050 emissions. Second, despite large fuel price increases, demand changes induced by H.R. 2454 are small, as aviation demand is inelastic and the policy results in modest GDP changes. Third, as detailed below, the fleet becomes less fuel efficient in our policy scenarios than in the reference case. 7 650 600 550 [billion kg] 500 450 400 350 300 250 200 2 % Change vs. Reference [%] 0 -2 -4 -6 -8 -10 -12 -14 -16 -18 Reference F1 F2 M1 M2 Figure 1. Aviation CO2 emissions in the reference and policy scenarios, 2006-2050. 8 Our finding that H.R. 2454 reduces fleet efficiency warrants greater discussion. Fleet efficiency is gauged by fuel use per available ton kilometer (ATK). As there is a one-to-one mapping between fuel burn and CO2 emissions, proportional changes in fuel use equal proportional changes in CO2 emissions. Fuel use per revenue ton kilometer (RTK), which depends on load factors, is also informative, as this metric indicates fuel use per passenger kilometer. Changes in these variables induced by H.R. 2454 relative to the reference are presented in Table 2. In scenario M1, fuel per ATK increases by 0.2% in 2015, 0.5% in 2030 and 0.6% in 2050. Similarly, in other scenarios, H.R. 2454 increases fuel per ATK relative to the reference through time. Decreases in load factors, relative to the reference, are larger in 2015 than later years, as it takes some time for airlines to adjust aircraft stocks in response to demand changes. Load factor decreases are larger in more stringent scenarios than less stringent scenarios. Fuel use per RTK is influenced by fleet efficiency and load factors. The largest changes in fuel per RTK are observed for the M2 scenario, where fuel per RTK increase by 4.7% in 2015, 1.6% in 2030 and 2.3% in 2050, relative to the reference. Table 2. Changes in fuel use per ATK and per RTK, and load factors relative to the reference. Scenario ATK 2015 2030 RTK 2050 2015 2030 Load factor 2050 2015 2030 2050 F1 0.1% 0.2% 0.3% 1.0% 0.5% 0.5% -0.9% -0.3% -0.2% F2 0.2% 0.5% 0.7% 1.8% 1.2% 1.3% -1.6% -0.6% -0.6% M1 0.2% 0.5% 0.6% 2.4% 0.7% 1.2% -2.1% -0.3% -0.5% M2 0.5% 1.0% 1.4% 4.7% 1.6% 2.3% -4.1% -0.6% -1.0% We examine the drivers of our fleet efficiency results by displaying proportional changes in fleet size, average aircraft age and average aircraft size relative to the reference in Table 3. In all scenarios, fewer new aircraft are purchased relative to the reference, so the number of aircraft in the fleet decreases and aircraft age increases on average. As new aircraft tend to be larger than existing aircraft, average aircraft size also decreases. Thus, the decrease in fleet efficiency is not only driven by airlines flying older, less efficient aircraft, but also, when selecting from the same set of technologies as in the reference scenario, airlines purchasing smaller aircraft, which burn more fuel per ATK. In APMT-E, fleet efficiency changes are driven by two opposing forces: (i) rising fuel prices, which accelerate the introduction of new, more fuel efficient aircraft, and (ii) reduced demand, which slows the introduction of new aircraft. In our simulations, the demand effect dominates the fuel-price effect. 9 Table 3. Changes in the number of aircraft in the fleet, average aircraft age and average aircraft size relative to the reference. Scenario Number of aircraft Average age Average size 2015 2030 2050 2015 2030 2050 2015 2030 2050 F1 -0.5% -1.9% -4.2% 0.5% 0.4% 0.8% 0.0% -0.2% -0.7% F2 -1.2% -3.8% -8.3% 1.0% 0.8% 1.5% 0.0% -0.3% -1.1% M1 -1.9% -4.7% -8.7% 1.5% 1.0% 1.2% 0.0% -0.1% -0.3% M2 -3.7% -8.7% -16.0% 3.1% 1.6% 2.2% 0.0% -0.1% -0.3% A major concern for the aviation industry is the impact of H.R. 2454 on profitability. In this connection, the U.S. Air Transport Association (ATA) estimates that the bill would increase U.S. airline industry costs by $5 billion in 2012 and $10 billion in 2020 (Khun, 2009). Our results are in broad agreement with these numbers: estimated fuel cost increases range from $1.1 (F1) billion to $6.8 billion (M2) in 2012, and from $2.7 billion (F1) to $21.4 billion (M2) in 2020. However, cost increases in APMT-E are passed on to consumers via increased fares, so cost increases only influence profits via their impact on demand. To examine changes in financial viability of the aviation sector, we report changes in financial indicators relative to the reference in Table 4. Unit (per seat mile) operating costs are affected by rising fuel prices, decreased average efficiency, and reduced load factors. Consequently, unit operating costs increase by 1.9% in 2015, 2.9% in 2030 and 5.0% in 2050 in scenario F1, and larger cost increases are observed for scenarios with higher CO2-e prices. As expected, profit changes are negatively correlated with fuel price changes. The largest proportional profit decreases, for scenario M2, are 6.2% in 2015, 9.4% in 2030 and 17.1% in 2050, or (in 2006 dollars) $0.4 billion in 2015, $0.9 billion in 2030 and $2.9 billion in 2050. Table 4. Changes in total operating costs, unit costs and operating profits relative to the reference. Scenario Operating Costs 2015 2030 Unit Costs Operating Profits 2050 2015 2030 2050 2015 2030 2050 -0.2% -1.3% 1.9% 2.9% 5.0% -1.1% -2.5% -5.4% F1 0.5% F2 1.1% 1.2% 2.1% 4.0% 7.6% 15.6% -2.2% -5.0% -10.3% M1 1.3% 0.4% -0.3% 5.5% 6.4% 11.5% -3.2% -5.0% M2 2.9% 3.0% 11.5% 15.3% 29.8% -6.2% -9.4% -17.1% 4.8% -9.5% 5. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS An important finding in our analysis is that H.R. 2454 reduces fleet efficiency. In this section, we investigate the robustness of this result to key components of AMPT-E. Specifically, we examine the sensitivity of results to aircraft retirement decisions, aircraft fuel-efficiency improvements, and income and price elasticities. As above, proportional changes in fuel use per ATK relative to the reference scenario are used to measure efficiency changes. Table 5 reports 10 efficiency changes in 2015, 2030 and 2050 for our F1 scenario, for the base case and for each sensitivity analysis. Sensitivity results for other scenarios follow a similar pattern. Table 5. Changes in fuel use per ATK relative to the reference for the F1 scenario. Sensitivity scenario 2015 2030 2050 Base 0.10% 0.24% 0.27% Lower old aircraft survival probability 0.10% 0.21% 0.22% Higher new aircraft efficiency (reference & policy) 0.11% 0.27% 0.29% -0.44% -4.01% -10.63% 0.06% 0.19% 0.24% -0.40% -1.59% -2.69% Higher new aircraft efficiency (policy only) No income-induced demand change Zero price elasticity demand 5.1 Aircraft retirement decisions As noted in Section 2, aircraft retirements in APMT-E are based on FESG-CAEP8 retirement functions. Retirement curves are assumed to follow a Weibull distribution. Specifically, the probability that an aircraft of a certain age will survive in a given period under policy, ρpolicy, is: ρ 1 1 1⁄ρ 1 (1) e∆ where ρbase is the survival probability in the FSEG forecast, ∆C is the cost of flying the existing aircraft minus the cost of flying new aircraft, and λ is the sensitivity of the survival probability to cost differences. In a sensitivity analysis, we increase λ from 0.03 to 0.04, which decreases the survival probability of existing aircraft under climate policy, relative to our base F1 scenario. As illustrated in Table 5, earlier retirement of old aircraft decreases fuel per ATK relative to our base F1 scenario. However, changes in fleet fuel burn per ATK are small (fuel burn relative to the reference case increases by 0.21% in 2030 and 0.22% in 2050, compared to 0.24% in 2030 and 0.27% in 2050 in our base F1 scenario). 5.2 New aircraft fuel efficiency In another sensitivity analysis, we increase the scope for airlines to respond to rising fuel prices by purchasing new technologies. New aircraft fuel efficiency rises by 1% per year in APMT-E. In a sensitivity analysis, we impose a 1.5% annual fuel efficiency improvement, which we apply to both the reference and policy scenarios. With higher new aircraft efficiency, fuel use per ATK increases relative to the reference, as in our base F1 scenario. We also consider a sensitivity analysis where higher fuel prices induced by H.R. 2454 spur development of new technologies. In this analysis, new aircraft efficiency improves by 1.5% annually in the policy case and 1% annually in the reference case. In this case, unlike in our base scenario, fleet fuel efficiency increases relative to the reference – by 0.44% in 2015, 4.01% in 11 2030, and 10.63% in 2050. These efficiency changes are large, but not unexpected given that the growth rate for new aircraft efficiency is 50% larger in the policy scenario than in the reference. This simulation indicates the importance of technology responses to price changes. 5.3 Income and price elasticities H.R. 2454 slows the introduction of new aircraft by reducing the demand for aviation. Accordingly, in separate sensitivity analyses, we examine the impact of the income elasticity of demand and price elasticities of demand. In one analysis, we set the income elasticity of demand for aviation equal to zero, so GDP changes induced by climate policy do not influence aviation demand. Under such a scenario, fuel per ATK decreases relative to the base F1 scenario, but still increases relative to the reference scenario, by 0.24% in 2050. In another analysis, we set the price elasticity of demand for aviation equal to zero. Under this extreme price-response assumption, fuel use per ATK, relative to the reference, decreases by 0.40% in 2015, 1.59% in 2030 and 2.69% in 2050. 6. CONCLUSIONS We examined the impact of climate policy on aviation emissions and economic outcomes in the U.S.. Our analysis, benchmarked to ICAO/GIACC (2009) forecasts, estimated that aviation emissions between 2012 and 2050 will increase by between 97% and 122% under H.R.2454, compared to 130% without climate policy. These results indicate that aviation emissions abatement options are costly relative to mitigation options in other sectors. Key determinants of marginal abatement costs in APMT-E include the specification of new aircraft capital costs, fuel efficiency improvements, and retirement rates. Currently, there are limited opportunities for airlines to replace more CO2-intensive energy sources with less CO2-intensive energy sources, and to substitute between energy and other inputs. Another noteworthy finding is that, under the set of assumptions in our framework, GDP and fuel price changes induced by H.R. 2454 reduce fleet efficiency, as the demand effect outweighed the fuel-price effect. That is, the impact of reduced demand for aviation on new aircraft purchase decisions dominated incentives to purchase more efficient aircraft in the face of rising fuel prices. We examined the sensitivity of our results to several key modeling assumptions. In general, our finding that H.R. 2454 reduces average fleet efficiency is robust to plausible alternative modeling assumptions examined in our sensitivity analyses. However, our fleet efficiency results were overturned when we assumed that aviation demand was perfectly inelastic, and when we assumed that fuel price increases induced by H.R 2454 increased the fuel efficiency of new aircraft by 50%, relative to the reference scenario. Several caveats to our analysis should be noted. First, as we focused on long-run trends, adjustments associated with business cycles were not considered. In economic downturns, airlines may park old aircraft, which are replaced by new aircraft in high-growth periods rather than brought back into service. Second, our modeling framework did not capture some adjustments available to airlines using the existing fleet. For example, we did not allow airlines to retrofit seat configurations or use slower flight speeds in response to fuel price changes. Third, 12 we did not consider how changes in air traffic management, induced by climate policy, might improve operations and reduce emissions. When these adjustments are considered, climate policy may have a larger positive impact on fleet efficiency than in our study. Future research will focus on this. Acknowledgments The authors would like to thank Thomas Cuddy, Maryaclie Locke, Richard Hancox, Caroline Sinclair, Carl Tipton and Daniel Rankin for valuable input. Any errors are the sole responsibility of the authors. This work is funded by the U.S. Federal Aviation Administration Office of Environment and Energy under FAA Award Number: 06-C-NE-MIT, Amendment Nos. 018 and 028. The project is managed by Thomas Cuddy of FAA. The Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change is funded by the U.S. Department of Energy and a consortium of government and industrial sponsors (for a complete list, see http://globalchange.mit.edu/sponsors/current.html). Additional funding for Wollersheim was provided by the Erich-Becker Foundation. Any opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this material are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the FAA, NASA or Transport Canada. This report is also released as Partnership for AiR Transportation Noise and Emissions Reduction (PARTNER) Report No. PARTNER-COE-2011-001. 7. REFERENCES Airbus, 2009: Flying smart, thinking big, Global Market Forecast 2009-2028, Blagnac Cedex. Albers, S., J.A. Bühne, and H. Peters, 2009: Will the EU-ETS instigate airline network reconfigurations? Journal of Air Transport Management, 15(1): 1-6. Anger, A., and J. Köhler, 2010: Including aviation emissions in the EU ETS: Much ado about nothing? A review. Transport Policy, 17(2): 38-46. Boeing, 2010: Current Market Outlook 2009-2028. (http://active.boeing.com/commercial/forecast_data/index.cfm). Bond, T.C., D.G. Streets, K.F. Yarber, S.M. Nelson and J. Woo, 2004: A technology-based global inventory of black and organic carbon emissions from combustion. Journal of Geophysical Research, 109: D14203. Boon, B., M. Davidson, J. Faber and A. van Velzen, 2007: Allocation of allowances for aviation in the EU ETS – The impact on the profitability of the aviation sector under high levels of auctioning. A report for WWF UK, Delft, CE Delft, March 2007. Clarke, L., J. Edmonds, V. Krey, R. Richels, M. Tavoni and S. Rose 2009: International climate policy architectures: Overview of the EMF 22 international scenarios. Energy Economics, 31(S2): S64-S81. Dimaranan, B.V. (ed.) 2006: Global Trade, Assistance, and Production: The GTAP 6 Data Base. Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University. Ernst and Young, 2007: Analysis of the EC proposal to include aviation activities in the Emissions Trading Scheme, A report by Ernst and Young and York Aviation, York. Forsyth, P., 2008: The impact of climate change policy on competition in the air transport industry. Department of Economics, Monash University, Discussion paper No. 2008-18. 13 Gillen, D.W., W.G. Morrison and C. Stewart, 2002: Air travel demand elasticities: Concepts, issues and measurement, Final Report, Department of Finance, Canada. Haites, E., 2009: Linking emissions trading schemes for international aviation and shipping emissions. Climate Policy, 9(4): 415-430. Hofer, C., M.E. Dresner, and R.J. Windle, 2010: The environmental effects of airline carbon emissions taxation in the U.S.. Transportation Research Part D (Transport and Environment), 15: 37-45. IATA (International Air Transport Association) 2010: Fuel impact on operating costs (https://www.iata.org/pressroom/facts_figures/fact_sheets/Pages/fuel.aspx). ICAO/GIACC (International Civil Aviation Organization / Group on International Aviation and Climate Change), 2009: U.S. fuel trends analysis and comparison to GIACC/4-IP/1, Fourth Meeting of the Group on International Aviation and Climate Change, May 25 to 28, 2009, Montreal. IEA (International Energy Agency), 2004: World Energy Outlook: 2004. OECD/IEA: Paris. Khun, M., 2009: U.S. cap and trade scheme could cost billions: ATA, FlightGlobe, Sutton, UK. (http://www.flightglobal.com/articles/2009/05/28/327041/us-cap-and-trade-scheme-couldcost-billions-ata.html). Kincaid, I. and M. Tretheway, 2007: Estimating air travel demand elasticities, InterVISTAS. Lee D.S., D. Pitari, V. Grewe, K. Gierens, J.E. Penner, A. Petzold, M.J. Prather, U. Schumann, A. Bais, T. Bernsten, D. lachetti, L.L. Lim, R. Sausen, 2009: Transport impacts on atmosphere and climate: Aviation, Atmospheric Environment, In Press. (doi:10.1016/j.atmosenv.2009.06.005). Mahashabde, A., P. Wolfe, A. Ashok, C. Dorbian, Q. He, A. Fan, S. Lukachko, A. Mozdzanowska, C. Wollersheim, S. Barrett, M. Locke, and I. A. Waitz, 2010: Assessing the environmental impacts of aircraft noise and emissions. Progress in Aerospace Sciences, in Press. Mayor, K. and R.S.J. Tol, 2010: The impact of European climate change regulations on international tourist markets. Transportation Research Part D (Transport and Environment), 15: 26-36. Mendes, L.M.Z. and Santos, 2008: Using economic instruments to address emissions from air transport in the European Union. Environment and Planning A, 40(1): 189-209. Morrell, P., 2007: An evaluation of possible EU air transport emissions trading scheme allocation methods. Energy Policy, 35: 5562-5570. MVA Consultancy, 2009: Aviation Environmental Portfolio Management Tool (APMT): APMT-Economics. Algorithm Design Document (ADD), MVA Consultancy, London and Manchester. Oberthür, S., 2003: Institutional interaction to address greenhouse gas emissions from international transport: ICAO, IMO and the Kyoto Protocol. Climate Policy, 3: 191-205. Olivier, J.G.J. and J.J.M. Berdowski, 2001: Global emissions sources and sinks. In: The Climate System, J. Berdowski, R. Guicherit and B.J. Heij (eds.), A.A. Balkema Publishers/Swets & Zeitlinger Publishers, Lisse, The Netherlands, pp. 33-78. Paltsev, S., J. Reilly, H.D. Jacoby, R.S. Eckaus, J. McFarland, M. Sarofim, M. Asadooria and M. Babiker, 2005: The MIT Emissions Prediction and Policy Analysis (EPPA) Model: Version 14 4. MIT JPSPGC Report 125, August, 72 p. (http://globalchange.mit.edu/files/document/MITJPSPGC_Rpt125.pdf). Paltsev S., J. Reilly, H. Jacoby, A. Gurgel, G. Metcalf, A. Sokolov and J. Holak, 2007: Assessment of U.S. cap-and-trade proposals. Climate Policy, 8(4): 395-420; MIT Joint Program Reprint 2008-16; http://globalchange.mit.edu/files/document/MITJPSPGC_Reprint08-16.pdf. Paltsev S., J. Reilly, H. Jacoby, and J. Morris, 2009: The cost of climate policy in the United States. Energy Economics, 31(S2): S235-S243; MIT Joint Program Reprint 2009-16; http://globalchange.mit.edu/pubs/abstract.php?publication_id=2020. Penner J.E., D.H. Lister, D.J. Griggs, D.J. Dokken and M. McFarland, 1999: Aviation and the Global Atmosphere: A Special Report of IPCC Working Groups I and III, Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge/New York. Petersen, M., 2008: The legality of the EU’s stand-alone approach to the climate impact of aviation: the express role given to the ICAO by the Kyoto protocol. Review of European Community and International Environmental Law, 17(2): 196-204. Scheelhaase, J.D., and W.G. Grimme, 2007: Emissions trading for international aviation – an estimation of the economic impact on selected European airlines. Journal of Air Transport Management, 13(5): 253-263. Scheelhaase, J.D., M. Schaefer, W.G. Grimme and S. Maertens, 2010: The inclusion of aviation into the EU emission trading scheme – Impacts on competition between European and nonEuropean network airlines. Transportation Research Part D (Transport and Environment), 15(1): 14-25. Vespermann, J. and A. Wald, 2010: Much ado about nothing? – An analysis of economic impacts and ecologic effects of the EU-emissions trading scheme in the aviation industry. Transportation Research Part A, in press. Wit, R.C.N., B.H. Boon, A. van Velzen, M. Cames, O. Deuber, and D.S. Lee, 2005: Giving wings to emission trading – Inclusion of aviation under the European emission trading system (ETS): Design and impacts, CE Solutions for Environment, Economic and Technology, Report for the European Commission, Delft. 15 APPENDIX: LITERATURE REVIEW Several studies examine the impact of climate policy on aviation. To date, most papers focus on the EU-ETS. Some studies analyze the general implications of cap-and-trade schemes or carbon taxes. To our knowledge, only one study, Hofer et al. (2010), focuses on U.S. Table A1 summarizes the literature to date. Studies can be grouped into three categories: (1) papers focusing on aviation financial indicators and environmental benefits from reduced aviation emissions, (2) analyses of the competitive effects of carbon policies, and (3) studies that analyze legal and political aspects. Studies focusing on legal aspects include Haites (2009), Oberthuer (2003), and Peterson (2008). Studies examining the impact of climate policy on airline competition tend to analyze case studies (Albers et al., 2009; Forsyth, 2008; Scheelhaase et al., 2010). Papers that assess the financial and environmental implications of including aviation in climate policy either utilize existing models (Anger, 2010; Boon et al., 2007; Wit et al, 2005) or develop new models (Ernst and Young, 2007, Hofer et al., 2010; Mendes, 2008, Morrell, 2007, Scheelhaase and Grimme, 2007; Vespermann, and Wald, 2010). All studies in this group use an assumed allowance price, except Anger (2010), who uses a dynamic macroeconomic model. 16 Table A1. Studies evaluating the impact of climate policy on aviation. Methodology Scope Key Assumptions Key Findings Anger (2010) Dynamic macro. model EU-ETS Allowance prices €5-€40 per ton of CO2; full cost pass-through; efficiency improvements of 1% p.a. Air transport CO2 emissions decrease by up to 7.4%, relative to baseline in 2020. Boon et al. (2007) AERO-MS model EU-ETS Allowance prices €15 to €45; 47.3% to 100% cost pass-through in 2020. Evidence of perfect competition. Ernst & Young (2007) Simulation model EU-ETS Allowance prices €6- €60; 29% to 35% cost pass-through; fuel efficiency improvements of 1% p.a. Airline profits decrease by €40 billion over the period 2011 to 2022. Hofer et al. (2010) Simulation model Carbon tax on U.S. Aviation Air fare increase of 2%; price elasticity of -1.15; cross-price elasticity (air/car) of 0.041%. Five billion ton reduction in aviation emissions. Increase in vehicle emissions of 1.65 billion lbs (2,540 million additional passenger miles). Mayor and Tol (2010) Hamburg Tourism Model EU-ETS; Carbon taxes in some countries EU-ETS allowance price €23, full cost pass-through; carbon taxes of €11€45 in the Netherlands and €14- €54 in the UK. The three policies reduce global welfare by €12.6 billion. Tourists shift away from the taxed areas. Demand reductions due to EU-ETS less than 2%. Small supply-side emissions reductions due to high abatement costs. 17 Study Mendes and Santos (2008) Simulation model EU-ETS Allowance prices €7, €15, and €30, full cost pass-through. Morrell (2007) Three UK case studies EU-ETS Allowance price $40; full cost passthrough. Climate policy has a larger impact on low cost carriers than full service airlines. EU-ETS Allowance prices €15-€30; full cost pass-through; fuel efficiency improvements of 1% to 1.47% p.a. Small costs increases due to the EUETS compared to recent fuel price rises; the EU-ETS creates competitive distortions. Risk analysis software EU-ETS Allowance prices are normally distributed with an expected value of €25. The EU-ETS reduces the annual growth of CO2 emissions by about 1% per year; Small financial impacts on aviation; Small competition distortions. AERO-MS Model EU-ETS Allowance prices €10-€30; full/no cost pass-through; fuel efficiency improvements of 1% p.a. Industry-wide CO2 emissions reductions of 20-26 Mt (13%-22%) in 2012. Scheelhaase and Grimme (2007) Vespermann and Wald (2010) Wit et al. (2005) Simulation model REPORT SERIES of the MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change 1. Uncertainty in Climate Change Policy Analysis Jacoby & Prinn December 1994 2. Description and Validation of the MIT Version of the GISS 2D Model Sokolov & Stone June 1995 3. Responses of Primary Production and Carbon Storage to Changes in Climate and Atmospheric CO2 Concentration Xiao et al. October 1995 4. Application of the Probabilistic Collocation Method for an Uncertainty Analysis Webster et al. January 1996 5. World Energy Consumption and CO2 Emissions: 1950-2050 Schmalensee et al. April 1996 6. The MIT Emission Prediction and Policy Analysis (EPPA) Model Yang et al. May 1996 (superseded by No. 125) 7. Integrated Global System Model for Climate Policy Analysis Prinn et al. June 1996 (superseded by No. 124) 8. Relative Roles of Changes in CO2 and Climate to Equilibrium Responses of Net Primary Production and Carbon Storage Xiao et al. June 1996 9. CO2 Emissions Limits: Economic Adjustments and the Distribution of Burdens Jacoby et al. July 1997 10. Modeling the Emissions of N2O and CH4 from the Terrestrial Biosphere to the Atmosphere Liu Aug. 1996 11. Global Warming Projections: Sensitivity to Deep Ocean Mixing Sokolov & Stone September 1996 12. Net Primary Production of Ecosystems in China and its Equilibrium Responses to Climate Changes Xiao et al. November 1996 13. Greenhouse Policy Architectures and Institutions Schmalensee November 1996 14. What Does Stabilizing Greenhouse Gas Concentrations Mean? Jacoby et al. November 1996 15. Economic Assessment of CO2 Capture and Disposal Eckaus et al. December 1996 16. What Drives Deforestation in the Brazilian Amazon? Pfaff December 1996 17. A Flexible Climate Model For Use In Integrated Assessments Sokolov & Stone March 1997 18. Transient Climate Change and Potential Croplands of the World in the 21st Century Xiao et al. May 1997 19. Joint Implementation: Lessons from Title IV’s Voluntary Compliance Programs Atkeson June 1997 20. Parameterization of Urban Subgrid Scale Processes in Global Atm. Chemistry Models Calbo et al. July 1997 21. Needed: A Realistic Strategy for Global Warming Jacoby, Prinn & Schmalensee August 1997 22. Same Science, Differing Policies; The Saga of Global Climate Change Skolnikoff August 1997 23. Uncertainty in the Oceanic Heat and Carbon Uptake and their Impact on Climate Projections Sokolov et al. September 1997 24. A Global Interactive Chemistry and Climate Model Wang, Prinn & Sokolov September 1997 25. Interactions Among Emissions, Atmospheric Chemistry & Climate Change Wang & Prinn Sept. 1997 26. Necessary Conditions for Stabilization Agreements Yang & Jacoby October 1997 27. Annex I Differentiation Proposals: Implications for Welfare, Equity and Policy Reiner & Jacoby Oct. 1997 28. Transient Climate Change and Net Ecosystem Production of the Terrestrial Biosphere Xiao et al. November 1997 29. Analysis of CO2 Emissions from Fossil Fuel in Korea: 1961–1994 Choi November 1997 30. Uncertainty in Future Carbon Emissions: A Preliminary Exploration Webster November 1997 31. Beyond Emissions Paths: Rethinking the Climate Impacts of Emissions Protocols Webster & Reiner November 1997 32. Kyoto’s Unfinished Business Jacoby et al. June 1998 33. Economic Development and the Structure of the Demand for Commercial Energy Judson et al. April 1998 34. Combined Effects of Anthropogenic Emissions and Resultant Climatic Changes on Atmospheric OH Wang & Prinn April 1998 35. Impact of Emissions, Chemistry, and Climate on Atmospheric Carbon Monoxide Wang & Prinn April 1998 36. Integrated Global System Model for Climate Policy Assessment: Feedbacks and Sensitivity Studies Prinn et al. June 1998 37. Quantifying the Uncertainty in Climate Predictions Webster & Sokolov July 1998 38. Sequential Climate Decisions Under Uncertainty: An Integrated Framework Valverde et al. September 1998 39. Uncertainty in Atmospheric CO2 (Ocean Carbon Cycle Model Analysis) Holian Oct. 1998 (superseded by No. 80) 40. Analysis of Post-Kyoto CO2 Emissions Trading Using Marginal Abatement Curves Ellerman & Decaux Oct. 1998 41. The Effects on Developing Countries of the Kyoto Protocol and CO2 Emissions Trading Ellerman et al. November 1998 42. Obstacles to Global CO2 Trading: A Familiar Problem Ellerman November 1998 43. The Uses and Misuses of Technology Development as a Component of Climate Policy Jacoby November 1998 44. Primary Aluminum Production: Climate Policy, Emissions and Costs Harnisch et al. December 1998 45. Multi-Gas Assessment of the Kyoto Protocol Reilly et al. January 1999 46. From Science to Policy: The Science-Related Politics of Climate Change Policy in the U.S. Skolnikoff January 1999 47. Constraining Uncertainties in Climate Models Using Climate Change Detection Techniques Forest et al. April 1999 48. Adjusting to Policy Expectations in Climate Change Modeling Shackley et al. May 1999 49. Toward a Useful Architecture for Climate Change Negotiations Jacoby et al. May 1999 50. A Study of the Effects of Natural Fertility, Weather and Productive Inputs in Chinese Agriculture Eckaus & Tso July 1999 51. Japanese Nuclear Power and the Kyoto Agreement Babiker, Reilly & Ellerman August 1999 52. Interactive Chemistry and Climate Models in Global Change Studies Wang & Prinn September 1999 Contact the Joint Program Office to request a copy. The Report Series is distributed at no charge. REPORT SERIES of the MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change 53. Developing Country Effects of Kyoto-Type Emissions Restrictions Babiker & Jacoby October 1999 54. Model Estimates of the Mass Balance of the Greenland and Antarctic Ice Sheets Bugnion Oct 1999 55. Changes in Sea-Level Associated with Modifications of Ice Sheets over 21st Century Bugnion October 1999 56. The Kyoto Protocol and Developing Countries Babiker et al. October 1999 57. Can EPA Regulate Greenhouse Gases Before the Senate Ratifies the Kyoto Protocol? Bugnion & Reiner November 1999 58. Multiple Gas Control Under the Kyoto Agreement Reilly, Mayer & Harnisch March 2000 59. Supplementarity: An Invitation for Monopsony? Ellerman & Sue Wing April 2000 60. A Coupled Atmosphere-Ocean Model of Intermediate Complexity Kamenkovich et al. May 2000 61. Effects of Differentiating Climate Policy by Sector: A U.S. Example Babiker et al. May 2000 62. Constraining Climate Model Properties Using Optimal Fingerprint Detection Methods Forest et al. May 2000 63. Linking Local Air Pollution to Global Chemistry and Climate Mayer et al. June 2000 64. The Effects of Changing Consumption Patterns on the Costs of Emission Restrictions Lahiri et al. Aug 2000 65. Rethinking the Kyoto Emissions Targets Babiker & Eckaus August 2000 66. Fair Trade and Harmonization of Climate Change Policies in Europe Viguier September 2000 67. The Curious Role of “Learning” in Climate Policy: Should We Wait for More Data? Webster October 2000 68. How to Think About Human Influence on Climate Forest, Stone & Jacoby October 2000 69. Tradable Permits for Greenhouse Gas Emissions: A primer with reference to Europe Ellerman Nov 2000 70. Carbon Emissions and The Kyoto Commitment in the European Union Viguier et al. February 2001 71. The MIT Emissions Prediction and Policy Analysis Model: Revisions, Sensitivities and Results Babiker et al. February 2001 (superseded by No. 125) 72. Cap and Trade Policies in the Presence of Monopoly and Distortionary Taxation Fullerton & Metcalf March ‘01 73. Uncertainty Analysis of Global Climate Change Projections Webster et al. Mar. ‘01 (superseded by No. 95) 74. The Welfare Costs of Hybrid Carbon Policies in the European Union Babiker et al. June 2001 75. Feedbacks Affecting the Response of the Thermohaline Circulation to Increasing CO2 Kamenkovich et al. July 2001 76. CO2 Abatement by Multi-fueled Electric Utilities: An Analysis Based on Japanese Data Ellerman & Tsukada July 2001 77. Comparing Greenhouse Gases Reilly et al. July 2001 78. Quantifying Uncertainties in Climate System Properties using Recent Climate Observations Forest et al. July 2001 79. Uncertainty in Emissions Projections for Climate Models Webster et al. August 2001 80. Uncertainty in Atmospheric CO2 Predictions from a Global Ocean Carbon Cycle Model Holian et al. September 2001 81. A Comparison of the Behavior of AO GCMs in Transient Climate Change Experiments Sokolov et al. December 2001 82. The Evolution of a Climate Regime: Kyoto to Marrakech Babiker, Jacoby & Reiner February 2002 83. The “Safety Valve” and Climate Policy Jacoby & Ellerman February 2002 84. A Modeling Study on the Climate Impacts of Black Carbon Aerosols Wang March 2002 85. Tax Distortions and Global Climate Policy Babiker et al. May 2002 86. Incentive-based Approaches for Mitigating Greenhouse Gas Emissions: Issues and Prospects for India Gupta June 2002 87. Deep-Ocean Heat Uptake in an Ocean GCM with Idealized Geometry Huang, Stone & Hill September 2002 88. The Deep-Ocean Heat Uptake in Transient Climate Change Huang et al. September 2002 89. Representing Energy Technologies in Top-down Economic Models using Bottom-up Information McFarland et al. October 2002 90. Ozone Effects on Net Primary Production and Carbon Sequestration in the U.S. Using a Biogeochemistry Model Felzer et al. November 2002 91. Exclusionary Manipulation of Carbon Permit Markets: A Laboratory Test Carlén November 2002 92. An Issue of Permanence: Assessing the Effectiveness of Temporary Carbon Storage Herzog et al. December 2002 93. Is International Emissions Trading Always Beneficial? Babiker et al. December 2002 94. Modeling Non-CO2 Greenhouse Gas Abatement Hyman et al. December 2002 95. Uncertainty Analysis of Climate Change and Policy Response Webster et al. December 2002 96. Market Power in International Carbon Emissions Trading: A Laboratory Test Carlén January 2003 97. Emissions Trading to Reduce Greenhouse Gas Emissions in the United States: The McCain-Lieberman Proposal Paltsev et al. June 2003 98. Russia’s Role in the Kyoto Protocol Bernard et al. Jun ‘03 99. Thermohaline Circulation Stability: A Box Model Study Lucarini & Stone June 2003 100. Absolute vs. Intensity-Based Emissions Caps Ellerman & Sue Wing July 2003 101. Technology Detail in a Multi-Sector CGE Model: Transport Under Climate Policy Schafer & Jacoby July 2003 102. Induced Technical Change and the Cost of Climate Policy Sue Wing September 2003 103. Past and Future Effects of Ozone on Net Primary Production and Carbon Sequestration Using a Global Biogeochemical Model Felzer et al. (revised) January 2004 Contact the Joint Program Office to request a copy. The Report Series is distributed at no charge. REPORT SERIES of the MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change 104. A Modeling Analysis of Methane Exchanges Between Alaskan Ecosystems and the Atmosphere Zhuang et al. November 2003 105. Analysis of Strategies of Companies under Carbon Constraint Hashimoto January 2004 106. Climate Prediction: The Limits of Ocean Models Stone February 2004 107. Informing Climate Policy Given Incommensurable Benefits Estimates Jacoby February 2004 108. Methane Fluxes Between Terrestrial Ecosystems and the Atmosphere at High Latitudes During the Past Century Zhuang et al. March 2004 109. Sensitivity of Climate to Diapycnal Diffusivity in the Ocean Dalan et al. May 2004 110. Stabilization and Global Climate Policy Sarofim et al. July 2004 111. Technology and Technical Change in the MIT EPPA Model Jacoby et al. July 2004 112. The Cost of Kyoto Protocol Targets: The Case of Japan Paltsev et al. July 2004 113. Economic Benefits of Air Pollution Regulation in the USA: An Integrated Approach Yang et al. (revised) Jan. 2005 114. The Role of Non-CO2 Greenhouse Gases in Climate Policy: Analysis Using the MIT IGSM Reilly et al. Aug. ‘04 115. Future U.S. Energy Security Concerns Deutch Sep. ‘04 116. Explaining Long-Run Changes in the Energy Intensity of the U.S. Economy Sue Wing Sept. 2004 117. Modeling the Transport Sector: The Role of Existing Fuel Taxes in Climate Policy Paltsev et al. November 2004 118. Effects of Air Pollution Control on Climate Prinn et al. January 2005 119. Does Model Sensitivity to Changes in CO2 Provide a Measure of Sensitivity to the Forcing of Different Nature? Sokolov March 2005 120. What Should the Government Do To Encourage Technical Change in the Energy Sector? Deutch May ‘05 121. Climate Change Taxes and Energy Efficiency in Japan Kasahara et al. May 2005 122. A 3D Ocean-Seaice-Carbon Cycle Model and its Coupling to a 2D Atmospheric Model: Uses in Climate Change Studies Dutkiewicz et al. (revised) November 2005 123. Simulating the Spatial Distribution of Population and Emissions to 2100 Asadoorian May 2005 124. MIT Integrated Global System Model (IGSM) Version 2: Model Description and Baseline Evaluation Sokolov et al. July 2005 125. The MIT Emissions Prediction and Policy Analysis (EPPA) Model: Version 4 Paltsev et al. August 2005 126. Estimated PDFs of Climate System Properties Including Natural and Anthropogenic Forcings Forest et al. September 2005 127. An Analysis of the European Emission Trading Scheme Reilly & Paltsev October 2005 128. Evaluating the Use of Ocean Models of Different Complexity in Climate Change Studies Sokolov et al. November 2005 129. Future Carbon Regulations and Current Investments in Alternative Coal-Fired Power Plant Designs Sekar et al. December 2005 130. Absolute vs. Intensity Limits for CO2 Emission Control: Performance Under Uncertainty Sue Wing et al. January 2006 131. The Economic Impacts of Climate Change: Evidence from Agricultural Profits and Random Fluctuations in Weather Deschenes & Greenstone January 2006 132. The Value of Emissions Trading Webster et al. Feb. 2006 133. Estimating Probability Distributions from Complex Models with Bifurcations: The Case of Ocean Circulation Collapse Webster et al. March 2006 134. Directed Technical Change and Climate Policy Otto et al. April 2006 135. Modeling Climate Feedbacks to Energy Demand: The Case of China Asadoorian et al. June 2006 136. Bringing Transportation into a Cap-and-Trade Regime Ellerman, Jacoby & Zimmerman June 2006 137. Unemployment Effects of Climate Policy Babiker & Eckaus July 2006 138. Energy Conservation in the United States: Understanding its Role in Climate Policy Metcalf Aug. ‘06 139. Directed Technical Change and the Adoption of CO2 Abatement Technology: The Case of CO2 Capture and Storage Otto & Reilly August 2006 140. The Allocation of European Union Allowances: Lessons, Unifying Themes and General Principles Buchner et al. October 2006 141. Over-Allocation or Abatement? A preliminary analysis of the EU ETS based on the 2006 emissions data Ellerman & Buchner December 2006 142. Federal Tax Policy Towards Energy Metcalf Jan. 2007 143. Technical Change, Investment and Energy Intensity Kratena March 2007 144. Heavier Crude, Changing Demand for Petroleum Fuels, Regional Climate Policy, and the Location of Upgrading Capacity Reilly et al. April 2007 145. Biomass Energy and Competition for Land Reilly & Paltsev April 2007 146. Assessment of U.S. Cap-and-Trade Proposals Paltsev et al. April 2007 147. A Global Land System Framework for Integrated Climate-Change Assessments Schlosser et al. May 2007 148. Relative Roles of Climate Sensitivity and Forcing in Defining the Ocean Circulation Response to Climate Change Scott et al. May 2007 149. Global Economic Effects of Changes in Crops, Pasture, and Forests due to Changing Climate, CO2 and Ozone Reilly et al. May 2007 150. U.S. GHG Cap-and-Trade Proposals: Application of a Forward-Looking Computable General Equilibrium Model Gurgel et al. June 2007 151. Consequences of Considering Carbon/Nitrogen Interactions on the Feedbacks between Climate and the Terrestrial Carbon Cycle Sokolov et al. June 2007 Contact the Joint Program Office to request a copy. The Report Series is distributed at no charge. REPORT SERIES of the MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change 152. Energy Scenarios for East Asia: 2005-2025 Paltsev & Reilly July 2007 153. Climate Change, Mortality, and Adaptation: Evidence from Annual Fluctuations in Weather in the U.S. Deschênes & Greenstone August 2007 154. Modeling the Prospects for Hydrogen Powered Transportation Through 2100 Sandoval et al. February 2008 155. Potential Land Use Implications of a Global Biofuels Industry Gurgel et al. March 2008 156. Estimating the Economic Cost of Sea-Level Rise Sugiyama et al. April 2008 157. Constraining Climate Model Parameters from Observed 20th Century Changes Forest et al. April 2008 158. Analysis of the Coal Sector under Carbon Constraints McFarland et al. April 2008 159. Impact of Sulfur and Carbonaceous Emissions from International Shipping on Aerosol Distributions and Direct Radiative Forcing Wang & Kim April 2008 160. Analysis of U.S. Greenhouse Gas Tax Proposals Metcalf et al. April 2008 161. A Forward Looking Version of the MIT Emissions Prediction and Policy Analysis (EPPA) Model Babiker et al. May 2008 162. The European Carbon Market in Action: Lessons from the first trading period Interim Report Convery, Ellerman, & de Perthuis June 2008 163. The Influence on Climate Change of Differing Scenarios for Future Development Analyzed Using the MIT Integrated Global System Model Prinn et al. September 2008 164. Marginal Abatement Costs and Marginal Welfare Costs for Greenhouse Gas Emissions Reductions: Results from the EPPA Model Holak et al. November 2008 165. Uncertainty in Greenhouse Emissions and Costs of Atmospheric Stabilization Webster et al. November 2008 166. Sensitivity of Climate Change Projections to Uncertainties in the Estimates of Observed Changes in Deep-Ocean Heat Content Sokolov et al. November 2008 167. Sharing the Burden of GHG Reductions Jacoby et al. November 2008 168. Unintended Environmental Consequences of a Global Biofuels Program Melillo et al. January 2009 169. Probabilistic Forecast for 21st Century Climate Based on Uncertainties in Emissions (without Policy) and Climate Parameters Sokolov et al. January 2009 170. The EU’s Emissions Trading Scheme: A Proto-type Global System? Ellerman February 2009 171. Designing a U.S. Market for CO2 Parsons et al. February 2009 172. Prospects for Plug-in Hybrid Electric Vehicles in the United States & Japan: A General Equilibrium Analysis Karplus et al. April 2009 173. The Cost of Climate Policy in the United States Paltsev et al. April 2009 174. A Semi-Empirical Representation of the Temporal Variation of Total Greenhouse Gas Levels Expressed as Equivalent Levels of Carbon Dioxide Huang et al. June 2009 175. Potential Climatic Impacts and Reliability of Very Large Scale Wind Farms Wang & Prinn June 2009 176. Biofuels, Climate Policy and the European Vehicle Fleet Gitiaux et al. August 2009 177. Global Health and Economic Impacts of Future Ozone Pollution Selin et al. August 2009 178. Measuring Welfare Loss Caused by Air Pollution in Europe: A CGE Analysis Nam et al. August 2009 179. Assessing Evapotranspiration Estimates from the Global Soil Wetness Project Phase 2 (GSWP-2) Simulations Schlosser and Gao September 2009 180. Analysis of Climate Policy Targets under Uncertainty Webster et al. September 2009 181. Development of a Fast and Detailed Model of Urban-Scale Chemical and Physical Processing Cohen & Prinn October 2009 182. Distributional Impacts of a U.S. Greenhouse Gas Policy: A General Equilibrium Analysis of Carbon Pricing Rausch et al. November 2009 183. Canada’s Bitumen Industry Under CO2 Constraints Chan et al. January 2010 184. Will Border Carbon Adjustments Work? Winchester et al. February 2010 185. Distributional Implications of Alternative U.S. Greenhouse Gas Control Measures Rausch et al. June 2010 186. The Future of U.S. Natural Gas Production, Use, and Trade Paltsev et al. June 2010 187. Combining a Renewable Portfolio Standard with a Cap-and-Trade Policy: A General Equilibrium Analysis Morris et al. July 2010 188. On the Correlation between Forcing and Climate Sensitivity Sokolov August 2010 189. Modeling the Global Water Resource System in an Integrated Assessment Modeling Framework: IGSMWRS Strzepek et al. September 2010 190. Climatology and Trends in the Forcing of the Stratospheric Zonal-Mean Flow Monier and Weare January 2011 191. Climatology and Trends in the Forcing of the Stratospheric Ozone Transport Monier and Weare January 2011 192. The Impact of Border Carbon Adjustments under Alternative Producer Responses Winchester February 2011 193. What to Expect from Sectoral Trading: A U.S.-China Example Gavard et al. February 2011 194. General Equilibrium, Electricity Generation Technologies and the Cost of Carbon Abatement Lanz and Rausch February 2011 195. A Method for Calculating Reference Evapotranspiration on Daily Time Scales Farmer et al. February 2011 Contact the Joint Program Office to request a copy. The Report Series is distributed at no charge. REPORT SERIES of the MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change 196. Health Damages from Air Pollution in China Matus et al. March 2011 197. The Prospects for Coal-to-Liquid Conversion: A General Equilibrium Analysis Chen et al. May 2011 198. The Impact of Climate Policy on U.S. Aviation Winchester et al. May 2011 Contact the Joint Program Office to request a copy. The Report Series is distributed at no charge.