I Measurement of Productivity Improvements: An Empirical Analysis RAJIV D . BANKER* SRIKANT M . DATAR* MADHAV V. RAJ AN* In this paper, we test for productivity gains resulting from the introduction of a productivity-based incentive program in a large manufacturing plant of a Fortune 500 corporation. We develop a methodology based on a stochastic nonparametric frontier estimation technique to evaluate productivity in the postincentive plan period relative to the pre-incentive plan period. We also test for productivity gains using stochastic parametric frontier approaches. The results of both the nonparametric and parametric stochastic frontier analyses indicate that the incentive program has a positive effect on indirect labor, manufacturing services, and materials productivity and relatively little effect on direct labor productivity. 1. Introduction Productivity improvement and cost control have become key objectives of U.S. corporations in recent years. As a result, many corporations have introduced productivity improvement programs, especially productivitybased incentive payments to workers. The implementation and evaluation of the impact of such incentive programs have placed demands on management accountants to develop reliable measures of productivity and manufacturing efficiency—an issue largely ignored in the management accounting literature. The agency theory literature studies the motivational effects of providing incentives to woricers. The site at which a productivity-based scheme has recently b ^ n introduced serves as a natural experiment for testing the effect of an incentive contract intencted for improving labor productivity. Evaluation of its inqjact depends ontfjemettiod employed to measure productivity. Univosity 319 320 JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING, AUDITING AND FINANCE We use data from the site to compare conclusions drawn by altemative methods of measuring productivity about the impact of the incentive plan on productivity improvements. In our model, productivity measures the efficiency with which each of four inputs (direct labor, materials, indirect labor, and manufacturing support services) is consumed in producing two outputs. Accounting systems in practice are not geared to evaluating productivity. Simple input-output quantity ratios implicitly assume constant returns to scale (CRS) and the absence of multiple inputs and outputs. The use of input prices further obfuscates measures of productivity. Standard usage variances ignore indirect labor productivity and additionally assume linear and separable technologies. Advanced management accounting textbooks, such as Kaplan (1982), discuss ordinary least squares (OLS) approaches for estimating cost functions. This can be adapted for estimating production functions and improvements in productivity by regressing each input on the outputs produced and testing for decreases in input consumption in the' 'event'' period—the period after the introduction of the gain-sharing program. The specification of stochastic disturbance terms with zero means implies Ae estimation of an average production function. The theoretical definition of a production function expresses the minimum amount of each input to produce given outputs with a fixed technology. An ordinary least squares analysis is therefore inconsistent with a frontier production function that forms the core of microeconomic theory. This has led to the development and estimation of parametric frontier cost and production functions in the economics literature (see, for instance, Aigner and Chu [1%8] and Aigner, Lovell, and Schmidt [1977]). A weakness of such parametric fh)ntier estimation is its inability to theoretically substantiate or statistically test the maintained hypottiesis about the paran^tric form for the production function and the postulated distribution for the disturbance term. Furthennore, the restrictions imposed on the production correspondence by these hypottieses are not immediately apparent. We adopt an altemative nonparametric stochastic frontier estimation technique called Stochastic Data Envelopment Analysis that only imposes conditions of monotonicity and concavity on the production function, llie technique we employ is sufficiently general to allow for multiple inputs and ou^uts and for some of the inputs to be fixed. We examine these altemative n^thods of evaluating productivity using data from a large manufacturing plant that has recently establisted a productivity-based incentive compensation plan for its workers. Tlie plant manufactures traditional engineering products. It has gained a leadership position by providing quality products at low cost. Maintaining cost advantage I MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCTIVITY IMPROVEMENTS 321 through {M-oductivity improvements is critical in this mature, stable, competitive industry. The gain-sharing bonus scheme is an incentive to enhance labor productivity by sharing the financial gains from improved productivity with employees. Indirect plant labor and salaried staff are included in the plan to provide incentives for savings in the shop floor-related portion of indirect labor, including time spent on repairs and maintenance, equipment handling, set-ups, and inspection of set-ups. Strong links exist between methods discussed in this paper and those of traditional capital markets research. Although we specify a production economics model, as opposed to a financial economics one, we perform a variation of residual analysis based on an estimated standard. Patel (1976), for instance, estimates a referent market model for the relationship between firm and market returns and uses deviations from this as a measure of abnormal returns and thus the infonnation content of eamings forecasts. Similarly, we estimate a referent production set for the input-output correspondence and compute deviations from it to measure improvements in manufacturing productivity and thereby the impact of the incentive scheme. Further, we use the 0-1 variables technique as in Schipper and Thompson (1983) to identify productivity gains in different periods of interest relative to a common referent correspondence. The objective of our analysis is to describe a methodology to examine the productive impact of the gain-sharing scheme in the setting described; additional refinements to the methodology may be warranted based on the specific situation encountered by a researcher and his or her observations on the production process being studied. This paper has the following structure: In Section 2 we discuss the empirical setting of the problem and issues involved in obtaining and handling the data. Section 3 examines the merits and demerits of various economic models used to identify stochastic input consumption frontiers in order to measure deviations of actual input consumption from the frontier in the event period. We consider both parametric and nonparametric estimation techniques and describe the structure imposed and the corresponding estimation procedure employed. Section 4 discusses the results and interprets our findings. 2. Empirical Setting Our site is a manufacturing plant within a highly diversified Fortune 500 company. Productivity improvement is a key component of the division's comp^tive strategy. The division leads its industry in technological advancement and market share. It has secured and retained its position by iwoviding better quality and more reliable products at a lower cost than its 322 JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING, AUDITING AND FINANCE competition in a mature, no-growth industry. Productivity improvements are critical for long-run competitive advantage. Output prices are controlled by competitive maiket forces and reductions in input prices are generally available to competitors as well. Historically, the company has made great strides in productivity improvements, by producing more outputs with the same or lesser quantity of inputs, through technological innovation, and by efficient shop floor management rather than by substituting labor for capital. This fact is stressed by its chairman, who notes in the company's annual report that the company's strategy was to put "increased emphasis on new technology and new engineering capacity, training, product quality, productivity and cost reduction." Among management's stated "high-priority" areas were "applying technology to new and improved products and processes" and "improving quality, productivity and employee motivation." To continue this trend and to maintain its cost leadership, the company has embarked on a IKW campaign to improve productivity. The behavioral setting of our investigation is cost minimization. Production requirements are determined by the marketing department and taken as given by the manufacturing plant.* The plant's focus is on minimizing resource consumption while producing the outputs required. Productivity gains are manifested via reduced quantities of inputs required to produce specified quantities of outputs. Ilie particular plant we focus on is labor intensive with relatively stable capital. As a direct consequence of this nonemphasis on capital, depreciation accounts for only 3% of total costs and is a relatively minor item in the plant's monthly expense summary accounts. Direct labor, on the other hand, constitutes 20-25 percent of total expenses, and indirect labor and supervisory costs 25-30 percent. As part of its campaign to increase productivity, a gain-sharing program^ was instituted at the plant with benefits tied predominantly to improvements in labor efficiency. Hie gain-sharing plan includes indirect plant labor and salaried staff b(»:ause these elements are a significant percentage of t ( ^ labor costs and offer consider£d)le potential for {Hoductivity improvement. Including indirect labor in the gain-sharing arrangement also facilitates union negotiations because the incentive arrangement encompasses all wOTkers in tiie plant. We describe below the basic steps of the gain-sharing computation. Labor "pnxluctivity" in successive periods is computed relative to a base 1. If inpats and outputs are simultaneously determined, a simuhimeous equMions model must be estimated (see Zellaor. Kmetta, uid Droe {1966}). 2. The design <^ this gain-diaring program is discussed in detail in Baidta- and Datar (1987b). MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCTIVITY IMPROVEMENTS 323 period benchmaii^. The first step entails a computation of the standard direct labor hours in die base period (denoted by s^,) obtained by multiplying the standard direct labor hours per unit for each product (based on industrial engineering estimates) by the quantity of each product produced in the base period. The actual total labor hours (denoted by a^) including direct labor, indirect plant labor, and salaried staff hours are also computed for the base period. The ratio of actual direct and indirect labor hours to standard direct labor hours in the base period determines a base ratio (denoted by Tb — Ot/st,). In each subsequent nranth t, the ratio r, of actual total labor hours a, to the standard direct labor hours Sf (based on the direct labor content of products produced in period t) is computed. The gain-sharing fraction g, for period t is calculated as -^ = ~^. r, Values of ^, greater than one indicate a,l Sy "productivity" gains; values of g, less than one signal "productivity" declines. The gain-sharing agreement calls for woricers to be paid at base-period wage rates if g, in a period is less than one. When g, is greater than one, half of the "productivity" gains are paid to workers. For example if g, = 1.14, which signals a 14 percent increase in "productivity," each worker receives a bonus of 7 percent over the base wage or salary. Our objective is to identify increases in productivity in each of the four inputs in the 15 months following the program's introduction relative to the 33 months preceding it. Monthly data were available for a 48-month period labeled 1 through 48, with the gain-sharing program taking effect in month 34. Monthly data on the physical quantities of the two products produced were obtained firom plant production reports. The summary of manufacturing costs provided details of the actual number of direct and indirect labor hours employed each period. Gains in labor productivity are measured via reductions in hours worked. This provides a good measure of productivity because the mix of workers at various skill levels and pay levels has remained constant over the entire period of study. Productivity gains as reflected in a reduction of labor hours is achieved by employing fewer temporary laborers. Tht two [Hoducts manufacbired in the plant use a common metal which accounts for 90 percent of total raw material cost (which constitutes about 15-20 percent of total cost). We deflate material cost of production by the increase in material prices each period to obtain a constant-cost estimate of material consunqition. For miscellaneous manufacturing oveiiieads, we group several relatively minor costs such as power (about 3 pereent of t c ^ cost), gas (1-2 percent), perish^le tools and jigs (4 percent), and janitorial 324 JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING, AUDITING AND FINANCE services (1-2 percent) that represent important support services for the operation of the plant, under the single category of manufacturing support services (25-30 percent of full cost). We deflate the cost each period by appropriate indices, based on plant records and suppliers' bills, to obtain a constant-cost estimate of consumption of manufacturing services. The financial reporting focus of the accounting system required significant assumptions to be made in our analysis. The only information available with respect to material cost was the material cost of goods sold for each product. The material cost of production for each product is calculated by multiplying the (deflated) material cost of goods sold by the ratio of goods produced to goods shipped for each individual product. The total material cost of production is derived by aggregating material costs over all products. The material consumption data are thus noisy and approximate and our results with respect to material costs must be interpreted cautiously. There are four cost components: direct labor, materials, indirect labor, and manufacturing services. The stability and relative maturity of the manufacturing process limits the potential for improvement in materials and direct labor productivity. The input-output relationships including the noise and stochasticity in these relationships are well known, and management can control these costs on the basis of inputs consumed and outputs produced. Indirect labor and manufacturing services inputs, on the other hand, are discretionary in nature with no identified direct relationship between inputs and outputs. Consequently, these costs cannot be controlled by monitoring outputs and inputs. Instead, incentives need to be provided to influence the behavior and effort of workers. The labor-based gain-sharing program is an example of such an incentive. Consequently, we expect the gain-sharing program to result in improvements in indirect labor and possibly manufacturing services. The impact on manufacturing services is likely to be smaller because the program does not directly provide incentives to improve manufacturing services productivity. Nevertheless, the general focus on improving labor productivity may positively influence manufacturing services pnxluctivity as well. 3. Methodfrilogy for Testing the Impact of Productivity Improvement Programs In describing the methodology, we (tenote die' two out{Hits produced as yi and yz written in vector form as y = (yttyz)- The {^ysical inputs Xi, X2, X3, and X4 are denoted by the vector x = (jt,,X2,JC3,jC4) where JC, represents direct laixx, x^ indirect hSofX, x-^ materials consumption, aiMi X4 consumption of manufacturing wrvices. ITie [Htxluction technology at the pknt permits MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCTIVITY IMPROVEMENTS 325 little substitution among inputs. Because the plant is labor intensive, the capital employed is small and relatively constant over the period of our analysis. Similarly, material consumption cannot be reduced by substituting other inputs for materials. Our analysis of the production process indicated that the consumption of each input depends on only the quantity of outputs y, and )'2 produced and in particular is independent of the level of consumption of the other inputs. That is, Xi = fi(y,,y2) for all i = 1,2,3,4. Our objective is to evaluate if, after controlling for the outputs produced, input consumption in the post-gain-sharing period is less than the input consumption in the pre-gain-sharing period. The usual approach for testing for efficiency gains in the post-gainsharing period relative to the pre-gain-sharing period is to use a least squares regression by fitting prespecified functional forms for the correspondence between outputs and each input. Following the methodology of Schipper and Thompson (1983), dummy (0-1) variables representing the pre- and post—gain-sharing periods could be introduced to capture shifts in the relationships across these periods. For instance, specifying a loglinear relationship between each input and output y, and ^2 yields the following estimation model: [A] log Xi, = aoi + a,i log yi, -t- a2i log y^, + b A + ^a Vi=l,...4, t=l,...48 where D, = 0 for t = 1 , . . . 3 3 = 1 for t = 3 4 , . . . 48 The eleiments of Ci are assumed to be distributed i.i.d. N(O,CT^) and uncorrelated withji andy2- Significantly negative values ofbi indicate lower input costs Xi (and productivity gains with respect to input i) in the postgain-sharing period. Hiere are two important limitations in applying least squares techniques to estimate the input consumption relationship between each input Xi and the output prcKluced y = (y^ya). First, tiie regression-based approach estimates ibe average amount of input consumed to produce given levels of ouQmts, whereas the theoretical definition of a production function expresses the minimum amount of input for given levels of outputs. Moreover, from a managennnt ccmtrol perspo^ve, comparing future period input consunq)tion with theregressicm-basedestimated consumption indicates whether input consumption in tiie post-gain-sharing period has been less tiian av- 326 JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING, AUDITING AND FINANCE erage, rather than whether input consumption is lower than the best diat was achieved in die pre-gain-sharing period. Furthermore, least squares regression estimates assume that the disturbance term arises from an i.i.d. stochastic process so that deviations of actual observations from the estimated function are a s s u n ^ to result fiom random deviations. In reality, these deviations result from extemal random factors as well as inefficiencies of plant workers. Indeed, the productivity-based incentive plan is aimed at motivating workers to put in greater effort to reduce inefficiency and improve productivity. Second, regression-based parametric methods assumed a particular and often arbitrary functional form on die input-output correspondence. This problem is partly mitigated by assuming a flexible parametric relationship between inputs and outputs such as a translog or loglinear functional form. In die next section we provide a methodology to test for productivity gains assuming a loglinear stochastic production technology. 3.1. Parametric Stociiastic Frratier Estimatitm Estimating a frontier production function involves the specification of the error term as being made up of two components, one normal and die other from a one-sided distribution. That is, the error structure is given by: e,, = Vi, -f- Uu V i = 1 , . . . 4 and t = 1 , . . . 48. TTie error component Ui, represents a symmetric disturbance, where for each I, {UjJ are assumed to be independendy and identically distributed as N(O,(ji.). The error component Vj, is assumed to be distributed independently of «i, satisfying Vj, S: 0. In particular, {vJ are a s s u n ^ to be independently and identically distributed from a half-normal distribution Ar^(0,o^) trunc a t e below at zero. The logic untterlying this specification is that die production process is subject to two disturbances. Hie irannegative disturbance Vj, refl«;ts the condition that for each input the input consumption level must lie above the fircmtier (a minimum omsumption level) over all time periods. These deviations are attributable to factcvs umler the worker's control such as iiwfficiencies, wastage, die effort provicted by employees, and the extent of reworked, ctefective, and dmnaged products. For each i, die random disturbance term Ujt reixeseirts die stochastic nature of die frontier itself over time, v ^ much like d n random disdirbance term in a least square regression model. Hie Uj, t^m is the result of favtHabie as well as unfavtnable raiuknn extemal events not controllable at ihe plant level, such as rand(»n p^cnmance, iiKMtel specificioicm, and cm»s of ob%rvati<»i and MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCnVlTY IMPROVEMENTS INPUT OUTPUT Figure 1 of Composed Error Specification n:^asurement. Figure 1 distinguishes between average and frontier relationships and illustrates the notion of composed errors in the single-input and single-output case. The point M represents an ou^ut level of OL and input consumption of LM. Under ttie composed error model, the input consumption frontier level is estimated to be LN. The total deviation MN comprises the inefficiency component NP and a random effect PM which exceeds the level of inefficiency. The stochastic input p(»sibility frontier expresses the Pareto efficient input combinations necessary to {Hoduce specified vectors of outputs given die existing technology. Input consumption in excess of frontier levels is a reflectk»i of ii^fficiency in implementing production. Reducing the degree of inefficiency in production is an inqxntant motivation for the introduction of a gain-sharing {nt^ram. It could alternatively be argued that incentives 328 JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING, AUDITING AND FINANCE {»x)vided by the gain-sharing agreement induce new ways of organizing production and result in shifts in the input possibility frontier. We take the position that the input possibility frontier is not shifting (note that capital investment in technology is also relatively stable over the period of our fuialysis) and test whether the probability distribution generating the inefficiency terms decreases with the introduction of the gain-sharing program. Our objective is to examine if productivity in the 15 months following the gain-sharing program increases relative to the 33 months preceding it. Production inefficiencies are measured by the nonnegative disturbance term Vj, and represent deviations firom the frontier attributable to factors under the workers' control. Note that since for each i, Vj, is assumed to be independently and identically distributed from a half-normal distribution N^{O,ail,) truncated below at zero, any increase in productivity will decrease both the mean and the variance of the distribution of Vu (because the mean and variance of a half-normal distribution are not independent). One way to examine this is to test if v,, is distributed as half-normal A^^(O,CTVJ) for the 33-nionth pre-gain-sharing period and as N^(O,(TI — 80 for the 15month post-gain-sharing period. Assuming a loglinear relationship (or, alternatively, a translog function), we could proceed by estimating the following model: [B] log Xj, = aoi + au log y,, + azi log yz, + Cj,, i = 1 , . . . 4, t = 1 , . . . ,48 where €(, = Ui, -I- Vj, and Ui, ~ N(O,a^.) Vi, ~ N " ( 0 , a J . ) f o r t = l , . . . , 3 3 Vi, ~ N^(O,aJ. - 8i) for t = 3 4 , . . . ,48. Henceforth, cFy. is used to denote (TI. for observations 1—33 andCTJ.~ Si for observations 34—48. An approach to estimating the stochastic frontier production function models as in [B] discussed by Aigner, Lovell, and Schmidt (ALS) (1977) and Olson, Schmidt, and Waldman (OSW) (1980) is a maximum likelihood estimator (MLE). Following Weinstein (1964), the density function of €i for each i = 1 , . . . 4 is given by: wtere of = o^. + o^., Xj =CTv/o^Bjand f*() and F*(-) are tfie standard nonnal (tensity and distdbutiiHi functicms, reflectively. We tl^refore have: MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCTIVITY IMPROVEMENTS 329 that is. Ln fied = Ln - ^ -ITT The relevant loglikelihood function for all 48 observations is given by: Therefore, L ( ) = 48Ln IT CT 48 Ln[F* + tE = 34 33 V . 2 48 - 1 Ji - 8, where €i, = ln Xjt — doi — «» In ^u ~ fl2i In )'2f The loglikelihood function can then be maximized with respect to the unknown parameters Ooi, au, 021, (TIJ (TI. and 8i using a nonlinear search algorithm (such as Fletcher-Powell). A test of the null hypothesis of 8; = 0 would then provide evidence on productivity gains and reduction in inefficiency with respect to input i in the post-gain-sharing period. The maximum likelihood estimator of 6i is consistent and asymptotically efficient, but its finite sample distribution is not known. An alternative approach maintains somewhat different assumptions and it models the input-ou^t relationship as: [C] log Xi, = aa + au log y,, + a2i log y2, + €;, w t e r e €i, = Uj, -I- Vj, and uu ~ N(0,cr2.) fOT t = 1 , . . . ,33 wtere Vj, = vi -I- b, for t = 3 4 , . . . ,48. 330 JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING, AUDITING AND FINANCE Note that in model [B], the inefficiency terms V;,, both pre- and post-gain sharing, are drawn from a half nonnal distribution that ranges over [0,<»), with the post-gain-sharing distribution hypothesized to have a lower mean and, accordingly, a lower variance. In contrast, in model [C], pre- and post-gain-sharing inefficiencies are drawn from distributions with the same variance, but ranging over [8i,oo) and [0,«>),respectively,with 8; hypothesised (in the altemate hypothesis) to be positive. A positive value of Sj in model [C] indeed implies tiiat mean inefficiency is greater pre-gain sharing, but it also implies that, in every instance of the pre-gain-sharing period, there is inefficiency in input consumption, relative to frontier levels, of at least e^i. This is apparently a restrictive feature of this model. Model [C] is also consistent with an altemative set of maintained assumptions, namely, a neutral shift in the frontier unaccompanied by any shifts in the probability distribution from which the inefficiency terms arise. Of cotirse, this does imply that this model cannot be employed to distinguish between the two altemative sets of assumptions. Conversely, if tiiere is no a priori evidence to maintain one set of assumptions rather than the other, model [C] provides a robust formulation. The model in [C] can be estimated as: [C] log X,, = aoj + a,i log y,, + a2i log y2, - B A + Uj, -I- \„ where Uj, ~ V, ~ N"(O,aJ.) D, = O f o r t = l , . . . , 3 3 = 1 fort = 34, . . . , 4 8 . Hie maximum likelihood estimation technique discussed earlier can be employed to test the null hypothesis of Sj = 0 versus the altemative that 8^ >0. Stochastic frontier production function models as in [C] can also be estimated as discussed by ALS (1977) and OSW (1980) using a corrected ordinary least squares (denoted by CDLS) estimator. Hie COLS coefficients are obtained by estimating an ordinary least squares (OLS) regression for the composed error model in [ C ] . Except for the constant term, the OLS estimator is unbiased and consistent. Tlie bias of the constant term is the mean of €i = + \/2hT (Tyj. Consistent estimates of the variances l ^i can be obtained by: 4)il3i]^ and ^ = A-^i IT where |j4i and |i4i are the second and third monwnts of the OLS residuals. MEASUREMENT OF reODUCnVITY IMPROVEMENTS 331 A consistent COLS estimate of the constant term is obtained by subtracting \/5/iir dvi ftom the OLS estimate of the constant term. This COLS estimate, however, is not asymjHotically efficient and its finite sample distribution is unknown. In a Monte Carlo experiment designed to compare the COLS and MLE estimators mentioned above, OSW (1980) find diat die COLS estimator is more n»an square error (MSE) efficient for sample sizes 200 and below. At sample sizes of 400 and 800, die MLE is MSE efficient for estimating al., (TI., and a? but COLS is stUl superior for d,i and dj,. OSW (1980) could not reject the null hypothesis diat there is no difference in variance between MLE and COLS parameter estimates for any parameter for sample sizes greater dian 25. OSW (1980) conclude diat COLS and MLE techniques are both ai^licable in estimating parameters ofthe equation in [B] in moderately sized samples. The above discussion also suggests that the computationally simple COLS estimators are preferred to the MLE estimators in smaller samples. There is, however, one important problem widi the COLS estimator in diat the estimator may not exist (in a meaningful form) in some samples. This may happen in one of two ways. A "Type I " failure occurs if dv. is negative. The problem occurs when X; = a^./CTu^ is small. A "Type H" failure occurs when d^ < 0 and corresponds to die situation when X is large. This problem does not' exist in the case of MLE estimators because the MLE procedure simply maximizes the loglikelihood function widi respect to X and as reported by OSW (1980) provides unbiased estimates of a^, au, and Oii- Indeed, as the variance of o^. of the one-sided efficiency term increases, die MLE estimators dominate because die MLE mediodology takes die exact nature of the asymmetry of the distribution of the disturbance into account. Because we encounter situations in which the COLS estimators do not exist, we report the results of both die COLS and MLE estimations of each input on the ou^uts i»oduced. 3.2 N<Mq>anunrtric Stochietk Frontkr Estimation Although die paranwtric stochastic estimation of production frontiers described in Section 3.1 overcomes tte conceptual difficulties of estimating an averse relationship between inputs and outputs inherent in the usual regression analysis, it does assume a particular functional form for the production cOTtespomience airi the error stmcture. TTw statistical distributitms of the i»rameters are based on ttese assumed functional forms. Inferences based on die statistical tests are consequently conditional on die specification of tbe nKxlel ctwiectly reflecting the un(teriying 332 JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING, AUDITING AND FINANCE production relation (see Hildenbrand [1981], Varian [1984], and Banker and Maindiratta [1987]). But the choice of a particular functional form is difficult to justify on a priori grounds. This problem can be partially mitigated by using fiexible functional forms such as the translog that can be used to approximate various production functions. Unfortunately, these forms require the estimation of a large number of parameters relative to the 48 available observations. Furthennore, the underlying regularity conditions of monotonicity and strict quasi-concavity are violated at many points of most data sets, thus biasing inference; for a theoretical analysis of regularity conditions see Caves and Christensen (1980) and Bamett and Lee (1985). The problems inherent in parametric estimation can be overcome by estimating a nonparametric stochastic frontier using the approach of Stochastic Data Envelopment Analysis (SDEA) (see Banker [1986a]). This technique is an extension of Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA), which was introduced by Chames, Cooper, and Rhodes (1978). DEA is a nonparametric method for evaluating productivity which assumes only the regularity conditions of monotonicity ofthe prodtiction function and convexity ofthe input possibility frontier; it imposes no additional stmcttire on the specified functional form. Banker, Chames, and Cooper (1984) show its flexibility in modeling production operations in the presence of multiple outputs. The DEA approach has been used in a variety of empirical settings. Examples include program evaluation (Chames, Cooper, and Rhodes [1981]), evaluation of school district efficiencies (Bessent et al. [1983]), productivity measurement for manufacturing operations (Banker [1985]; Banker and Maindiratta [1986]), and tiie estimation of hospital production fimctions (Banker, Conrad, and Strauss [1986]). Some other settings in which the DEA technique has been employed are steam-electric power generation (Banker [1984]), coal mines (Bymes, Fare, and Grosskopf [1984]), pharmacy stores (Banker and Morey [1986a]) and fast-food restaurants (Banker and Morey [1986b]). DEA's limitation lies in the fact that it does not allow for the possibility of extemal random errors impacting the production process. Any difference between the actual input consumption and the estimated frontier level is therefore attributed to inefficiency. TTie SDEA model, on the otiier hand, allows for the possibility of random errors in model specification or measurement via a symmetric random error component, in addition to the onesicted deviations attributable to inefficiency in the use of input resources. TMs formulfttion for the error term resembles tte composed error specifications of the mo(tels of Aigner, Lovell, and Schmidt (1977) ar^ Meeusen and van det Broeck (1977) discussed in Secticm 3.1. The nonlinear maximum likelilKxxl estimation models require an a pricm MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCTIVITY IMPROVEMENTS 333 (and often arbitrary) specification of the parametric distributions of the two error terms. On the other hand, the linear programming-based formulation of SDEA requires the relative weights for the two types of deviations (or error terms) to be specified in the objective function. By varying the relative weights, we examine the sensitivity ofthe estimation results to the postulated importance of deviations due to inefficiency or external random factors. In fact, for specific extreme values of these weights, the model includes the traditional nonstochastic DEA model (in which all variations of actual values from the predicted frontier are attributed to inefficiency) and also the minimum absolute deviations (MAD) regression model (in which all variations of actual values from the predicted values are attributed to external random factors). Since the consumption of each input is independent of the consumption of other inputs, we employ the SDEA model to estimate a separate stochastic production frontier for each input i, that is, x, = f{y) relating the input consumed x, to the output vector y, with f:Y-^R where Y is the convex hull of y. We do not impose any parametric form on / and only assume that/i is monotonic and convex. We model the technological specification and the input possibility frontier for all inputs to be the same in the pre- and post-gain-sharing periods. Our objective is to examine if productivity of input consumption is greater in the post-gain-sharing period than in the pre-gain-sharing period. To do so, we split the data comprising 33 observations in the pre-gain-sharing period and 15 observations in the post-gain-sharing period into two sets of 24 observations each. The first set comprises all odd-numbered observations and includes 17 observations from the pre-gain-sharing period and 7 observations from the post-gain-sharing period. We refer to this sample as the estimation sample because this sample is used to actually estimate the stochastic nonparametric frontier for each input i.^ We then computed the efficiency scores for all observations in the second sample, referred to as the test sample, by comparing the estimated minimum input consumption with the actual input consumption. These efficiency scores are used to test whether productivity in the post-gain-sharing period is significantly greater than pnxiuctivity in the pre-gain-sharing period. The frontier values ii, = fi(yu, y^) are estimated by specifying the structure imposed on the deviations of ;Ci, from 4 . As in Section 3.1, the deviation Xn - 4 is expressed as the 3. We also re-eaimated tf» fhwlier using a random sample of 17 observations from the 33 pregain-sharing observations and 7 (*servati<»is ftran the 15 pmt-gain-shahng observations. The results were sinilm' to Ibose repcxted in detail hoe. 334 JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING, AUDITING AND FINANCE sum of two components; Vj, represents the excess of input i consumed in period t due to inefficiency and u,, represents the effect of random factors including specification and measurement errors. That is, Xi, - X,, = Vi, -I- Ui,. (1) Because Vj, measures input inefficiency relative to the input consumption frontier, Vi, is nonnegative and the symmetric term u,, is unconstrained in sign. Unlike the parametric stochastic frontier estimation of Section 3.1; no particular parametric form is assume for Uj and Vi. As in goal programming formulations, the symmetric error Un is expressed as: u., = Uit - UiT widi Ui^; Ui7 > 0, andSr=,Ui: = 2r.,Ui7 (2) (3) Therefore, Vi Xi, = Xi, = Vi, + Urt - Ui7 with Ui^. Ui7 > 0 , The stochastic, nonparametric input consumption frontier values Hi, = fi(y,,,y2,) are estimated by minimizing a weighted sum of different components of deviations subject to die monotonicity and convexity constraints. The monotonicity and convexity conditions for ii, = ^(y,) can be represented by inequality (4) as follows: For each t, i^i, — ii, S: Wi,(ys — yj for all s = 1,—n (4) where Wa is a nonnegative vector (see, for instance, Bazaraa and Shetty [1979] and Banker [1986a]). The intuition for (4) follows fitom die fact diat all points of a monotonic and convex function lie above die tangent hyperplane at any point t. Substituting (1) and (2) into (4) yields: x« - Xi, 2: Wi,(y, - yd + (Vis - Vj,) -I- (Ui^ ~ u^ - \i^ + u^) foralls=l,...,n. (5) For each input i, i= 1 , . . . ,4, the linear program to be solved is given by: [D] Minimize 2 ^ , (u^ -I- u^ subject to MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCTIVITY IMPROVEMENTS [D.I] [D.2] [D.3] 335 for e a c h t = l , . . . , 2 4 . x« - Xi. > Wi,(y, - y.) + (vu - v,,) -I- (Uit - Ui7 - u.t + Ui7) for all s = 1 , . . . ,24, s 7^ t 2 , ^ , (u,r - Ui7) = 0 Wi, > 0 , Vi,, Ui:,Ui, > 0 . TTie weight Cj > 0 in the objective function is a prespecified constant. Varying the value of c, gives different estimates of the production frontier values. Small values of Ci corresponds to greater weight being placed on the inefficiency term Vi, and for c, < - leads to the conventional DEA n formulation in which all variation is attributable to inefficiency. Increasing Ci increases the amount of variation attributed to the random factors reflected in the «i, terms and for Ci > 2 corresponds to MAD regression. By estimating the model for various values of c,, we are able to assess the sensitivity of the estimation to assumptions about the relative weights assigned to the different sources of deviations of actual values from estimated frontier values. In Figure 2, we illustrate the estimation of the production frontier corresponding to different values of c for the case of a single input and a single output. Here, for small values of Cj (< 0.2) we obtain tiie DEA estimates, which assume no random specification or measurement errors and the linear program estimates the minimum amount of input consumption for a given level of output assuming monotonicity and convexity. The frontier is computed based on available observations and without recourse to any a priori assumptions about the specific underlying functional form ofthe input-output correspondence. For each input, the input productivity measure in any period t is the ratio of the minimum amount of input for the level of output produced as determined by tiie estimated fr^ontier, and the actual input consumption in that period. Thus, for period 4 the productivity equals ABIAC. This DEA measure of productivity is a relative measure because it evaluates the productivity of any period relative to available observations subject to tiie conditions of monotonicity, convexity, and minimum extrapolation. For Ci = 0.8, the input consumption frontier is pulled upward because some of tte deviation of actual input consumption from estimated values is attributed to random stochastic factors rather than inefficiency alone. The inefficiency scores for various observations is, in general, lower. For still larger values of c,(Ci = 1.2), variations of actual from estimated values are entirely ^tributed to random factc»s and yield the MAD regression equation. TMs has tte effect of fiirtter pushing up tiie estimated input consumption function and reducing tite iirefficiency scores. Note, however, that the MAD 336 JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING, AUDITING AND FINANCE INPUT OUTPUT FIGURE 2 Estimation <tf Sto<^astic, Ntrnpanunetrk Input Consumption Function regression is a flexible, nonparametric formulation for estimating monotonic and convex functional correspondence of outputs and inputs and does not impose any parametric form for the production relationship. A stochastic, nonparan^tric frontier is e^imat^ for each input i and for each value Cj basc^ on the 24 observations in die estimation sample. Tliese yield estimates of d^ minimum amount of input consunq^cm ij, for given levels of o u ^ t s {yu,y-hi assuming a one-sided (feviation due to inefficiency Vjt imd a symmetric two-sided emn* conqx)nent u^ attributable to random factors including model specificaticm and nwasurement errors. E>ifferent values of Cj provide different weights on Vjt and u^. MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCnVITY IMPROVEMENTS 337 Productivity (efficiency) scores are then computed for each of the 24 observations in the test sample for each input i and for all values c, as the rado of the estimated consumption ii, and the actual consumption Xi,. The Mann-Whitney (1947), Welch (1937), and Kolmogorov-Smimoff (Conover [1980]) tests are used to examine if the average productivity of the 8 observations in the post-gain-sharing period is significandy greater than the average productivity of the 16 observations in the pre-gain-sharing period. The tests are run for all inputs i, / = 1 , . . . ,4 and all values of Ci. This enables a determinadon of the sensitivity of our conclusions to changes in the relative weights attributable to the random and inefficiency factors. Comparing the results ofthe nonparametric and parametric stochastic frontier analysis provides some insight into the robustness of our conclusions about the impact of the gain-sharing program at the particular site. In addition to estimating productivity measures for each of the inputs, we compute an overall measure of productivity for each period using a generalization ofthe Davis (1955) method. The overall productivity measure aggregates the individual input productivities in each period using the actual cost shares of the inputs in that period as weights."* The productivity of each input may be analyzed in terms of productivity variances analogous to direct material and direct labor usage variances in cost accounting.' The aggregation described above is equivalent to computing total variance for a period as the weighted sum of the individual input variances. If inputs are not separable, cost savings can be realized by subsdtuting one input for another in die event of changes in the relative prices of inputs. As in Banker (1985), we can compute two separate variances: an allocative variance that evaluates die ratio at which inputs are employed relative to their prices and a technical variance that examii^s the physical consumption of inputs reladve to the estimated firontier consumption for the given mix of inputs. The product of the two variances represents the aggregate variance. In the next section, we discuss and interpret our findings based on both a nonparametric and a parametric analysis of stochastic input consumption functions. 4. Results and Interpretatioiis Given the methodological advantages of nonparametric stochasdc fronder estimadon, we start by discussing the results of Stochasdc Data En4. WeiiJiting each input productivity by the share of tfiat input in total cost emphasizes gains in the most significimt ekments (tf total cost in the computation of total productivity. 5. Ualike vaHances, the n ^ measures described in this paper control for volume changes and laoss periods. I 338 JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING, AUDITING AND FINANCE velopment Analysis. Tables 1 through 5 contain the results of tests for differences in productivity scores in the pre- and post-gain-sharing periods for direct labor, indirect labor, materials, manufacturing services, and aggregate inputs. The one-sided Welch two-means test makes inferences on the relative magnitude of means in the two periods. The one-sided MannWhitney test measures die presence of significant differences in the locations of the underlying distributions in the pre- and post-gain-shMing periods. The Kolmogorov-Smimoff test evaluates a more general form of differences among productivity scores in the two periods. The alternative hypothesis is that productivity scores in periods after gain sharing "tend to be higher" than those before its introduction. Table 1 presents the results for direct labor productivity for various estimates of c that increases the weight on random deviations relative to the inefficiency component. The table indicates that direct labor productivity is not significantly different in the post-gain-sharing period relative to tiie pregajn-sharing period for all values of c. A likely explanation is the limited potential for improvement in direct labor productivity for a mature technology. The input-output relationship for direct labor is well documented and can be effectively monitored via engineering standards. Besides, improvements in direct labor productivity may be constrained by machineoperating constraints and strict quality-control standards in place at the plant. Results on the impact of the gain-sharing program on indirect labor productivity are presented in Table 2. Welch's two-means test, the MannWhitney test, and the Kolmogorov-Smimoff test indicate tiiat indirect labor productivity is significantly greater (at the 10 percent level) in the postgain-sharing period than in the pre-gain-sharing period. This basic conclusion is relatively st^le across all values of c. These results are consistent with our hypothesis that providing gain-sharing incentives influences workers' behavior and motivates tiiem to determine ways to increase productivity of indirect labor. The input-output relationship in Has. case of indirect labor is not directly identified, so that unlike direct labor, monitoring indirect labor productivity via engineering standards is considerably more difficult. Table 3 describes tiie results for materials productivity and indicates significant gains in materials productivity in the post-gain-sharing period. Although these gains could be attributed to reduced scrap, wastage, and reworic, the labor-tosed gain-sharing program does not directly motivate efforts to improve materials productivity. Morraver, mataials {ooductivity is more effectively controlled via evaluating materials consunoption requirements of the ou^uts produc»l. As indicate in Section 2, data on ti^ {riiysical units of materials consumed each period were •aot available and our results may be an artifact of the noise in our estimates (rf material MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCTIVITY IMPROVEMENTS 339 TABLE lA Welch's Two-Means Test on Direct Labor Productivity c=0.04 (DEA) 0 = 0.2 c = 0.4 0 = 0.6 0 = 0.8 0=1.0 (MAD) 95% Conf. Interval for Difference in Average Productivity r (Test Statistic) Degrees of Freedom Level of Significance (-0.109,0.088) (-0.109,0.088) (-0.109,0.088) (-0.116,0.108) (-0.112,0.109) (-0.119,0.122) -0.22 -0.22 -0.22 -0.08 -0.02 + 0.02 15.2 15.2 15.2 14.6 14.4 14.0 0.59 0.59 0.59 0.53 0.51 0.49 TABLE IB Mann-Whitney Test on Direct Labor Productivity 95.4% Cor^idence Interval Point Estimate for Difference in Average Prodttctivity -0.0093 -0.0093 -0.0093 0 0 -0.0017 o o o o o o o o o o o o 1 1 1 1 1 1 c = 0.04 (DEA) 0=0.2 0 = 0.4 0=0.6 0 = 0.8 0=1.0 (MAD) W (Test Statistic) Level of Significance 96 100 100 99 0.5 0.5 TABLE IC K<dmogorov-Snilm(^ Test tor Direct Labor Productivity T,* (Test Statistic) Level of Significance c = 0.04 (DEA) c=0.2 c = 0.4 c = 0.6 0.125 >0.10 0.125 >0.10 0.125 >0.10 0.187 >0.10 -0.8 0.187 >0.10 c=I.O (MAD) 0.187 >0.10 The difference in manufacturing services productivity in the pre- and post-gain-sharing period shown in Table 4 demonstrates some, though not significant, improvement in productivity. Manufacturing services productivity is di£ficult to monitor based on tiie quantity of services consumed and tHi^Hits produced, and providing incentives to influence behavior may be useful in motivating incieased efficiency. Ontiieother hand, the gain-sharing {Hognun focuses on labor productivity aloiK rather than total input productivity, and consequently provides no direct incentives for improving manufacturing services jwoductivity. Thus, although some improvement in jHoductivity is realized, tiiese gains are not significant. Tidde 5 describes changes in tiie overall jMtxiuctivity in the two periods based on an aggregation of individual input productivities. The table signals I 340 JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING, AUDITING AND FINANCE TABLE 2A Welch's Two-Means Test on Indirect Labor Productivity c = 0.04 (DEA) c = 0.2 c = 0.4 c = 0.6 c = 0.8 c=I.O c = 1.2 (MAD) 95% Conf. Interval for Difference in Average Productivity T (Test Statistic) Degrees of Freedom Level of Significance (-0.1,0.438) (-0.1,0.438) (-0.11,0.444) (-0.11, 0.451) (-0.12,0.467) (-0.12,0.48) (-0.12,0.493) 1.48 1.48 1.46 1.44 1.38 1.40 1.42 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.6 7.6 7.8 0.091 0.091 0.094 0.097 0.11 0.10 0.099 TABLE 2B Mann-Whitney Test on Indirect Labor Productivity Point Estimate for Difference in Average Productivity 95.4% Confidence Interval W (Test Statistic) Level of Significance 0.0753 0.0753 0.0859 0.0849 0.086 0.0834 0.0932 (0, 0.21) (0, 0.21) (0, 0.21) (-0.02,0.21) (-0.03,0.22) (-0.02,0.25) (-0.02,0.26) 130.5 130.5 131.5 128.5 119.5 123.5 125.5 0.0331 0.0331 0.0288 0.0432 0.1223 0.0795 0.0629 c = 0.04 (DEA) c = 0.2 c = 0.4 c = 0.6 c = 0.8 c=1.0 c = 1.2 (MAD) TABLE 2C Kolmogorov-SmimofF Test for Indirect Labor Productivity c = 0.04 c=0.2 (DEA) Tl (Test Statistic) Level of Significance 0.5 0.05 0.5 0.05 c = 0.4 c = 0.6 c=0.8 c = 1. (MAD) 0.5 0.05 0.437 0.10 0.375 0.437 >0.10 0.10 0.437 0.10 gains in aggregate productivity since introduction of the gain-sharing program. This reflects the weights assigned to individual input productivities (based on the actual cost shares of various inputs) in computing aggregate productivity as well as the productivity gains experienced by indirect labor, materials, and to a lesser extent manufacturing services. We next compare the results of the nonparametric analysis with the conclusions based on a parametric estitimticm of the input consumption function. Using mo<tel [C], tl^ latter requires a jKinuneiric specification of the functional relationship between iapats and o u ^ t s as well as distiibutional assumptions about the random error term and inefficiency conqtoi^nts. 341 MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCTIVITY IMPROVEMENTS TABLE 3A Welch's Two-Means Test on Materials Productivity c = 0.04(DEA) c = 0.2 c = 0.4 c=0.6 c = 0.8 c=1.0 c= 1.2 (MAD) 95% Conf. Interval for Difference in Average Productivity T (Test Statistic) Degrees of Freedom Level of Significance (0.032, 0.245) (0.032. 0.245) (0.022. 0.248) (0.022.0.251) (0.015. 0.264) (0.011.0.301) (0.010. 0.305) 2.71 2.71 2.49 2.48 2.34 2.29 2.27 22 0 22.0 21.7 21.3 19.5 16.2 16.0 0.0065 0.0065 0.011 0.011 0.015 0.018 0.019 TABLE 3B Mann-Whitney Test on Materials Productivity Point Estimate for Difference in Average Productivity 95.4% Confidence Interval W (Test Statistic) Level of Significance 0.163 0.163 0.1591 0.1566 0.1395 0.1694 0.1686 ( 0.001.0.25) ( 0.001.0.25) (-0.002. 0.276) (-0.002,0.280) (0. 0.3) (0.002. 0.331) (0. 0.322) 133 133 131 129 133 134 133 0.0233 0.0233 0.0309 0.0405 0.0233 0.0201 0.0233 c = 0.04(DEA) c = 0.2 c = 0.4 c = 0.6 c = 0.8 c=1.0 c= 1.2 (MAD) TABLE 3C Kolmogorov-SmirnofF Test for Materials Productivity c = 0.04 c = 0.2 (DEA) T,* (Test Statistic) Level of Significance 0.562 0.025 0.562 0.025 = 0.4 c = 0.6 c = 0.8 c=1.0 c=1.2 (MAD) 0.5 0.05 0.5 0.05 0.5 .05 0.562 0.025 0.437 0.10 In Tables 6A and 6B we describe the COLS and MLE estimates assuming a translog production function that includes as special cases the CobbDouglas and CES functional forms. Table 6A indicates productivity gains significant (at the 5% level) in indirect lahor, materials, and manufacturing services (see estimates of 5,). The asymptotic f-statistics should be interpreted cautiously because the sample size is 48 and small sample distributions of COLS are not known. Many of the coefficients on ttie loglinear and logquadratic (translog) terms are not significant, arguably due to multicollinearity among the independent variables. Furttermore, as discussed by Caves and Christensen (1980) and 342 JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING, AUDITING AND FINANCE TABLE 4A Wekh'!s Two-Means Test cta Maniifactoring Services ProdiKtivity 0 = 0.04 (DEA) 0 = 0.2 0 = 0.4 0 = 0.6 0 = 0.8 0 = 1 . 0 (MAD) 95% Conf. Interval for Difference in Average Productivity' TfTest Statistic) Degrees of Freedom Level cf Significance (-0.15,0.376) (-0.15,0.376) (-0.15,0.380) (-0.15,0.381) (-0.16,0.387) (-0.16,0.414) 0.% 0.96 0.96 0.95 0.96 0.97 10.1 10.1 9.8 9.7 9.6 lO.l 0.18 018 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18 TABLE 4B Mann-Whitney Test on 1Vfanufacturing Services Productivity Point Estimate for Difference in Average Productivity 95.4% Cor^idence Interval W (Test Statistic) Level of Significance 0.0712 0.0172 0.0807 0.0766 0.0766 0.0957 (-0.06,0.21) (-0.06,0.21) (-0.05,0.23) (-0.05,0.23) (-0.05,0.22) (-0.07,0.29) 119.5 119.5 117.5 116.5 115.5 116.5 0.1223 0.1223 0.1489 0.1636 0.1792 0.1636 0 = 0.04 (DEA) 0 = 0.2 0 = 0.4 0 = 0.6 0 = 0.8 0 = 1 . 0 (MAD) TABLE 4C Kolmogorov-Smimoff Test for Manufacturing Services Productivity T,* (Test Statistio) Level of Signifioanoe 0 = 0.04 (DEA) 0 = 0.2 0 = 0.4 0=0.6 0.313 >0.10 0.313 >0.10 0.313 >0.10 0.313 >0.10 0 = 0.8 0.313 >0.10 0=1.0 (MAD) 0.375 >0.10 Bamett and Lee (1985), the regularity conditions of monotonicity and strict quasi-concavity are often violated at many points of data sets. Etesides, the translog form requires the estimaticHi of a large number of parameters relative to the 48 available observsrtions. In addition, the COLS estimation suffers from "Type I" failure for direct labor, indirect labor, and materials as discu^ed by Olson, Schmidt, and Waidman (1980), because tl^ third mrni^ot of the OLS residuals is positive, implying tiiat a , is negative. Hie bias of 0.073 in die i n t e n d term in the case of manufacturing %rvices is cfHiected using tiie n^tiKxloIogy described in Section 3. In order to overconw tiie "Type I" failure in the COiJS estimatkm, we also estimate the translog infmt consuroiHion function using Maximum Like- NfEASUREMENT OF PRODUCnVlTY IMPROVEMENTS 343 TABLE SA Welch's Two-Means Test on OveraO Productivity 95% Conf. Interval for Difference in c = 0.04 (DEA) c=0.2 c=0.4 0=0.6 c = 0.8 c=1.0 c= 1.2 (MAD) Average Productivity T(Test Statistic) Degrees of Freedom Level of Significance (-0.064,0.293) (-0.064,0.293) (-0.068,0.297) (-0.072,0.304) (-0.077,0.316) (-0.078,0.336) (-0.078,0.341) .45 .45 .42 .40 .37 .41 .42 9.5 9.5 9.3 9.3 9.1 9.2 9.2 0.091 0.091 .094 0.097 0.10 0.096 .095 TABLE SB Mann-Whitney Test on Overall Productivity Point Estimate Average Productivity 95.4% Confidence Interval W (Test Statistic) Level of Significance 0.0904 0.0904 0.0928 0.0852 0.0799 0.0894 0.0914 (-0.012,0.191) (-0.012, 0.191) (-0.015,0.194) (-0.022,0.204) (-0.024,0.222) (-0.012,0.242) (-0.020 0.242) 126.5 126.5 129.5 128.5 126.5 129.5 129.5 0.0557 0.0557 0.0379 0.0432 0.0557 0.0379 0.0379 for Difference in c = 0.04 (DEA) c = 0.2 c=0.4 c = 0.6 c=0.8 c=1.0 c= 1.2 (MAD) TABLE SC for Overail Productivity = 0.2 c = 0.4 c = 0.6 c = 0.8 c= I (DEA) T|* (Test Statistic) Level of Significance 0.437 0.10 (MAD) 0.437 0.10 0.437 0.10 0.437 0.10 0.437 0.10 0.437 0.10 0.50 0.05 lihood Estimation (MLE). This is done using the program LIMDEP (see Greene [1985]). The results reported in Table 6B are very similar to the COLS estimation with consumption of indirect labor, materials, and manufacturing services significantly lower in the post-gain-sharing period (see estinuttes of 5) resulting in greater productivity and efficiency. It is interesting to note that the MLE estimate of <Ty, turns out to equal zero in the case of direct labor, indirect l^x>r, and materials. Consequently, for these inqputs, tte COLS estimates are maximum likelihood resulting in identical panaaster estimates in T^les 6A and 6B. results of the translog model are difficult to interpret in a straight- 344 JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING, AUDITING AND FINANCE TABLE 6A Estimates of the Translog COLS Model log X, = ao, + a,i log y,, + a^, log y,, + a,, (log y,,)' + a* (log ya)' + %, (log y,,) (log y^) - 8,D, + e, where i = l , . . . , 4 ; t = l 48, and €„ = !!„ + v«. u. ~ N(0, o i ) , v, ~ N*(0, aid Estimates ao a, aj a3 a, as 8 Estimate of Bias in Intercept Direct Labor Indirect Labor Materials Cost Manitfacturing Services 16.697 (1.98) -2.891 (-1.37) -0.102 (-0.12) 0.305(2.07) 0.057 (1.77) -0.067 (-0.63) -0.013 (-0.61) 33.990~ (3.24) -7.072~ (-2.69) -0.529 (-0.50) O.537~ (2.93) 0.031 (0.76) 0.037 (0.28) -7.793 (3.02) -13.980 (-0.72) 3.747 (0.77) 1.201 (0.61) -0.271 (-0.79) -0.139 (-1.86) 0.107 (0.43) 0.162~ (3.24) 1.182 (0.40) 1.900 (1.59) 0.170 (0.82) 0.081 (1.80) -0.406~ (-2.73) 0.065~ ( 2.16) — — — 0.073 0.08r Figures in parentheses indioate t-statistios. The superscript ~ indicates a ooeffioient signifioant at the 5% level. TABLE 6B Estimates of the Translog MLE Model log X, = aa + a,, log y,, + aj. log y^ + a,, (log y,,)' + a4, (log ya)' + a,, (log y,,) (log y j - 8,D, + e,, where i = l , . . . , 4 ; t = l , . . . , 4 8 , and €, = u,, + V,. u, ~ N(0, ai), v, ~ N*(0, al,) Estimates Direct Labor Indirect Labor Materials Cost Mantrfacturing Services 16.697 (1.98) -2.891 (-1.37) -0.102 (-0.12) 0.305(2.07) 0.057 (1.77) -0.067 (-0.63) -0.013 (-0.61) 33.t«6~ (3!24) -7.072~ (-2.69) -0.529 (-0.50) O.537~ (2.93) 0.031 (0.76) 0.037 (0.28) 0.081(3.02) -13.975 (-O.72) 3.747 (0.77) 1.201 (0.61) -0.271 (-0.79) -0.139 (-1.86) O.tO7 (0.43). 0.162" (3.24) -5.S76 (-0.32) 1.075 (0.22) 1.552 (1.21) 0.137 (0.42) 0.067 (I.M) -0.331(-2.06) 0.047~ (1.96) Figures in {HuentlKses indioate t-statistios. The superscript — indicates a ooefficwnt significant at the 5% tevel. MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCTIVITY IMPROVEMENTS 345 TABLE 7A Estimates of the LogUnear COLS Model log X, = aa -I- a,, log y,, -I- aj, log y^ - 8 A + e,, where i = l , . . . ,4; t = l , . . . ,48, and e. = u, + v,. u, ~ N(0, a^), v« ~ N*(0, al,) Estimates Direct Labor Indirect LtUmr Materials Cost Manufacturing Services 3.638" (10.97) 0.725" (16.34) 0.213" (8.47) -0.008 (-0.36) 6.988" (16.76) 0.352" (6.32) 0.135" (4.28) 0.093" (3.35) -0.449 (-0.61) 0.842" (8.56) 0.0514 (0.92) 0.164~ (3.36) -0.024 Estimate of Bias in Intercept 0.641" (9.99) 0.237" (6.54) 0.073" (2.27) 0.105 Figures in parentheses indicate t-statisdcs. The superscript ~ indicates a coefficient significant at the 5% level. TABLE 7B Estimates of the LogUnear MLE Modei log x, = ao, + a,, log y,, + a,, log y^ - 8 A + e, where i = l 4; t = l 48, and e. = u. -H V. u. ~ N(0, ai), v» ~ N*(0, aid Estimates Direct Labor Indirect Labor Materials Cost Manitfacturing Services 3.638" (10.97) 0.725" (16.34) 0.213~ (8.47) 6.988" (16.76) 0.352" (6.32) 0.135" (4.28) 0.093" (3.35) -0.449 (-0.61) 0.842" (8.56) 0.051 (0.92) 0.164" (3.36) 0.412 (0.75) 0.644" (10.27) 0.201" (5.32) 0.062" (2.12) (-0.36) Figures in {xirentheses indicate t-statisdcs. The superscript ~ indicates a coefficient significant at the 5% level. forward manner because of the presence of second-order terms. Further, as noted earlier, the results are adversely affected by multicollinearity among the indepen^nt variables and the large number of parameters estimated relative to available oteervations. To provide a partial resolution to these issues, we estim^e a restiicted form of the translog, the logline^ functional form. TTie results, described in Tables 7A and 7B, sue very similar to those obtaiiKd in tiw more general translog model. The gain-sharing agreement 346 JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING, AUDITING AND FINANCE has a positive impact on productivity of indirect labor, materials, and manufacturing services. Once again the COLS estimations presented in Table 7A suffer from "Type I " failure due to negative estimates for av. The loglinear form is re-estimated using MLE (see Table 7b) and yields estimates very similar to those obtained using COLS. In the cases of' 'Type I'' failures, MLE estimates av to equal zero. The results of the nonparametric and parametric stochastic frontier analyses are remaricably similar. They suggest that the gain-sharing progr^n has a positive effect on indirect labor, manufacturing services, and materials productivity and relatively little effect on direct labor. Our conclusions appear to be robust to the assumed functional forms ofthe input consumption functions although we are somewhat skeptical about the reliability of the materials consumption data. Nevertheless, the consistency ofthe parametric analysis with the stochastic nonparametric estimation increases the degree of confidence in our analysis. REFERENCES 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. Aigner. D. J.. C.A.K. Lovell, and P. J. Schmidt. "Formulation and Estimation of Stochastic Frontier Production Models." Journal of Econometrics (19T7). pp. 21-37. Aigner. D. J.. and S. F. Chu, "On Estimating the Industry Production Function," American Economic Review (1968). pp. 826-839. Banker. R. D.. "Estimating Most Productive Scale Size Using Data Envelopment Analysis." European Journal of Operational Research (July 1984). pp. 35-44. Banker. R. D.. "Productivity Measurement and Management Control," in The Management of Productivity and Technology in Mamrfacturing. P. Kleindorfer (ed.) (New Yoric: Plenum, 1985). Banker, R. D.. "Stochastic Data Envelc^ment Analysis," Camegie Mellon University, mimeo (1986a). Banker. R. D.. "Maximum Likelihood. Consistency and Data Bivelopment Analysis." Carnegie Mellon University, mimeo (1986b). Banker. R. D., A. Chames, and W. W. Co<^r, "Models for the Estimation of Technical and Scale Inefficiencies in Data Envelopment Analysis." Management Science (September 1984), pp. 1078-1092. Banker. R. D., and A. Maindiratta. "Piecewise Loglinear Estimation of Efficient Production Surfaces." Management Science (January 1986), pp. 126-135. Banker. R. D.. and A. Maindiratta. "Nonparametric Analysis of Technical and Allocative Efficiencies in Production," Econometrica, in press (1987). Banker. R. D., and R. C. Morey. "Efficiency Analysis for Exogenousiy Fixed Inputs and Outputs." Operations Research (1986a), pp. 513-521. Banker, R. D., and R. C. Morey, "Data Enveic^Mnent Analysis with OtfegcHica] Inputs and Outputs." Management Science (December 1986b), i^. 1615-1627. Banker. R. D., R. F. Conrad, and R. P Strauss, "A Cm^karative Af^licalion of DEA and Translog Methods: An Illustrative Study of Hospital Production," Management Science (January 1986), pp. 30-44. Banker, R. D., and S. M. DaJar, ProductivityAccomtingfiirMimt^tmingOperations, research monograph commissioned by the American Accounting Association, in ptcss (1987a). Banker, R. D., and S. M. Datar, "Accounting fm Ldx>r Productivity in Manufacturing Operalmas: An Apfdicitfiai," in Field Studies in Management AcoomUing and ConOxA, W. Brans and R. Ka|4an (eds.), (Cambrid^, Mass.: Harvad Business School Press, forthcoming [1987b]). Bamett, W. A., and Y. W. Lee, "The Global Prcqxsrties of the Minflex Laurent, Genoalized Lemtief and Traiisl<^ FlexiMe Functicnal Fffltns," Ectmometrica (1985), RI. 1421-1437. MEASUREMENT OF HiODUCTIVITY IMPROVEMENTS 16. 347 Bazaraa, M. S., and C. M. Shetty, Nonlinear Programming: Theory and Applications (New Yoric: Wiley, 1979). 17. Bessent, A., W. Bessent, J. Kennington, and B. Reagan, "An An>lication of Mathematical Programming to Assess Productivity in the Houston Independent School District," Management Science (December 19S2), pp. 1355-1367. 18. Byrnes, P., R. Fare, and S. Grosski^f, "Measuring Productivity Efficiency: An Application to Illinois Strip Mines," Management Science (June 1984), pp. 671-681. 19. Caves, D. W., and L. R. Christensen, "Global Properties of Flexible Functional Forms," American Economic Review (1980), K>. 422-432. 20. Chmnes, A., W. W. Cooper, and E. Rhodes, "Measuring the Efficiency of Decision-Making Units," European Journal of Operational Research (1978), pp. 429-444. 21. Chames, A., W. W. Cooper, and E. Rho(fes, "Evaluating Program and Managerial Efficiency," Management Science (June 1981), pp. 668-697. 22. Conover, W. J., Practical Nonparametric Statistics (New Yoilc: Wiley, 1980). 23. Davis, H. S., Productivity Accounting, The Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania, Industrial Research Unit (1955). (Reprint 1978.) 24. Gieene, W. H., "LIMDEP" (New York, 1985). 25. Hildenlwand, W.,"Short-run Production Functions Based on Micro-data," Econometrica (September 1981), pp. 1095-1125. 26. K^lan, R. S., Advanced Management Accounting (Ea^viooACX\fk, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1982). 27. Mann,M. B.,andD. R. Whitney, "On a Test of Whether One or Two Variables is Stochastically Larger Than the Other," Annals of Mathematical Statistics (1947). 28. Meeusoi, W., and J. van der Broeck, "Efficiency Estimation from Cobb-Douglas Production FuncdcMis with Composed Error," Intemational Economic Review (1977), |^. 435-444. 29. Olson, J. A., P. J. Schmidt, and D. M. Waldman, "A Monte Carlo Simuladon of Esdmators of Stochastic Frontier Producdon Funcdons," Journal cf Econometrics (1980), pp. 67-82. 30. Patell, J. M., "Corporate Fmecasts of Eamings per Share and Stock Price Behavior," Journal of Accounting Research (1976), pp. 246-276. 31. Richmond, J., "EstimatingtheEfiiciencyofProducdon,"/n/erna(iona/£cono/Ric/?evi>H'(l974), K>. 515-521. 32. Schii^jer, K., and R. Thompson,' 'The Impact of Merger-Related Reguladons on the Shareholders of Acquiring Firms," Journal of Accounting Research (1983), pp. 184-221. 33. Varian, H., "The Nonparametric Af^noach to Production Analysis," Econometrica (1984), I^. 579-597. 34. Weinsein, M. A., '"Vas Sum of Values fh>m a Normal and a Truncated Nonnal Distribution," Technometrics (1964), {^. 104-105. 35. Welch, B. L., "Tte Significance of the Difference between Two Means When the Population Variances Are Unequal," Biometrika (1937), pp. 350-62. 36. Zellner, A., J. Kmento, and J. Dreze, "Specificadon and Esdmadon of Cobb-Douglas Production FuDcdon Moifels," Econometrica (1966), pp. 784-795.