Applied Financial Economics Letters, 2006, 2, 189–192 Hedging or speculation in derivative markets: the case of energy futures contracts Cetin Ciner Cameron School of Business, University of N. Carolina – Wilmington, Wilmington, NC 28403, USA E-mail: cinerc@uncw.edu This study examines whether hedging or speculation is the principal motive behind trading in energy futures markets. This question is important since facilitating risk allocation is considered to be one of the main benefits of the futures markets, while excess speculation in futures markets could destabilize the underlying spot market. Studying the linkage between volume and subsequent price movements leads to the conclusion that hedgers dominate speculators in all of the markets examined. I. Introduction An important benefit of futures markets to society, along with price discovery, stems from the facilitation of risk allocation (hedging). While many empirical studies focus on the accuracy of price discovery, few papers provide evidence on the relative importance of hedging versus speculation as the main form of trading activity in futures markets.1 This bifurcation is important because futures markets are sometimes portrayed as forums where informed traders can fleece unsophisticated investors, leading to regulatory attempts to control the amount of trading in futures markets.2 Furthermore, if speculators dominate the futures markets, it could be argued that futures market trading might destabilize underlying spot markets. Thus, the amount of risk allocation, relative to speculation, is important to regulators and policy makers. Ederington and Lee (2002) report on the first study that examines who actually trades in a major futures market. They document the trading activities of the 223 largest traders in the heating oil futures market, who account for almost 80% of the total trading volume and open interest. They show that potential hedgers, defined as traders who have positions on both spot and futures markets, dominate the trading activity. The present study further investigates whether hedging or speculation is more prevalent in energy futures (crude oil, heating oil and unleaded gasoline) markets by relying on a relatively new approach 1 The main reason why there is little empirical work is data limitation. To determine whether futures markets properly facilitate hedging, hedgers need to be segregated from speculators in total market activity. In prior work, researchers, such as Wang (2003), de Roon et al. (2000), Chang et al. (2000) and Bessembinder and Senguin (1993), use the commercials versus non-commercials classification by the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) to disaggregate total market activity into hedgers and speculators. 2 Chang et al. (2000) report that over 100 bills have been introduced to lower or even abolish the amount of trading in futures markets, although almost always the attempt was unsuccessful. Applied Financial Economics Letters ISSN 1744–6546 print/ISSN 1744–6554 online ß 2006 Taylor & Francis http://www.tandf.co.uk/journals DOI: 10.1080/17446540500461729 189 C. Ciner 190 by Llorente, Michaely, Saar and Wang (2002, LMSW).3 Their model, which is discussed further below, suggests that trading volume on a financial market acts as a signal to market observers about whether hedging or speculation is the main motive to trade. They conduct an empirical investigation of their model using US stock market data and find supportive evidence. Moreover, Lucey (2005) and Ciner and Karagozoglu (2004) apply the model in Irish and Turkish equity markets, respectively.4 However, this is the first study to focus on the futures markets within the LMSW framework. In empirical analysis, the study shows that days with high trading volume are followed by price reversals (negative return autocorrelations) in all three energy futures contracts, namely, the crude oil, heating oil and unleaded gasoline futures. This finding suggests that hedging is relatively more important than speculation as the main motive to trade in energy futures markets, which is perfectly consistent with the conclusions of Ederington and Lee (2002). II. Background and Hypotheses LMSW propose a simple equilibrium model to examine the relation between trading volume and price movements in asset markets. Their model suggests that returns are generated by three separate sources: public information, hedging and speculation. It is assumed that public news causes only a white noise component, while returns generated by hedging and speculation are serially correlated. Hedging trades do not reflect new information and the expected payoff from the asset remains the same. Hence, the asset must be sold at a discount to attract other traders to take the other side of the transaction. Price rises back to its original level in the next period, since the fundamental value is unchanged. In a hedging trade, therefore, an initial negative return is followed by a positive return in the second period, generating negative return autocorrelations. Speculative trades, on the other hand, are caused by the asymmetric information of informed traders. LMSW argue that private information will be only partially incorporated into prices in the current period and therefore, prices will continue to change in the same direction in the next period. Consequently, speculative trades generate positive return autocorrelations. Volume has a prominent role in the LMSW model. Specifically, LMSW argue that volume can be used to distinguish between price changes due to public information and those due to hedging or speculation. Public news is incorporated into prices via normal trading, while hedging and speculative trades are characterized by extensive volume. Hence, as stated in the introduction, the central implication of the LMSW approach is that high volume days will be followed by price reversals, when hedging is the primary motive to trade, however, price continuations will be observed when speculation is the primary motive. This proposition can be examined by estimating the following equation: Rt ¼ þ 0 þ 1 Vt1 þ 2 V2t1 þ 3 h1=2 t1 Rt1 þ ut ð1Þ in which Vt denotes log volume series, Rt denotes returns, calculated as log price differences, and ht1 is the conditional volatility series obtained from the following GARCH model5: Rt ¼ "R,t "R,t j t1 t:dð0, ht , vÞ ht ¼ 0 þ 1 "2R,t1 þ 2 h2t1 þ et in which the residual term "R,t follows a conditional Student’s t distribution (t.d) with degrees of freedom and a conditional variance ht. t1 is the information set that contains all relevant information at time t 1. The model in Equation 1 is a modified version of the regressions in LSMW.6 It measures the interaction between return autocorrelation and lagged volume by 1, lagged volume squared by 2, and conditional volatility by 3. Squared volume series are included to account for nonlinear relations between return autocorrelations and volume and 3 examines linkages between conditional variance and volume (see, Karpoff (1987) for a survey of volumevolatility linkages). However, the main coefficient interest in the investigation is 1, the measure of interaction between 3 The study focuses on the energy futures markets for two main reasons. First, the energy futures markets are among the most active and liquid futures markets. Second, the recent work of Ederington and Lee (2002), suggesting that potential hedgers are more active on the heating oil futures market, provides a priori expectations to compare the results of the present study. 4 Lucey (2005) argues that the conclusions of LMSW do not obtain on the Irish market, while Ciner and Karagozoglu (2004) find supportive evidence in the Turkish case. 5 In a strict sense, returns do not exist in futures markets since there is no initial investment. 6 The regression estimated by LMSW does not include a conditional volatility term. Hedging or speculation in derivative markets 191 Table 1. Sample summary statistics Crude oil Mean Std. Deviation Skewness Kurtosis Heating oil Unleaded gasoline Returns Volume Returns Volume Returns Volume 0.00003 0.023 1.733 27.895 0.014 0.342 0.601 1.033 0.00009 0.0275 1.529 25.352 0.014 0.343 0.147 0.223 0.00003 0.026 0.461 11.859 0.016 0.314 0.215 0.358 Note: This table provides descriptive statistics of the data set. The sample covers the period between 2 January 1990 and 26 December 2001, for a total of 3002 observations. The volume series are detrended using a 200-day moving average component. return autocorrelation and lagged volume. If hedging is relatively more important than speculation on the energy futures markets, high volume days will be followed by price reversals and 1 will be negative and statistically significant. On the other hand, if speculation is the primary trading motive, price continuations are expected following high volume days and 1 will be positive and significant. III. Data and Findings The data consist of daily closing prices and trading volume for crude oil, heating oil and unleaded gasoline futures contracts traded on the NYMEX. The data span the period between 2 January 1990 and 26 December 2001, for a total of 3003 observations and are obtained from the NYMEX. The closing prices are constructed as continuous series by rolling over nearby contracts, which are typically the most active. Returns are calculated as log price differences and volume is detrended using a 200-day moving average component to obtain stationary series.7 The detrended volume is calculated as: Vt ¼ logðVt Þ 1 X 1 logðVtþi Þ 200 i¼200 in which Vt denotes daily trading volume. Some summary statistics for daily returns and volume can be found in Table 1. The findings suggest that energy futures returns, on average, have zero mean, negative skewness and excess kurtosis. Equation 1 is estimated originally by the ordinary least squares (OLS). However, the Godfrey (1978) test points to significant autocorrelation in residual; hence, the error terms are modelled as autoregressive processes and reestimate the regressions by the maximum likelihood (ML) method. Lags of one through five are considered and the appropriate lag determined for the autoregressive structure by calculating the Godfrey test against white noise alternatives.8 The findings, reported in Table 2, indicate that 1 is negative and statistically significant in all cases, suggesting that days with high trading volume are followed by price reversals. This finding implies that, within the context of LMSW, hedging is relatively more important in energy futures markets, in line with the arguments of Ederington and Lee (2002). This is also consistent with the overall conclusions of Chang et al. (2000) on stock index futures markets. Furthermore, estimates of 2 suggest significant nonlinearities in the volume-return autocorrelation linkage for the heating oil futures, as implied by the framework of LMSW, although not for the other contracts. IV. Conclusion Evidence is provided on whether hedging or speculation is the principle motive behind trading in energy futures markets. Within the context of the LMSW model, the findings indicate that hedging is more important than speculation as the main motive to trade in energy futures markets, which corroborate results published in prior work. This finding is of interest to participants and regulators in futures markets. As pointed out by Pashigian (1986) and Stoll (1998), futures markets 7 LMSW also use a 200-day moving average component to detrend daily volume. The analysis is also conducted using a 100-day moving average component to detrend the series. The overall findings are qualitatively the same. 8 If the test is significant at any lag less than five, but not for greater, then the test is recalculated against an autoregressive structure of lags higher, up to five. It is found that two autoregressive lags are appropriate for the crude oil and heating oil futures contracts, while four lags are indicated for the unleaded gas futures contract. C. Ciner 192 Table 2. Regression results Crude oil Heating oil Unleaded gasoline 0.0002 (0.63) 0.0003 (0.50) 0.0001 (0.70) 1 0.144 (0.01) 0.256 (0.00) 0.218 (0.00) 2 0.134 (0.17) 0.432 (0.00) 0.228 (0.07) 3 0.509 (0.64) 5.138 (0.00) 3.474 (0.27) 1 0.368 (0.00) 0.282 (0.00) 0.461 (0.00) 2 0.192 (0.00) 0.106 (0.00) 0.206 (0.00) 3 – – 0.133 (0.00) 4 – – 0.074 (0.00) Note: The following regression is estimated by the maximum likelihood method. n X Rt ¼ þ 0 þ 1 Vt1 þ 2 V2t1 þ 3 h1=2 i uti t1 Rt1 þ ut þ i¼1 Two lags are found to be appropriate for crude and heating oil futures contracts in the moving average component, while four lags are indicated for the unleaded gasoline contract. are sometimes regarded as forums where informed traders can fleece unsophisticated investors, justifying regulatory attempts to curb trading. The results of the present study are not supportive of this viewpoint. Furthermore, the findings of the present study are against the notion that increased volume in futures markets could destabilize the underlying spot market. Acknowledgements I wish to thank Harlan Platt, Dan Rogers and Ahmet Karagozoglu for helpful comments. The usual disclaimer applies. References Bessembinder, H. and Senguin, P. J. (1993) Price volatility, trading volume, and market depth: evidence from futures markets, Journal of Financial and Qualitative Analysis, 28, 2015–34. Chang, E., Chou, R. Y. and Nelling, E. F. (2000) Market volatility and demand for hedging in stock index futures, Journal of Futures Markets, 20, 105–25. Ciner, C. and Karagozoglu, A. (2004) Information asymmetry, speculation and foreign trading activity: emerging market evidence, paper presented at Eastern Finance Association Meetings, Norfolk, VA. de Roon, R. A., Nijman, T. E. and Veld, C. (2000) Hedging pressure effects in futures markets, Journal of Finance, 55, 1437–57. Ederington, L. and Lee, J. H. (2002) Who trades futures and how: evidence from the heating oil futures market, Journal of Business, 75, 353–73. Godfrey, L. G. (1978) Testing against general autoregressive and moving average error models when the regressors include lagged dependent variables, Econometrica, 46, 1293–301. Karpoff, J. (1987) The relation between price changes and trading volume: a survey, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 22, 109–26. Llorente, G., Michaely, R., Saar, G. and Wang, J. (2002) Dynamic volume-return relation of individual stocks, Review of Financial Studies, 15, 1005–47. Lucey, B. (2005) Speculation or hedging in the Irish stock market, Applied Financial Economics Letters, 1, 9–14. Pashigian, P. B. (1986) The political economy of futures market regulation, Journal of Business, 59, 55–84. Stoll, H. R. (1998) Regulation of financial markets: a focused approach, Multinational Finance Journal, 2, 87–99. Wang, C. (2003) The behavior and performance of major types of futures traders, Journal of Futures Markets, 23, 1–31.