Balance Sheet Capacity and Endogenous Risk

advertisement
Balance Sheet Capacity and Endogenous Risk
Jon Danielsson
London School of Economics
Hyun Song Shin
Princeton University
Jean—Pierre Zigrand
London School of Economics
December 2010
Balance Sheet Capacity
• Balance sheet capacity is capacity of banking (intermediary) sector to
channel credit
• Balance sheet capacity is impaired during crises
— Erosion of bank capital due to credit losses
— Deleveraging
• One rationale for central bank purchase of risky securities is to restore
lost balance sheet capacity
1
Total Asset Growth
0
10
20
Procyclical Leverage
2008q1
2007q3
-10
2008q2
2007q4
2008q3
1987q4
1998q4
-20
2008q4
-40
-20
0
20
Leverage Growth
Adrian and Shin (2010)
2
Balance Sheet Capacity Decomposed
Asset growth = log  ( + 1) − log  ()
Leverage Growth = log  ( + 1) − log  ()
− (log  ( + 1) − log  ())
45 degree line represents constant equity line:
log  ( + 1) − log  () = 0
Above 45 degree line, equity increasing.
Below 45 degree line, equity decreasing.
Straight line with slope 1 is constant equity growth line, with intercept
being growth rate
3
Balance Sheet Capacity Decomposed
• Equity seems to play role of exogenous variable
— Contrast to corporate finance textbooks extending MM
• Balance sheet capacity is
Equity × Permitted Leverage
• Our approach: intermediaries are subject to Value-at-Risk constraint
Equity = Total Assets × VaR per dollar of assets
Leverage =
Assets
1
=
Equity
Unit VaR
4
Endogeneity of Risk
• True risks impacting financial markets are attributable (at least in part)
to actions of economic agents.
• Endogenous risk is fixed point of mapping:
perceived risk ⇒ actual risk
• Solve for volatility  and risk premium  −  in closed form, where
— Banking sector capital (equity) is state variable
— Fundamental uncertainty is constant
5
Some Themes
• Volatility depends on balance sheet capacity, even though fundamental
uncertainty is constant (“Endogenous Risk” Danielsson and Shin (2003))
• Risk premium depends on balance sheet capacity
— Lagrange multiplier of VaR constraint enters like a risk aversion
parameter
— “As if” preferences + endogenous risk generate risk premiums that
depend on balance sheet capacity
• Implication: intermediary balance sheet size forecasts asset returns
— Adrian, Moench and Shin (2009) for asset returns in US
— Etula (2009) for commodities
— Adrian, Etula and Shin (2009) for FX returns for USD cross rates
6
Simplified Financial System
Intermediated
Credit
end-user
borrowers
Banks
(Active
Investors)
Directly granted credit
Debt
Claims
Households
(Passive
Investors)
Intermediated and Directly Granted Credit
7
Model
• Time indexed by  ∈ [0 ∞).
•   0 non-dividend paying risky securities (date  price of th risky
security is )
• One risk-free bond (0 = 1  = , with  constant)
• Two types of traders
— Active (risk-neutral, with VaR constraints) - banks
— Passive (residual demand/supply curves) - households, value investors
8
Posit equilibrium of form:
⎡
⎣
11
⎤
⎡
1
⎤
⎡
−
 1
..
⎦ = ⎣ .. ⎦  + ⎣
− 
 



−
−
⎤⎡
⎦⎣
1
⎤
..
⎦

© ª
 independent Brownian motions (fundamental shocks enter via passive
traders’ demands)
© ª
© ª
Scalars  and 1 ×  vectors   are as yet undetermined coefficients
to be solved in equilibrium
Solve for rational expectations equilibrium (REE) with respect to active
traders’ beliefs
9
Portfolio Choice of Active Traders
• Risk-neutral traders
• (Ultra) short horizons
• Value-at-Risk (VaR) constraint:
enough to meet VaR
capital (i.e. equity) should be large
 is dollar holding of th security at 
 is trader’s capital (notice no superscript for trader, due to aggregation
result, to follow)
Balance sheet identity
 =  −
P




10
Evolution of capital
£
¤
>
 =  +  ( − )  + > 
> is transpose of ,   is the  ×  diffusion matrix,  = (     )>.
Expected capital gain:
[] = [ + >( − )]
(1)
Var() = >  >
  
(2)
Variance of capital:
Trader maximizes (1) subject to VaR constraint, where VaR is  times
forward-looking standard deviation of return on equity.
11
Assuming trader is solvent (  0) maximization problem is
max  + >( − )

subject to
q
 >  >
  ≤ 
First-order condition
 −  = (>Σ)−12 Σ
where   is Lagrange multiplier for VaR constraint, and Σ :=   >
 .
1
−1
Σ
( − )
 =
(>Σ)−12  
12
Constraint binds due to risk-neutrality
q
 =  >Σ
Therefore
(3)
 −1
 = 2 Σ ( − )
 
“As if” preferences. Optimal portfolio is similar to mean-variance optimal
portfolio where the Lagrange multiplier   appears like a risk-aversion
coefficient.
Substitute into (3) to solve for Lagrange multiplier
p

 =

13
where
  := ( − )>Σ−1
 ( − )
Lagrange multiplier   is
√
• proportional to generalized Sharpe ratio 
• does not depend directly on equity 
Interpretation.
Additional unit of capital relaxes VaR constraint by
multiple  of standard deviation, raising expected return by risk-premium
on the portfolio per unit of standard deviation
14
Finally, solve for optimal portfolio:

 = p Σ−1
 ( − )
 
Optimal portfolio is homogeneous of degree one in equity 
Aggregation result.
Portfolio depends on , total capital of active
trading (banking?) sector, not on profile of individual equity capital.
⇒ Take aggregate capital, , as state variable
15
Closing the Model
Passive traders in aggregate have vector-valued exogenous demand schedule
for the risky assets,  = (1      ) where
¡ 1
¢ ⎤
1
  − ln 
..
⎦
⎣
 = Σ−1

¡
¢
   − ln 
⎡
1
  is scaling parameter for slope of the demand curve
 is positive demand shock for asset 
 = ∗ +   
16
The market-clearing condition  +  = 0 gives
¡ 1
¢ ⎤
1
  − ln 

..
⎦=0
p ( − ) + ⎣ ¡
¢
 



  − ln 
⎡
1
Equilibrium prices are
 = exp
Ã
!



p
(
−
)
+


 ;

  
 = 1     
17
Single Risky Asset
Look for equilibrium of form:

=  +  

(4)
 and   are undetermined coefficients to be solved in equilibrium,  is
standard (scalar) Brownian motion. Equivalently,
¶
µ
1 2
(5)
 ln  =  −    +  
2
“Seeds” of fundamental shocks given by exogenous shocks to passive
traders’ demands:
 = ∗ +   , for known constants   0    0
18
Start with market-clearing price with VaR-constrained traders
¶
µ
  
 = exp  +

Take logs and apply Ito’s Lemma
¶
µ
  
 ln  =   +

= ∗ +    +
1
(  +   +  )

(6)
• Unpack  and  , and substitute back into (6)
• Compare coefficients with (5)
19
Step 1. Unpack  as an Ito process
 = [ + ( − )] +  
¸
∙

( − )
 + 
=  +
 

Key step is the simplification allowed by binding VaR constraint:
  = 
20
Step 2. Unpack   as an Ito process
From Itô’s Lemma on (),

1  2
2
 +
(
)
  =


2 ()2
)
(
∙
¸
µ
¶
2
1  2

 

( − )
 +
+
 (7)

+
=
2

 
2 ()

 
2
where we substutute in  and where () =
¡  ¢2


21
Substitute everything back into (6) and re-arrange:
µ
¶¸
∙

  
1
 ln  = (drift term)  +   +
  + 



 
By hypothesis,
¶
µ
1
 ln  =  −  2  +  
2
(*)
(**)
Comparing coefficients between (*) and (**),
µ
¶

  
1
  + 
() =   +


 
22
giving ordinary differential equation:
2

= 2(  −   ) −  

Generic solution:
"
1 − 2
() =    − 2 

Z
∞
2

−  
−


#
where  is a constant of integration, and Ei () function (“exponential
R ∞ −
integral” function) − −   is defined provided  6= 0.
23
Constant of integration  can be tied down as follows.
Consider limit case  → 0 where “fundamental shocks” are shut down
As  → 0

 () →

Restriction. In the absence of fundamental shocks, volatility is zero
This implies  = 0 so that
³ 2 ´
n 2 o
() =    exp −  × Ei 
2
24
Equilibrium drift 

 = +
2 
½
∙
¸¾
2


2 (∗ − ) +  2 −   + (  −   ) 22 +
−2

Sharpe ratio:
½
∙
¸¾
2
1
 
 − 
∗
2
2
2 ( − ) +   −   + (  −   ) 2  +
=
−2

2 

25
Example
 = 001 ∗ = 0047  = 6  = 27   = 03  = 15
26
Risk and Return
σ
µ
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
0
20
40
Equity
60
80
Risk and Return
σ
µ
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
0
20
40
Equity
60
80
Risk and Return
σ
µ
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
0
20
40
Equity
60
80
Leverage under P
Asset Growth
0.4
0.2
0.0
−0.2
−0.4
−0.6
−0.6
−0.4
−0.2
0.0
Leverage growth
0.2
0.4
Risk and Return
σ
µ
γ
0.6
0.5
0.20
0.15
0.4
0.10
0.3
0.2
0.05
0.1
0.0
0
20
40
Equity
60
80
Many Risky Assets
Special case of  risky securities case can be solved using ODE solution
from the single risky asset case.
Assumption (Symmetry)
1. Diffusion matrix for  is ̃   where ̃   0 is a scalar and  is the
 ×  identity matrix.
2.   =  for all .
Let  
 be coefficient giving effect of change in demand shock of th security
on price of th security.
27
From assumption of symmetry, we only need to solve for one diffusion
11
variable,  
 =   , since for  6=  the cross effects are tied down by
12
11
 
 =   =   − ̃  .
Define  ≡ () the solution to the ODE for single risky asset with 
replaced by  .
Proposition 1. Assume (S). The following is a REE.
 −1
The REE diffusion coefficients are  
=

+


 ̃  , and for  6= ,
1

2 2
=

−
̃
.
Also,
Σ
=
Var
(return
on
security
)
=

̃  +
 




¡
 ¢

1
2 2
2 2

,
and
for

=
6
,
Σ

−

̃
= Cov(return on security 




¡
¢
return on security ) = 1  22 − 2̃ 2 and Corr(return on security 
return on security ) =
Risky holdings are  =
1  2 ̃ 2
 2 − 

−1 2 2
 2 + 
 ̃ 
.

.
 32
28
The risk-reward relationship is given by
( µ
¶2

 − 
1
 −1

√
̃


=
+
−
̃  +




2  ̃ 


∙
¸¾
2
√ ³

 ´

  − ̃  22 +
−2


(8)
The intuition and form of the drift term is very similar to the  = 1 case
and reduces to it if  is set equal to 1.
29
Related Literature
• Two strands coming together
— Competitive equilibrium models of crashes: Leland (1990), Genakoplos
(1997) and Geanakoplos and Zame (2003)
— Corporate finance elements: Shleifer and Vishny’s (1997), Holmström
and Tirole (2001), He and Krishnamurthy (2007)...
• Portfolio constraints: Basak and Croitoru (2000), Chabakauri (2008),
Aiyagari and Gertler (1999), Gromb and Vayanos (2002), Brunnermeier
and Pedersen (2009), Rytchkov (2008), Pavlova et al (2008)
• Wealth effects: Kyle and Xiong (2001). Xiong (2001) solves for fixed
point numerically.
30
• Lagrange multipliers associated with VaR constraints: Danielsson, Shin
and Zigrand (2004), Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009), Danielsson and
Zigrand (2008), Oehmke (2008).
• Asset pricing taking account of balance sheet constraints: Adrian,
Etula and Shin (2009) [for exchange rates], Etula (2009) [commodities],
Adrian, Moench and Shin (2009)
31
Avenues for Further Research
• Having  as sole state variable is limiting
— Single state variable cannot take account of time dependence
— “Long period of tranquility builds up vulnerabilites...”
• Backward-looking learning (e.g. RiskMetrics)
— In practice, banks use historical data to forecast volatility
— ... also encouraged by regulators (Basel II)
— This is one way to tie down beliefs, and overcome multiplicity of
equilibrium
— Encompasses history-dependence
32
Download