Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection Dr. Hanqing Jin A Joint work with Xun Yu Zhou and Song Zhang Mathematical Institute & Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 1/27 Behavioural Preference • Reference point B • S -shaped utility u(·): u(x) = u+ (x+ ) − u− (x− ) with u± (·) concave, ↑ and u± (0) = 0 • Probability distortion T± (·): T± (0) = 0, T± (1) = 1, ↑ Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 2/27 Behavioural Preference • Reference point B • S -shaped utility u(·): u(x) = u+ (x+ ) − u− (x− ) with u± (·) concave, ↑ and u± (0) = 0 • Probability distortion T± (·): T± (0) = 0, T± (1) = 1, ↑ • Behavioural criterion: for a r.v. Y , V (Y ) = Z +∞ u(y)d[−T+ (P (Y ≥ y))] + 0 Z 0 u(y)d[T− (P (Y ≤ y))] −∞ Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 2/27 Behavioural Preference • Reference point B • S -shaped utility u(·): u(x) = u+ (x+ ) − u− (x− ) with u± (·) concave, ↑ and u± (0) = 0 • Probability distortion T± (·): T± (0) = 0, T± (1) = 1, ↑ • Behavioural criterion: for a r.v. Y , V (Y ) = Z +∞ Z +∞ u(y)d[−T+ (P (Y ≥ y))] + 0 = 0 T+ (P (u+ (Y + ) ≥ y))dy − Z 0 u(y)d[T− (P (Y ≤ y))] −∞ Z +∞ T− (P (u− (Y − ) ≥ y))dy 0 Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 2/27 Behavioural Preference • Reference point B • S -shaped utility u(·): u(x) = u+ (x+ ) − u− (x− ) with u± (·) concave, ↑ and u± (0) = 0 • Probability distortion T± (·): T± (0) = 0, T± (1) = 1, ↑ • Behavioural criterion: for a r.v. Y , V (Y ) = Z +∞ Z +∞ u(y)d[−T+ (P (Y ≥ y))] + 0 = 0 T+ (P (u+ (Y + ) ≥ y))dy − Z 0 u(y)d[T− (P (Y ≤ y))] −∞ Z +∞ T− (P (u− (Y − ) ≥ y))dy 0 • Behavioural Preference: compare V (X − B) Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 2/27 Continuous time portfolio selection • A market in a finite time horizon: t ∈ [0, T ] • Arbitrage free and complete with pricing kernel ρt Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 3/27 Continuous time portfolio selection • A market in a finite time horizon: t ∈ [0, T ] • Arbitrage free and complete with pricing kernel ρt ◦ A contingent claim ξ at time T is obtainable from initial wealth x0 if and only if • lower bounded, E[ξρT ] ≤ x0 . Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 3/27 Continuous time portfolio selection • A market in a finite time horizon: t ∈ [0, T ] • Arbitrage free and complete with pricing kernel ρt ◦ A contingent claim ξ at time T is obtainable from initial wealth x0 if and only if • lower bounded, E[ξρT ] ≤ x0 . ◦ Black-scholes market: ρt = e 2 −(r+ (µ−r) )t− µ−r W (t) σ 2σ 2 . Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 3/27 Continuous time portfolio selection • A market in a finite time horizon: t ∈ [0, T ] • Arbitrage free and complete with pricing kernel ρt ◦ A contingent claim ξ at time T is obtainable from initial wealth x0 if and only if • lower bounded, E[ξρT ] ≤ x0 . ◦ Under some condition, the completeness can be relaxed. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 3/27 Continuous time portfolio selection • A market in a finite time horizon: t ∈ [0, T ] • Arbitrage free and complete with pricing kernel ρt ◦ A contingent claim ξ at time T is obtainable from initial wealth x0 if and only if • lower bounded, E[ξρT ] ≤ x0 . • Denote ρ = ρT . Portfolio selection with criterion U (·): Maximize U(X) X is lower bounded, X ∈ A s.t. E[Xρ] ≤ x0 where A is a constraint on portfolio Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 3/27 Outline of this talk • Unconstraint behavioural portfolio selection • Behavioural portfolio selection with controlled loss • Examples for the latter Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 4/27 Behavioural portfolio selection problem Maximize V (X − B) X is lower bounded, X ∈ A s.t. E[Xρ] ≤ x0 Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 5/27 Behavioural portfolio selection problem Maximize V (X − B) X is lower bounded, X ∈ A s.t. E[Xρ] ≤ x0 Suppose the reference is lower bounded. Rewrite the problem by changing variable X̃ = X − B , Maximize V+ (X̃ + ) − V− (X̃ − ) X̃ is lower bounded, X ∈ A s.t. E[X̃ρ] ≤ x̃0 := x0 − E[ρB] where V± (Y ) = R +∞ 0 T± (P (u± (y) ≥ y))dy . Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 5/27 Unconstraint case — Property of optimal solution • Split X̃ into X̃ + − X̃ − Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 6/27 Unconstraint case — Property of optimal solution • Split X̃ into X̃ + − X̃ − • Key property: Given V (X̃) only depends on the distribution of X̃ increasingly, X̃ ∗ must be a decreasing function of ρ. • {X̃ ∗ ≥ 0} = {ρ ≤ c∗ }, x̃∗+ := E[(X̃ ∗ )+ ρ] ≥ x̃+ . 0 Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 6/27 Unconstraint case — Property of optimal solution • Split X̃ into X̃ + − X̃ − • Key property: Given V (X̃) only depends on the distribution of X̃ increasingly, X̃ ∗ must be a decreasing function of ρ. • {X̃ ∗ ≥ 0} = {ρ ≤ c∗ }, x̃∗+ := E[(X̃ ∗ )+ ρ] ≥ x̃+ . Furthermore, 0 (X̃ ∗ )+ is optimal for max V+ (X̃+ ) X̃+ ≥ 0 s.t. X̃ = 0 when ρ > c∗ E[X̃+ ρ] = x̃∗+ Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 6/27 Unconstraint case — Property of optimal solution • Split X̃ into X̃ + − X̃ − • Key property: Given V (X̃) only depends on the distribution of X̃ increasingly, X̃ ∗ must be a decreasing function of ρ. • {X̃ ∗ ≥ 0} = {ρ ≤ c∗ }, x̃∗+ := E[(X̃ ∗ )+ ρ] ≥ x̃+ . Furthermore, 0 (X̃ ∗ )+ is optimal for max V+ (X̃+ ) X̃+ ≥ 0 s.t. X̃ = 0 when ρ > c∗ E[X̃+ ρ] = x̃∗+ (X̃ ∗ )− is optimal for min V− (X̃− ) X̃− ≥ 0, X̃− is bounded s.t. X̃− = 0 when ρ < c∗ E[X̃− ρ] = x̃∗+ − x̃0 Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 6/27 Unconstraint case — Splitting • Splitting: for any c ∈ (essinfρ, esssupρ), x̃+ ≥ x̃+ , solve the 0 following problems to get their value function v± (c, x̃+ ) max V+ (X̃+ ) X̃+ ≥ 0 s.t. X̃ = 0 when ρ > c E[X̃+ ρ] = x̃+ (Positive Part Problem) min V− (X̃− ) X̃− ≥ 0, X̃− is bounded s.t. X̃− = 0 when ρ < c E[X̃− ρ] = x̃+ − x̃0 (Negative Part Problem) Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 7/27 Unconstraint case — Splitting • Splitting: for any c ∈ (essinfρ, esssupρ), x̃+ ≥ x̃+ , solve the 0 following problems to get their value function v± (c, x̃+ ) max V+ (X̃+ ) X̃+ ≥ 0 s.t. X̃ = 0 when ρ > c E[X̃+ ρ] = x̃+ (Positive Part Problem) min V− (X̃− ) X̃− ≥ 0, X̃− is bounded s.t. X̃− = 0 when ρ < c E[X̃− ρ] = x̃+ − x̃0 (Negative Part Problem) • Then find the optimal splitting c∗ and x̃∗+ by solving Maximizec∈(essinfρ,esssupρ),x̃+ ≥x+0 v+ (c, x̃+ ) − v− (c, x̃+ ). Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 7/27 Recovery of optimal contingent claim • If ◦ c∗ , x̃∗+ is an optimal splitting ∗ , X̃ ∗ are optimal for the two subproblems respectively ◦ X̃+ − with parameters c∗ , x̃∗+ , ∗1 ∗ then X = X̃+ ρ≤c∗ − X̃− 1ρ>c∗ + B is optimal Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 8/27 Recovery of optimal contingent claim • If ◦ c∗ , x̃∗+ is an optimal splitting ∗ , X̃ ∗ are optimal for the two subproblems respectively ◦ X̃+ − with parameters c∗ , x̃∗+ , ∗1 ∗ then X = X̃+ ρ≤c∗ − X̃− 1ρ>c∗ + B is optimal • If any of them fails to exist, then there is no optimal contingent claim Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 8/27 Positive part problem Consider the problem R +∞ max V+ (Y ) = 0 T+ (P (u+ (Y ) ≥ y))dy Y ≥0 max-Y s.t. E[Y ρ] = a with constant a > 0. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 9/27 Positive part problem Consider the problem R +∞ max V+ (Y ) = 0 T+ (P (u+ (Y ) ≥ y))dy Y ≥0 max-Y s.t. E[Y ρ] = a with constant a > 0. Theorem 1 Suppose this problem admits an optimal solution Y ∗ , with cumulative distribution function G(·), then Y ∗ = G−1 (1 − Fρ (ρ)), a.s., where Fρ (·) is the distribution function of ρ. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 9/27 Positive part problem Denote Z = 1 − Fρ (ρ), then Z ∼ U (0, 1), and the problem can be written into max v1 (G(·)) = s.t. R +∞ 0 T (P {u+ (G−1 (Z)) > y})dy G(·) is a CDF with G(0) = 0 E[G−1 (Z)Fρ−1 (1 − Z)] = a Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 10/27 Positive part problem Denote Z = 1 − Fρ (ρ), then Z ∼ U (0, 1), and the problem can be written into max v1 (G(·)) = s.t. R +∞ 0 T (P {u+ (G−1 (Z)) > y})dy G(·) is a CDF with G(0) = 0 E[G−1 (Z)Fρ−1 (1 − Z)] = a Change optimization variable from G(·) to g(·) = G−1 (·), max v̄1 (g(·)) := E[u+ (g(Z))T ′ (1 − Z)] (max-g) s.t. E[g(Z)Fρ−1 (1 − Z)] = a g(·) is a qunatile function with g(0+) ≥ 0 Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 10/27 Positive part problem — The optimal solution Assumption 1 : (1) Fρ (·) is continuous; (2) −xu′′+ (x) on [0, 1]; (3) lim inf u′ (x) > 0; (4) + x→+∞ E[u+ ((u′+ )−1 ( T ′ (Fρρ (ρ)) ))T ′ (Fρ (ρ))]< Fρ−1 (·) T+′ (·) is increasing +∞. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 11/27 Positive part problem — The optimal solution Assumption 1 : (1) Fρ (·) is continuous; (2) −xu′′+ (x) on [0, 1]; (3) lim inf u′ (x) > 0; (4) + x→+∞ E[u+ ((u′+ )−1 ( T ′ (Fρρ (ρ)) ))T ′ (Fρ (ρ))]< Theorem 2 Fρ−1 (·) T+′ (·) is increasing +∞. Suppose Assumption 1 holds. Then for any c ∈ (essinfρ, esssupρ] and x̃+ ≥ x̃+ 0 , the optimal solution for the positive part problem is ∗ X̃+ The optimal value is = (u′+ )−1 (λ ρ )1ρ≤c . ′ T+ (F (ρ)) v+ (c, x̃+ ) = E[u+ ((u′+ )−1 (λ ρ ′ ))T + (F (ρ))1ρ≤c ], ′ T+ (F (ρ)) ∗ feasible. where λ is the unique one making X̃+ Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 11/27 Negative part problem — Unconstraint case Consider the problem (min-Y) min V− (Y ) = s.t. R +∞ 0 T− (P {u− (Y ) > y})dy E[Y ρ] = a, Y ≥ 0 Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 12/27 Negative part problem — Unconstraint case Consider the problem (min-Y) min V− (Y ) = s.t. R +∞ 0 T− (P {u− (Y ) > y})dy E[Y ρ] = a, Y ≥ 0 Similar to the positive part problem, denoting Z = Fρ (ξ), we can translate the problem into min v̄2 (g(·)) := E[u− (g(Z))T−′ (1 − Z)] (min-g) s.t. g(·) is a quantile function with g(0+) ≥ 0 E[g(Z)Fρ−1 (Z)] = a. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 12/27 Negative part problem — Unconstraint case Consider the problem (min-Y) min V− (Y ) = s.t. R +∞ 0 T− (P {u− (Y ) > y})dy E[Y ρ] = a, Y ≥ 0 Similar to the positive part problem, denoting Z = Fρ (ξ), we can translate the problem into min v̄2 (g(·)) := E[u− (g(Z))T−′ (1 − Z)] (min-g) s.t. g(·) is a quantile function with g(0+) ≥ 0 E[g(Z)Fρ−1 (Z)] = a. • If g ∗ (·) is optimal, then Y ∗ := g ∗ (Fρ (ρ)) is optimal Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 12/27 Negative part problem — Unconstraint case • Problem (min-g) is to minimize a concave objective over a convex set Theorem 3 If Problem (min-g) admits optimal solutions, then one of them is in the form g(x; c) = a E[ρ1ρ≥c ] 1x≥Fρ (c) . • g ∗ (·) is a two-piece step function • Only need to solve the problem (minV-c) min u− ( E[ρ1aρ≥c ] )T− (P (ρ > c)) s.t. c ∈ [essinfρ, esssupρ) • The optimal solution Y ∗ , if exists, is automatically bounded. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 13/27 Negative part problem — Unconstraint case Theorem 4 For any c ∈ [essinfρ, esssupρ), x̃+ > x̃+ 0 , the optimal value of the negative part problem is x̃+ − x̃0 v− (c, x̃+ ) = inf u− ( )T− (1 − F (c2 )). Eρ1ρ>c2 c2 ∈[c,esssupρ) Furthermore, if c∗2 achieves the optimal value v− (c, x̃+ ), then ∗ X̃− x̃+ − x̃0 = 1ρ≥c∗2 . Eρ1ρ>c∗2 Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 14/27 Unconstraint case — Final optimal solution The optimal splitting c∗ , x̃∗+ can be determined by (sp) x̃+ −x̃0 max v+ (c, x̃+ ) − u− ( E[ρ1 )T− (1 − F (c)) ρ>c ] s.t. x̃+ ≥ x̃0 , c ∈ [essinfρ, esssupρ) Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 15/27 Unconstraint case — Final optimal solution The optimal splitting c∗ , x̃∗+ can be determined by (sp) x̃+ −x̃0 max v+ (c, x̃+ ) − u− ( E[ρ1 )T− (1 − F (c)) ρ>c ] s.t. Theorem 5 x̃+ ≥ x̃0 , c ∈ [essinfρ, esssupρ) Suppose Assumption 1 hold. (i) If (c∗ , x̃∗+ ) is optimal for Problem (sp), then ∗ x̃ ρ + − x̃0 ′ −1 ∗ X = (u+ ) (λ ′ )1ρ≤c∗ − 1ρ>c∗ + B T+ (F (ρ)) E[ρ1ρ>c∗ ] is an optimal contingent claim. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 15/27 Unconstraint case — Final optimal solution The optimal splitting c∗ , x̃∗+ can be determined by (sp) x̃+ −x̃0 max v+ (c, x̃+ ) − u− ( E[ρ1 )T− (1 − F (c)) ρ>c ] s.t. Theorem 5 x̃+ ≥ x̃0 , c ∈ [essinfρ, esssupρ) Suppose Assumption 1 hold. (i) If (c∗ , x̃∗+ ) is optimal for Problem (sp), then ∗ x̃ ρ + − x̃0 ′ −1 ∗ X = (u+ ) (λ ′ )1ρ≤c∗ − 1ρ>c∗ + B T+ (F (ρ)) E[ρ1ρ>c∗ ] is an optimal contingent claim. (ii) If there is no optimal (c, x̃+ ), then there is no optimal contingent claim. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 15/27 Loss control • For the optimal contingent, the loss (X̃ ∗ )− , although finite, can be very large. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 16/27 Loss control • For the optimal contingent, the loss (X̃ ∗ )− , although finite, can be very large. • An exogenous constraint X̃ − ≤ L controls the loss. ( L is a positive number) Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 16/27 Loss control • For the optimal contingent, the loss (X̃ ∗ )− , although finite, can be very large. • An exogenous constraint X̃ − ≤ L controls the loss. ( L is a positive number) • X̃ − ≤ L is the same as X ≥ B − L ◦ No bankruptcy constraint if L = B Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 16/27 Loss control • For the optimal contingent, the loss (X̃ ∗ )− , although finite, can be very large. • An exogenous constraint X̃ − ≤ L controls the loss. ( L is a positive number) • X̃ − ≤ L is the same as X ≥ B − L ◦ No bankruptcy constraint if L = B • Consider the problem with controlled loss Maximize V (X̃) X̃ ≥ −L s.t. E[X̃ρ] ≤ x̃0 Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 16/27 Negative part problem • With the controlled loss ◦ splitting of the problem still holds Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 17/27 Negative part problem • With the controlled loss ◦ splitting of the problem still holds ◦ positive part problem is formally the same Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 17/27 Negative part problem • With the controlled loss ◦ splitting of the problem still holds ◦ positive part problem is formally the same ◦ Difficulty exists in the negative part problem min V− (X̃− ) X̃− ≥ 0, X̃− ≤ L (cnp) s.t. X̃− = 0 when ρ < c E[X̃− ρ] = x̃+ − x̃0 where (c, x̃+ ) is a splitting. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 17/27 Negative part problem with constraint Consider the problem min V− (Y ) Y ≥ 0, Y ≤ L s.t. E[Y ρ] = a Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 18/27 Negative part problem with constraint Consider the problem min V− (Y ) Y ≥ 0, Y ≤ L s.t. E[Y ρ] = a • By the same transformation, it is equivalent to solve min v̄2 (g(·)) := E[u− (g(Z))T−′ (1 − Z)] g(·) is a quantile function with g(0+) ≥ 0 s.t. g(·) ≤ L on [0, 1) E[g(Z)Fρ−1 (Z)] = a. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 18/27 Negative part problem with constraint • With the constraint g(·) ≤ L, the boundary of the feasible region changed. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 19/27 Negative part problem with constraint • With the constraint g(·) ≤ L, the boundary of the feasible region changed. Theorem 6 If there are optimal g(·), then one of them is in the form g(x; c1, c2 ) = q(c1 , c2 ; a)1x∈[Fρ (c1 ),Fρ (c2 )) + L1x≥Fρ (c2 ) , where q(c1 , c2 ; a) = a−LE[ρ1ρ≥c2 ] E[ρ1ρ∈[c1 ,c2 ) ] . Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 19/27 Negative part problem with constraint • With the constraint g(·) ≤ L, the boundary of the feasible region changed. Theorem 6 If there are optimal g(·), then one of them is in the form g(x; c1, c2 ) = q(c1 , c2 ; a)1x∈[Fρ (c1 ),Fρ (c2 )) + L1x≥Fρ (c2 ) , where q(c1 , c2 ; a) = a−LE[ρ1ρ≥c2 ] E[ρ1ρ∈[c1 ,c2 ) ] . L q Fρ (c1 ) Fρ (c2 ) Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 19/27 Negative part problem with constraint • With the constraint g(·) ≤ L, the boundary of the feasible region changed. Theorem 6 If there are optimal g(·), then one of them is in the form g(x; c1, c2 ) = q(c1 , c2 ; a)1x∈[Fρ (c1 ),Fρ (c2 )) + L1x≥Fρ (c2 ) , where q(c1 , c2 ; a) = a−LE[ρ1ρ≥c2 ] E[ρ1ρ∈[c1 ,c2 ) ] . • Only need to solve the problem (min-c) min v̄2 (g(·; c1 , c2 )) s.t. essinfρ ≤ c1 < c2 ≤ esssupρ Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 19/27 Negative part problem with constraint Theorem 7 For any c ∈ [essinfρ, esssupρ), x̃+ > x̃+ 0 , the optimal value of the Problem (cnp) is where v− (c, x̃+ ) = inf c≤c1 <c2 ≤esssupρ) v3 (c1 , c2 ; c, x̃+ ), v3 (· · · ) = u− (q(c1 , c2 , x̃+ − x̃0 ))(T− (P (ρ ≥ c2 )) − T− (P (ρ ≥ c1 ))) +u− (L)T− (P (ρ ≥ c2 )). Furthermore, if v− (c, x+ ) is obtained at (c∗1 , c∗2 ), then ∗ = q(c∗1 , c∗2 ; x̃∗+ − x̃0 )1ρ∈[c∗1 ,c∗2 ) + L1ρ≥c∗2 X̃− is an optimal solution for Problem (cnp). Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 20/27 Optimal contingent with constraint The optimal splitting c∗ , x̃∗+ can be determined by (sp’) max v+ (c, x̃+ ) − v3 (c, c2 ; c, x̃+ ) s.t. x̃+ ≥ x̃0 , essinfρ ≤ c < c2 ≤ esssupρ Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 21/27 Optimal contingent with constraint The optimal splitting c∗ , x̃∗+ can be determined by (sp’) max v+ (c, x̃+ ) − v3 (c, c2 ; c, x̃+ ) s.t. Theorem 8 x̃+ ≥ x̃0 , essinfρ ≤ c < c2 ≤ esssupρ Suppose Assumption 1 hold. (i) If (c∗ , c∗2 , x̃∗+ ) is optimal for Problem (sp’), then ρ ′ −1 ∗ )1ρ≤c∗ −q(c∗ , c∗2 ; x̃∗+ − x̃0 )1ρ∈[c∗ ,c∗2 ) −L1ρ≥c∗2 +B X = (u+ ) (λ ′ T+ (F (ρ)) is an optimal contingent claim. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 21/27 Optimal contingent with constraint The optimal splitting c∗ , x̃∗+ can be determined by (sp’) max v+ (c, x̃+ ) − v3 (c, c2 ; c, x̃+ ) s.t. Theorem 8 x̃+ ≥ x̃0 , essinfρ ≤ c < c2 ≤ esssupρ Suppose Assumption 1 hold. (i) If (c∗ , c∗2 , x̃∗+ ) is optimal for Problem (sp’), then ρ ′ −1 ∗ )1ρ≤c∗ −q(c∗ , c∗2 ; x̃∗+ − x̃0 )1ρ∈[c∗ ,c∗2 ) −L1ρ≥c∗2 +B X = (u+ ) (λ ′ T+ (F (ρ)) is an optimal contingent claim. (ii) If there is no optimal (c, c2 , x̃+ ), then there is no optimal contingent claim. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 21/27 Example: power value function • Generally, X ∗ is a three-piece function of ρ Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 22/27 Example: power value function • Generally, X ∗ is a three-piece function of ρ • Consider the example with u+ (x) = xα , u− (x) = kxα for some k > 1 and α ∈ (0, 1) ◦ In this example, optimal solution always exists Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 22/27 Example: power value function • Generally, X ∗ is a three-piece function of ρ • Consider the example with u+ (x) = xα , u− (x) = kxα for some k > 1 and α ∈ (0, 1) ◦ In this example, optimal solution always exists • Define f1 = 1 − Fρ , f2 (x) = E[ρ1ρ≥x ], f (x) = f2 (f −1 (x)) 1 Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 22/27 Example: power value function • Generally, X ∗ is a three-piece function of ρ • Consider the example with u+ (x) = xα , u− (x) = kxα for some k > 1 and α ∈ (0, 1) ◦ In this example, optimal solution always exists • Define f1 = 1 − Fρ , f2 (x) = E[ρ1ρ≥x ], f (x) = f2 (f −1 (x)) 1 Theorem 9 If h(x) = T− (f −1 (x))) is a convex function, then the optimal splitting (c∗ , c∗2 , x∗+ ) satisfies c∗ = c∗2 . Hence the optimal contingent claim is ∗ X = (u′+ )−1 (λ ρ )1ρ≤c∗2 − L1ρ≥c∗2 + B. ′ T+ (F (ρ)) Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 22/27 Example: power value function • Consider the case h(x) = xβ with β > 0 • If β < 1, Theorem 9 does not apply Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 23/27 Example: power value function • Consider the case h(x) = xβ with β > 0 • If β < 1, Theorem 9 does not apply Theorem 10 Given h(x) = xβ for some β > 0. Then • If β ≥ α, then c∗2 = c∗ , and X ∗ = (u′+ )−1 (λ T ′ (Fρ (ρ)) )1ρ≤c∗2 − L1ρ≥c∗2 + B. + Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 23/27 Example: power value function • Consider the case h(x) = xβ with β > 0 • If β < 1, Theorem 9 does not apply Theorem 10 Given h(x) = xβ for some β > 0. Then • If β ≥ α, then c∗2 = c∗ , and X ∗ = (u′+ )−1 (λ T ′ (Fρ (ρ)) )1ρ≤c∗2 − L1ρ≥c∗2 + B. + • If β < α, then c∗2 = +∞, and X∗ = (u′+ )−1 (λ T ′ (Fρ (ρ)) )1ρ≤c∗ + − x̃∗+ −x̃0 ∗ Eρ1ρ≥c∗ 1ρ≥c + B. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 23/27 Example: power value function • Consider the case h(x) = xβ with β > 0 • If β < 1, Theorem 9 does not apply Theorem 10 Given h(x) = xβ for some β > 0. Then • If β ≥ α, then c∗2 = c∗ , and X ∗ = (u′+ )−1 (λ T ′ (Fρ (ρ)) )1ρ≤c∗2 − L1ρ≥c∗2 + B. + • If β < α, then c∗2 = +∞, and X∗ = (u′+ )−1 (λ T ′ (Fρ (ρ)) )1ρ≤c∗ + − x̃∗+ −x̃0 ∗ Eρ1ρ≥c∗ 1ρ≥c + B. In any case, X ∗ is a two-piece function of ρ. Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 23/27 Example: power value function • Is the optimal solution always two-piece for power value function? Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 24/27 Example: power value function • Is the optimal solution always two-piece for power value function? • An three-piece example: ◦ L = 10, x̃0 = −1, β = 0.85, α = 0.88, k = 2.25, ρ ∼ Lognormal(−0.045, 0.09) ◦ h(x) = 0.5x x ∈ [0, 0.05] β (x − 0.05) + 0.025(0.1 − x) x ∈ [0.05, 0.1] 20 ∗ 0.1 xβ x ∈ [0.1, 1] ◦ The optimal solution X̃ ∗ = X ∗ − B is as in the next figure Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 24/27 Example: power value function x 10 5 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 rho -5 -10 Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 25/27 Summary • Without loss control, the unconstrained optimal contingent claim is a two-piece function of ρ Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 26/27 Summary • Without loss control, the unconstrained optimal contingent claim is a two-piece function of ρ • With loss control, the unconstrained optimal contingent claim is a three-piece function of ρ Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 26/27 Summary • Without loss control, the unconstrained optimal contingent claim is a two-piece function of ρ • With loss control, the unconstrained optimal contingent claim is a three-piece function of ρ • For power value function, the three-piece optimal contingent claim merge to two-piece function in many case Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 26/27 Thank you very much! Loss Control in Behavioural Portfolio Selection – p. 27/27