The Relation Between the Cost of Capital and Economic Profit Michael S. Pagano* Villanova University College of Commerce and Finance 800 Lancaster Avenue Villanova, PA 19085 Michael.Pagano@villanova.edu (610) 519-4389 JEL Classification: G32, G31, G3 Keywords: Cost of Capital, Capital Budgeting, Corporate Finance, Empirical Analysis Current Version: January, 2003 * - The author wishes to thank Ivan Brick, Steve Cochran, Javier Estrada, Victoria McWilliams, Bob Patrick, Dave Stout, and seminar participants at the 2002 Financial Management Association Annual Meeting, Rutgers University, and Villanova University for helpful comments, as well as Craig Coulter for capable research assistance. A Summer Research Fellowship from Villanova University supported this research. Please do not quote or cite without permission of the author. The Relation Between the Cost of Capital and Economic Profit Please do not quote or cite without permission Abstract This paper develops empirical estimates of the average cost of capital for 58 U.S. industries during 1990-1999. A simple, parsimonious theoretical relation between an industry’s weighted average cost of capital (WACC) and the industry’s economic profit is used to obtain empirical estimates of the WACC for these 58 industries. We show that our technique requires fewer data inputs for deriving ex post WACC estimates than the conventional (or “textbook”) cost of capital technique and can be applied to firm-level as well as industry data. We find that our estimates are positively correlated with an industry’s cost of capital estimated via conventional methods and that differences between the two sets of estimates are related to industry-specific differences in growth opportunities and profitability. The model’s estimates are also more positively related to realized stock returns and perform better in out-of-sample forecasts than estimates based on the conventional method. Overall, the results suggest our technique can be a more expedient, descriptive, and precise method of deriving estimates of an industry’s (or firm’s) weighted average cost of capital and economic profit. Estimating a firm’s weighted average cost of capital (WACC) is of critical importance to managers who evaluate investment projects for capital budgeting purposes as well as to investors who wish to assess the overall riskiness and expected return from a company’s activities for valuation purposes. For example, corporate finance textbooks typically devote several chapters to the problems of capital budgeting, cash flow estimation, and the determination of a firm’s cost of capital. However, it can be difficult in practice to obtain reliable estimates of the inputs required to perform capital budgeting as recommended by the textbooks. As Fama and French (1997, 1999) point out, some of these practical difficulties exist because there is considerable uncertainty in estimating a firm’s (or even an industry’s) cost of capital. This uncertainty is similar to the risk faced by the firm when projecting a project’s cash flow. In addition, surveys of corporate finance practitioners indicate there is wide variation in corporate WACC estimation methods, primarily due to managers’ differences in estimating a firm’s cost of equity capital (e.g., see Bruner, Eades, Harris, and Higgins, 1998). Thus, a simple, parsimonious, less-subjective, and accurate method of estimating the WACC for a firm or industry can be a useful tool to managers interested in capital budgeting problems and investment decision-making in general.1 We present such a method and perform empirical tests based on this technique for 58 U.S. industries. In addition, our method provides estimates of economic profit (also referred to as “economic value added” or EVA® by the Stern Stewart and Co. consulting firm). These estimates of economic profit can be useful for analysts who wish to study the long-term performance of corporations before and after an important financial event. For example, our model’s economic profit estimates might be helpful in identifying (via an event study format) the long-term over- or under-performance of firms issuing new securities or merging with other firms. 1 We can define a “simple” method as one that is less intensive in terms of the time and computations required to obtain a WACC estimate when compared to the conventional textbook method. Likewise, a “parsimonious, less-subjective” method can be defined as one that requires fewer inputs and/or calculations that are based on subjective judgments made by the analyst and / or the firm’s management. The conventional approach to identifying a firm’s WACC is based on estimating the costs of the individual components of the firm’s sources of financing.2 For example, computing the WACC for a company with debt and common equity in its capital structure entails estimating: 1) the relative weights of debt and equity in the capital structure, 2) the required after-tax return on the firm’s debt securities, and 3) the required return on the company’s common equity. One of the difficulties in implementing the above method is that it is sometimes hard to identify the correct weights of the capital structure components because the market values of many debt securities (e.g., bank loans, privately placed debt) might not be known. In addition, estimating the required returns on the debt securities can be problematic due to the general paucity of data related to corporate debt instruments. Further, as Fama and French (1997, 2002) confirm, estimating the required return on common equity can be difficult due to the statistical noise inherent in estimating an asset pricing model’s time-varying factor loadings and risk premiums. Using dividend and earnings growth models, Fama and French (2002) show that the expected equity premium for 1951-2000 is probably much lower than estimates based on realized stock returns (e.g., 2.55% – 4.32% versus the 7.43% estimate based on actual stock returns). This result is due to the statistical problems associated with the use of realized returns as proxies for expected returns. Recent results reported in Elton (1999) also suggest the use of historical returns as a proxy for ex ante returns is not appropriate when one examines the long-term performance of various securities such as U.S. government bonds and Tbills. This study addresses the issues described above by proposing a method for estimating a firm’s cost of capital that neither requires estimating the firm’s capital structure nor the firm’s required return on debt and equity securities. The approach is based on the microeconomic concept of “economic profit” first posited by Alfred Marshall (1890) over a century ago. Recent work on economic value added (EVA®) by Stewart (1991) has revived interest in estimating the economic profit of a firm or 2 See Ehrhardt (1994) for an in-depth discussion of the practical application of various methods of cost of capital estimation. 2 industry. Marshall described economic profit as the excess of the entity’s marginal revenue over its marginal cost. Thus, a firm or industry that is generating returns greater than those required by investors is said to be earning economic profits or, in Stewart’s terminology, adding economic value. Conversely, a firm or industry that yields returns less than those required by investors is destroying economic value or generating economic losses. We use the economic profit concept to derive an implicit relation between economic profit and the firm’s weighted average cost of capital. This relation can then be used to estimate firm- or industry-level WACC estimates. These estimates can be obtained via regression analysis using relevant data from the firm’s financial statements. To be more precise, the technique provides an ex post historical average of the firm’s or industry’s marginal cost of capital over the estimation period. By using this method, the analyst is freed from making several (potentially subjective) assumptions about the firm’s capital structure and the costs of these capital components.3 In turn, this historical average of the marginal WACC can be used to formulate ex ante WACC estimates when the firm’s or industry’s WACC fluctuates fairly predictably over time. We identify five main results from testing this new estimation method. First, we find that the average WACC across all 58 industries during 1990-1999 is 11.01% with a general increase in the cost of capital over the two 5-year sub-periods of the sample (i.e., 10.42% in 1990-1994 and 11.34% during 1995-1999). When the model’s average economic profit is restricted to zero (i.e., the model’s intercept equals zero), the estimates also possess small standard errors (0.50-0.67%) and typically explain a large proportion of the variance in the industries’ after-tax operating income (i.e., usually over 90% of the variation). These WACC estimates are statistically more precise than those reported in prior research and suggest that our approach can be used as an aid to practitioners in realworld capital budgeting / security valuation problems. Second, the model’s WACC estimates are significantly positively related to realized stock returns of value-weighted portfolios of the stocks that comprise the 58 industries. The model’s estimates are also more effective in generating out-of-sample forecasts of future levels of industry 3 As Weaver (2001) notes, there is considerable cross-sectional variability in how real-world firms try to estimate their respective cost of capital and economic profit. Weaver finds that no two firms (out of a sample of 29) use the same method to estimate their firms’ cost of capital and EVA®. 3 profitability. This is in contrast to WACC estimates published by Ibbotson Associates using the conventional textbook method. These latter estimates show no significant relation to realized industry stock returns and are poorer predictors of future industry profitability, thus suggesting that our model may be more descriptive of real-world returns to capital. Third, consistent with the finding related to stock returns and our WACC estimates, we find that our WACC estimates are also more closely correlated with relevant financial variables related to profitability and growth opportunities than published estimates based on the conventional textbook method. Thus, our approach holds the potential of providing WACC estimates that are closer descriptions of the actual financial costs facing a firm or industry when compared to using the conventional textbook method of WACC estimation. Fourth, our 1995-1999 results are corroborated by out-of-sample tests for the 1990-1994 period.4 Our approach is therefore robust to the choice of time period. We also find evidence that WACC estimates vary over time in a predictable manner. Specifically, we report statistically significant mean-reversion in our WACC estimates during 1990-1999. This is particularly encouraging in terms of being able to use our ex post averages of the industries’ WACC in order to develop out-of-sample ex ante WACC estimates. Fifth, the technique proposed here also allows us to estimate a firm’s or industry’s average annual economic profit (or EVA®). We find that the average industry generated $2.37 billion in annual excess profit during 1995-1999 and effectively zero EVA® during 1990-1994. This finding appears to be consistent with the strong economic growth and above-normal stock returns experienced in the U.S. during the latter time period. Although the approach presented here simplifies the amount of data required to estimate a firm’s WACC, it typically requires reliance on financial accounting data that might not always reflect economic reality due to accounting conventions such as accruals and revenue/cost matching principles. However, the proposed methodology simplifies 4 Due to the limitations on the Compustat and Ibbotson Associates data available to us, we focus our analysis on the 1990-1999 time period. Clearly, more data for periods earlier than 1990 would be helpful to document the stability of the relations reported here. However, the main thrust of the paper (i.e., the use of the economic profit relation to estimate the weighted average cost of capital) can be demonstrated effectively with the 1990-1999 data. 4 the estimation problem considerably and removes most of the potentially subjective decisions required by the conventional WACC estimation method. Thus, the gains in simplicity and objectivity appear to outweigh the potential drawbacks of using accounting data.5 This paper therefore contributes to the cost of capital literature by providing a new estimation method that can be used to complement or supplement the textbook approach. The rest of the study is organized as follows. Section I reviews some of the research relevant to our analysis. Section II develops the theoretical relations that are then tested using the data and methodology described in Section III. Section IV reports the results of our tests while Section V presents some concluding remarks and avenues for future research. I. Relevant Research As noted in the previous section, there have been several attempts in recent years to estimate the cost of capital of U.S. companies at the industry level. Most notably, Poterba (1998), Fama and French (1997, 1999, 2002), and Gebhardt, Lee, and Swaminathan (2001) use different approaches to tackle the problems associated with estimating the cost of corporate capital. Using the Fama-French (1993) three-factor model, Fama and French (1997) estimated the cost of equity capital for 48 industries and found that, on average, the excess return on equity capital (i.e., the return above the riskfree rate) is 6.64% with a large degree of variability (e.g., standard errors of typically greater than 3.0%). Indeed, the authors claim that the large degree of imprecision in the excess returns makes these estimates useless in practice for corporate discounted cash 5 For example, analysts frequently argue that accounting data might not reflect the true market value of a firm’s activities. However, since we are looking at WACC as a relative measure based on the relation between net operating profits and firm capital, our accounting-based WACC might be as accurate as a market-based estimate when the biases inherent in accounting profits and capital are offsetting. Given recent accounting scandals reported in the popular press, it is comforting to know that, for our methodology, most of management’s accounting choices (including fraudulent ones) are naturally offsetting in terms of accounting profits and the book value of the firm’s total capital. For example, if a company under-states its expenses by fraudulently capitalizing these costs, then both reported profits and total capital are inflated because over-stated profits also lead to over-stated common equity via the retained earnings account. Thus, our method is relatively insensitive to these potential problems with accounting data. 5 flow analysis. In addition, economy-wide WACC estimates are also relatively imprecise with Fama and French (1999) reporting standard errors ranging from 1.67% to 2.21%. The authors admit that even these standard errors are probably under-estimates of the true standard errors. Fama and French (2002) show that equity premiums based on fundamentals such as dividend and earnings growth can yield more precise estimates of equity premiums than those based on realized stock returns. For example, the standard error of dividend growth during 1951-2000 was 0.74% and is much smaller than the standard error of 2.43% for average stock returns during this time period. This recent evidence from Fama and French (2002) is consistent with our findings that using fundamental data can lead to more precise estimates of a firm’s cost of capital. Gebhardt et al. (2001) estimate the cost of equity capital but use a dividend discount model (DDM) methodology and IBES earnings estimates. They find that the cost of equity capital for large, U.S. publicly traded companies ranged between 10% and 12% during 1979-1995, depending on the assumptions used with the DDM approach. Interestingly, Myers and Borucki (1994) obtain the same range of estimates for the cost of equity capital of a limited sample of U.S. utility companies using a DDM-type method. Similar to Claus and Thomas (2001), Easton, Taylor, Shroff, and Sougiannis (2001) employ a less-restrictive version of the model used by Gebhardt et al. (2001) and find somewhat higher estimates of the industry-level cost of equity capital with an average value of around 13% during 1981-1998 for publicly traded stocks that are followed by the I/B/E/S information service. However, these papers require analyst forecasts that Claus and Thomas (2001), among others, find to be biased upward (i.e., analysts typically over-estimate the actual growth rate of earnings). Fama and French (1999) and Poterba (1998) are recent examples of research focused on estimating WACC rather than simply a firm’s equity capital.6 Poterba (1998) uses aggregate financial flow of funds data from 1959-1996 to estimate the annual inflation-adjusted WACC for the entire U.S. macroeconomy. He reports an inflation- 6 These papers follow in path of the seminal empirical work on cost of capital estimation presented in Miller and Modigliani (1966). 6 adjusted WACC of 5.1% which translates to a nominal WACC estimate between 8% and 9%. Fama and French (1999) use Compustat data for 1950-1996 to estimate the annual WACC for large, publicly traded U.S. companies using the discounted cash flow technique. Their estimates of 7.1% - 7.3% for the inflation-adjusted WACC are somewhat higher than those reported by Poterba (1998). On a nominal basis, Fama and French (1999) show estimates that range from 10.7% to 11.8%. As Fama and French note, the difference between the two sets of estimates could be driven by Fama-French’s selective sample of larger, publicly traded U.S. companies when compared with Poterba’s more comprehensive data set. In effect, Poterba’s estimate captures smaller, private companies as well as the large, publicly traded companies analyzed in Fama and French (1999). If these small, private firms are less risky and less profitable than their larger, public peers, then one could explain the observed difference between the two sets of WACC estimates in terms of differences in the sample of companies employed. As noted in the previous section, Ehrhardt (1994) and Bruner et al. (1998) identify several areas where the conventional textbook approach can force analysts to make subjective judgments. For example, Ehrhardt (1994) notes that choices related to the selection of asset pricing model, market factor proxy, periodicity of returns, and capital structure can all cause WACC estimates to vary widely. Bruner et al. (1998) and Weaver (2001) confirm these observations by surveying large corporations about their WACC methodologies. Both sets of authors find that significant differences exist in estimating the equity capital component of the firm, particularly via the use of the CAPM. Ideally, we desire a less-subjective WACC method that allows the results of actual firm-specific economic activities to “speak for themselves” and removes as many ad hoc judgments made by analysts and / or the firm’s managers as possible from the estimation process. As will be described in greater detail in the following section, our approach proposes a solution to several of the problems that have confronted researchers in this area. 7 II. Theoretical Framework As noted above, we can use the EVA framework first detailed in Stewart (1991) to derive an empirical relation that is useful for obtaining estimates of a firm’s or an industry’s WACC: EVAit = NOPATit - WACCit ⋅ TOTAL CAPITALit-1 (1) where, EVAit = economic value added for the i-th firm at time-t, NOPATit = net operating profit after taxes for the i-th firm at time-t,7 WACCit = weighted average cost of capital for the i-th firm at time-t, and TOTAL CAPITALit = book value of long-term debt, common stock, and preferred stock for the i-th firm at time-(t-1).8, 9 7 The basic definition of NOPAT is defined as Earnings Before Interest but after Taxes (i.e., NOPAT = EBIT – Taxes) generated at time-t. NOPAT is defined as the quarterly Compustat data item, Operating Income after Depreciation, which is derived by subtracting Cost of Goods Sold (Q30), SG&A Expense (Q1), and Depreciation (Q5) from Sales (Q2). Taxes are defined as the difference between Pretax Income (Q23) and Net Income (Q69). For simplicity, we follow the typical financial convention and assume that this flow variable is received at one point in time (i.e., at time-t) even though, in reality, NOPAT is most likely generated over the entire period between time-t-1 and time-t. As Stewart (1991) discusses, adjustments to the NOPAT definition can be used to tailor the NOPAT figure to a specific firm or industry. Note that Depreciation Expense is not added back to EBIT to obtain NOPAT. This is because depreciation is viewed as a true economic cost that represents the amount of money that the firm must spend to maintain its existing set of assets. See Peterson and Peterson (1996) and Stewart (1991) for a detailed discussion of how to estimate NOPAT, as well as TOTAL CAPITAL. Depending on the company, Peterson and Peterson note that numerous adjustments can be made to the basic NOPAT formula. In our case, data on most of these adjustments are not available on a quarterly basis. Consequently, we focus our analysis on the basic definition of NOPAT. 8 As Peterson and Peterson (1996) point out, the relevant estimate of a firm’s total capital is based on book values, not market values, when the analyst is attempting to assess the historical performance of a firm in terms of EVA®. This is based on the notion that market values (particularly for equity) include forwardlooking estimates of the value of future growth prospects. However, the NOPAT figure is based on historical accounting data that are derived from existing assets. Thus, using market value data for TOTAL CAPITAL will bias EVA® estimates downward because NOPAT will appear relatively low since it does not directly include future growth opportunities. This situation further simplifies our estimation process because market values for many debt instruments are frequently difficult to obtain. By using book values, the problem of finding market values for debt securities is avoided. Also, the TOTAL CAPITAL variable which is lagged one period in Equation (1) to avoid counting the current portion of Retained Earnings as part of the firm’s capital at the beginning of the current period. The quarterly Compustat data items used for long-term debt, preferred stock, and common equity are Q51, Q55, and Q59, respectively. 9 Note that we do not include short-term debt (Q45) in our specification because many textbooks, as well as most practitioners, focus on the long-term sources of corporate financing (long-term debt, preferred stock, common stock) when estimating a firm’s cost of capital. For example, Gitman and Vandenberg (2000) find in a survey of large U.S. firms that most practitioners focus on the long-term debt and common equity components of the capital structure when estimating their firms’ respective WACC. As will be discussed in the Empirical Results section, our results are not affected materially by the inclusion or exclusion of short-term debt from the TOTAL CAPITAL calculation. 8 Damodoran (1996) describes in detail how (1) can be viewed as an equilibrium relation for a value-maximizing firm that has established an optimal capital structure and generates sufficient perpetual, non-growing cash flows that satisfy investors’ required returns on the firm’s securities. If, for example, the return generated by the firm’s equity does not meet investors’ required return, then investors will exert selling pressure on the firm’s common stock so that, in equilibrium, the firm’s stock price falls to a level that equates the investors’ required equity return with the expected return on the firm’s stock. Growth in NOPAT can be accommodated in (1) by assuming a constant growth rate, g, and including it within the WACC term. In this case, WACC = (NOPAT / TOTAL CAPITAL) + g. This is similar in spirit to Gordon’s (1961) constant growth model for equity valuation. Non-constant growth can also be incorporated into the definition but this makes the WACC term more complicated and requires additional assumptions by the analyst. For the sake of simplicity, we use the perpetual, zero growth definition included in (1) for our analysis. To the extent that growth in NOPAT is large and variable, our estimates of WACC will differ from the “true” WACC figures. Indeed, we perform tests to determine which financial variables can explain differences in our WACC estimates with those developed using the conventional textbook approach and published by a commercial financial analysis firm, Ibbotson Associates (see the following Data section for more details). It should also be noted that our WACC estimates based on (1) are unbiased when growth is a constant (g) and the firm’s dividend/profit retention policy is irrelevant for valuation purposes. For example, it can be shown that the WACC estimates will be unchanged if growth is constant and can be estimated via a conventional formula such as: g = (after-tax net operating profit retention ratio ⋅ WACC). Plugging this formula into a constant growth model of total firm valuation (i.e., firm value = [(1 – retention ratio) ⋅ NOPAT] / (WACC – g)) yields a relation between firm value and WACC that is independent of the growth rate. That is, using a conventional constant growth model and inserting the above assumptions about growth and WACC yields the relation that firm value = NOPAT / WACC. Thus, our simplified model presented in (1) might also be 9 relatively accurate when the above conditions hold for a particular firm or industry with non-zero growth.10 [NOTE to Reviewer: Please see the attached supplement at the end of the paper that demonstrates algebraically and numerically the independence between value and growth when the above assumptions are met.] Another perspective for interpreting (1) can be traced to Marshall (1890). As is well known from microeconomic theory, in a perfectly competitive industry, equilibrium occurs when marginal revenue equals marginal cost. In terms of Equation (1), we can view NOPATit as the firm’s marginal return on capital and WACCit ⋅ TOTAL CAPITALit as the marginal cost of capital. Thus, in equilibrium, EVAit should be zero. However, as Marshall (1890) noted, firms and/or industries might be in temporary disequilibrium because a new product or technological innovation can convey economic, or “abnormal,” profits on a firm/industry that, ultimately, attracts competitors that, in turn, eventually erode these profits and force EVAit back to zero. We can view EVAit in Equation (1) as an estimate of the Marshallian concept of economic profit. Re-arranging (1) and including a stochastic disturbance term, eit, yields a more useful relation for the purposes of estimating WACC:11 NOPATit = EVAi + WACCi ⋅ TOTAL CAPITALit-1 + eit (2) In the above specification, we can interpret EVAi and WACCi as parameters to be estimated via a bivariate regression analysis, where NOPATit is the dependent variable and TOTAL CAPITALit-1 is the independent variable. To account for possible heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation in the residuals, we use the Newey-West (1984) 10 Note that there is more than one way to demonstrate the irrelevance of the growth factor when specific assumptions are used to constrain a constant growth valuation model. In our case, we use some standard textbook definitions of the dividend payout ratio and the growth rate to show the independence between growth and value. Other approaches can also arrive at the same conclusion using different definitions and the constancy of factors such as operating profitability, a capital requirement ratio, and the investment in capital. Since other approaches yield the same conclusion as ours, we prefer to use our original formulation because it is more closely aligned with the standard textbook definitions of the components of a constant growth valuation model. We thank an anonymous referee for pointing out the possibility of these alternative approaches. 11 The stochastic disturbance term is included because unusual, non-recurring errors might be contained in the historical financial data. For example, a major revision in an accounting standard might significantly affect NOPAT and/or TOTAL CAPITAL for a specific quarter or year. Or, the firm/industry might have an unusually good or bad quarter due to a merger, strike, lawsuit, etc. Thus, the eit term attempts to capture these random idiosyncracies in the accounting data. 10 generalized method of moments (GMM) estimator of the model’s variance-covariance matrix. When the instrumental variables used in the analysis are the same as the independent variables in Equation (2), the GMM parameters are identical to those obtained via OLS but the standard errors are adjusted for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation. Strictly speaking, a regression’s parameter estimates of our model described above in Equation (2) are ex post averages over time of the marginal cost of capital and marginal economic profit related to a specific industry or firm. When the markets for physical and financial capital are efficient, investors can use the realized levels of NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL as reliable indicators of a firm’s or industry’s cash flows and invested capital. In this case, the regression parameter estimates from (2) can be interpreted as the average levels of EVA and WACC during the estimation period. That is, we can view the intercept and slope parameters of Equation (2) as measures of the average relationship between an industry’s NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL over the sample period. In Equation (2), the estimated intercept is an expected value of the average level of EVA over the sample period that has a standard error associated with it. Likewise, the slope parameter estimate can be interpreted as the expected WACC over the sample period that also possesses a standard error. Therefore, the estimated intercept and slope parameter in Equation (2) should not be interpreted as being literally constant over the entire sample period. Instead, these parameter estimates should be viewed as econometric theory defines them: that is, as measures of the average relationship between NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL that minimizes the sum of squared residuals. Viewed in this light, we can see that EVA and WACC do not have to be constant for every quarter within our sample period in order for us to obtain reliable parameter estimates via Equation (2).12 12 While we agree that one needs to make certain assumptions in order to use the EVA relation for empirical estimation purposes as defined by Equation (2) (e.g., a constant growth framework and efficient markets), we would like to point out that, based on fundamental econometric theory, the intercept term of our bivariate regression, EVA, is equal to: EVA = average of NOPAT - (WACC parameter estimate * average of TOTAL CAPITAL). Thus, the intercept can be interpreted as follows: the average level of an industry's EVA is literally a function of the average levels of NOPAT, WACC, and TOTAL CAPITAL and does not have to be constrained to a constant value for all time periods within the sample period. So, our model is amenable to empirical testing because, based on the econometric relationship noted above, we do not require EVA (or WACC for that matter) to be constant for all time periods. 11 We can use time series accounting data for a firm or industry to estimate the parameters of Equation (2).13 The slope parameter of this regression provides us with an estimate of the relevant firm’s or industry’s average WACC for the time period analyzed. For example, we can use quarterly accounting data for 1995-1999 to estimate the 5-year average of the marginal WACC for an industry during the late 1990s. This estimate is obtained simply (via generalized method of moments, GMM) and less subjectively (because there is less room for analyst judgment in the choice of data inputs).14 As noted earlier, Equation (2) shows that the intercept term of a bivariate regression yields an estimate of the firm’s or industry’s average EVA® over the estimation period. One can view this estimate as the 5-year average of the economic value added by the firm or industry. For example, if we use annual accounting data, then the EVA® estimate from (2) is an estimate of the average annual marginal economic profit generated by the firm or industry.15 13 Equation (2) can also be estimated cross-sectionally at a point in time. For example, we could estimate the WACC for an industry during a specific quarter or year by using a cross-section of quarterly or annual financial statement data for firms within that industry. Similarly, one could also estimate an economy-wide WACC by using a cross-section of industry-level financial statement data. In either case, weighted least squares (WLS) would be appropriate for these cross-sectional analyses in order to account for differences in the size of firms within an industry or the size of industries within a macroeconomy. To conserve space, we focus on the time series application of Equation (2). 14 In Equation (2), the “true” value of NOPAT may be measured with error whereas the TOTAL CAPITAL variable is more or less directly observable since it is based on book values (as theory suggests). As Greene (1993) notes, the measurement error of NOPAT is not a problem in terms of biasing our parameter estimates since NOPAT appears as the dependent variable in (2). Therefore, the effect of measurement error in our model is reflected in a more volatile error term rather than biased parameter estimates. As we will see in the Empirical Results section of the paper, the relatively tight fit of our model suggests that NOPAT’s measurement error is not a significant problem in our sample. 15 It should be noted that the model can expanded to accommodate increased complexity, such as timevarying interest rates, via explicit risk premiums for an industry’s cost of debt and equity. However, we think that such a model departs from our original objective of constructing a simple, parsimonious model that does not require the analyst to choose a specific asset pricing model for the cost of debt and equity. By choosing a specific asset pricing model, we would be moving towards a potentially more accurate model but one that is decidedly more complex and more taxing on the analyst in terms of developing inputs and assumptions for the model. This is the classic trade-off in financial modeling between simplicity / tractability and realism. Our position is that we prefer to use a simpler, possibly more stylized model given the inherent difficulties in developing sensible inputs and results when a model is too detailed. Thus, we use the model described by Equation (2) but readily admit that the model can be expanded upon if an analyst has specific preferences related to the choice of asset pricing model. We thank an anonymous referee for pointing out this possibility. 12 Another relation implied by (2) also pertains to the intercept term, EVAi. If we suppress the intercept term of the regression of (2), then we are, in effect, estimating a restricted form of (2) where the WACC slope parameter can be interpreted as an estimate of the “required” WACC for a firm/industry based on a rational expectations equilibrium. In addition, the approach ensures that the average NOPAT is equal to the expectation of NOPAT generated by the right hand side of Equation (2). As Muth (1961) first noted, market participants form rational expectations when, on average, their expectations are indeed realized over time and there are no systematic errors in their forecasts. Thus, according to Muth (1961), for an estimate to be a rational expectation it simply has to have no systematic biases. That is, when the EVAi parameter is suppressed in our regression, we are estimating what return, on average, rational investors would have required on the firm’s/industry’s assets in order to earn a “fair” return (i.e., a return which yields an NPV of zero, which is equivalent to yielding an average EVA of zero over the period of analysis). It should also be noted that we are not claiming that the restricted form of our model will yield the “true” WACC for an industry or firm. Our objective in suppressing the intercept is to estimate a “required” WACC value for a given industry over a specified sample period, which might not be equal to the “true” unobserved WACC because of measurement error or other modeling problems. That is, when the intercept is suppressed, we are stating that EVA is, on average, zero over the sample period and that the resulting slope parameter estimate is consistent with a rational investor’s unbiased expectation of an industry’s WACC during this time period. Given the properties of the OLS and GMM estimators, our WACC estimates satisfy this requirement. In addition, our estimates are preferable to other rational expectations estimates because our estimates also satisfy the criterion of minimizing the sum of squared residuals. When we suppress the intercept and estimate our “required” WACC values for each industry, we are not requiring EVA to be zero for all periods and we are not trying to estimate the unknowable “true” WACC. Our more modest goal is to show that the model can be used to uncover what WACC a rational expectations investor would require so that EVA would be, on average, zero during the sample period. Note also that this does not require the investor to have perfect foreknowledge since there is an error term contained within 13 our model. Thus, a rational investor can make forecasting errors, as long as there is no systematic bias in these errors. Accordingly, we can re-estimate (2) a second time without the intercept term in order to obtain estimates of the relevant WACCs required by investors within a rational expectations framework. It is also important to note that suppressing the intercept in our model does not imply that one can estimate the firm’s WACC by algebraically manipulating Equation (2). For example, one cannot calculate the firm’s WACC by simply dividing the firm’s average NOPAT by the firm’s average TOTAL CAPITAL (i.e., WACC ≠ average NOPAT ÷ average TOTAL CAPITAL). As Greene (1993) and Kennedy (1998) demonstrate, the mean of a dependent variable in a bivariate regression (e.g., a random variable denoted as y) will not equal the product of the slope’s parameter estimate and the mean of the random independent variable (denoted as x) when the intercept is set to zero. Both Greene and Kennedy show that the slope parameter is estimated in this case via the equation: slope = Σyx / Σx2. Only by coincidence would this slope parameter estimate be equal to the ratio of the means of y and x. Thus, one must estimate the slope parameter (in our model, the WACC parameter) via regression and cannot be estimated by simply dividing the historical averages of NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL. In theory, it is the above estimates of the “required” WACC that should be used in corporate decision-making rather than ex post, unrestricted WACC estimates based on historical realizations of the firm’s cash flows. To the extent that these required WACC estimates change slowly and predictably over time, these historical estimates can be useful to an analyst who wishes to forecast the future level of WACC for a firm or industry. In our discussion of the empirical results (Section IV), we report the results of this required WACC estimation process as well as the results based on the unrestricted form of Equation (2). Thus, we develop two estimates of WACC via Equation (2), an ex post required return (using the restricted equation) and an ex post realized return (based on the unrestricted equation). Given (2), we can gather the relevant time series of accounting data for a set of companies and estimate the WACCi and EVAi parameters. However, we must verify whether or not these estimates are realistic by comparing our WACC figures to WACC estimates derived from the conventional cost of capital approach. In the ideal case, our 14 approach would be of great use to analysts and managers if it could generate reasonably accurate WACC estimates but without the need for subjective judgments and timeconsuming data collection required by the conventional method. Thus, we can generate another set of WACC estimates using the conventional approach and then compare these estimates with the WACC figures derived from (2). Our expectation is that our WACC estimates will be positively correlated with the conventional cost of capital figures. III. Data and Empirical Methodology A. Data The data used to estimate Equation (2) were obtained from the Standard & Poor’s Compustat database. We use quarterly data for 1990-1999 to compute NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL for 58 U.S. industries (based on the primary two-digit SIC designations of individual firms).16 The NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL figures for each company within an industry are summed to obtain quarterly industry-wide estimates of NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL.17 We then use these data to estimate industry-specific WACCs for three time periods (1990-1994, 1995-1999, and 1990-1999). To create annual estimates of WACC and EVA®, we form four-quarter moving sums of the NOPAT variable.18 In this way, the slope and intercept terms of (2) can be directly interpreted as annual estimates of the relevant industry’s WACC and EVA®.19 This 16 See the Appendix for the Standard Industry Classification (SIC) definitions of the 58 industries. 17 To reduce survivorship bias, we do not require each company to have data for all years in the sample. A firm’s data are included as long as it has data for any quarter during January 1990 – December 1999. 18 According to the EVA® proponents at Stern Stewart and Co., there are numerous alternative definitions of NOPAT that can be used. Yook (1999) attempts to estimate NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL using five of the most common adjustments recommended by Stern Stewart and Co. We find a very high correlation between our simple definitions of NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL noted earlier and those computed using Yook’s method. For example, our simple definitions of NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL have statistically significant correlations of 0.94 and 0.86 with Yook’s method of calculating these variables. Due to very high positive correlation between these alternative definitions, we prefer to use the simpler forms of NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL described earlier for the tests reported here. 19 It should be noted that some of our WACC and EVA® estimates could be biased downward if there are numerous small, young firms within an industry. This type of firm typically has low or negative NOPAT yet can have relatively high levels of TOTAL CAPITAL. This problem is mitigated by the fact that we use 2-digit SIC codes (rather than 3- or 4-digit SICs) and thus our industry categories are rather broad and contain, on average, over 60 firms in each industry group. Thus, the 2-digit SIC groups are much more 15 approach also has the advantage of smoothing out some of the quarter-to-quarter volatility present in NOPAT, thus reducing the potential distortionary effects of cyclical/seasonal variations in NOPAT. In addition, the use of the GMM estimation technique helps adjust the model’s standard errors to account for any autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity that the moving sum of NOPAT might create so that proper inferences about the model parameters can be made. To develop a benchmark WACC estimate for each industry to compare with our estimates, we use the annual editions of the Ibbotson Associates’ Cost of Capital Quarterly (CCQ) publication. This source provides five different estimates of WACC for the 58 two-digit SIC industries employed in our analysis. The CCQ estimates are all calculated using the textbook approach described earlier. The five estimates correspond to different methods of estimating an industry’s cost of equity capital.20 For example, CCQ publishes WACC estimates based on the conventional CAPM, a “size-adjusted” CAPM, Fama and French’s (1993) three-factor model, as well as two estimates based on discounted cash flow techniques (see Ibbotson Associates, 1999, or their web site, www.ibbotson.com for more details on these estimation methods).21 The firms included in our 58 industry estimates are matched with the firms included in Ibbotson’s CCQ reports on an annual basis. We then form 5-year averages of these annual WACC estimates for the 1995-1999 period and across Ibbotson’s five estimation methods. As noted earlier, firms are allowed to enter and leave the industry groups over our sample’s time horizon, thus minimizing potential survivorship bias. The above matching procedure yields a total of 3,653 companies across the 58 industries. However, our sample is limited to publicly traded firms and therefore our results are not directly applicable to privately held companies that might operate in these industries. likely to include a representative mix of large and medium-sized, established firms rather than be dominated by smallish, young start-ups. 20 Similar to our model’s WACC estimates, Ibbotson’s estimates are value-weighted within each industry to ensure comparability between our method and theirs. 21 The analysts at Ibbotson Associates also adjust their estimates based on “reality checks”. For example, WACC estimates less than the yield on a 20-year U.S. Treasury bond or greater than 100% are omitted altogether. 16 B. Empirical Methodology B. 1) Estimating the Cost of Capital To estimate Equation (2), we first use quarterly Compustat data for 1995-1999 for each company within a two-digit SIC industry to compute aggregate, industry-wide values for NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL. Therefore, we have 58 quarterly values for these two variables for each of the 20 quarters that comprise the January, 1995 – December, 1999 time period. In effect, we form 58 time series (one for each industry) where each series comprises 20 quarters of data. We then perform separate regression analyses based on (2) to obtain WACC estimates for each of the 58 industries. These WACC estimates are the 5-year average of marginal WACCs for the relevant industries during the 1995-1999.22 For corporate managers, this historical estimate can be of use in determining how their firm’s WACC compares with its relevant industry. For example, industries such as public utility companies might find the above estimates useful in determining how to set utility rates within a particular operating region. B. 2) Two Types of Out-of-Sample Tests One way to test the robustness of our model is by re-estimating (2) for a time period outside the original 1995-1999 sample period. For example, we can perform an out-of-sample test of (2) to obtain required WACCs for each of the 58 industries during an earlier time period (e.g., 1990-1994). We can compare these WACC estimates to the 1995-1999 estimates to see if there are substantial differences over the two time periods. However, we cannot compare the 1990-1994 estimates to Ibbotson’s figures because Ibbotson Associates did not begin publishing the CCQ report until 1995. Nevertheless, the out-of-sample tests can be useful for replicating the model’s 1995-1999 results and to study the dynamics of how WACC estimates change over time. We have also developed a second out-of-sample test of our model’s validity by using the following relation to forecast NOPAT one quarter ahead over the entire 20quarter 1995-1999 period: 22 As described in the previous section, we can re-estimate (2) a second time without an intercept term in order to derive estimates of the required WACC. 17 NOPATi,t = EVAi + (WACCi * TOTAL CAPITALi,t-1) (3) Where the right-hand-side estimates of EVAi and WACCi are based on a regression using 1990-1994 data for the i-th industry. We then use actual quarterly data for TOTAL CAPITAL during the 1995-1999 period to estimate NOPAT for each quarter (and each industry) of this out-of-sample period. For example, we use the actual TOTAL CAPITAL at the end of the fourth quarter of 1994, along with our model’s parameter estimates for EVAi and WACCi, to forecast NOPAT for the first quarter of 1995. (We can use the actual TOTAL CAPITAL level for the previous quarter because the above relation specifies that TOTAL CAPITAL is lagged one quarter.) We then use the actual TOTAL CAPITAL for the first quarter of 1995 (along with the same 1990-1994 parameter estimates for EVAi and WACCi) to forecast NOPAT for the second quarter of 1995, and so on. We can compare these forecasts of NOPAT with the actual values of NOPAT to compute the statistics reported later in Table 4 of the Empirical Results section. Note that we do not re-estimate our model’s parameters using additional information contained in the quarterly data within the 1995-1999 period. The parameters are effectively “frozen” at the end of 1994 and are not allowed the benefit of, for example, the additional information contained in the first quarter of 1995 to forecast NOPAT for the second quarter of 1995, and so on. Thus, our test is a particularly strict one that works against our model’s estimates in terms of developing accurate out-of-sample forecasts. For the Ibbotson WACC estimates, we compute the forecast statistics using the only data available to us (i.e., the 1995-1999 Average and Median estimates). Thus, we are stacking the test further in favor of Ibbotson’s estimates because these estimates are based on data contained within the out-of-sample test period of 1995-1999. As noted earlier, we are forced to use these data because Ibbotson did not start developing WACC estimates until 1995. Also, the test favors Ibbotson’s estimates because these estimates are based on updated information and are not “frozen” like our estimates. For example, Ibbotson’s 1996 WACC estimates contain information for 1995 while our forecasts do not. Given that more information is better than less information in terms of generating accurate forecasts, our model’s forecasts are at a distinct disadvantage when compared to Ibbotson’s. 18 B. 3) Comparing the Cost of Capital Estimates with Realized Stock Returns Another way to test the robustness of the model is by comparing our WACC estimates with realized stock returns for each of the industry groups. We expect our WACC estimates to be positively related to realized stock returns because the definition of a firm’s cost of capital shows that WACC is a positive linear function of the firm’s cost of equity capital. Thus, on average, an industry’s realized stock returns should be a reasonable proxy for the cost of equity capital that, in turn, implies a positive correlation between our WACC estimates and realized stock returns. In addition, we can compare the correlation of our WACC estimates with stock returns to the correlation of Ibbotson’s WACC estimates with these same stock returns. If our technique provides a closer approximation of the industry’s “true” (but unobservable) WACC, then we would expect our WACC estimates to be more positively related to realized stock returns than Ibbotson’s estimates.23 B. 4) Comparing the Cost of Capital Estimates with Ibbotson’s Estimates Once the WACC estimates are computed according to Equation (2), we can compare them to the Ibbotson CCQ estimates to determine whether or not our methodology yields estimates that are consistent with those derived via the textbook approach. The non-parametric Wilcoxon test can be performed in order to make these comparisons. Since we do not know whether our WACC estimates or those from Ibbotson Associates are the nearest approximations of the “true” unobservable WACCs, we can use simple correlation analysis to see which set of estimates are more closely 23 It should be noted that, ideally, it would be better to compare our WACC estimates with the total returns to both stockholders and debtholders. However, we cannot obtain reliable estimates of the return to debtholders because we do not have sufficient data on the average yield to maturity (YTM) of each firm’s / industry’s debt load. We therefore do not think approximations such as estimating the cost of debt via the division of interest payments by the book value of outstanding debt are appropriate because this method does not capture: a) the current YTM facing the firm (instead, it represents the current yield at the time the debt was issued), b) sudden changes in financial leverage that might cause interest payments to appear very high (or very low) relative to end-of-period debt figures (thus creating unreasonably high, or low, cost of debt estimates), and c) bond-related capital gains. In addition, from a statistical perspective, the returns on equity will typically be much more volatile than the returns on debt. Thus, the correlations between our WACC estimates and the industry’s total returns to both stockholders and debtholders will be driven largely by the correlations between our WACC estimates and the industry’s stock returns. So, the use of stock returns rather than returns to both shareholders and debtholders is most likely not that problematic for our purposes. 19 correlated to key financial variables related to stock returns, profitability, growth opportunities, risk, and liquidity.24 The set of estimates that are most closely correlated with these variables can be interpreted as a more accurate description of the industry’s actual cost of capital. This follows from the premise that the true cost of capital should be influenced by factors such as profitability, growth opportunities, risk, and liquidity. In addition to the univariate tests described above, we can estimate a crosssectional regression using the differences between our 58 average required WACC estimates and the 5-year averages (or medians) of the Ibbotson WACCs as the dependent variable.25 These differences in the WACC estimates can then be regressed on a set of variables based on the factors noted above. For example, we can estimate the following cross-sectional regression: Required WACCi - Ibbotson Average WACCi = DIFFMEANi = f(Growth Opportunitiesi, Profitabilityi, Riski, Liquidityi) + vi (4) where, Required WACCi = WACCi estimated via Equation (2) with the intercept suppressed, Ibbotson Average WACCi = 5-year average of WACCi estimated via Ibbotson CCQ’s five techniques,26 Growth Opportunitiesi = proxy variables such as the Market-to-Book Equity ratio (MB) and the percentage of sales derived internationally (FORSALE),27 24 Since theory does not provide us with an explicit set of factors that affect a firm’s cost of capital, we have chosen those influences that have been typically cited in the literature. 25 Using differences between Ibbotson’s and our model’s WACC estimates provides a more parsimonious and efficient way of identifying differences between the two sets of WACC estimates when compared to estimating Equation (4) below using the means and medians of the two sets of WACC estimates in separate regressions. The results of performing separate regressions of Equation (4) for Ibbotson’s and our model’s WACC estimates are qualitatively similar to those reported in Table 8 and are not reported here in order to conserve space. 26 This variable is calculated by taking annual averages of the five average WACC estimates Ibbotson Associates reports in its annual CCQ report based on five different asset pricing models and then averaging these annual estimates over the entire 1995-1999 period. Similarly, we can form a 5-year average of the annual medians of the five Ibbotson estimates to create an alternate dependent variable, DIFFMEDIANi. Thus, DIFFMEDIANi = Required WACCi – 5-year average of Ibbotson’s Median WACCi. 27 FORSALE can be viewed as a proxy for growth opportunities since extensive international sales imply large, growing markets for the industry’s goods and services. In addition, FORSALE can be viewed as a 20 Profitabilityi = Return on Common Equity (ROE), Riski = Stock Price Volatility (VOL) and Assets-to-Common Equity ratio (LEVERAGE),28 Liquidityi = Share trading volume (VOLUME), and vi = stochastic disturbance term for the i-th industry. To be consistent with the dependent variable, the independent variables are computed as 5-year averages of annual data during 1995-1999.29 As described in the theoretical framework of Section II, our model of WACC found in Equation (2) is most directly applicable to firms with zero growth (or to firms with constant growth-- assuming dividend/profit retention policy is irrelevant). Thus, differences between Ibbotson’s and our WACC estimates might be due to differences related to growth (e.g., industryspecific growth opportunities and profitability). In addition, the riskiness of an industry’s equity, financial leverage (possibly serving as a proxy for financial distress costs), and liquidity can also affect the cost of capital estimates. As noted above, since theory does not give us clear guidance about the factors to be included in (3), we have chosen those variables that are typically cited in the empirical literature as proxies for these four influences. If our model’s estimates are valid measures of the “true” WACC, then the parameter estimates for MB, FORSALE, ROE, VOL, and LEVERAGE should be positive (due to the direct relation between WACC and factors such as growth opportunities, profitability, risk, and financial distress costs). In contrast, the parameter estimates for VOLUME should be negative due to the inverse relation between WACC proxy for risk (due to the diversification possibilities of international operations as well as the risks related to foreign currency movements and international politics). 28 VOL is defined as the difference between the annual high and low stock price divided by the prior year’s year-end stock price and is reported in Compustat as a measure of stock price risk. Other market-based risk measures, such as a market-weighted industry average beta, were also tested. However, VOL exhibited the strongest relation with the dependent variable and thus is the market-based measure reported here. 29 The 5-year averages of the independent variables, MB, ROE, VOL, LEVERAGE, are obtained from the annual market value-weighted averages of the relevant variables for each industry. For VOLUME and FORSALE, data for individual firms within an industry are simply summed each year and then averaged over the 5-year period. 21 and liquidity. So, if we find statistically significant parameters consistent with these expectations, then we can infer that our model’s WACC estimates are more responsive to the above factors than Ibbotson’s estimates. This finding would provide indirect evidence that our model generates WACC estimates that are more descriptive of realworld variations in key financial variables. In addition, this result would suggest that our assumption of zero growth in Equation (2) is not that restrictive since our model can, even with this assumption, provide WACC estimates that are more responsive to important financial variables than the conventional approach. Conversely, if we find that the parameters for these variables are statistically significant and are of opposite sign to those noted above, then we can infer that our model’s WACC estimates are not good descriptions of the true WACC. Likewise, if we find that the parameters are not statistically significant, then we can infer that the above factors affect our WACC and Ibbotson’s WACC estimates in a similar manner and that differences in the two estimates are not attributable to those factor(s). In sum, if we find differences between our estimates and those of Ibbotson, then the correlation and regression analyses should confirm which variables related to growth opportunities, profitability, risk, and liquidity explain a substantial portion of DIFFMEAN (or DIFFMEDIAN). In turn, these analyses should help us answer the question regarding the relevance of Equation (2) in estimating industry-specific costs of capital. IV. Empirical Results A. The Cost of Capital Estimates Before discussing the results of the various tests described in the previous section, it should be noted that diagnostic tests were performed on the two key variables found in Equation (2). Namely, we performed unit root and cointegration tests for each of the 58 industry-specific time series of NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL. These tests are based on Phillips and Perron (1988) and Phillips and Ouliaris (1990), respectively. None of the 58 pairs of NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL variables are cointegrated or non- 22 stationary.30 Thus, we can proceed with our tests knowing that these econometric problems are not biasing our results. Panel A of Table 1 provides summary statistics of the industry WACC estimates based on Equation (2) and the textbook approach, while Panel B contains statistics for selected cross-sectional financial variables. This table shows that the average WACC for the entire set of 58 industries during the 1995-1999 time period was 10.09% based on estimating (2) in its unrestricted form (referred to as the Ex Post WACC).31 However, the estimates based on this form are relatively noisy with a large average standard error of 2.67%. This wide variation is consistent with the notion that the estimates are essentially realized return estimates which, by their nature, will typically be more volatile than investors’ ex ante returns. Despite the noisiness of the Ex Post WACC figures, the unrestricted form of (2) has the side-benefit of providing an estimate of the average annual EVA® generated by the firms that comprise the 58 industries used in our analysis. As Table 1 reports, the average annual economic value added was $2.367 billion during 1995-1999. This figure is statistically significant at the 1% confidence level. This postive EVA® finding is not that surprising given the exceptionally strong economic conditions and stock market performance during the late 1990s. We also show in Table 1 that, based on the restricted form of (2), the average required WACC required by investors was 11.34% (referred to as the Required WACC in the table).32 In effect, this is the return that would have set the average EVA® equal to 30 Results are available, on request, from the author. 31 We refer to the unrestricted form’s WACC estimate as the “Ex Post WACC” because this estimate is based on realized values of NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL and therefore represents an estimate of the actual cost of capital realized by investors rather than a required return on invested capital. 32 Note that our model’s WACC estimates reported here and in subsequent tables are based on the exclusion of short-term debt from the TOTAL CAPITAL calculation and the inclusion of debt-related tax benefits in our NOPAT computation. Thus, strictly speaking, our resulting slope parameter estimates can be viewed as an estimate of the before-tax WACC for each industry. When we re-estimate the restricted model with the debt-related tax benefits excluded from NOPAT to estimate an after-tax WACC, we find, as expected, that the average required WACC is lower (10.51% vs. 11.34%) but that the precision of the WACC estimates remains essentially unchanged. Likewise, when short-term debt is included in the TOTAL CAPITAL figure, the WACC estimates are lower by 93 basis points (10.41% vs. 11.34%) but the dispersion and precision of the estimates are effectively unchanged. For the unrestricted model, the WACC estimates are affected in a similar manner with the average estimate falling from 10.09% to 9.84% and 9.60% when the debt-related tax shields are excluded and when short-term debt is included, respectively. These results suggest that our model can 23 zero during the 1995-1999 period for our sample of 58 industries. As will be discussed in more detail below, these estimates are also the most precise ones reported in Table 2. Despite the Required WACC’s relatively precise parameter estimates, the WACCs themselves exhibit considerable cross-sectional dispersion. Figure 1 plots the distribution of Required WACC estimates for our sample. This graph shows substantial variation in WACCs across industries, with most estimates clustered between 8% and 14%. Panel A of Table 1 also reports the median and average Ibbotson WACC estimates for the aggregate set of five estimation techniques (referred to as Ibbotson Average and Ibbotson Median in the table) as well as the median and average WACC estimates for each of the five asset pricing approaches (referred to as: CAPM for the WACC estimates based on equity capital estimates derived from the Capital Asset Pricing Model, Adjusted CAPM for the size-adjusted CAPM, Fama-French for the 3factor Fama-French model, Discounted CF for the 1-stage discounted cash flow model, and 3-Stage DCF for the 3-stage discounted cash flow model). Although there is some modest variation in these models’ WACC estimates, their dispersion is noticeably smaller than that reported for estimates based on Equation (2). For example, the Ibbotson average of all five techniques is 12.69% with a standard deviation of 1.69% (the median estimates are quite similar to the average with values of 12.64% and 1.35%, respectively). These estimates are somewhat higher than our model’s estimates as well as those reported in other studies (e.g., 10.7-11.8% in Fama and French, 1999, and 8-9% in Poterba, 1998). As Figure 2 demonstrates, the Ibbotson estimates are also more tightly clustered between 10% and 14% than our model’s estimates. This result might be due to the “reality checks” performed by Ibbotson Associates to remove high and low WACC estimates from their reports. It is possible the less-disperse results shown in Figure 2 are due also to analysts’ conservatism and easily accommodate these alternative definitions of NOPAT and TOTAL CAPITAL since the inclusion or exclusion of debt-related tax shields and / or short-term debt lowers the overall average WACC estimates by less than 1 percentage point. We report the results of these alternative definitions here to conserve space and because our focus is on presenting the simplest, most parsimonious model that can be readily used by analysts. 24 subjectivity when estimating the components of WACC via the conventional textbook method. Panel B of Table 1 displays summary statistics for several financial variables that are relevant to estimating Equation (4). Overall, these statistics suggest that the industries in our sample were profitable (e.g., average ROE of 11.0%), large (average assets of $51.6 billion), and rewarded shareholders (average annual stock return of 25.6%). The data underlying these statistics are used to estimate (4). The results of these tests are presented in Table 8 and will be discussed in detail later. Table 2 displays various WACC estimates and their standard errors for each of the 58 industries. The first six columns contain estimates based on the restricted and unrestricted forms of (2), while columns 7-10 show average and median Ibbotson estimates. Columns 3 and 6 report the adjusted “raw” R2 statistics for the two forms of our model. The final two columns of Table 2 present the EVA® estimates and their standard errors based on the unrestricted form of (2). The average and standard deviation for each column is presented at the bottom of the table to summarize the results across all 58 industries. What is most striking about Table 2 are the low standard errors and high explanatory power of the Required WACC estimates. For example, the Required WACC standard errors are nearly half as large as those reported for the Ibbotson estimates (0.50% versus 0.90-0.98%).33 The average t-statistic for these parameter estimates is also quite large at 22.50 when compared to the average t-statistics for the Ex Post WACC (3.78), Ibbotson Average (12.95), and Ibbotson Median (14.04) estimates. Further, the average Required WACC estimates are consistent with those published in other studies such as Fama and French (1999) and Poterba (1998). However, the standard errors for the Required WACC estimates are relatively small when compared to the estimates reported in Fama and French (1999). For example, Table 2 shows that the average standard error of the Required WACC provides a much tighter confidence interval 33 The standard errors reported for the Ibbotson estimates are probably under-estimated because these standard errors are based on five different WACC estimates that have standard errors themselves. However, Ibbotson does not publish the standard errors for each of the five WACC estimates. In addition, as noted earlier, Ibbotson analysts will omit unusually high or low WACC estimates in their “reality checks”, thus further exacerbating the under-estimation of standard errors. 25 compared to Fama-French’s (1999) standard errors of 1.67-2.21%. In addition, the explanatory power of our model, measured by what Aigner (1971) calls “raw” R2, is remarkably good.34 Panel A shows that the average adjusted R2 for the restricted form of (2) is .9348 while the unrestricted form’s average adjusted R2 is .9627. Thus, our method appears to provide a more precise set of WACC estimates when compared to other studies. Overall, the table indicates that our model’s WACC estimates are generally lower and more widely dispersed than the Ibbotson estimates. For example, the average difference between the Required WACC and Ibbotson estimates is 1.30-1.35% (and is statistically significant at the 1% level according to a conventional t-test). However, the Required WACC column contains three estimates (for SICs equal to 10, 62, and 78) that are below 6.0%. Admittedly, these estimates are probably unrealistically low. If these three estimates are omitted, the average required WACC rises to 11.74% and its difference of 0.90-0.95% with the Ibbotson figures is no longer statistically significant. Further, from the perspective of economic significance, the average estimates from the restricted form of (2) and Ibbotson Associates are quite close with a difference of no more than 135 basis points. However, an inspection of the industry-specific WACC estimates suggests the average figures might be masking greater variation at the industry/SIC level. We examine these differences between our model’s and the textbook method’s WACC estimates in more detail later in Section IV. C. B. The Results of the Two Out-of-Sample Tests When the intercept is suppressed, the regular definition of R2 ( ∑ ( yˆ − yˆ ) 2 / ∑ ( y − y ) 2 ) loses its interpretation as a measure of the explained variance of the dependent variable. However, Aigner (1971) shows that the “raw” R2 (defined as ∑ yˆ 2 / ∑ y 2 ) does represent the proportion of the dependent 34 variable’s variance that is explained by the model. Consequently, we report the raw R2 statistics for the restricted and unrestricted forms of (2) in order to present a proper comparison of the two forms of the model. We adjust these statistics for degrees of freedom to create adjusted raw R2 statistics. Chow tests of the two forms’ raw R2 statistics for each of the 58 industries indicates that 33 (or 57%) of the R2 pairs are statistically different from each other. Nevertheless, even these differences are not sizable, particularly when viewed from the perspective of economic significance. For example, the average difference between the two forms’ R2 is only .0279 (i.e., .9348 versus .9627). 26 We continue our investigation of the model described in Equation (2) by performing our first out-of-sample test based on industry data for 1990-1994. Table 3 displays the Required WACC estimates for the 58 industries based on three time periods (1990-1994, 1995-1999, and the full 10-year period, 1990-1999). The results show that the average Required WACC is lower during 1990-1994 (10.42% versus 11.34% for 1995-1999) but this difference is not significant at the 5% level. In addition, the variability in WACC estimates is essentially the same for the two 5-year periods (3.8% vs. 3.7%). The precision of the 1990-1994 WACCs is similar to 1995-1999 with an average standard error of 0.67% and an average adjusted R2 of .8959 (vs. 0.50% and .9348 for the later period).35 Further, a Wilcoxon test confirms that the two sets of WACC estimates are not statistically different from each other. Thus, the earlier period’s results replicate those obtained for 1995-1999 and suggest that our model’s findings are not a statistical artifact of a specific sub-sample. Lastly, the WACC estimates for the full 10-year period yield a similar average cost of capital figure of 11.01% but, as expected when a larger sample is used, the cross-sectional dispersion and standard errors are lower (i.e., 3.41% and 0.51%, respectively). The estimates presented in Table 3 also indicate that industry-specific WACCs might vary over time in a predictable fashion. For example, WACCs might exhibit mean-reverting behavior similar to that observed by Blume (1975) for empirical estimates of market betas. Thus, we run a Blume-type cross-sectional regression of the 1995-1999 WACCs on the 1990-1994 WACC estimates to determine whether or not the earlier period’s estimates can explain the future period’s cost of capital. To conserve space, we report the results of this regression at the bottom of Table 3. The statistically significant slope parameter estimate of 0.582 is consistent with the hypothesis that our WACC estimates exhibit mean-reverting behavior because this parameter, as in Blume (1975), is significantly lower than 1.0 at the 1% confidence level. With an adjusted R2 of .3451, the regression also possesses relatively good explanatory power. Overall, the out35 Interestingly, the EVA estimate for 1990-1994 of –$1.01 billion is substantially lower than the 19951999 EVA estimate of +$2.37 billion. However, the 1990-1994 EVA figure is effectively zero because this parameter estimate is not statistically significant. Thus, in contrast to the early 1990s, there appears to be a significant increase in EVA during the late 1990s. 27 of-sample tests reported in Table 3 provide further evidence of the validity of our model. In addition, the tests have identified mean-reverting, predictable variations in the cost of capital over time. This information, coupled with the technique described by (2), might be able to help practitioners develop more accurate ex ante forecasts of a firm’s or industry’s cost of capital. For our second test, we report in Table 4 the superior out-of-sample forecasting ability of our model in terms of predicting future industry profitability, as measured by NOPAT. Table 4 reports the root mean squared error (RMSE), mean absolute error (MAE), Theil’s U-statistic (U), along with four other measures of forecast reliability suggested by Theil (the R2, Bias, Variance, and Covariance of the model’s forecasts). Ideally, we would like to see values close to zero for all of these measures except the R2 and Covariance statistics (which are ideally close to 1).36 These seven standard measures of forecast accuracy are presented for four sets of WACC estimates. In panel A of Table 4, the first two rows of the table display the forecast statistics based on our model using the restricted and unrestricted forms, respectively. The next two rows of Panel A of Table 4 show the forecast statistics based on using Ibbotson’s Average and Median WACC estimates, respectively. Panel B reports statistics for the same four sets of WACC estimates after making a first-order, AR(1), autoregressive correction in the quarterly NOPAT forecasts to remove any autoregressive tendency in the NOPAT time series. A quick review of these panels shows that the restricted model’s forecast statistics are uniformly closer to the ideal levels than the other three WACC estimates. Panels C and D repeat the same rows as in panels A-B in order to report the percentage improvements in the forecast statistics when our restricted model’s WACC estimates are used to forecast NOPAT for the 1995-1999 period. For example, the RMSE of the 36 Theil’s (1971) U-statistic can be decomposed into three components (Bias, Variance, and Covariance) that sum to 1. The Bias statistic indicates the percentage of the U-statistic that is associated with any systematic bias in the quarterly NOPAT forecasts. The Variance and Covariance figures represent the model’s ability to duplicate NOPAT’s actual variability and the model’s random error, respectively. As noted above, a “good” model is one where Bias and Variance are near zero (indicating no systematic bias and an exact replication of NOPAT’s variability) and Covariance is near one (suggesting that all forecast errors are simply caused by random fluctuations). The R2 statistic suggested by Theil is based on a regression of actual and forecasted values of NOPAT and, ideally, should be equal to 1 in order to show that the model’s forecasts closely fit the actual out-of-sample data. 28 restricted model’s estimates are between 16% and 27% smaller than those reported for the Ibbotson forecasts. Despite the inherent advantages Ibbotson’s estimates have in this out-of-sample test, we find that our restricted, or “required”, WACC model’s estimates of NOPAT are consistently superior to Ibbotson’s estimates across all seven measures of forecast accuracy. In addition to the restricted model’s lower RMSE forecast errors, the other forecast statistics such as the MAE and Theil’s U-statistic show similar (and many times, greater) levels of improvement in panels C and D of the table. Interestingly, the Bias statistic indicates that our restricted model’s systematic bias is virtually negligible (0.01 and 0.02 in Panels A and B, respectively). This lack of bias confirms our earlier claim that the Required WACC estimates can be interpreted as WACC estimates based on a rational expectations framework. The positive results for our model are true regardless of whether or not an AR(1) error correction is employed to remove any autoregressive pattern in the data. Our unrestricted model’s NOPAT forecasts do not perform as well as our restricted model’s forecasts but the former model still performs on a par with the Ibbotson estimates. In sum, Table 4’s strong results in favor of our model (despite the aforementioned disadvantages of our forecasts when compared to Ibbotson’s) provide compelling evidence that our model can be useful in terms of developing out-of-sample forecasts and generating more accurate estimates than Ibbotson’s conventional approach. C. Cross-Sectional Comparisons of the Model’s and Ibbotson’s Cost of Capital Estimates Despite Table 2’s confirmation that the average estimates of Equation (2) and Ibbotson’s CCQ report are relatively close, we still find that less than half of the industryspecific Required WACC estimates are within +/- 200 basis points of either Ibbotson’s average or median estimates (i.e., 25 or 43% of the total). Thus, there appear to be a significant number of large deviations between our model’s and Ibbotson’s industryspecific estimates. Table 5 confirms this observation by reporting the results of nonparametric Wilcoxon tests comparing the Required WACC industry estimates with the average and median Ibbotson figures. Both tests indicate that the industry-specific WACC estimates are significantly different at the 1% confidence level. Even when the 29 three “low” Required WACCs are omitted from the tests, the p-values for the Wilcoxon z-statistics are still .0133 and .0107 for the Ibbotson average and median estimates, respectively. Another way to examine the usefulness of our model’s WACC estimates is by comparing these estimates with realized stock returns. As noted earlier, we expect our WACC estimates to be positively correlated with stock returns because the cost of capital formula is a linear function of a firm’s or industry’s cost of equity capital. In addition, Fama (1981), among others, has shown that stock returns are statistically related to economic activity, inflation, and the return on capital. We test the above hypothesis by regressing, on a cross-sectional basis, the 5-year (1995-1999) value-weighted total returns for the common stocks that comprise each of the 58 industry groups on our model’s Required WACC estimates (as well as Ibbotson’s average and median estimates).37 The results of these regressions are reported in Table 6 and show that the parameter estimates for the Required WACC estimates (both for 1990-1994 and 19951999) are consistently significant and positive (see Tests 1 and 2) whereas both sets of the Ibbotson estimates are insignificant (Tests 3 and 4). In fact, Tests 5 and 6 of the table show that when the 1995-1999 Required WACC and one of the Ibbotson WACC estimates are included in the same regression, the only significant parameter is the one for the Required WACC estimates. From the set of six tests shown in Table 6, it appears that the 1995-1999 Required WACC estimates provides the best description of realized stock returns during 19951999 (as reported in Test 2 of the table). The 1990-1994 Required WACC estimates are also significant but have lower explanatory power than the 1995-1999 Required WACC estimates. This latter result suggests that our model’s WACC estimates might have, in addition to exhibiting the mean-reverting behavior shown in Table 3, some predictive power for explaining future industry-level stock returns. This intriguing result might be explained by the fact that industry-level WACCs can change slowly over time. Thus, the inherent serial correlation of the WACCs due to mean-reversion might be correlated with 37 Similar tests based on the average 1-year total stock returns for each industry yield results similar to those reported in Table 6 and are therefore not reported here in order to conserve space. 30 future stock returns. Overall, the above tests provide relatively clear evidence of the greater explanatory power of our model’s WACC estimates when compared to those that are based on the conventional WACC method used by Ibbotson. In order to investigate further the differences between our model and Ibbotson’s method, we also calculate the simple correlations between the four types of WACC estimates reported in Table 2 and various financial variables discussed in Section III related to growth opportunities, profitability, risk, and liquidity. In addition, the average annual stock return and total revenue for the industries are included in the analysis to gauge the various WACC estimates’ correlations with actual equity market values and the relative size of the industries (proxied for by average total revenue for each industry). Table 7 reports these correlations. The first column of this table shows the correlations between our Required WACC estimates, the other WACC estimates, and the financial variables. All of the correlations in this column (except total revenue and stock volatility) are statistically significant at the .05 level. The Required WACC is the only variable that is significantly correlated with nearly all other variables in Table 7. For example, the three other WACC estimates are correlated with only six or eight of the 12 variables listed in Table 7. Interestingly, the Required WACC estimates are not only positively correlated with the Ex Post and Ibbotson WACC estimates (.43, .26, and .33) but also strongly correlated with the financial variables related to growth opportunities (MB, FORSALE), profitability (ROE), and financial leverage (LEVERAGE). In addition, our model’s WACC estimates exhibit a greater amount of simple correlation with stock returns (.28 and .45) than the Ibbotson estimates (.03 and .28). These latter results are not surprising given the results found earlier in Table 6. In contrast, the only variables that are consistently correlated with the Ibbotson WACCs are the size proxy (Total Revenue), LEVERAGE, and stock price volatility (VOL). Thus, the key factors related to the Ibbotson estimates are industry size, equity risk, and financial leverage. Other factors related to growth opportunities, profitability, and liquidity do not appear to be consistently related to the Ibbotson figures. In sum, the Required WACC estimates are the ones most consistently correlated to financial variables which, a priori, we would expect to be related to an industry’s cost of capital. 31 This is also consistent with our earlier finding that the Required WACC estimates are significantly related to stock returns whereas Ibbotson’s estimates are not related to realized stock returns. We can investigate the relation between the Required WACC, Ibbotson’s estimates, and key financial variables on a multivariate basis by performing some cross-sectional tests according to the framework described by Equation (4). Table 8 displays the OLS regression results based on Equation (4) for two dependent variables: 1) the difference between the Required WACC and Ibbotson Average WACC estimates (DIFFMEAN) and 2) the difference between the Required WACC and Ibbotson Median WACC estimates (DIFFMEDIAN). The columns labeled, Test 1 and Test 2, report the regression results for DIFFMEAN. Test 1 contains all six financial variables expected to influence the difference between the Required WACC and Ibbotson estimates whereas Test 2 is based on the three variables that are most significantly related to DIFFMEAN. Tests 3 and 4 contain the results of similar tests using DIFFMEDIAN. For both dependent variables, the two variables that are consistently significant factors affecting the differences between our model and Ibbotson’s approach are: 1) international sales activity (FORSALE) and 2) profitability (ROE). Also, note that for all four tests the explanatory power of (3) is quite good, as measured by the adjusted R2 statistics (ranging from .5270 to .5390). As described earlier, FORSALE can be interpreted as a proxy for growth opportunities because international operations imply larger markets for the industry’s goods and services. In addition, FORSALE might also be a proxy for greater diversification (and hence lower risk). Conceivably, one can also argue that FORSALE might represent greater risk (due to higher currency and country risks faced by firms with substantial international operations). Overall, the positive parameter estimates for FORSALE in Table 8 suggest that the growth opportunities and higher risk rationales related to this variable are the ones best supported by our sample. A positive parameter estimate indicates that the Required WACC is more likely to be larger (smaller) than the Ibbotson estimate when FORSALE is relatively high (low). This suggests that our model’s WACC estimates are more sensitive to variations in FORSALE than Ibbotson’s estimates. Thus, our model’s 32 estimates might be capturing the effect of variations in the growth opportunities and risks associated with an industry’s international exposure.38 The results for ROE indicate that the level of profitability is also directly related to an industry’s cost of capital. Thus, the positive parameter estimates for ROE also suggest that the Required WACC estimates are more sensitive to these factors than the Ibbotson figures. Interestingly, the market-to-book ratio (MB), stock volatility (VOL), and liquidity (VOLUME) variables are not significant factors influencing the differences between the two methods’ WACC estimates. Lastly, Table 8 reports mixed results for LEVERAGE with statistically significant negative parameter estimates based on DIFFMEDIAN but no significance when the regressions are run with DIFFMEAN as the dependent variable. The consistent negative sign for both dependent variables suggests that industries with larger amounts of financial leverage are expected to have lower WACCs based on our method when compared to those WACCs derived with Ibbotson’s approach. This finding is consistent with the notion that industries with high financial leverage typically keep operating / business risks relatively low so that they can reap debt’s tax benefits as well as take advantage of debt’s lower overall cost (versus equity). It is not consistent, however, with the notion that LEVERAGE might be proxying for expected financial distress costs. Thus, the empirical results suggest that firms with high financial leverage might have lower WACCs due to the cost advantages of debt and these firms’ relatively low operating risk. Credit institutions such as those contained in SIC industry codes 60 and 61, as well as public utilities found in code 49, are classic examples that illustrate the inverse relation between debt and the firm’s cost of capital noted above. Not surprisingly, the Required WACC estimates for all three of these industries are less than 10% (and less than the corresponding Ibbotson estimates). 38 It should be noted that the construction of Ibbotson’s estimates might also be affecting this parameter estimate. For example, the Ibbotson estimates are based on the costs of U.S.-financed corporate debt and equity. Thus, if an industry with large foreign sales also borrows overseas extensively, then Ibbotson’s estimates might be systematically different than WACC estimates based on Equation (2) because our method does not require such data. However, confirmation of this possibility and its potential impact on the magnitude of the parameter estimates is beyond the scope of this paper. 33 In sum, Tables 4-8 report several results that support our inference that the restricted form of Equation (2) can generate WACC estimates that are more closely related to financial factors such as stock returns, growth opportunities, profitability, and risk than estimates derived from the conventional textbook approach. Since we do not observe the “true” WACC for the industries in our sample, we cannot be certain that our model presents a more accurate picture of real-world cost of capital figures. However, the indirect evidence reported in Tables 4-8 indicates that Equation (2) can provide WACC estimates that are more responsive to those financial factors that are commonly thought to be important influences on a firm’s cost of capital. V. Conclusion We have presented a model that can provide estimates of an industry’s weighted average cost of capital (WACC) in a simple, parsimonious, less-subjective (and potentially more accurate) fashion than the conventional textbook approach. The tests presented here indicate that our economic profit-based approach summarized by Equation (2) provides ex post estimates of industry-level WACCs for the 1990-1999 period that are positively correlated to conventional WACC estimates published by Ibbotson Associates. In addition, our WACC estimates are more positively correlated with realized stock returns and yield superior out-of-sample forecasts of an industry’s future profitability than the Ibbotson estimates. Further, when compared to these textbook-based estimates, our model’s estimates are more closely related to key financial variables that, a priori, one would expect to be correlated with an industry’s cost of capital. Our estimates are also more closely aligned with WACC estimates reported by other studies such as Fama and French (1999) and Poterba (1998). Our WACC estimates exhibit mean-reverting behavior over time similar to the dynamics in market betas observed by Blume (1975) and thus provide a means for using our model to develop out-of-sample, or ex ante, WACC estimates. In addition, the unrestricted form of Equation (2) enables an analyst to estimate the average economic profit generated over the estimation period. We find that the average per-industry economic profit rises from 0 to $2.37 billion during 1990-1999. It should be noted that follow-on research related to this topic is quite feasible in at least three areas. First, additional cross-sectional tests within an industry would be 34 helpful to develop shorter-term industry-specific WACC estimates. For example, one can estimate our model for one industry on a cross-sectional basis at a point in time (e.g., during one quarter or one year). A weighted least squares approach (with the weights equal to the relative size of each firm within the industry) might be preferable for these tests. This approach would also enable the analyst to form a longer time series of WACC estimates that could then be used to explore the time variation and mean-reverting behavior of WACC in more detail. Second, there are potentially several straightforward applications of our model to event studies in corporate finance and market microstructure. For example, one can study the impact of a change in capital structure or dividend policy on the firm’s cost of capital and economic profit in a more direct way because Equation (2) provides a method for estimating a firm’ WACC for both the pre- and post-event periods. In addition, a change in the microstructure of a securities exchange might enhance liquidity that, in turn, could lower the liquidity premium associated with a firm’s securities. This effect can be measured by estimating the firm’s WACC before and after the microstructure change (and, obviously, controlling for other potential confounding factors). Third, asset pricing tests might also benefit from our proposed methodology because, in theory, one could infer the cost of equity capital from our WACC estimates if the researcher had a reasonably good estimate of the firm’s capital structure and the costs of debt/preferred stock. This would enable the analyst to identify the cost of equity capital without having to specify an explicit asset pricing model. 35 References: Aigner, D., 1971, Basic Econometrics, (John Wiley: New York), 85-90. Blume, M., 1975, Betas and their regression tendencies, Journal of Finance 30, 785-795. Bruner, R.F., Eades, K.M., Harris, R.S., and R.C. Higgins, 1998, Best practices in estimating the cost of capital: Survey and synthesis, Financial Practice and Education 8:1, 13-28. Claus, J., and J. Thomas, 2001, Equity premia as low as three percent? Evidence from analysts’ earnings forecasts for domestic and international stock markets, Journal of Finance 56, 1629-1666. Damodoran, A., 1996, Investment valuation: Tools and techniques for determining the value of any asset, (John Wiley: New York). Easton, P., Taylor, G., Shroff, P., and T. Sougiannis, 2001, Estimating the cost of equity capital using forecasts of earnings, Journal of Accounting Research, forthcoming. Ehrhardt, M.C., 1994, The Search for Value: Measuring the Company’s Cost of Capital (Harvard Business School: Boston), 25-29, 52-65. Elton, E.J., 1999, Presidential address: Expected return, realized return, and asset pricing tests, Journal of Finance 54, 1199-1220. Fama, E.F., 1981, Stock returns, real activity, inflation, and money, American Economic Review 71, 545-564. Fama, E.F., and K. French, 1993, Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds, Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3-56. Fama, E.F., and K. French, 1997, Industry costs of equity, Journal of Financial Economics 43, 153-193. Fama, E.F., and K. French, 1999, The corporate cost of capital and the return on corporate investment, Journal of Finance 54, 1939-1967. Fama, E.F., and K. French, 2002, The equity premium, Journal of Finance 57, 637-659. Gebhardt, W.R., Lee, C.M.C., and B. Swaminathan, 2001, Toward an implied cost-ofcapital, Journal of Accounting Research 39, 135-176. Gitman, L.J., and P.A. Vandenberg, 2000, Cost of capital techniques used by major firms: 1997 vs. 1980, Financial Practice and Education 10:2, 53-68. 36 Greene, W.H., 1993, Econometric Analysis, (Macmillan: New York) 279-287, 149-150. Gordon, M.J., 1961, The investment, financing, and valuation of the corporation, (Richard D. Irwin: Burr Ridge, IL). Ibbotson Associates, 1999, Cost of Capital Quarterly. Kennedy, P., 1998, A Guide to Econometrics (MIT Press: Cambridge, MA) 52. Marshall, A., 1890, Principles of Economics (MacMillan: New York). Miller, M.H., and F. Modigliani, 1966, Some estimates of the cost of capital to the electric utility industry, 1954-1957, American Economic Review 56, 333-391. Muth, J., 1961, Rational expectations and the theory of price movements, Econometrica 29, 315-335. Myers, S.C., and L.S. Borucki, 1994, Discounted cash flow estimates of the cost of equity capital—a case study, Financial Markets, Institutions, and Instruments 3, 941. Peterson, P.P., and D.R. Peterson, 1996, Company performance and measures of value added, Monograph, The Research Foundation of the Institute of Chartered Financial Analysts. Phillips, P.C.B., and P. Perron, 1988, Testing for a unit root in time series regression, Biometrika 75, 335-46. Phillips, P.C.B., and S. Ouliaris, 1990, Asymptotic properties of residual based tests for cointegration, Econometrica 58, 165-193. Poterba, J.M., 1998, The rate of return to corporate capital and factor shares: New estimates using revised national income accounts and capital stock data, CarnegieRochester Conference Series on Public Policy 48, 211-246. Stewart, B.G., 1991, The quest for value: A guide for senior managers, (Harper Business: New York). Theil, H., 1971, Principles of Econometrics, (J. Wiley and Sons: New York). Weaver, S.C., 2001, Measuring economic value added: A survey of the practices of EVA® proponents, Journal of Applied Finance 11, 50-60. Yook, K.C., 1999, Estimating EVA using Compustat PC Plus, Financial Practice and Education 9:2, 33-37. 37 Appendix A. (The SIC Code is followed by the Industry Title) 01 10 13 15 16 17 20 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 42 44 45 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 67 70 72 73 75 78 79 80 82 87 Agriculture Production Crops Metal Mining Oil and Gas Extraction Building Construction-General Contractors and Operative Builders Heavy Construction Other Than Building Construction-Contractors Construction-Special Trade Contractors Food and Kindred Spirits Textile Mill Products Apparel and Other Finished Products Made from Fabrics Lumber and Wood Products, Except Furniture Furniture and Fixtures Paper and Allied Products Printing, Publishing, and Allied Industries Chemicals and Allied Products Petroleum Refining and Related Industries Rubber and Miscellaneous Plastic Products Leather and Leather Products Stone, Clay, Glass, and Concrete Products Primarily Metal Industries Fabricated Metal Products, Except Machinery and Transportation Equipment Industrial and Commercial Machinery and Computer Equipment Electronic and Other Electrical Equipment Transportation Equipment Measuring, Analyzing and Controlling Equipment Miscellaneous Manufacturing Industries Railroad Transportation Motor Freight Transportation and Warehousing Water Transportation Transportation by Air Transportation Services Communications Electric, Gas, and Sanitary Services Wholesale Trade-Durable Goods Wholesale Trade-Nondurable Goods Building Materials, Hardware, Garden Supply and Mobile Home Dealers General Merchandise Stores Food Stores Automotive Dealers and Gasoline Service Stations Apparel and Accessories Stores Home Furniture, Furnishings, and Equipment Stores Eating and Drinking Places Miscellaneous Retail Depository Institutions Non-depository Credit Institutions Security and Commodity Brokers, Dealers, Exchanges, and Services Insurance Carriers Insurance Agents, Brokers, and Service Real Estate Holding and Other Investment Offices Hotels, Rooming Houses, and Other Lodging Places Personal Services Business Services (including Software Development) Automotive Repair, Services and Parking Motion Pictures Amusement and Recreation Services Health Services Educational Services Engineering, Accounting, Research, Management, and Related Services 38 Table 1. Descriptive Statistics (1995-1999) The following two panels display summary statistics for the 58-industry cross-section of cost of capital estimates and selected financial variables, respectively, during 1995-1999. Panel A. Variable Cost of Capital Estimates N Mean Std. Dev. Required WACC Ex Post WACC EVA ($Mil.) Ibbotson Average Ibbotson Median Median CAPM Median Adjusted CAPM Median Fama-French Median Discounted CF Median 3-Stage DCF Average CAPM Average Adjusted CAPM Average Fama-French Average Discounted CF Average 3-Stage DCF Adjusted R2 - Required WACC Adjusted R2 - Ex Post WACC Panel B. Variable ROE ROA Assets / Book Value-Equity Number of Firms NOPAT ($ Mil.) Total Assets ($ Mil.) Total Revenue ($ Mil.) Foreign Rev. / Total Revenue Stock Return (Annual %) Market-to-Book Ratio Beta Stock Volatility Share Volume (000 sh.) 58 58 58 58 58 58 58 58 58 57 58 58 58 58 56 58 58 11.34 10.09 2,366.55 12.69 12.64 10.74 12.30 13.78 13.50 12.88 11.89 12.49 13.55 14.03 10.82 0.9348 0.9627 3.70 11.04 7,457.92 1.69 1.35 1.29 1.53 1.96 2.32 1.46 1.67 1.79 2.49 3.27 1.66 0.1299 0.0867 Minimum 2.83 -9.52 -17,064.95 8.56 8.38 8.17 8.99 8.95 7.62 9.02 8.06 8.32 9.28 7.71 6.95 0.1585 0.3538 Cross-Sectional Financial Variables N Mean Std. Dev. Minimum 58 58 58 58 58 58 58 56 58 58 58 58 58 11.06 3.86 4.1166 59.9069 5,233.0 51,569.2 45,445.1 0.1441 25.5965 4.4448 0.8577 0.6430 54,685.1 39 5.08 2.18 4.4165 70.4608 8,485.7 89,214.5 79,168.3 0.1457 19.6266 3.2944 0.4707 0.2205 147282 1.95 -0.15 1.1618 5.0000 12.2950 326.3 531.8 0.0000 -7.3300 1.0800 -1.8000 0.2600 616.8 Maximum 18.98 61.44 33,742.03 15.32 15.31 13.47 15.33 17.55 20.51 15.76 14.83 15.41 20.24 23.55 14.77 0.9989 0.9989 Maximum 25.11 8.66 25.9825 296.2000 37,899.8 390,244.0 361,609.0 0.4587 91.9000 19.5000 1.9800 1.4000 905755 Table 2. Industry-Specific Cost of Capital Estimates (1995 – 1999) The column labeled, Required WACC, contains cost of capital estimates for 58 industries (referred to as SIC in the table) based on the restricted form of Equation (2). The columns labeled, S.E. and Adj. R2, report the standard error of the corresponding WACC estimate and the regression equation’s adjusted coefficient of determination, respectively. The column labeled, Ex Post WACC, reports cost of capital estimates based on the unrestricted form of Equation (2). The intercept from this model’s regression is reported below in the column labeled EVA. The WACC estimates based on the average and median of Ibbotson Associates’ five cost of capital estimation techniques are reported in the columns labeled, Ibbotson Average and Ibbotson Median. Summary statistics are presented at the bottom of the table (Average and Std. Dev.). No. of Firms denotes the average number of firms used to estimate the Required and Ex Post WACC figures. SIC 1 10 13 15 16 17 20 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 No. of Firms 11 22 118 23 11 5 82 31 39 20 24 36 53 225 21 46 16 19 48 47 237 250 67 227 38 Required WACC 11.22 3.89 7.43 8.95 10.64 6.60 18.98 8.87 14.99 10.49 13.33 11.77 14.09 18.76 9.74 15.90 10.57 18.70 10.63 16.19 14.99 15.12 11.77 15.97 16.04 S.E. 0.979 1.342 0.558 0.487 0.434 0.510 0.133 0.246 0.322 0.455 0.466 0.394 0.646 0.178 0.346 0.545 0.529 1.099 0.812 0.213 0.725 0.519 0.708 0.200 0.463 2 Adj. R 0.8854 0.1585 0.8896 0.9590 0.9742 0.8740 0.9989 0.9826 0.9877 0.9684 0.9819 0.9782 0.9571 0.9989 0.9788 0.9780 0.9609 0.9489 0.9061 0.9966 0.9721 0.9883 0.9576 0.9982 0.9779 Ex Post WACC -1.81 -9.52 1.55 17.32 6.63 5.07 16.11 8.44 20.43 5.82 19.92 2.29 3.83 29.08 13.81 -0.26 30.60 26.21 -8.89 14.80 5.81 8.29 2.41 13.30 10.21 S.E. 13.753 5.291 2.380 1.181 1.639 3.605 1.079 7.508 2.230 2.773 0.846 5.707 2.567 3.658 3.439 3.660 2.113 5.454 3.988 0.689 1.232 1.256 0.824 1.658 3.514 40 2 Adj. R 0.8964 0.3538 0.9194 0.9885 0.9790 0.8756 0.9988 0.9826 0.9919 0.9737 0.9955 0.9834 0.9788 0.9880 0.9744 0.9895 0.9926 0.9546 0.9646 0.9970 0.9853 0.9831 0.9921 0.9968 0.9803 Ibbotson Average 11.85 12.51 13.19 12.52 14.67 12.03 11.97 11.93 13.17 14.50 13.56 11.25 12.83 12.72 10.58 13.95 14.71 13.37 13.48 12.45 13.08 14.56 9.44 12.81 13.35 S.E. 1.101 1.718 1.145 1.462 0.851 1.483 1.012 0.834 0.691 1.584 0.868 0.427 0.442 0.993 0.297 0.519 0.957 1.281 1.139 0.975 1.573 1.383 0.757 0.876 0.784 Ibbotson Median 12.25 12.55 12.63 11.46 13.91 11.75 11.54 11.20 12.52 14.71 13.45 11.29 12.61 14.02 11.40 12.81 13.97 13.22 13.44 13.31 14.58 15.29 12.50 14.74 12.24 S.E. 1.073 1.542 1.106 0.863 0.854 1.358 0.580 0.545 0.834 0.873 1.054 0.464 0.593 0.671 0.670 0.639 1.291 1.056 0.889 0.677 0.781 1.097 0.888 0.830 0.714 EVA 659.11 801.01 2401.12 -889.10 183.95 3.03 1765.19 60.91 -518.63 282.07 -572.33 3368.13 3179.21 -17064.95 -6377.46 2102.42 -336.20 -579.87 5055.21 314.49 10145.12 6838.40 26771.20 989.32 343.77 S.E. 688.90 284.43 1053.35 131.37 64.29 6.99 873.81 1059.07 189.48 147.7085 78.57 2045.22 738.04 5996.76 5157.27 455.35 36.79 440.34 983.68 135.90 1338.66 1291.22 2774.89 631.85 214.98 Table 2. Industry-Specific WACC Estimates (continued) SIC 40 42 44 45 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 67 70 72 73 No. of Required Firms WACC 9 7.58 24 9.13 11 6.93 22 13.56 8 9.85 66 11.08 185 7.26 101 9.40 53 10.47 10 14.53 28 12.33 29 14.79 10 10.44 33 13.90 22 11.17 64 13.09 57 9.49 296 9.29 30 8.50 46 2.83 91 10.03 19 18.06 34 7.97 82 10.70 11 7.92 7 10.77 216 18.16 S.E. 0.549 0.380 0.516 0.603 0.173 0.509 0.314 0.287 0.380 0.343 0.385 0.320 0.512 0.982 0.359 0.177 0.250 0.442 1.297 0.211 0.145 0.751 0.214 1.021 0.278 0.476 0.435 2 Adj. R 0.9241 0.9752 0.9236 0.9818 0.9916 0.9673 0.9838 0.9856 0.9779 0.9926 0.9875 0.9904 0.9639 0.9298 0.9816 0.9957 0.9867 0.9739 0.6754 0.5179 0.9965 0.9666 0.9847 0.8626 0.9747 0.9661 0.9921 Ex Post WACC S.E. 0.41 1.531 16.84 2.418 16.59 2.495 5.58 4.697 8.30 1.317 10.46 1.674 3.29 1.017 5.15 0.940 7.60 11.918 18.43 0.550 11.01 1.578 15.17 1.247 4.14 1.061 61.44 8.510 30.96 4.056 9.10 0.749 10.88 1.302 6.54 0.558 1.13 0.329 0.29 0.363 9.30 0.678 9.43 1.285 5.45 0.747 4.90 1.945 8.24 1.180 4.15 1.282 16.92 1.717 2 Adj. R 0.9744 0.9844 0.9544 0.9614 0.9919 0.9322 0.9921 0.9925 0.9847 0.9981 0.9958 0.9904 0.9901 0.9630 0.9932 0.9985 0.9876 0.9894 0.9461 0.9455 0.9967 0.9905 0.9881 0.9100 0.9748 0.9905 0.9869 41 Ibbotson Average 11.57 13.24 14.00 12.22 12.46 11.36 8.69 13.32 11.92 15.32 12.32 10.40 15.12 14.06 13.63 13.23 13.47 9.68 8.56 9.24 12.32 14.39 11.21 9.67 14.53 14.37 14.66 S.E. 0.453 1.045 1.212 1.010 0.859 0.543 0.398 0.521 0.643 2.505 0.504 0.716 1.236 0.819 1.123 0.532 1.071 0.578 0.245 0.783 0.422 0.933 1.060 0.672 1.637 1.372 2.052 Ibbotson Median 12.00 12.24 11.65 12.87 13.38 12.02 8.38 12.72 11.71 13.49 11.10 10.72 12.23 14.27 12.45 12.53 12.87 10.07 9.95 13.95 13.29 13.97 10.86 11.66 12.60 14.26 15.31 S.E. 0.631 0.888 0.800 0.987 1.094 0.800 0.346 0.632 0.640 1.306 0.498 0.532 1.056 1.099 0.846 0.814 0.784 0.683 0.431 1.186 0.725 0.952 0.993 1.241 1.537 1.030 1.441 EVA 2902.94 -353.38 -474.85 3399.99 59.07 1577.35 21472.74 1010.46 847.69 -479.52 722.19 -88.64 233.76 -6101.84 -1218.57 966.41 -357.49 17510.38 15776.30 33742.03 1172.63 106.10 220.72 1070.32 -20.58 54.67 973.79 S.E. 600.25 121.60 103.55 2014.52 47.98 4482.95 3983.74 232.64 376.66 78.81 1548.71 289.12 29.69 1073.57 259.34 160.23 305.87 2612.80 1113.97 4395.01 1081.31 14.75 3.10 280.18 74.42 9.41 991.10 Table 2. Industry-Specific WACC Estimates (continued) SIC 75 78 79 80 82 87 No. of Required Firms WACC 6 10.86 23 5.33 31 8.07 71 8.55 6 10.37 55 9.86 Average Std. Dev. 11.34 3.70 S.E. 0.517 0.638 0.615 0.491 0.834 0.529 Adj. R 0.9480 0.8214 0.9180 0.9510 0.9170 0.9573 Ex Post WACC 9.06 -3.91 0.92 1.68 16.44 18.06 0.504 0.273 0.9348 0.1299 10.09 11.04 2 S.E. 7.280 2.536 1.078 1.321 2.083 1.652 2.67 2.67 Adj. R 0.9479 0.8645 0.9880 0.9843 0.9468 0.9866 Ibbotson Average 10.82 12.83 15.28 12.98 14.04 14.76 0.9627 0.0867 12.69 1.69 2 42 S.E. 0.815 0.949 0.957 0.800 1.574 1.628 Ibbotson Median 11.17 13.14 13.30 12.96 12.66 14.03 S.E. 0.822 1.135 1.090 0.706 1.393 0.922 EVA 77.01 290.30 713.98 2815.13 -14.90 -271.12 S.E. 312.68 68.89 86.00 516.32 5.35 48.55 0.98 0.45 12.64 1.35 0.90 0.28 2366.55 7457.92 933.48 1375.29 Table 3. Out-of-Sample Required WACC Estimates The WACC estimates based on the restricted form of Equation (2) for three time periods, and related summary statistics, are presented below. At the bottom of the table, a Blume-style (1975) cross-sectional regression is presented using the 1995-1999 WACC estimates reported below as the dependent variable and the 1990-1994 WACC estimates as the independent variable. Parameter estimates and t-statistics displayed in bold face are statistically significant at the .01 level. 1990-94 1995-99 1990-99 1990-94 1995-99 1990-99 SIC WACC WACC WACC SIC WACC WACC WACC 1 7.79 11.22 9.99 47 8.84 9.85 9.35 10 4.60 3.89 4.62 48 11.64 11.08 10.92 13 3.63 7.43 5.38 49 8.47 7.26 7.63 15 5.34 8.95 6.89 50 10.58 9.40 9.84 16 7.50 10.64 10.29 51 10.15 10.47 10.45 17 6.85 6.60 6.85 52 11.81 14.53 13.90 20 16.76 18.98 18.35 53 12.60 12.33 12.60 22 10.33 8.87 9.20 54 13.08 14.79 14.17 23 12.67 14.99 13.83 55 13.15 10.44 11.67 24 9.18 10.49 10.62 56 14.18 13.90 13.96 25 20.54 13.33 13.55 57 8.41 11.17 10.51 26 6.18 11.77 10.89 58 13.40 13.09 13.30 27 12.52 14.09 13.95 59 12.16 9.49 9.77 28 11.55 18.76 18.06 60 16.28 9.29 10.09 29 7.36 9.74 8.73 61 6.96 8.50 8.59 30 12.09 15.90 14.59 62 2.69 2.83 2.82 31 10.66 10.57 10.40 63 10.48 10.03 10.06 32 13.61 18.70 16.37 64 18.42 18.06 18.32 33 10.39 10.63 9.89 65 5.78 7.97 7.01 34 13.36 16.19 16.00 67 8.80 10.70 9.91 35 8.66 14.99 12.95 70 10.63 7.92 8.02 36 8.09 15.12 14.89 72 15.98 10.77 12.08 37 7.21 11.77 10.54 73 16.06 18.16 16.81 38 10.30 15.97 14.00 75 7.03 10.86 9.09 39 16.50 16.04 15.49 78 10.21 5.33 7.35 40 10.80 7.58 9.23 79 8.67 8.07 8.91 42 10.30 9.13 9.51 80 9.85 8.55 9.16 44 4.32 6.93 5.82 82 15.53 10.37 11.19 45 4.96 13.56 11.27 87 8.50 9.86 9.01 Average 10.42 11.34 11.01 Std. Deviation 3.80 3.70 3.41 Minimum 2.69 2.83 2.82 Maximum 20.54 18.98 18.35 OLS Regression: 1995-99 WACCi = a + b (1990-1994 WACCi) + ei Parameter S.E. t-statistic Constant 1.158 No. Observ. 5.274 4.55 1990-94 WACC 0.105 Adjusted R2 0.582 5.57 43 58 0.3451 Table 4. Out-of-Sample NOPAT Forecasting Ability Using the WACC estimates based on both the restricted and unrestricted forms of Equation (2), as well as Ibbotson Associates’ Average and Median WACC estimates, out-of-sample forecasts of NOPAT are computed via Equation (3) for the 20-quarter period during 1995-1999. From these quarterly NOPAT forecasts, seven measures of forecast accuracy are presented below for the restricted (Required WACC) and unrestricted (Ex Post WACC) models, as well as for the two sets of Ibbotson estimates (Ibbotson Average and Ibbotson Median). The seven measures are the forecasts’ Root Mean Squared Error (RMSE), and Mean Absolute Error (MAE), as well as Theil’s R2 statistic (R2) corresponding to a regression of the actual NOPAT values on the forecasted values of NOPAT for each industry, Theil’s U-statistic (U), and Theil’s decomposition of the U-statistic into Bias, Variance, and Covariance. These latter three statistics sum to 1 with Covariance ideally equal to 1 and the remaining two statistics equal to zero. Panel A reports the forecast statistics based on Equation (2) while Panel B adjusts all four sets of forecasts with a first-order autoregressive, AR(1), function to account for potential autoregressive behavior in the quarterly NOPAT time series for each industry. Panels C and D repeat the same rows as in Panels A and B in order to report the percentage improvements in the forecast statistics when the Required WACC estimates are used to forecast NOPAT. R2 U .6457 .5032 .4122 .3884 0.28 0.36 0.46 0.39 0.01 0.03 0.06 0.01 0.01 0.09 0.38 0.04 0.99 0.88 0.56 0.95 .9472 .9069 .9022 .9178 0.11 0.15 0.16 0.14 0.02 0.08 0.10 0.09 0.16 0.28 0.51 0.37 0.82 0.64 0.39 0.55 Forecast Method RMSE MAE Panel A. Conventional Forecasts Required WACC Ex Post WACC Ibbotson Average Ibbotson Median 4717.1 5819.7 6335.3 6487.3 1186.5 1667.9 1992.2 1687.3 Bias Variance Covariance Panel B. Forecasts with AR(1) Adjustment Required WACC Ex Post WACC Ibbotson Average Ibbotson Median 1744.9 2109.4 2225.8 2073.8 442.5 783.1 808.3 762.1 Panel C. Percentage Improvement of Required WACC via Conventional Forecasts Required WACC Ex Post WACC Ibbotson Average Ibbotson Median -18.9 25.5 27.3 -28.8 40.4 29.7 -28.3 56.7 66.3 -22.2 39.1 28.2 -66.7 83.3 0.0 -88.9 97.4 75.0 -12.3 76.8 4.2 Panel D. Percentage Improvement of Required WACC via Forecasts with AR(1) Adjustment Required WACC Ex Post WACC Ibbotson Average Ibbotson Median -17.3 21.6 15.9 -43.5 45.3 41.9 -4.4 5.0 3.2 44 -26.7 31.3 21.4 -75.0 80.0 77.8 -42.9 68.6 43.2 -28.1 110.3 49.1 Table 5. Non-Parametric Wilcoxon Tests of the Cost of Capital Estimates The first two rows of the table report results of a Wilcoxon test of the differences between the Required WACC and Ibbotson Average WACC estimates reported in Table 2. The last two rows of the table report results of a Wilcoxon test of the differences between the Required WACC and Ibbotson Median WACC estimates reported in Table 2. The z-statistic and corresponding p-value are reported in the last two columns. Variable N Sum of Scores Expected Sum Under Null Mean Score Required WACC Ibbotson Average 58 58 2,889.0 3,897.0 3,393.0 3,393.0 49.810 67.190 -2.78 - 0.0054 - Required WACC Ibbotson Median 58 58 2848.0 3938.0 3393.0 3393.0 49.103 67.897 -3.01 - 0.0026 - 45 z-statistic p-value Table 6. Cross-Sectional Regressions of the Relation Between Stock Returns and the Model’s and Ibbotson’s Estimates of the Cost of Capital The dependent variable is the 5-year (1995-1999) value-weighted total return on the common stocks that comprise each of the 58 industry groups in our sample. We regress the stock returns for these 58 industries on their respective WACC estimates (either from the restricted form of our model, Required WACC, or from Ibbotson Associates’ WACC estimates). A parameter estimate and its t-statistic (in parentheses) are printed in bold face if the estimate is significant at the .05 level. Variable Test 1. Test 2. Test 3. Test 4. Test 5. Test 6. CONSTANT 11.379 (2.57) 6.824 (1.44) 20.460 (2.43) 5.254 (0.58) 12.448 (1.49) -0.414 (-0.05) Required WACC (1990-1994) 0.802 (2.01) 1.220 (2.98) 1.032 (2.50) Required WACC (1995-1999) 1.138 (2.87) Ibbotson Average WACC (1995-1999) -0.526 (-0.82) -0.058 (-0.09) Ibbotson Median WACC (1995-1999) 0.678 (0.95) 1.164 (1.62) 58 58 58 58 58 58 Adjusted R2 .0503 .1128 -.0177 .0276 .1076 .1112 F-statistic 4.02 8.25 0.08 2.62 4.44 4.57 No. Observations 46 Table 7. Correlations of Selected Financial Variables (1995-1999) This table displays the partial correlation statistics for selected explanatory variables as well as the dependent variables. Correlations which are significant at the .05 level are displayed in bold face. Variable 1. Required WACC 2. Ex Post WACC 3. Ibbotson Average 4. Ibbotson Median 5. Stock Return 6. Total Revenue 7. MB 8. FORSALE 9. ROE 10. LEVERAGE 11. VOL 12. VOLUME 1 2 .43 .26 .28 .33 .22 .28 .45 .02 -.00 .39 .31 .39 .01 .60 .34 -.27 -.19 .12 .35 .31 .08 3 4 5 6 .68 .03 .28 -.49 -.27 .18 .03 .19 .26 .11 .07 .29 -.02 .14 -.11 .04 .26 .18 -.61 -.29 .17 .25 .29 .46 .73 -.20 .17 .38 .60 .12 47 7 8 .17 .28 -.05 .09 .17 .06 -.15 .11 .36 9 10 11 .29 -.04 -.01 .09 -.05 .50 12 Table 8. Cross-Sectional Tests of the Differences Between the Model’s and Ibbotson’s Estimates of the Cost of Capital The results are based on the model specified in Equation (4). The results for two alternative dependent variable, DIFFMEAN and DIFFMEDIAN, are reported here. DIFFMEAN is the difference between the Required WACC and Ibbotson Average WACC estimates reported in Table 2. DIFFMEDIAN is the difference between the Required WACC and Ibbotson Median WACC estimates reported in Table 2. A parameter estimate and its t-statistic (in parentheses) are printed in bold face if the estimate is significant at the .01 level. DIFFMEAN Test 1. Test 2. DIFFMEDIAN Test 3. Test 4. -6.187 (-4.21) 0.050 (1.48) 6.114 (2.37) 44.767 (6.05) -0.119 (-1.37) -1.497 (-0.83) 2.9E-6 (1.00) 7.391 (3.07) 48.990 (6.95) -0.137 (-1.59) -5.158 (-3.66) 0.034 (1.05) 4.043 (1.64) 46.099 (6.50) -0.294 (-3.54) -1.517 (-0.88) 2.0E-6 (0.72) 4.828 (2.13) 49.088 (7.37) -0.307 (-3.77) No. Observations 58 58 58 58 Adjusted R2 .5270 .5228 .5297 .5390 Variable CONSTANT MB FORSALE ROE LEVERAGE VOL VOLUME -7.283 (-8.25) 48 -6.221 (-7.46) Figure 1. Distribution of WACC Estimates using the Restricted Form of the Model This figure plots the distribution of WACC estimates based on the restricted form of Equation (2). The distribution is derived from 5-year average Required WACC estimates of 58 two-digit SIC industries during 1995-1999. 50% Probability 40% 32.8% 30% 20% 10% 13.8% 12.1% 10.3% 17.2% 6.9% 6.9% 0% 6 8 10 12 14 WACC Estimate (%) 49 16 18 Figure 2. Distribution of WACC Estimates based on Ibbotson Data This figure plots the distribution of WACC estimates based on the average estimates published by Ibbotson Associates for five different estimation techniques. The distribution is derived from 5-year average WACC estimates of 58 two-digit SIC industries during 1995-1999. 46.6% 50% P r o b a b i l i t y 40% 30% 24.1% 19% 20% 10.3% 10% % 6 8 10 12 14 WACC Estimate (%) 50 16 18 SUPPLEMENT FOR REVIEWERS: An Algebraic and Numeric Derivation of the Independence between Firm Value and Growth in a Constant Growth Model Framework We can begin with the conventional Constant Growth Model (CGM) popularized by Gordon (1961) and apply it, without loss of generality, to valuing the entire firm (VA), not just the firm’s equity value. This model can be summarized by the following relation and associated definitions: VA = CFA KA − gA where, CFA = net free cash flow available to the firm’s investors (i.e., creditors as well as equity holders). In our context, this variable can be interpreted as the portion of NOPAT that is expected to be distributed to investors in the form of dividends, interest payments, etc. over the course of the next period;39 KA = the required return on the investors’ investments in the firm and, in equilibrium, is equal to the firm’s WACC; and gA = the expected constant growth rate of the investors’ investments in the firm. Key Assumptions: The following assumptions can be used to simplify further the above valuation equation: 1) CFA can be defined as the portion of next year’s expected NOPAT that is distributed to investors and equals d ⋅ NOPATt+1, where d = the percentage of NOPAT that is paid out to all investors (i.e., not just to equity holders). 2) The variable, d, can be viewed as a “pay-out ratio” for all investors and is assumed to remain constant in perpetuity. 39 Note that the CFA variable defined above includes both dividend and interest payments because this variable refers to cash flow paid to all investors, not just dividends paid to equity holders. In this sense, the above model is a generalization of the constant growth dividend discount model used for equity valuation. In our case, we are focusing on CFA because, as noted earlier, we are interested in valuing the total firm, not just the equity component of the firm. 51 3) The growth rate variable, gA, can be estimated via the relation: gA = (1 – d) ⋅ KA . Note that this assumption is the conventional one used in textbooks used to estimate growth in the firm’s equity except that our relation applies broadly to all of the firm’s investors’ investments and not only common equity. That is, (1 – d) can be interpreted as the “retention ratio” (i.e., the percentage of NOPAT retained by the firm on behalf of all investors to reinvest in the firm’s operations after making dividend and interest payments) and KA can be viewed as the expected return on those retained net operating profits. 4) A crucial assumption is that the required return on the firm’s debt and equity is not affected by the choice of pay-out ratio, d. That is, both creditors and equity holders are indifferent between receiving their returns in the form of capital gains or dividends / interest income. This is essentially the famous “dividend irrelevance” argument of Miller and Modigliani (1961) except that it is now extended to encompass both creditors and equity holders. If this form of “dividend irrelevance” holds, then the required return on the investors’ investments (KA) is not affected by the firm’s choice of d because the firm’s cost of debt (KD) and equity (KS), as well as the firm’s capital structure, are unaffected by d.40 5) Another implicit assumption, again consistent with Miller and Modigliani, is that capital structure is irrelevant in terms of its effect on KA and firm value. 6) As in Miller and Modigliani (1961), the true value of the firm is therefore based solely on the firm’s operating cash flows (denoted here as CFA) and the required return on the firm’s investments (defined here as KA). This intuition is formalized by using the above valuation equation and 40 One can view the yield-to-maturity (YTM) of the firm’s debt as being comprised of a current yield component and a capital gains component, similar to the way one views the firm’s stock return as being comprised of a dividend yield and a capital gain/loss. Thus, M-M’s dividend irrelevance theory can apply to the firm’s YTM as long as there are no differences in the tax rates for interest payments and capital gains/losses related to the firm’s bonds. 52 substituting the relevant definitions of the CFA and gA variables, as follows: VA = d ⋅ NOPATt +1 d ⋅ NOPATt +1 d ⋅ NOPATt +1 NOPATt +1 CFA = = = = K A − g A K A − (1 − d ) ⋅ K A K A − K A + d ⋅ K A d ⋅KA KA According to the above formula, the equilibrium value of VA can simply be computed by dividing the firm’s expected NOPAT by the current return required by the firm’s investors. Thus, the choice of an expected growth rate, gA, is not explicitly required in order to estimate the firm’s overall value. Clearly, the KA term will have a growth estimate implicitly embedded in it but the analyst does not need to explicitly separate out this estimate of gA in order to value the firm using the CGM technique. Once again, this result holds only when the above assumptions are all met. Deviations from these assumptions will clearly not allow the CGM to be simplified to the above solution. The following numerical solution demonstrates the independence between growth rate assumptions and firm value when the above assumptions are met. Assume: d = 50% (i.e., the firm pays out half of its expected NOPAT to creditors and equity holders); NOPATt+1 = $10.00; KA = 20%; and therefore gA = (1 – d) ⋅ KA = (1-.50) ⋅ 20% = 10%; and CFA = d ⋅ NOPATt+1 = .50 ⋅ $10.00 = $5.00. Using our valuation equation, the value of the firm can be computed as: VA = $5.00 / (.20 - .10) = $5.00 / .10 = $50.00. Now, if we assume a different pay-out ratio, say 80%, then we can re-compute the value of the firm as: VA = (.80 ⋅ $10.00) / (.20 - ((1-.80) ⋅ .20)) = $8.00 / (.20 - .04) = $50.00. Once again, the value of the firm is $50.00 even though our current growth rate assumption is now 4% rather than 10% assumed in the first part of this example. In fact, 53 both estimates of the firm’s value are equivalent to simply dividing the expected NOPAT by KA. That is, we can obtain the same value for the firm as follows: VA = $10.00 / .20 = $50.00. This latter calculation is, in effect, the same value obtained if we were to assume a zero growth rate. Thus, the above derivations suggest that assuming a zero growth rate for the paper’s economic profit relation might not be that egregious for our purposes as long as the aforementioned assumptions are relatively close to real world behavior. That is, assuming an explicit growth rate is not necessary in our model since it gives the same valuation estimate as long as: 1) the firm’s pay-out policy is constant (and irrelevant), 2) growth is constant and can be estimated by the product of the firm’s required return and retention ratio, and 3) the firm’s capital structure is irrelevant. 54