98-21 Privatization and Endogenous Strategic Trade Policy JoAnne Feeney University of Colorado at Boulder and Arye Hillman Bar-lian University PRIVATIZATION AND ENDOGENOUS STRATEGIC TRADE POLICY JoAnne Feeney! University of Colorado at Boulder Arye Hillman 1 Bar-llan University May 1998 Abstract This paper explores the interdependencebetween international financial markets, privatization, and strategic trade policies. We examine an economywhere portfolio allocations chosen by risk-averse agents reflect diversification incentives and incorporate rational forecasts of future trade policies. Assuming a governmentresponsiveto demandsof its constituency,we show that ownershipstructure will have a decisive impact on trade policy throughits effect on the lobbying activities of private agents. Portfolios and trade policy are thus jointly determinedin political-economicequilibrium. Privatizationof state-ownedindustry exertsan importantinfluence over local and foreign trade policy by expandingthe scopefor individual diversification. Key Words: Internationalfinancial markets,endogenouspolicy, privatization, strategictrade policy JEL Classification:F13, D72, F36, F12 1 We would like to thank Ken Beauchemin,Rick Bond, Jim Markusen,Keith Maskus,and Jay Wilson for useful discussionsand participantsat the Mid-West InternationalEconomicsand TheoryMeetings for helpful comments. We are responsiblefor any remaining errors. Feeneygratefullyacknowledgesfinancial supportfrom the National ScienceFoundation(grant#HRD-9637016)and the StemSchoolof Businessat New York University(while visiting duringthe 1997-98academicyear). Addressfor correspondence:JoAnneFeeney,Departmentof Economics,CampusBox 256, Universityof Coloradoat Boulder, Boulder,CO 80309-0256;phone:(303)492-5923; fax: (303)492-8960;emai1:feeney@colorado.edu; web: http//:spot.colorado.edu/-feeney 1. Introduction Recent events emphasize the growing interdependencebetween government policy and international financial markets The shifting patterns of ownership of flfffiS permitted through international trade in equities alter the coalitions in support of particular policies and thereby change the nature of governmentintervention. This paper focuses specifically on the influence of international financial marketson the use of strategictradepolicies. An extensive literature, beginning with a series of papers by James Brander and Barbara Spencer (in 1983 and 1985), reveals the potential benefits from strategic trade policies with imperfectly competitive internationalmarkets! These gains derive from the government's ability to indirectly manipulatemarketshareamongoligopolies to shift profits from foreign firms to domesticones. While the use of explicit exportsubsidiescontinuesto be prohibited by the World Trade Organizationas it was under the GAn, countries often use indirect forms of interventionto provide export assistance.U.S firms, for example,can benefit from low-interestloansmadeavailable throughthe Export-ImportBank Since imperfect competition characterizes many international markets, the scope for strategic interventionis potentiallyquite broad. We show that the applicationby governmentof suchpolicies will be limited, however, by the nature of uncertainty in exporting finns' profits in conjunction with the growing importanceof internationalfinancial markets. The benefitsof profit shifting via strategicsubsidiesarise only when domestic firms are owned primarily by domesticresidents. Lee (1990) and Dick (1993) show how the optimal strategicsubsidyis reduced by higher degrees of cross-national ownership of fInnS. Our first objective, therefore, is to endogenize the patterns of flml ownership, given the nature of technological uncertainty that characterizes oligopolistic industries,in orderto detenninethe subsidythatemergesin a political-economicequilibrium. While we expect ownership structure to affect the adoption of particular trade policies, we also know that 2 See also Grossman and Helpman (1985), Eaton and Grossman (1986), Krugman (1986), Grossman (1992), and the survey by Brander (1995). investorswill assessthe impactof future tradepolicies on equity valuesand dividendswhen selectingthe assetsthat will comprisetheseportfolios. We therefore include not only the effects of uncertainty on portfolio selection,but alsoforecastsof future tradepolicy, which itself is detenninedendogenously. A source of uncertaintyfundamentalto industries potentially targetedby strategictrade policy arises through technological competition (see Spencer and Brander, 1983): the first lInn to introduce a technologicalinnovationincreases its profits at the expenseof its competitors,and ownersof the innovating finD gain while others lose.3 When equity in finDS is tradeable, risk-averse investors will reduce exposure to this sort of risk by holding equity from each of the potentially innovating fInDS. We find, as implied by Feeney and Hillman (1997) and Cassing (1996), that asset market developmenthas an important impact on interventionist pressuresand policy outcomes. Our results help to explain the observation that governments engage in strategic trade policies less than one might otherwise expect. Moreover, our analysis emphasizes the role of endogenous ownership structlire in reducing the use of such policies, rather than the threat of countervailing duties, other retaliatory mechanisms, or policy implementation difficulties. Since ownershipstructureemergesas a critical determinantof .trade policy, our second and primary objective concerns the role of state ownership of firms and privatization for strategic trade policy. While in the U.S. private ownershipdominatesindustry, elsewheregovernmentsare heavily involved in production In EasternEurope and the former Soviet Union, for example, state ownership remains as the transition to marketeconomiescontinues. State-ownedindustry in Asia, Africa, Latin America, and to a lesserextentWesternEuropeand North Americaalsocontributessubstantiallyto gross domestic product. In many countries these sectors are currently undergoing privatization. The airline-frameindustryprovidesone exampleof governmentinvolvementin production in an industry potentiallytargetedby strategictrade policy. This sectorconsistsprimarily of a privately owned 3 The importance of demand uncertainty for the optimal choice of trade policy instrument in oligopolistic markets is examined in Cooper and Riezman (1989). Shivakumar (1993) considers the importance of the timing of the policy implementation with uncertainty. ') u.s. finn. Boeing, confronting a foreign competitor,Airbus, which is jointly owned by a number of Europeangovernments.Investorsin boththe U.S. and Europe(and elsewhere)may oln stock in Boeing, although these investors cannot diversify risk by holding stock in Airbus. Instead, the profits of such a stateowned fInn return to the private sector via one of two routes. If European governments distribute all the profits from stateownershipto their citizensvia increasedgovernmentbenefitsor reducedtax obligations, Europeanseffectively would hold nontradeableclaims to Airbus profits. Earningsof state-ownedfirms, however,often becomeinternalrentsenjoyedby flnn employeesalone. We showthat the use of strategic tradepolicies dependson which regimegovernsthe distribution of profits. Privatizationwould transform the government distribution of state-finn profits, on the one hand, and the internal rents, on the other, into tradeableclaims. As a consequence, the ongoingprivatizationof industryin Europe,Latin America,Asia, and the transition economies of EasternEurope may have unintended consequencesfor the trade policies of not only the privatizing country, but also of its trade partners.~ We assessthe importanceof uncertainty, risk sharing and state ownershipfor strategic trade policy by using the most basic model of finn competition, put forth in Branderand Spencer(1985), as our benchmarkand modifying that settingaccordingly. With this initial structurewe ensurethat in the absenceof thesemodifications strategicsubsidieswill be chosenby governmentto the benefit of local consumers: We examine the decisions of risk-averse consumer/investorswho face uncertainty in income due to the stochastic profits of firms. These agents will choose portfolio allocations, consumption,and lobbying activity. Lobbying will affect the policy implementedby governmentand 4 Boyko, Schleifer,and Vishny (1996)offer a modelto explain recentefforts acrossthe world to privatize,basedon endogenousefficiency gains that arise in privatizedfirms due to optimizing behaviorof political agents.We abstract from the efficiency differencessincethe distributionof profits, ratherthanthe amount,mattersfor our analysis.Also, seeHillman and Ursprung (1996)for a simultaneousconsiderationof endogenousprivatizationand tradepolicy. 5Somemodificationsto the basic modelcaneliminatethesebenefitsevenin the absenceof portfolio diversification: lack of governmentinformation on the strategicinteraction (Eaton and Grossman1986); retaliation (see Baldwin 1992); free entry (Horstman and Markusen1986,Markusenand Venables 1989); deadweightlosses in taxation (Dixit 1988);generalequilibrium effects(Dixit andGrossman1986);and rentseeking(Mooreand Suranovic1993). ~ agentswill recognizethis link, and alsothe structureof the gamethat firms are playing, when assembling portfolios. Using the benchmark model as our starting point, we will determine how policies differ in a risky world and how privatization will affect policy choices. We proceed in Section 2 to describe the economic and political environments and to present the decisionproblemsof fmns and consumer/investors.In Section 3 we establishequilibriumportfolios for home and foreign agents, detennine private-agentlobbying activity, and solve for the government's strategic trade policy. We consider this fiTStwhen all fmns are private, and second when state ownership of the flnn arises in one country. Section 4 summarizes our resultsand offers some concluding remarks. 2. The Economic and Political Environmen~ We considera world in which two rival finns, one located in the home country and the other in the foreign country, are the sale producersof a good, x, and competefor salesof x in a third country's market. Thesefinns face uncertainty in productioncosts (and thus profits), and in the home country, costsmayalso be affected by a governmentexportsubsidy.6Internationalfinancial marketspennit trade in the equity of private, but not state-owned,firms. Firm and consumer/investor decisions occur in three distinct stages. First, assettrades take place and portfolios are establishedat the end of period t to determine claims on period t + finn profits (stage1). At the beginningof period t + , whenassetmarketshaveclosed,cost shocksare realizedand observed by all. Given portfolios, the home governmentsubsidy is establishedthrough the political process(stage2). As in the basic strategictrade policy model, the foreign governmentdoesnot consider offering a subsidyto its export finn. Finally, finns independentlyand simultaneouslychoose output levels (hiring the appropriateamountof labor)andthus salesto the third marketto maximizeprofits and arrive at a subgarne-perfect Coumot-Nash Equilibrium (stage 3), At the end of the period, wagesare 6 It is beyond the scope of this paper to model the sources of the cost uncertainty that we presume arises from the researchand development process. For such an analysis. see Bagwell and Staiger (1994). 4 .7 paid, assetmarketsfe-open,dividends are distributed and consumptionout of disposableincome takes place. Any rearranging of portfolios occurs at this time to form stage one of the period t + 2 game. Since technologyshocksare temporary,outputdecisionsand governmentpolicy are set for one period at a time, and we solve this as a one-shotgame in eachperiod. Also, agentsin choosingportfolios fully understandthe finns' and government'sdecisionprocesses. 2.1 ProductionStructureand Equity Returns The home and foreign producers of x constitute a duopoly, eachfirm produces x solely for export, and home and foreign sales are denoted Xl and X2, respectively. In each country the remainder of the economy is consolidated into a single perfectly competitive industry which produces the consumption good, y. Output of the home and foreign industries is denoted yl and y2, respectively, and y acts as the numeraire. The third country imports x and uses its own production of y as payment. With stochasticcosts,profits of firm i are given by (1) where the randomnessin profits is indicated by the tilde and the specific time and state notation is suppressed until dividends are defined in equation (4). Finn profits, expressed in y units, depend on the relative price at which the good sells in the third market, p( X), on the level of sales, Xi, on the firm's total costs, Ci (Xi), and on a per-unit subsidy, ei, shouldone be offered by the governmentof country i (with e2 = 0 by assumption). The government'schoice of a subsidydependsin deterministicfashionon lobbying as put forth in section2.2. The equilibrium relative price dependsinversely on total sales,X, while costsdependon finn output and the realizationof the 'cost' or 'technology' shock. To simplify comparison of equity prices in the next section, we assume that firms' cost functions differ only due to the realization of the cost shocks. Also, y production in all three countries is detenninistic. 5 <0, The x sector is assumed small relative to the y sector in the traditional sense -the wage is determined in the y sector and the x finn may employ labor at that wage. The y sector is perfectly competitive and outputis producedwith labor and a sector-specific(capital)input. Labor and capital are fixed in supply and immobile acrosscountries.The wage equalsthe constantvalue of labor's marginal product in sector y and the return to capital is given by the nonstochastic value of its marginal product. The optimal productionchoice,madeoncecostsare revealed,satisfiesthe first-order condition, (2) a1!xi axi and the associated second-orderconditions (7r~i < 0 ).8 We assume that home and foreign output levels act as strategicsubstitutesby restrictingthird-countrydemandto be linear, which guarantees1r:i < 0 and 1r;f < o. Also, a changein a firm's own outputcreatesa larger effect on its profits than doesa changein the competitor's output (Jt'i~i< Jt'iji for i * j ).9 A subsidy offered by the home government lowers the firm's marginal cost and allows it credibly to expand sales to the third market. This leads to the well-known results that home market shareand profits rise, while foreign finn profits fall by an even greateramount: (3) a1rxl il trx2 aT>O, ilel When the home and foreign firms are owned entirely by own-countryresidents,a small subsidy,funded throughnon-distortionarytaxation,raisesdomesticwelfare and reducesforeign welfare. The presenceof uncertainty will not alter thesechangesin profits, but will lead to internationalrisk sharing which alters the identities of the beneficiariesand losersfrom the home subsidy. 7The labels firm and industry will be used throughout the paper to refer to the x and y sectors, respectively. 8Primes and subscripts denote partial derivatives. 9 See Brander and Spencer (1985) or Brander (1995) for further details on the nonstochastic model and derivations of the effects of a subsidy, and see Appendix 2 for expressions of second-orderconditions. 6 The profits earnedby firms form the basis of dividend paymentson firm equity. Equity in the x firm in each country is either traded in international equity markets, or not, if a firm is owned by the government. Equity in the y industry, by contrast, is always tradeable. By normalizing to one the number of total equity shares associated with each firm, the dividend, is,xi (s) , paid on equity in firm Xi in period t and state s equals total firm profits as given in eq. (1): (4) In the y industry, equity providesa claim on the nonstochasticreturnto capital: ()' yi = ri Ki (5) fori=1,2, I where ri and Ki denote the constant marginal revenue product of capital and the total supply of capital, respectively, in country i. 2.2 EndogenousPolicy Choice We proposea simple mechanismthat links policy outcomesto private agents' interests.Since salesofx occur only in the third-countrymarket,the government'srelevanttrade policy instrumentis an export subsidy.lOWe deviatefrom the basic model only by assumingthat the homegovernmentresponds to political pressurefrom its constituentsin deciding on this subsidy. The resolution of the political processfollows portfolio decisionsand realization of the cost shocks,and precedesthe simultaneous output decisions made by flfDlS.ll The interests of private agentsare made known to the governmentthrough lobbying activities, and lobbying affects the subsidyoffered to the domesticx sectorin the currentperiod. In particular,we 10We are restricting our analysis to the case of Cournot competition and thus to the use of a government subsidy. Bagwell and Staiger (1994) find in an environment with stochastic costs that when an increase in R&D lowers expected costs, a government R&D subsidy is optimal regardless of the form of product market competition. 11 One can also envision a world where agents lobby ex ante, but in so doing it would be necessary to incorporate the dual goals of such lobbying: rent shifting and insurance via trade policy. By considering the ex post decision, we are isolating the profit-shifting motive behind lobbying. 7 assumethe home government's offer of a subsidy, e1(s) = e( s) , increases with the effort, e(s), allocated to lobbying by the home agent in state s: (6) e(s) = e(l(s») where This general representation captures the influence of private agents on public policy in the context of political competition or political support maximization under representative democracy (as in Hillman 1989, Hillman and Ursprung 1988, Ursprung 1990, Grossmanand Helpman 1994, or Rodrik 1995) or under direct democracy(as in Mayer 1984). In theseenvironments,lobbying reflectsthe extentof political support,in the form of real resources,offered to a representativein exchangefor a subsidyor to a candidatewho promisesa subsidy. In direct democracy.it reflectsthe degreeto which the medianvoterfavorsa subsidy. Whenthe presenceof a democraticsystemitself is in doubt, lobbyingrepresentsthe political supportgiven to the regime in power in exchange for a subsidy.12 2.3 Consumer/lnvestorProblem Assettrade takesplacebeforethe resolutionof uncertainty,but with completeinformation on the distribution of the technologyshocksand the natureof the political process With exceptionsfor cases where an x firm is state-owned,the home agentis initially endowed with complete ownershipof the home x finn and y industry, while the foreign agent owns the foreign finn and industry. We imposethe following symmetry conditions in order to simplify the derivation of portfolio allocations under the different regimes: preferencesare identical acrossagents;cost shocksare drawn from the samedistribution, are perfectly negatively correlated across countries, and are identically and independently distributed over time; the y dividendsand the wage are the sameacrosscountries.13These imply that in the absenceof any possibility of strategic subsidies, expected x dividends are the same across countries, and with y dividends 12 See also Austen-Smith (1995) and Anderson (1996) who model political support as attempts to buy access to presentinformationto political agents. 8 and the wagealsothe same,homeand foreign agentshaveequalex-antewealth. Also, we assumethirdcountry agentsdo not engage in trade in claims to home or foreign x fmns.14 The representativeagentof the home country chooseslobbying effort and selectsa portfolio of assetsto maximize expected lifetime utility: (7) where utility, u(), over consumption, YTd(s), in period 1"and state s is increasing, strictly concave, and exhibits constant relative risk aversion, f3 is the discount factor (0 < f3 < 1), E, is the expectations operator given infonnation available at the end of period t, and l 1"(s) denotes time engaged in lobbying activities, where time is valued at v(.), for v'() > 0, v"() > 0, v(O)= 0, and v'(O) = 0 The foreign agent solves an analogous problem, but with lobbying set at zero. The agent'sallocation of time to working is inelasticallyset at one unit. so labor incomeequals the nonstochastic market wage, w The agentis also endowedwith one unit of free time which maybe divided between leisure and lobbying. Dividend income depends on the shares of each equity held. Finally, the home agent may be subject to a tax, Tt"(s), imposed to finance the export subsidy. The home agent's budgetconstraintat the end of period t is thus givenby (8) 13 Perfect negative correlation simplifies the exposition and is not critical for the results; independence in realizations, for example, generatesthe same diversification and policy outcomes. See Section 3. 14If this complexity were included, the third-country agent would only want to buy shares in risky x firms (and sell some shares in its nonstochastic y industry) if doing so would cause income to covary positively with the world price of x (and the country's expenditure on x). This is not in general the case, however. By (4) we can see that an adverse technology shock which raises costs and increases the price of x will reduce the x equity return. Thus, ownership of x equity will deliver lower income precisely when the third country's terms of trade have deteriorated. We also rule out shon sales,so the third country's residents have no interest in x equity. 9 where income, I,(s), dependson the period-t (vectors of) equity shares,ex-dividend equity prices, and dividends, denoted at, qt(s), and <>t(s),respectively, and the portfolio purchased at the end of period t that pays off in period t + is at+\ The dividends are defined in (4) and (5), while equity sharesand prices are endogenous. The foreign agent faces an analogous budget constraint, albeit without the tax. The x equity holdings will be denoted by ar,x; and a;..ri for home and foreign agents, respectively,wherethe secondsubscriptdistinguisheshome from foreign firm equity (i=1,2). The equity holdings in the y sector are analogously defined as at,y; and a,.,y;, Absent the time notation, the home agent's portfolio is a=(aXl,aX2,aYl,aY2)' with the foreign agent's given analogously, but with asterisks. All equity is subjectto a no-shoTt-sales restriction: 0 ~ a ~ 1 .Asset-market clearing requires homeand foreign holdingsof eachequity to sumto one. Maximization of expectedlifetime utility requirestwo decisionsby the home agent: first, upon realization of current finD cost shocks and income uncertainty, the agent must choose lobbying effort; second,facing uncertaintyregardingnext period's income, the agentmustchoose current consumption and the portfolio allocationswhich detenninenext period's state-contingent income.The state-contingent lobbying decision,and thus subsidy,in any future period dependson the agent's ponfolio and the agent will recognize this when detennining the optimal portfolio allocation. Fonnally, the period-t problem is: (9) max y,d,l"a'+1 subjectto \It 0 ~ f. t (S)~ 1, 0 ~ a'+1~ 1 where 1; (s) = e(f. I (s)) x, 1(s). The period-t consumption, lobbying, and portfolio choices must satisfy the following first-orderconditionsfor an interior solution: 10 (10) (a) ah'/(s) a1;(s) -v'(f,(s)) =0 for j = xl,x2,yl,y2 (c) The lobbying choice will be zero whenever (lOb) is negative at f t (s) = 0, and one when (lOb) is positive at f. t (s) = 1. We rule out the latter case by assuming sufficiently rapid diminishing returns to lobbying and increasing marginal costs of lobbying. The Euler equations, (1 Oc) and (1 Od), can be solved to determine relative prices of equity, q',"i(S) and q,.Yi(S), in terms of the numeraire, y,(s) for the home agent: (11) (a) - = L fJ1"-t 1"=,+1 'U/(Yt"d(S)) }+ COV~ ~:~d(~ ,b";'j~:~~~l , U'(Ytd (s)) } Since the total shares of equity have been normalized to one, each price reflects the total market value of the firm or industry. While eachprice dependson current, realizedmarginalutility, relative equity prices are independentof this numeraireeffect. Also, since only period-t dividendsare affected by the period-t choice of lobbying, these(ex-dividend)prices will not be affected by the resultingsubsidy. Expectations of future subsidies,however,will affectcurrentequity prices. Home and foreign agents' portfolio and lobbying decisions give rise to a political-economic equilibrium, which we define asfollows: 11 Definition: A political-economic equilibrium consists of: a pair of portfolio allocations, a and a*," a choice of lobbying effort, f(s); e(f(s)); an export subsidy, sales of x, Xl(S) and X2(S),"home and foreign consumption, yd(s) and yd*(S); goods and equity prices, p( s) and q( s) that satisfy: (i) firm and consumer first-order conditions, in (2) and (10); (ii) budget and time constraints, (9); (iii) the no-shorr-sales constraint on assets,(9); (iv) the non-negativity constraint on lobbying, (9); (v) asset-market clearing conditions Sincecostshocksare purely temporary,the equilibrium may be state-dependent, but not time-dependent. Time notation will be eliminated wheneverclarity is not compromised. The portfolios, lobbying activities, and policies will dependon which of three regimes(complete privatization, state-ownership with profit distribution, and state-ownership with rent appropriation) characterizes the rival economies. 3. Political-EconomicEquilibria 3.1 CompletePrivatization We first consider the choice of strategictrade policy when all finns are owned by the private sectorand equity is tradeable in internationalmarkets. We establish the following politicalc-econornic equilibrium for this regime: Equilibrium 1 (No StateOwnership). Thepolitical-economicequilibriumwhenall firms are ownedby the private sector consists of." Portfolios, a = (~,~, 1,0) and a* = (~,~, 0,1); lobbying, f(s) = 0 'if s; subsidy,e(s)= 0 'if s; and X2(S) satisfying (2) given e=O; firm values, q;; =q;2' p = p( X(s)),jor X(s) = Xl(S)+X2(S). 12 and relative commodityprice, d* When agents anticipate e(s) = f(s) = 0, they expect by (4) the profits and thus dividends of home and since underlying cost shocks are drawn from the samedistribution. With a xi = a;i = t, homeand foreign budgetconstraintsgive consumptionas: w=w and 8,1 = 8,2 Consumption is nonstochastic since Corr{ c5xl (s). c5x2 (s)} = -1. Non- stochasticconsumptionleads to a known intertemporalmarginal rate of substitution of unity so the covariance tenDSin the asset-pricing equations (11) disappear.15 Since the expected values and variances of the home and foreign fInns are the same, (11) implies thatfirms' marketvalueswith internationalequitytrade, q;;, areequalized: Since agents correctly anticipate the policy outcome and the corresponding equity values when establishingportfolios, home and foreign agentshave the sameex-antewealth. Each agentthus owns exactly half of the home and foreign firms in equilibrium (satisfying asset-market-clearing conditions), while retaining all of the y industry in the agent's own country of residence. It remains to be confIrmed that e(s) = ((s) = 0 in equilibrium. Given the portfolios described above, the condition governing the lobbying choice, (lOb), becomes: £,(s)=O 15Note that with a zero correlation, for example, consumption would retain a stochastic element, but would still be the same acrosscountries ex post. That delivers the same value for the covariance terms so that equity prices are equalized across agentsat theseportfolio allocations, and home and foreign finDShave the same relative value. This also holds for Equilibrium 2. 13 3.2.1 Since total profits of home and foreign firms fall with a home subsidy (by (3)), the term in square brackets on the left-hand side is negative. The portfolio that eachagenthas acquired makesthe home agent indifferent to the pure (zero-sum) shifting of profits that the subsidy creates, but makes the agent worse off as a consequenceof the reduction in aggregateprofits.16Consequently,a comer solution with f.( s) = 0 arises as lobbying is constrained to be non-negative. Since no political support is offered for strategictrade policy, the political processgives rise to a zero subsidyin everystate of nature. Home and foreign sales of x follow (2) for e = 0 and p( X (s)) is determined accordingly 3.2 State Ownershipand StrategicSubsidies We now considercircumstanceswhere the foreign competitoris state owned. The home firm remains privately owned, and its equity continues to be tradeable in international markets. Portfolios consist only of three assets: a = (aXI ' ayl ' a)'2) for the home agent and with asterisks for the foreign agent. The distribution of the profits earned by the foreign firm is important here. We begin by assumingthat foreign profits of the state-ownedfinn accrue indirectly to foreign residents via state expenditureswhich provide consumptionthat is a perfect substitutefor y. We also considerthe policy outcome when the foreign profits becomeinternal rents appropriatedby employeesof the foreign firm, while residents at large receivenone of the proceeds. This allows us to detennine how privatization abroadaffectsthe use of strategictrade policy by the governmentof its traderival. Foreign Firm Profits Indirectly Distributed The returns from the state-owned firm are distributed to foreign private-sector agents via lump sum transfers, g*(s)= 1CX2(S),which introduces a source of uncertainty in foreign consumption that is not 16 Since i) T Ii) I. = Xl .e'( e) > 0 at e(I.) = 0, the second term is zero, while f(s) = 0, v'(f(s)) = 0, so the costs of lobbying are strictlypositive. 14 - = Et I.f31'-t (16) 1'=t+1 All gains from equity trade are thereby exhaustedand asset-marketclearing is satisfied. Confinnation of this policy outcome for theseportfolios is found through reexaminationof (1 Db), ( ) aer(s) () }-v ' (l,s)-u air s ' ( d ( )) a1;(s) y, S () <O ai, s at £,(s)=o, for a xl = a x2 = o. With a complete buyout of the domestic firm by foreigners, domestic investors lose all interestin this industry, as they neitherconsumeits output nor enjoy its dividends. The home political processgives rise to a zero subsidy in every state. Firms' state-contingent output levels, which reflect the We see that state ownershipof imperfectlycompetitive fmns will not by itself invoke strategic subsidies. Privatizationof state-ownedfinns in this environmentwill have no impact on the extent of strategic subsidies used by the government of one's competitor in trade. If there are limitations on the tradability of foreign wealth embodied in its competitive sector. however. a buyout of the domestic fIrm may not be possible. Alternatively, such buyouts may be prevented by tradeability limitations in the home x sector arising from principal-agent problems, or in some countries from explicit government restrictions on complete foreign ownership. In these casesthe home agents will retain some of the risky domestic flrm and may benefit from lobbying as determinedby (lOb). This situation arises when rent appropriationtakes placeandso is analyzedexplicitly in the followingcase. 3.2.2 Foreign Firm Profits as Intra-Firm Rents A second scenario under state-ownershiprecognizes the possibility that rents may be appropriated by firm workers,managers,or political agents. Foreigncitizens at large (distinguishedfrom the group of rent-beneficiaries) face no risk. but have lower wealth and consumption since they receive no indirect return 16 from the statefirm. We assumethat foreign x employeesconstitutea small fraction. n, of the population, derive income primarily from the x sector, and have negligible claims to y sector capital by comparison. The foreign agent that trades in international equity markets then representsthe foreign citizens at large. In this setting, we establishthe following political-economic equilibrium: Equilibrium 3 (Foreign State Ownership with AppropriatedProfits). With sufficientlydecreasing marginal costs,thepolitical-economicequilibriumwhentheforeign finn is state-ownedand its profits are appropriatedby its employeesconsistsoft Portfolios,a = (r ,I, ro) and a* = (1- r, O,I-ro) with + < r < 1 and 0< ro < 1.. homelobbying, l(s) > 0 ":t s.. subsidy, e(s) > 0 ":t s.. consumption. yd (s) = w + y8xt (s)+ 8)0. + co. 8)02 -T(s) and yd. (s) = (1- n)w. + (1- r )8XI(s)+ (1- ro}8)'2; sales,Xl (s) and X2(S)satisfying(2)for e(s)> 0; equity values, q;; Iq;2 > 1, and p = p(X(s)) for X(s) = XI(S)+X2(S). The home agentreceives a share of the foreign industry, (J), in exchange for selling a share, 1- r, of the home finn. This exchangereflects the relative value of the home flnn in terms of the foreign y industry and equatesrelative equity prices across agents (see Appendix 1 for derivation): w (18) I./3'-'{E, {O;I(S)}} ~!=~ -'='+1 Q',Y2(S) -I./3'-' '='+1 {O;2} I./3'-' {E, {O;I(s)}} = ,om COV{O;I (S),U'(Y:(S))} + -I- (homeagent) I./3'-'{O;2 E,{u'(Y:(S))}} ,=m Cov{o;(s),u'(y:'(s))} (foreign agent) for y:(s) and y:*(s) as statedin Equilibrium3. The first termsin (18) are identical for homeand foreign agents regardless of portfolio allocations, while the second tenD is the risk premium which captures the amountby whichthe price of the equity is reducedto compensateagentsfor bearingrisk and dependson the amountof the risky equity held. If r = 1 , homeconsumptionis stochastic,while foreign consumption dependsonly on the nonstochasticwage and returns from y-sectorcapital. Hence, the covarianceterm 17 y. for the foreign agent would be zero, while the covariance tenD for the home agent would be negative (see Appendix 1). With the home agent's relative price of Xl equity less than that of the foreign agent, some of this equity will be sold in exchange for claims to the foreign y industry. At the other extreme where r = 0, the home agent's consumptionwould not be risky, so the covariancetenD for home would be zero, while the foreign agent's relative valuation would be lower due to a negative covariance term.17 Hence, r mustlie betweenzeroand one. Sincethe foreignagentreceivesno incomefrom the local x firm, however,we know thatex-antewealthof the home agentexceedsthat of the foreign agent. Consequently, constant relative risk aversion preferences guarantee that in equilibrium the home agent retains more than half the homefirm: ~ < r < 1.18 A subsidywill be soughtif this share of the increasedprofits is large enoughto offset the tax neededto fund a (marginal)subsidy.This is detenninedby (lOb), expressedhereas: (19) J [ aOtXl(s) U'(Y:(S)1Yo ~W ] ~ ae,(s)} ae,(s) ~-V'(f.I(S)) >0 at t'r(S)=O Dropping time subscriptsand substitutingfor a subsidy'seffectson profits and taxes,this becomes: f(s) = 0 a e( s) since v'( f(s)) = 0 and e(s)= 0 at f(s) = o. The sign of this tenDdependsonthe sizeof r, the specification of inverse demand,and the nature of costs. We can simplify this condition further as: If r = O. the homeagenthasno interestin ~e homex flrIn. so t(s) = e(s)= T(s)V's in sucha case. 18 See Merton (1971) for a proof that the share of wealth invested in a risky asset (Xl) rises with income for agents with constant relative risk aversion preferences. or see Hakansson (1987) for a more general discussion. 18 With constantmarginal costs, a.t"2(S)/ae(s)= 1/3p'(X(s)). In this case,solving for r reveals that the home agent must retain over three-quartersof the home fInn before lobbying will be worthwhile. Given that Y;<y< this may occur and will be more likely the greater is the difference in wealth between the two agents. The presenceof decreasing marginalcosts,however,lowers substantiallythe minimum ownership share of the home firm that will motivate the home agent to lobby. With decreasingmarginal costs, we have instead(seeAppendix2): (21) a X2 (s) -1t';1 -1 -a-;{lJ"-D- p,(",2-4"'+3) where 1("reflects the degree of decreasingmarginal costs with 1("= c" / p' for 0 < 1("< 1. By inserting this into (20) we can solve for the minimum ownership share of the home firm for which (20) holds. As 1Crises from 0 (constant marginal costs) to I, that minimum falls from .75 to 0, as shown in Figure 1. When the actual share retained equals or exceedsthat minimum. a positive subsidy will be anticipated by both agents in all future periods. 19 This subsidy will shift rents to both horne and foreign investors at the expense of the employeesof the foreignstate-owned finn. Such an outcome, by (3) and (4), raises future dividends of the home fino and lowers profits of the foreign firm and, by (II) and its foreign analogue, leads to an increase in the value of the home firm relative to the foreign finn:2Oa {Q;;/q;2}/ ae(s) 1 .. > 0 for a = (r , 1, (J))and a. = (1- r , 0, 1- (J)) . e=O,a.a This effect is positive since in everystate db'XJ(s)jde(s) > 0 and d1!X2(s)/de(s)< o. Consequently, state ownership of the foreign fInn raises home agent wealth relative to foreign agent wealth, since all agentsanticipatea positive exportsubsidyand incorporatetheseexpectationsinto current equity values. 19Since t < r < I , decreasingmarginal coststhat place that minimum at one-half or less guaranteesthat the home agent lobbies the government. A subsidy will arise with a smaller degree of decreasingmarginal cost, the larger is r . 20The relative wealth held in tradeable y equity of the foreign x workers i.sassumedto be sufficiently small as to be negligible for the determination of assetprices in the foreign country. 19 Privatizationof the foreign state-owned finn, that delivers tradableclaimsto finn profits into the privatesector,will lead to further diversificationof portfolios as in Equilibrium I. This will eliminatethe use of the strategic subsidy by its trade rival, will increase the market value of the foreign finn relative to the homefirm, and will raise foreignwealth. 4.3 HomeFirm State-Ownedand AppropriatedRents State ownership of the home firm, when profits are appropriatedby a narrow group of firmaffiliated agents,gives rise to the appearanceof two types of agentswithin the homecountry: one type (A) works and owns claims to the y sector capital income, while the other (B) is the group of x employees,who havecapturedthe rentstherein,own no claims to y capital income,andcomprisea small faction (n) of the population. Portfolios now consist of a = (a.t2 ,ayl ,aY2) for the home A agent and with asterisks for the foreign agent. We establish the following political-economic equilibrium: Equilibrium 4 (Home Firm StateOwned). Thepolitical-economicequilibriumwhen theforeign firm is state-owned and its profits are appropriatedby thefirm's employeesconsistsof Portfolios, a = (1- v, 1- .u,o), a* = (v, .u,1) fort consumption, y~(s) = (l-n)w+(l- < v < 1 ,. lobbying f(s) > 0 'V s,. subsidy e(s) > 0 'Vs,. v). 0.t2(S)+ (l-.u)' and yd*(s)=w*+v8.t2(S)+.u8YI+8Y2,. Oyl -(I-n)T(s), y~ = nw+ trXI(S)- nT(s), sales, XI(S) and X2(S) satisfying (2) given e>O; unequal firm equity values, q~ Iq;2 > 1, and p= p(X(s)) for X(S)=Xl(S)+X2(S). Risk-sharingwill occur as the home agentsellssharesof yl to the foreign agentin exchangefor part of the risky foreign finn. Since the foreign agentis the wealthier, the home agentwill hold less than haIf the risk associatedwith the foreign finn. The portfolio equilibrium is opposite in fonn to that in Equilibrium 3 since the identity of the state-owned finn has been shifted from foreign to home. In this case,however,the home A agenthasno incentiveto lobby for a subsidyto the home x firm, since no incomeaccruesfrom that source(as in Equilibrium 2). The home employeesof the x firm, by contrast, 20 form a more narrow group whoseincome is closelytied to x profits. Theseagentswould enjoy all of the increasein dividends that follow the imposition of a subsidy. Furthermore,the financing cost of the subsidy would be spread across the entire population, so their tax cost would effectively be zero. Reinterpretationof (19) indicatesthat theseagentslobby for an export subsidyin all statesof nature: (21) t'B(S) = 0 = 0 for all statesand v'(O)= O. The subsidyis granted through the political process and transfers income from foreign agents to the narrow group of x-affiliated agentsin the homecountry. Analogousto Equilibrium3, the subsidylowers the value of the foreign firm relative to the (shadow)value of the homefirm. Privatization that permits the ownership of x firm profits to be exchanged across agents would reduce the political pressuresfavoring strategic subsidiesin the home country. The foreign agent benefits from privatization in the home country sincethe elimination of the subsidyincreasesforeign marketshareandprofits relative to those of the homefirm. S. Concluding Remarks A comparisonof the four political-economicequilibria reveals the interdependencebetween portfolio allocations,privatization, and strategictrade policies. One impedimentto the diversification neededto eliminate a subsidy equilibrium can arise from restricted accessto international financial markets,and anotherthrough state-ownershipof firms. Our results suggestthat privatization may have broadereffectsthanotherwisethoughtdue to the endogenous responseof trade policy. When equity in both firms is tradeable,uncertaintyand international financial marketscreate assetportfolios that induce a country to abandonthe use of strategic subsidies. This occurssince the profit shifting createdby suchsubsidiesmerelyreallocatesdividends within an agent's portfolio and the aggregatenegativeeffect on profits reducesthe total value of the agent's portfolio. The presenceof a 21 home bias in portfolios persists (see Tesar and Werner 1995), however, and if such bias exists in industries subjectto strategicinteraction, lobbying for subsidieswill arise. State ownershippreventsone firm's stock from trading in equity marketsand insteaddirects its profits either to governmentor to intra-finn rents. In the fonner case,when foreign agentsacquire all sharesof the homefirm, the home agenttakesno interestin strategicsubsidiesso that none are granted by the homegovernment.In the latter case,homeagentsretainmorethan half the home firm which may be enough to generate a subsidy under constant marginal costs. If not, sufficiently decreasing marginal costs guaranteethat lobbying for intervention occurs and the resulting export subsidy will increasethe value of equity in the home firm relative to that of the foreign firm. When the profits of a home state- owned finn are retainedby its employees,income for this groupremainsclosely tied to the x finn, and the political processestablishesan export subsidy. We conclude, therefore, that the privatization of a foreign state-owned finn would remove all incentives for the home governmentto provide a subsidyand would raise the value of the foreign firm relative to its home-country trade rival. Privatization of a home state-owned firm, in any form that ultimately pennits trade in equity of the firm, eliminates the pro-interventionist contingent at home, which creates a political climate that institutes free trade. In this case privatization has the paradoxical effect of loweringthe value of the home firm, relative to the equilibrium with state ownership,sincethe export subsidyis not offered. 22 }>o Appendix 1. RelativePrices Using equations (IIa) and (lIb) we can determine the relative prices of the home fiml's equity in temlS of the foreign industry equity for homeand foreign agents,respectively: ~:.::11 = Qr,Y2(S) i;~= Q;,y2(S) where (A2) Q"y2(S) = After substituting for Qr,y2and Q;,Y2'these can be expressed as in (18), The covariance tenus in (18) depend on consumption and consumptiondepends on the portfolio allocations. In the case of Equilibrium 3, consumption for home and foreign agents is given by: yd(S)= W+r8Xl(S)+8Yl +ro.8y2 and yd*(S)= w. +(1-y)8xl(s)+(1-co)8Y2 Since utility is strictly concave: This latter covariancetermcan bederivedexplicitly for the home agentas: Hence,when r = , the homeagent'srelative price will include a negativecovarianceterm, while the foreign agent'scovariancetenDwill be zero. The oppositeoccursfor r = O. 23 -1>0 2. Conditions for Strategic Subsidiesfor Different Cost Structures An export subsidy arises in equilibrium when home agents lobby the government. We derive the minimum ownership share, ax)' of the home firm (when owning none of the foreign firm) that generates an export subsidy. The decision to lobby is governed by (19), which is reproduced here (with all time subscriptssuppressedfor notationalsimplicity) for the casewhenthe foreignfirm's stockis not traded in equity markets (due, fOTexample, to state ownership): ae(( s))- } -V'(l(S))-U'(yd(S))~ at f(s) = 0 S home flnn profits increase by the amount aT(s) ( ) = Xl (s)- ae(s) bY rise taxes and X(S))_+XI(S) p'( XI(S). ((S )) >0 ae(s) at s at s ) yields: and v'(f(s)) =0), aX2(S) = a8XI(s) (so e(s)=O al .Substitution Evaluated at f(s)=O S ( at. ae(s) Xl(S)op'(X(S)) ~+xl(s) ]-xl(S)}.~> This condition can be simplified since we know u'(.) > 0, ae(s)jae(s» axl. dX2(S) 1+ p'( X(s)). -a-;w- 2.1 Constantmarginal costs. of a strategicsubsidyby the homecountry. 24 0 at f(s) = 0 0, and Xl(S) > 0, which leaves: "II 2.2 Diminishingmarginalcosts. Subscripts denote partial derivatives of firm i's profits with respect to firm i's or j's output. State notation is suppressedfor simplicity. The second-orderconditions with linear inverse demand and non-constantmarginal costs are: (A9) (a) 1r)) = 2p'-c)) . 2P' -C22 1CII < 1C12 and 1C;2 < 1C;1 1t"22= where <0 (b) 7r\2 = 7r;\ = p' < 0 < 0 Let c)) =c~ =c In this case, (A9)(a) can be expressedas 1Cii= 2p' -c" < o. The degree of diminishing marginal costs is captured by 1(. where c" = 1(.P'. Restricting /( to less than two satisfies both second-orderconditions. 1(< 2 . When 1(= 0, marginal costs are constant, and 0 < K"< 2 allows for decreasingmarginal costs. Replacing c with 1C p' in solving for the changein foreignfirm outputyields: (AIO) 1 ax2(S) -~= ae(s) -D p'(1(2 -41( + 3) The minimum ownership share required for the subsidy equilibrium, ~J' falls with the degree of ., diminishingmarginalcosts: a xl = 1(- -41(+3 As 1Crises from 0 (constant marginal costs) to 1, ax) 1("2 -41("+4 falls from. 75 to 0 as shown in Figure I 25 References Anderson, J., "The Market for Influence," plenary paper, European Public Choice Society Meetings, Tiberias,1996. Austen-Smith,D., "CampaignContributionsand Access,"American Political ScienceReview89 (1995) 566-581 Bagwell, K. and R. Staiger,"The Sensitivity of Strategic and Corrective R&D Policy in Oligopolistic Industries," Journal of International Economics 36 (1994), 133-150. Baldwin, R., "Are Economists' Traditional Trade Policy Views Still Valid?" Journal of Economic Literature30 (1992),804-829. Brander, J., "StrategicTrade Policy," Chapter27 in G. Grossmanand K. Rogoff, eds., Handbook of International Economics, Volume 3 (Amsterdam: Elsevier, 1995). Brander,J. and B. Spencer,"Export Subsidiesand InternationalMarket Shareand Rivalry," Journal of International Economics 19 (1985), 83-100. Boyko, M., A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, "A Theory of Privatization," Economic Joumall06 (1985), 309- 319. Cassing, J. H., "Protectionist Mutual Funds," European Journal of Political Economy 12 (1996), 1-18. Cooper,R. and R. Riezman,"Uncertainty and the Choice of Trade Policy in Oligopolistic Industries," Review ofEconomics Studies56 (1989),129-140. Dick. A..R., "StrategicTrade Policy and Welfare: The Empirical Consequencesof Cross-Ownership," Journal ofInternationalEconomics35 (1993),227-249. Dixit, A.., "Optimal Trade and Industrial Policy for the U.S. Automobile Industry," in R. Feenstra,ed., Empirical Methodsfor International Trade (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1988). Dixit, A. and G. Grossman,"TargetedExport Promotionwith SeveralOligopolistic fudustries,"Journal of InternationalEconomics21 (1986),233-250. 26 Eaton, J. and G. Grossman, "Optimal Trade and Industrial Policy under Oligopoly," Quarterly Journal of Economics 101 (1986),383-406. Reprinted in G. Grossman(1992). Feeney, J. and A. Hillman, "EndogenousTrade Liberalization in the Presenceof Domestic and International AssetMarkets,"Universityof ColoradoWorking Paper,1997. Grossman, G., ed., Imperfect Competition and International Trade (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1992). Grossman, G. and E. Helpman, "Protection for Sale," American Economic Review 84 (1994), 833-50. Hakansson,N., "Portfolio Analysis," in Eatwell, Milgate, and Newman,eds.,TheNew Palgrave: Finance (New York: Norton, 1987),227-237. Hillman, A., The Political Economy of Protection (New York: Harwood Academic Publishers, 1989). Hillman, A. and H. Ursprung,"Domestic Politics, Foreign Interests,and InternationalTrade Policy," AmericanEconomicReview78 (1988),729-745. Hillman, A. and H. Ursprung,'The Political Economyof Trade Liberalizationin the Transition," European Economic Review 40 (1996), 783-794. Horstman, I.J. and J.R. Markusen, "Up the Average Cost Curve: Inefficient Entry and the New Protectionism,"Journal ofInternationalEconomics20 (1986),225-247. Reprintedin J.P.Neary, ed., International Library of Critical Writings in Economics: International Trade (London: Edward Elgar, 1995). Krugman,P., ed., StrategicTradePolicy and the New .InternationalEconomics,(Cambridge:MlT Press, 1986). Lee, S., "InternationalEquity Marketsand Trade Policy," Journal of InternationalEconomics29 (1990), 173-184. Markusen, J.R. and A.J. Venables, "Trade Policy with Increasing Returns and Imperfect Competition: ContradictoryResults from CompetingAssumptions," Journal of International Economics24 (1988),299-316.Reprintedin Grossman(1992). Mayer, W., "Endogenous Tariff Fonnation," American Economic Review 74 (1984), 970-985. 27 Merton, R., "Optimal Portfolio and Consumption Rules in a Continuous-Time Model," Journal of EconomicTheory3 (1971),373-413. Moore,M. and S.M. Suranovic,"Lobbyingand Coumot-Nashcompetition:Implicationsfor strategictrade policy," Journal of International Economics 35 (1993), 367-376. Rodrik, D., "Political Economy of Trade Policy," Chapter 28 in G. Grossman and K. Rogoff, eds., Handbook of International Economics(Amsterdam: Elsevier, 1995). Shivakurnar,R., "Strategic Trade Policy: ChoosingbetweenExport Subsidiesand Export Quotasunder Uncertainty," Journal ofInternational Economics 35 (1993), 169-183. Spencer, B. and loA. Brander, "International R&D Rivalry and Industrial Strategy," Review of Economic Studies50 (1983),707-722. Tesar,L. and I. Werner,"Home Bias and High Turnover," Journal of InternationalMoneyand Finance 14 (1995),467-492. Ursprung,H., "Public Goods, Rent Dissipation,and CandidateCompetition," Economicsand Politics 2 (1990),15-132. 28 Minimum Ownershipof Home Firm for Implementationof StrategicSubsidies 0.8 0.7 0.6 ~ 0.5 ~ .c Cf) § 0.4 E .2 ~ 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 .I 0.00 I 0.10 I I 0.20 I I 0.30 I I 0.40 I I I 0.50 I 0.60 kappa Figure 1 29 I I 0.70 I I 0.80 I I 0.90 I . 1.00