1 DOES THE WELFARE STATE HURT EMPLOYMENT? An earlier version of the paper was presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco, CA, August 2001. For help and suggestions, I am extremely grateful to Peter Hall, Torben Iversen, Fritz Scharpf, David Soskice, and Anne Wren. 2 The question about the adverse impact of taxes on the employment performance of a political economy has emerged as a critical issue on the agenda of policy reform in most European economies. The publication of various policy white papers as well as the introduction of numerous policy changes testify to the importance of this issue in recent years1. For example, both left- and right-wing governments in France have attempted to address the persistent levels of unemployment, by introducing more than 40 policy measures that have lowered the social charges of employers and exempted a number of firms from social security contributions to various branches of the French welfare state2. During recent years, the Belgian and Dutch governments have enacted a number of policies reducing payroll taxes of employers in both the manufacturing and service sector3. The current red-green coalition government in Germany is considering a number of broad reforms in the mode of financing of social insurance – involving a partial shift to taxes that are not employment-based – such as ecological taxes – as well as various 1 For example of these policy debates, see for example, Conseil Supérieur de l’Emploi, ed., 1996, L’allègement des charges sociales sur les bas salaries. Rapport au premier ministre, Paris: La documentation française; European Commission, ed., 1995, Employment in Europe, Bruxelles: European Commission. 2 For an overview of these policy developments, see Bourguignon, François and Bureau, Dominique, ed., 1999, L’architecture des prélèvements en France: Etat des lieux et voies de réforme, Paris: La Documentation Française; De Foucauld, Jean-Baptiste, 1995, Le Financement de la Protection Sociale, Paris: La Documentation Française; Dehez, Pierre and Fitoussi, Jean-Paul, 1992, Revenu minimum, allocations-chomage et subventions a l’emploi: un modèle macroéconomique simple, Document de travail Nr. 92-07, Observatoire Français de Conjonctures Economiques, Paris: OFCE.; Piketty, Thomas, 1998 L’impact des incitations financiers au travail sur les comportements individuals: une estimation pour le cas français, Economie et Prévision, Nr. 132- 133, pp. 1- 35; Assouline, Mireille, et. al., 1998, L’impact macro-économique d’une baisse des cotisations sur les bas salaries, Travail et emploi, Nr. 73, pp. 41- 65. 3 See Investing in People and Jobs: Belgium’s 1999 Action Plan prepared in accordance with European Employment Guidelines and The Netherlands’ National Employment Action Plan, 1999, Brussels: European Commission. 3 proposals to direct fiscal transfers to low-earning employees and exempt employers from social security contributions4. Finally, tax reforms (in exchange for wage restraint) are an important issue on the agenda of new ‘social pacts’ in Europe.5 Most of these reforms respond to a growing political perception that the high levels of income and payroll taxes are one of the general causes of economic malaise experienced by European economies during recent decades. As Fritz Scharpf concludes in a recent study, “a considerable range of perfectly decent jobs, which in the absence of payroll taxes would be commercially viable, are eliminated from the private labor market of continental welfare states”.6 During recent years, many social democratic governments have begun to share the policy diagnosis that high non-wage labor costs are inimical to employment expansion and overall economic competitiveness7. This stands in sharp discontinuity to traditional social democratic economic policy, which has attempted to reconcile full employment and a redistributive welfare state. 4 On these policy debates in the German context, see, for example, Schelkle, Waltraud, 2000, Subsidizing low earnings. German Debates and US Experiences, Vierteljahresheft für Wirtschaftsforschung, 69, 1, 116; Bofinger, Peter, Fasshauer, Stephan, 1998, Reduzierung der Sozialabgaben statt Kombilohn, Wirtschaftsdienst, 78, 9, 519- 528; Wanger, Gert, 1999, Soziale Sicherung im Spannungsfeld von Demokratie und Arbeitsmarkt, in Nübler, Irmgard, Trabold, Harald, eds., Herausforderungen an die Wirtschaftspolitik an der Schwelle zum 21. Jahrhundert, Berlin: Sigma, pp. 77- 91. 5 On the development of these new social pacts, see Regini, Marino. 2000. Between Deregulation and Social Pacts: The Responses of European Economies to Globalization, Politics and Society, 28: 1, pp. 533; Fajertag, Giuseppe and Pochet, Philip, eds., Social Pacts in Europe, Brussels: European Trade Union Institute; Hassel, Anke, 1999. Bündnisse für Arbeit: Nationale Handlungsfähigkeit im europäischen Regimewettbewerb, Discussion Paper, Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies, Cologne. 6 See Scharpf, Fritz. 1999. Governing in Europe. How effective? How Democratic? Oxford: Oxford University Press, p. 142; see also Scharpf, Fritz. 1997. Employment and the Welfare State: A Continental Dilemma, Discussion Paper: Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies, Koln. 7 For the importance of policy considerations pertaining to the financing of social insurance for current social democratic governments, see for example, Julian Le Grand, 1999, New Approaches to the Welfare State, in Gamble, Andrew and Wright, Tony, eds., 1999, The New Social Democracy, Oxford: Blackwell Publishers, pp. 142- 150. 4 The goal of this paper is to provide a theoretical framework modeling the employment consequences of the growth of the welfare state. The analysis seeks to uncover the key institutional and political variables affecting the sensitivity of employment to taxation. What is the effect of the growth of taxes and social policy commitments on the employment performance of various political economies? Does it vary across countries – in other words, do salient cross-national institutional differences, such as differences in labor market institutions – affect the magnitude of the impact of taxes on employment? What is the importance of the economic choices made by unions, in this new political context of heightened austerity and retrenchment? To analyze these policy questions, this paper will develop a model exploring the impact of the growth of the welfare state on the wage demands of trade unions and on the level of unemployment in different economies. The results of the model can be summarized as follows. By explicitly modeling unions concern for social policy, I show how the optimal strategy of trade unions is to deliver wage restraint in exchange for social policy expansion (given a particular mix of social policy transfers and services). This proposition formalizes an insight of many corporatist studies that have highlighted the crucial role played by incomes policies in sustaining the simultaneous pursuit of welfare state expansion and employment expansion during the golden age period8. Moreover, I show how the structure of labor market institutions – more specifically the level of centralization of the wage bargaining authority – affects the magnitude of the 8 For a formulation of these arguments, see Cameron, David, 1984, Social Democracy, Corporatism and the representation of economic interests in advanced capitalist societies, in John H. Goldthorpe, ed., Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism, New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 143- 178; EspingAndersen, Gosta. 1990, Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, Princeton: Princeton University Press, (Chapter 5: Distribution Regimes in the power structure), pp. 105- 143; for a recent comprehensive overview of these themes see Hicks, Alexander. 1999. Social Democracy and Welfare Capitalism. A century of income security politics, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. 5 employment effects resulting from the wage restraint of trade unions. Building on the theoretical propositions advanced by Calmfors and Driffill and further refined by other scholars of corporatism, the model predicts a parabolic relationship between the level of centralization of the wage bargaining authority and the level of unemployment. Thus, economies with institutions of wage bargaining centralized at the sectoral-level have the worst employment performance. Next, I show how demographic and fiscal developments have strained this political exchange, undermining the ability of trade unions to deliver wage restraint. A series of developments that characterize the economic climate of two recent decades – such as population aging and the rise in the number of labor market outsiders – have contributed to a rise in the level of taxes. These developments have simultaneously raised the costs of social policy to unions (and employers) and have also reduced the share of social policy benefits received by union members, weakening thus the ability of unions to deliver wage restraint. Thus, while welfare states have become more overburdened, the ability of trade unions to deliver the wage restraint necessary to restore high levels of employment has declined. The model suggests that the process of welfare state maturation has undermined the political exchange between unions and governments premised on wage moderation in exchange for social policy expansion. Thus, while welfare state expansion and the pursuit of full employment were compatible policy goals during the first decades of the postwar period, demographic and fiscal developments have undermined this policy compatibility. This article is divided into three sections. The following section situates the analysis developed in this paper within recent theoretical debates in the study of advanced industrialized economies. Section 3 develops a model of the employment 6 consequences of the welfare state. In section 4, I test the main implications of the model using OECD data for the period 1960- 1995. A final section of the paper discusses implications of the model for future research on labor market developments in advanced industrialized economies. 2. MODELS OF WAGE BARGAINING, MACROECONOMIC POLICY AND THE WELFARE STATE: TOWARDS A NEW THEORETICAL SYNTHESIS. The model developed in this paper builds on recent theoretical developments in the study of economic policy-making in advanced industrialized democracies. This section will briefly review the main theoretical and empirical findings of this new research agenda and will situate the contribution of this paper within the existing literature9. I also seek to demonstrate that, while existing models have been rather successful in explaining the impact of existing institutions on cross-national differences in the level of unemployment, they have been less successful in explaining temporal changes in the level of unemployment in different political economies. The building block for my analysis is the influential economic model studying the relationship between wage bargaining institutions and macroeconomic performance developed by Lars Calmfors and John Drifill10. Building on Mancur Olson’s theory of 9 For similar comprehensive reviews of these recent theoretical developments, see Thelen, Kathleen. 2000. New Directions in the study of labor in the advanced industrial countries, Draft Paper for the APSA project on the ‘State of the Discipline’ edited by Ira Katznelson and Helen Milner, Hall, Peter and Soskice, David., An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism, in Hall, Peter and Soskice, David, Varieties of Capitalism: The Foundations of Comparative Institutional Advantage, Oxford: Oxford University Press. 7 collective action, Calmfors and Drifill’s model posits a “hump-shaped” relationship between the centralization of wage bargaining and the level of unemployment. This “hump-shaped” relationship is the consequence of two effects: the monopoly effect (resulting from an increase in union power) and the ability of large wage setters to internalize some of the negative labor market consequences of their wage demands. According to Calmfors and Drifill, when labor markets are extremely decentralized, individual companies compete in product markets which are characterized by a high elasticity of substitution among goods. In these environments, the trade-off between unemployment and wage increases faced by trade unions is extremely steep, as a wage settlements that exceeds the wage-rate paid by a competitor within the same industry contribute to a steep employment decline of a firm. The consequence is a high level of wage restraint and a low level of unemployment in economies in which wage bargaining takes place at the firm level (decentralized labor markets). An increase in the level of centralization of wage bargaining system – which generally takes the form of an increase in intra-sectoral centralization of wage bargaining – is associated with a decline in the elasticity of substitution of among the goods produced by the firms that are subject to unified wage demands of trade unions. This economic and institutional environment increases the incentives of trade unions for wage militancy. Calmfors and Driffill posit that the level of wage militancy is higher in economies with intermediate-level centralization of wage bargaining as compared to economies with decentralized labor markets. However, if a further increase in the level of centralization of wage bargaining – from industry-level to economy-level centralization—creates incentives for trade unions 10 Calmfors, Lars and Driffill, John. 1988. Bargaining structure, corporatism and economic performance. Economic Policy, 6, 1, 14-61. 8 to “internalize” some of the consequences of militancy. Thus, Calmfors and Driffill predict wage moderation and lower levels of unemployment in economies with highly centralized institutions of wage bargaining compared to intermediately-centralized wage bargaining systems. Figure 1 presents the relationship between the structure of labor market institutions and the level of unemployment hypothesized by the Calmfors and Drifill model. FIGURE 1 During recent years, a number of studies have developed a theoretical and empirical challenge of this model11. These studies critique the Calmfors and Drifill model for failing to take into account the importance of monetary policy in the determination of the level of inflation and unemployment. In a number of papers, David Soskice and Torben Iversen have returned to the original question about the impact of labor market centralization on unemployment posed by the Calmfors and Drifill model. Soskice and Iversen depart from Calmfors and Driffill by introducing an additional parameter modeling the degree of ‘accommodation’ of a monetary policy. Monetary accommodation is defined as the overall responsiveness of the government to the 11 For representative examples of research that attempt to model the interaction between the corporatist literature on wage bargaining and the literature on macroeconomic policy, see Scharpf, Fritz. 1991. Crisis and Choice in European Social Democracy, Ithaca: Cornell University Press; Hall, Peter A. and Franzese, Robert. 1998. Mixed Signals: Central Bank Independence, Coordinated Wage Bargaining and European Monetary Union, International Organization, 52, 3, 505- 535; Iversen, Torben, 1998, Wage Bargaining, Central Bank Independence and the Real Effects of Money, International Organization, 52, 3, 469- 504; Iversen, Torben, 1999. Contested Economic Institutions: The Politics of Macroeconomics and Wage Bargaining in Advanced Democracies, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; Soskice, David and Iversen, Torben. 2000. the non-neutrality of money with large price or wage setters, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 1, 1-20. 9 increases in the aggregate price level. In the Soskice and Iversen framework, a central bank that is completely accommodating sets the real money supply equal to the price level, whereas in the case of a totally ‘non-accomodating’ monetary policy, the money supply is entirely independent of changes in the prices level. The important finding of the Iversen and Soskice model is that in nonatomistic labor markets, monetary policy has a real impact on unemployment. Moreover, they show that the impact of monetary policy on unemployment is conditional upon the centralization of the wage bargaining system. The predictions for cross-national differences in the level of unemployment of the Soskice and Iversen model are in agreement with the Calmfors and Driffill model only for the case of an ‘accomodating’ macroeconomic policy regime. In this case, both models predict that the employment performance of economies characterized by intermediately centralized wage bargaining systems is inferior to the performance of economies in which wage bargaining is either extremely centralized or extremely decentralized. The predictions differ, however, in the case of a ‘non-accomodating’ macroeconomic policy. Soskice and Iversen argue that a ‘non-accomodating’ monetary policy can in part deter some of the wage militancy of trade unions. As Iversen argues, “if the monetary authority is non-accomodating, higher wages can no longer be externalized to the same extent and this will deter militant union behaviour. The collective action problem facing unions in intermediately centralized systems – which can lead to excessive wage demands and unemployment – is thus ‘solved’ (or at least dissipated) by an agent that is deliberately non-accomodating to union objectives. This crucial (and perhaps surprising) result is overlooked in all existing models of union behaviour (such as Calmfors and Driffill’s application of Olson’s theory) 10 because they fail to consider the conditioning effects of monetary policies on interunion interactions”12. [SEE FIGURE 2] Figure 2 summarizes the predictions about cross-national variation in the employment performance of European economies of various specifications of the Soskice and Iversen model. Common to all different specifications of the model is that the change in the macroeconomic policy orientation from monetary ‘accommodation’ to monetary ‘non-accommodation’ results in a decline in the level of unemployment. Iversen and Soskice (2000) predict that the increase in the centralization of wage bargaining should enhance the positive employment effects of monetary non-accomodation13. Thus, the lowest levels of unemployment should be encountered in economies in which the monetary policy regime is non-accommodating and the wage-bargaining system is highly centralized. In Contested Economic Institutions, Iversen introduces an additional assumption about unions’ concerns for wage equality14. Iversen argues that these 12 Iversen, Torben, 1998, op. cit., pp. 48- 49. 13 See Soskice, David and Iversen, Torben. 2000. The Nonneutrality of Monetary Policy with large price or wage setters, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 265- 284. 14 More specifically, Iversen assumes that the objective function of trade unions can be written as − U i = α ( wi − π ) − (1 − α )U i U − β (r i − r e ) 2 . Iversen, 1999, op. cit., pp. 38- 39. In this equation, wi denotes the percentage nominal wage increase, π the percentage increase in consumer prices, U i is the − i unemployment rate among the trade union members in sector i , U is the average unemployment rate, r is e the ideally sought wage ratio between low-wage and high wage workers and r is the actual wage ratio expected from a particular wage settlement. The parameters α and β denote the weights attached by trade unions to different policy objectives, such as the objective of an increase in the level of real wages (first 11 concerns for wage equality have a negative impact on employment in economies with highly centralized systems of wage bargaining. This is graphically represented in Figure 2 by the upward slope of the predicted employment for the case of the nonaccommodating monetary policy. The most striking aspect about the empirical predictions of Iversen’s model is the fact that it is totally at odds with the recent employment trends in European economies. Two implications of the model seem to be contradicted by recent labor market developments. First, the model seems unable to predict why unemployment has risen so dramatically in Europe during the recent two decades. Between 1960 and 1975, the average-level of European unemployment was 2.6 percent. Average unemployment rose to 8 percent between 1976 and 1995. However, the empirical predictions of the Iversen model go in the opposite direction! Since the increase in monetary non-accomodation shifts the curve predicting unemployment downwards, European unemployment should have declined between 1975 and 1995. Secondly, Iversen’s model remains unable to account for cross-national differences in the employment performance of European economies under conditions of monetary non-accomodation. While the model predicts that economies with highly centralized institutions of wage bargaining (Scandinavia) should perform worse than economies with sectoral-level wage bargaining (Belgium, Netherlands, Germany), the data suggest the opposite. For the period between 1976 and 1995, average unemployment rates in Scandinavian economies were 4.8 %, but 9.4 % in countries of the European community. If anything, these empirical data seem to confirm term of the utility) and the objective of wage equality (third term). This specification of the objective function of trade unions implies that unions’ utility will increase as the level of real wages ( wi − π ) increases, but that it will decline as the level of unemployment increases. Furthermore, an increase in differences between the “anticipated” and de facto level of wage incquality ( r − r ) also leads to a decline in the utility of unions. Ibid., p. 39. i e 12 the original Calmfors and Drifill hypothesis about the “hump-shaped” relationship between centralization of wage bargaining and unemployment. This suggests that additional economic and political factors (that were not included in the analysis of Iversen and Soskice) counteracted the employment effects of an increase in monetary non-accommodation. The model developed in this paper suggests that the steady rise in the level of payroll and income taxes can account for the deterioration in the employment performance of European political economies during the last two decades. The growth in the level of taxes has been the consequence of two developments. First, both demographic developments (such as population aging) and labor market changes (such as the development of early retirement policies) have increased the share in the population receiving social policy transfers, worsening the employment-dependency ratio of many European systems of social protection. Secondly, the explicit commitment to deficit reduction by many European governments during recent years has shifted a larger part of the burden of financing existing welfare state commitments to the tax system. Thus, to understand the recent steady rise of unemployment, we need to bring in the welfare state into existing models of macroecomic policy-making and explore the employment consequences of different systems of social protection. Both the Calmfors and Drifill model and the Soskice and Iversen framework serve as the building blocks of the analysis developed in this paper. I build in additional complexity to these models, by incorporating institutional and policy characteristics of the welfare state into the analysis. More specifically, I focus on differences in the mode of financing different welfare state commitments and on differences in the structure of 13 social policy benefits (the mix between social policy transfers and social services). This allows me to examine cross-national variation in the impact of the growth of the size of the welfare state on the level of employment in different political economies and to study the interaction between different labor market arrangements and different social policy arrangements. 3. THE MODEL This paper will use the standard set-up of the of the Calmfors and Drifill model15 and will also incorporate the differences in the monetary policy regime modeled by Iversen and Soskice. The game has the following policy stages. Governments choose the level of taxes (τ ), the level of deficit ( D ), and the macroeconomic policy orientation of an economy ( β ). Unions move next, announcing their wage demands. In contrast to the existing models of wage bargaining, I will assume that social policies are a crucial objective for trade unions (see below on the details of how social policy demands enter the utility of trade unions). Employers move next. After accepting the wage demands of trade unions, employers will choose the level of prices for the products in their sector. In a final stage of the game consumers will determine demand, based on the level of prices and on the elasticity of substitution among goods. In equilibrium, the level of demand will determine the level of employment of the economy. 15 For an analysis of similar questions, using a Nash bargaining framework, see Isabela Mares. 1999. Payroll taxes and unemployment, Paper Presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington DC. 14 The economy consists of I sectors, with J firms in each sector. The model assumes there are N unions in the economy. Denoting by n the total labor force, the number of members in each union is n , in other words the assumption is that either the N entire workforce is fully unionized or that unions’ contracts are binding even for those workers that are not union members. (This assumption is standard in the literature and follows Calmfors and Driffill). The cross-national variation in the institutional set-up of the wage bargaining system is modeled as a variation in the level of centralization of the bargaining authority. Building on the Calmfors and Driffill model, I introduce a distinction between decentralized, intermediately centralized and fully centralized wage bargaining systems. The above parameters I (the number of sectors) and J (the number of firms in each sector) distinguish among these cases as follows. The case of a totally decentralized political economy can be characterized as an economy in which both I and J are high. An intra-sectoral centralization of wage bargaining can be modeled as a decline in J. Thus in economies with intermediate centralization, wage determination is in the hands of sectoral-level trade unions. Finally, in an economy with national-level institutions of wage bargaining, both J and I take very low values. The limit case of this process of inter-sectoral centralization of wage bargaining is the case in which one union determines the level of wages of all firms in the economy. This distinction between intrasectoral and inter-sectoral centralization of the institutions of wage bargaining will allow me to model more systematically the mechanisms by which wages determined in one sector affect the level of employment in other sectors. FIGURE 3 15 I will assume a linear technology, i.e. xij = αaij (1) Throughout this paper, the double index ij denotes the j-th firm in sector i. In equation 1, xij denotes the demand for goods produced by firm j in sector i , aij is the level of employment of firm j in sector i and α is a productivity factor, assumed to be constant across all sectors. I will make the standard microeconomic assumption that consumers have a twolevel constant-elasticity of substitution (CES) utility function. [Mas Colell, Chapter 3]. In other words, I J i =1 j =1 σ −1 σ ρ −1 ρ σ −1 ρ ρ −1 σ ij U = (∑ (∑ x C ) ) (2) In equation 2, xij denotes the consumption of good ij . σ denotes the elasticity of substitution among goods created within one sector (assumed to be the same for all sectors). In contrast, ρ is the elasticity of substitution among sectors. A very natural assumption is that σ > ρ , in other words goods produced in one sector are closer substitutes to each other than goods produced in different sectors. To have a well-posed maximization problem for the firms, I will assume that σ , ρ > 1 . Consumers’ utility 16 function is constructed through a two-step aggregation process: first, goods produced in sector i are combined into a CES basket in the form J (∑ xij σ −1 σ σ ) σ −1 j =1 This consumption basket can be thought of as an “aggregate” or “synthetic” good produced in sector i . At a second stage, these “aggregate” goods produced by each sector are combined into a basked according to the CES rule. Consumers maximize their utility, U C subject to the budget constraint I J ∑∑ p x i =1 j =1 ij ij =E (3), where pij is the price of good j in sector i and E is the “total spending” in the economy. When choosing the level of prices for the goods produced in their sector, employers will maximize total revenue minus labor costs. Equation 4 below represents the utility of employers, U iE U iE = pi xi − wi (1 + τ E )ai (4) In this equation, pi and xi denote the prices and demand, respectively, for the good produced in sector i , wi are the total wages paid by employers and ai is the level of employment in this sector. Given equation 1, the level of employment is found by 17 dividing the demand for the goods in this sector by the productivity factor, i.e. aij = xij . α The model makes the following assumptions about the structure of taxes that are necessary to finance social policy transfers and services. Social policy expenditures are financed by two broad categories of revenues, income taxes (paid by union members) and payroll taxes (paid by unions and employers). The model does not take into account the importance of corporate taxes. The empirical justification for this assumption is the modest role played by corporate taxes in the financing of social policy expenditures in OECD countries. I will further assume that the ratio of payroll taxes paid by capital and labor is fixed and that the share of payroll taxes financed by unions and employers is ½ of the level of payroll taxes. Summarizing these assumptions and denoting by τ P the payroll taxes, τ I the income taxes and τ U and τ E the total share of taxes paid by unions and employers, respectively, equation 5 expresses the assumptions of the model about the distribution of the burden of financing the welfare state among capital and labor. τE = τP 2 τU = τ i + τP 2 (5) Before analyzing the maximization problem faced by trade unions, it is important to lay out the assumptions about the structure of social policy benefits made in this model. Building on an important distinction introduced by the comparative literature on social protection, the model distinguishes among “social services” such as education, publicly provided child-care and “social transfers” – which include unemployment benefits, pensions and disability benefits. The parameter S denotes the level of services 18 financed by the government. To simplify computations, I will assume that the level of generosity is the same across all major welfare state transfer programs and I will denote this generosity by b. Roughly, we can divide the population of an economy in two major groups: workers that are currently employed or seeking employment and the “inactive” population. Let n denote union members that are currently employed or that are seeking employment. In contrast, the parameter m will denote the non-active share of the population. This part of the population – which is sizeable in many European economies – comprises in addition to pensioners, early retirees and women who choose not to enter the labor market. The total population is thus m + n, the active labor force rate is n . m+n The parameter π denotes the “dependency ratio” of the economy (and will be used in the presentation of some of the comparative statics results of the analysis). Thus, π = m . n Summarizing the above discussion, equation 6 expresses the budget constraint equation determining the balance between total social policy expenditures and taxreceipts. The left-hand side of this equation comprises the three main categories of welfare state expenditures, transfers to the non-active population (bm) unemployment benefits to union members that are out-of work and social services. These expenditures can be financed either through a deficit (denoted by D) or through taxes. I J bm + b∑∑ ( i =1 j =1 I J n − aij ) + S = (τ U + τ E )∑∑ aij wij + D N i =1 j =1 (6) 19 We can now finally characterize the utility function of trade unions. In contrast to the existing economic literature on wage bargaining, I will assume that social policy considerations play an important role in the overall demands of trade unions. The model thus, formalizes an important observation of political scientists and sociologists. According to these studies, at the basis of the expansion of most welfare states in advanced industrialized democracies was a political exchange between unions and governments, in which unions exercised wage restraint in exchange for the expansion of social policy programs. To model this political exchange, I will assume that the objective function of trade union comprises not only wages but also social policy transfers to union members as well as social services (S). In this model, the level of publicly provided social services is endogenously determined. I will assume that in equation 6, the level of services (S) is I J chosen after the existing transfers to union members ( b∑∑ ( i =1 j =1 n − aij ) and to the nonN active population are financed. Another reformulation of this assumption is that passive social policy expenditures are “already committed”, due to their entitlement-based character, while services are more ‘discretionary’ in nature. I assume that services are divided equally among all members of the population. Given that each union has a total of n members and that the total size of the population is m+n, it follows that the social N services received by the individual union are 1 n S . This implies that the ability of IJ n + m trade unions to internalize the provision of services and collectively exercise wage restraint is influenced by the degree of centralization of the labor movement (IJ) and by 20 the share of active labor force participants of the total population. The higher the number of trade unions in the economy (N) and the higher the share of the population (m) receiving social policy transfers (c), the lower is the ability of trade unions to internalize the provision of services. Equation 7 expresses the utility of trade unions. As discussed above, the key assumption of this model is that there are three broad objectives that enter the calculation of the trade unions: the net (i.e. after tax) level of wages, the passive transfers for union members and the level of public services available to union members. U ijU = (1 − τ U ) wij aij + 14243 NET .WAGES n ( − aij )b IJ4243 1 TRANFERS .TO .UNION . MEMBERS + 1 n S + IJ m n 14243 (7) SOCIAL. SERVICES Since unions care about the real level of wages and social policy benefits, it is important to divide the net utility derived by union members by the aggregate price level in the economy. Following Soskice and Iversen, I will assume that the aggregate price level of the economy is a function of the degree of the accommodation of the monetary authority16. Let the parameter β denote the level of monetary non-accommodation. The parameter β takes values between 0 and 1. In the case of a totally non-accomodating monetary regime, β = 1 ; β decreases as the level of ‘monetary non-accommodation’ 16 I follow both the assumption of Iversen and Soskice 1999, p. 5. To make the comparison of the results easier, I use the same notation. 21 decreases17. Dividing by the aggregate price level of the economy, the utility of trade unions becomes U ijU = (1 − τ U ) wij aij Pβ n 1 n − aij )b S n + IJ β + IJ m + P Pβ ( (7*) From equation 6 (the tax balance equation), we can derive the level of services available in the economy as I J I J S = (τ U + τ E )∑∑ aij wij + b∑∑ aij − b(m + n) + D i =1 j =1 (8). i =1 j =1 We are now ready to find the solutions to this game. Given the assumption about the utility of the consumers made in equation 2, the aggregate price-level of the economy can be defined as the weighted average of the prices of sectors i. Thus, if the price-level in sector i is 1− β Iversen and Soskice reformulate this assumption as follows. Assume M = P where M is the nominal money supply, P is the aggregate price level and β is the parameter measuring the degree to which the Central Bank follows a non-accomodating policy rule. “If the central bank it completely accommodating, the Central Bank fixes the real money supply by setting M equal to the price level, whereas if the central bank is completely non-accommodating, it fixes the nominal money supply and sets M equal to unity”. Ibid., p. 5. In other words, in the case of nonaccomodating monetary policy ( β = 1 ), the money supply is independent of the price level, while in the case of accommodating monetary policy ( β = 0 ), the money supply is set equal to the price level. 17 22 1 J Pi = (∑ pij1−σ )1−σ j =1 the aggregate price-level of the economy becomes I 1 1− ρ 1− ρ P = (∑ Pi ) (9) i =1 It follows, that the optimal choices of consumers are xij = E Pi − ρ pij −σ ( ) ( ) NP P Pi (10) Substituting equation 9 into the utility function of employers, maximization with respect to pi yields pij = σ (1 + τ E ) wij (σ − 1)α (11) By substituting equation 10 into equation 8, we can determine the price-level in the economy and the level of demand for the goods produced by firm j in sector i . 1 P= σ (1 + τ E ) I J (∑∑ wij1−σ )1−σ (σ − 1)α i =1 j =1 (12) 23 E (σ − 1)α xij = σ (1 + τ E ) wij−σ I J ∑∑ w (13) 1−σ ij i =1 j =1 Since the level of employment for firm j in sector i is equal to E (σ − 1) aij = σ (1 + τ E ) wij−σ I J ∑∑ w i =1 j =1 xij , it follows that α (14) 1−σ ij We are now ready to compute the optimal wage demands of trade unions. After rearranging terms, the utility of the trade union setting wages in sector i becomes U iU = 1 n 1 n [(1 − τ U )aij wij + ( − ai )b + S] β P IJ IJ m + n (15) Since the wage demands of trade unions are conditional upon the level of services provided by the government, we need to substitute equation 6 (which express the level of services provided by the government) into equation 15. As a result of this substitution (and after rearranging some terms), unions’ utility becomes: 24 U ijU = + 1 1 n 1 n [(1 − τ U + (τ U + τ E ))aij wij + (−b + b )aij β P IJ m + n IJ m + n 1 n 1 n 1 n (τ U + τ E ) ∑ akl wkl + b ak , + D] ∑ IJ m + n IJ m + n k ,l ≠i , j IJ m + n k ,l ≠i , j The ratio (16) n can be expressed in terms of the dependency ratio π as m+n n 1 = , so the utility function can be rewritten as m + n 1+π U ijU = + 1 1 1 1 1 [(1 − τ U + (τ U + τ E )aij wij + (−b + b )aij + β P IJ 1 + π IJ 1 + π 1 1 IJ 1 + π ∑a k ,l ≠ i , j kl wkl + b 1 1 IJ 1 + π ∑a k ,l ≠i , j kl + 1 1 D IJ 1 + π (16’) The next step is to maximize 15 with respect to the wage demands wij . For reasons of analytical tractability, I will restrict to symmetric equilibria, i.e. equilibria in which w1∗ = w2∗ = ... = wN∗ = w SYM . The complete derivation of the equilibrium wage is presented in the appendix. After a series of computations, we obtain Proposition 1: In a symmetric equilibrium, the total level of employment is given by 25 * a SYM = E (σ − 1) bσ π 1−τU 1 1 D σ ] + (β + ) 1+ π 1+τ E 1+ π. IJ E σ − 1 π I ( J − 1)σ + ( I − 1) ρ + (1 + β ) 1+π. [ I ( J − 1)σ − J ) + ( I − 1) ρ + 1 + β (17). The optimal wage demand of trade unions is given by * wSYM =b I ( J − 1)σ + ( I − 1) ρ + (1 + β ) [ I (( J − 1)σ − J ) + ( I − 1) ρ + 1 + β π 1+π π 1 D σ 1+τE ](1 − τ U ) + ( β + ) IJ E σ − 1 1 + π 1+π (18) Before exploring the implications of the results, it is important to go back to the assumption by which this model differs from existing models of wage bargaining. The main difference lies in the assumption about the utility of trade unions. Existing models assume that unions care about wages (Iversen and Soskice)18 or wages and unemployment benefits for union members that are out-of-work (Calmfors and Driffill). In contrast, this paper assumes that social policy considerations are an important component of the utility of trade unions. Thus, in addition to wages and social policy benefits for their members, the objective function of trade unions used in this model comprises a third component – denoting unions’ concern for social policy. More formally, the difference between this model and the Calmfors and Drifill model can be 18 α α For example, Iversen and Soskice assume that the union in sector i is U i = wi ⋅ ei , where wi is the average wage for the union members in this sector and ei is the employment rate in sector i . See Iversen and Soskice, 1999, Monetary Integration, Partisanship and Macroeconomic Policy, Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the APSA, p. 7. 26 written as follows. The utility of a trade union which cares only about wages and unemployment benefits can be written as: U ij = ( (1 − τ U ) wij P β +( n − aij IJP β )b In contrast, this paper assumes that (1 − τ U ) wij aij + U ijU = ( P β44 1442 3 NET .WAGES n − aij ( )b β IJP 14 24 3 TRANFERS .TO .UNION . MEMBERS + 1 n S β IJ 42 m + n43 P 1 4 4 SOCIAL. SERVICES How does this additional assumption about the utility of trade unions affect the predictions about the level of unemployment? To answer this question, we need to study the impact of the additional term in the utility of trade unions on wages (and then employment). We begin by rewriting the utility of unions (after substituting the “social services component” of the utility function) U ij = (1 − τ U )aij wij − baij β 1444P 2444 3 U1 + I J I J 1 n 1 [( a w )] + b aij + D ∑∑ ij ij ∑∑ IJ m + n P β i =1 j =1 i =1 j =1 1444444442444444443 U2 27 In the equation above, I have decomposed the utility of trade unions into “wages and unemployment benefits) (U 1 ) and “benefits derived from the public provision of social services” (U 2 )19. We can show that Proposition 2: dU 2 < 0 . The wage demands of unions that internalize concerns dwi about the provision of social services are lower than the wage demands of unions that care only about the real wages and unemployment benefits of their members. The result formalizes an observation of the “neo-corporatist” literature, which has argued that an important political exchange between unions and governments has underpinned welfare state expansion during the first decades of the postwar period20. In exchange for the expansion of social programs (the expansion of the social wage), unions delivered wage restraint. The institutional structure of the wage bargaining system affects the employment consequences of this collective wage restraint: the employment is highest in economies with the most centralized levels of wage bargaining. ( dU 2SYM dw1 increases as N decreases). Note also that in the limit case of extremely decentralized labor markets (if N is very large) unions’ preoccupation with social policy has no impact on the equilibrium level of employment. In this case, the Calmfors Driffill model and the 19 Strictly speaking, benefits from income are U 1 + public provision of social services are U 2 − 20 nb , while the benefits derived by the union from the NP nb . NP For a formulation of these arguments by ‘corporatist scholars’, see footnote XX. 28 model of this paper yield the same predictions for the equilibrium level of employment. Summarizing these results, Figure 4 contrasts the employment predictions of this model and Camlfors and Driffill. [FIGURE 4] We are now ready to explore some of the implications of the equilibrium results of proposition 1. Why has the employment performance of European economies deteriorated so strongly during recent decades? What factors explain cross-national variation in the levels of unemployment? To answer these questions, we will study the impact on employment of the various parameters of the model: the structure of labor market institutions (centralization of wage bargaining authority), the macro-economic policy orientation of a government and the structure of welfare state commitments. We can further disaggregate the latter term and explore the effects of (a) a rise in the level of taxes, (b) an increase in the number of pensioners and (c) a commitment to deficit reduction and fiscal austerity. The model yields the following comparative statics results: Proposition 3: da * < 0 . Inter-sectoral centralization of wage bargaining promotes wage (a) dI restraint and higher employment. 29 da * < 0 . An increase in the level of taxes hurts employment. (b) ∂τ (c) da * < 0 . An increase in the number of labor market outsiders hurts dπ employment. (d) da * > 0 An increase in deficit spending contributes to higher employment. dD (e) da * > 0 . An increase in monetary non-accommodation promotes dβ employment. Proposition 3 identifies several causes accounting for the deterioration of the employment performance of European economies. In this model, the rise in the level of unemployment is a consequence of the inability of trade unions to deliver wage restraint, given a social policy mix characterized by high taxes and high level of social policy expenditures devoted to labor market outsiders. In other words, the process of welfare state maturation gradually undermines the political exchange among trade unions based on wage restraint in exchange for social policy expansion. To explore how changes in the size and the policy mix of the welfare state contribute to an increase in the real wage demands of trade unions consider again the budget constraint equation (equation 6) and the equation specifying the utility of trade unions (equation 7). Let me begin by exploring the simultaneous impact of worsening demographic developments and of an increase in the size of labor market outsiders. Both developments are modeled as an increase in the parameter m and, thus, to an increase in the first term of equation 6 (which denotes passive welfare state expenditures). Assume at first that the government does not 30 counterbalance this increase in expenditures by an increase in the level of taxes or an increase in deficits. The consequence of an increase in social policy commitments devoted to labor market outsiders is a decline in the level of social policy expenditures devoted to the public provision of social services. In other words, a mix in the composition of social policy commitments takes place. According to equation 7, this decline in the level of publicly provided social services contributes to a reduction in the term U 2 in the utility of trade unions and thus to an increase in the real wage demands of trade unions. Let us also examine the impact of changes affecting the level of taxes and in the mode of financing of welfare state commitments. If the government holds the level of social policy expenditures constant, a reduction in the level of deficit will lead to an increase in the level of taxes. Moving to equation 7, we see that higher taxes reduce the net wages of union members. Thus, given higher levels of taxes, the rational strategy of trade unions is to demand higher levels of wages. This implies that the growth in the level of tax burden necessary to finance existing social policy commitments undermines the ability of trade unions to deliver wage restrain, leading to a rise in the level of unemployment. The virtuous cycle between wage restraint and commitment to social policy expansion is more difficult to sustain in “mature” welfare states. FIGURE 5 The above analysis explains the downward shift in the equilibrium level of employment represented in Figure 5. These factors account for the steady deterioration of 31 the employment performance of European economies between the “Golden Age’ period and recent decades21. The analysis generates a number of predictions about cross-national differences in the level of employment, given similar level of taxes, deficits and policy mixes of transfers and social services. Here the model predicts that the level of structure of labor market institutions continues to exert a positive impact on the equilibrium level of employment. The model implies that intra-sectoral centralization of wage bargaining continues to exert a positive impact on the level of employment ( da * < 0 ). Holding all dI other parameters of the model constant, employment in economies with highly centralized institutions of wage bargaining will be significantly higher than employment in economies with industry-level centralization of wage bargaining. As in the Calmfors Driffill model, the Olsonian logic accounts for this result: large and encompassing trade union associations are better able to internalize some of the consequences of wage militancy and exercise wage restraint. 4. A CROSS-NATIONAL ANALYSIS The model developed in this paper yields implications about cross-national and temporal differences in the employment performance of advanced industrialized economies. I now turn to a test of the macro-level hypotheses for unemployment, using 21 Note that an increase in the level of monetary nonaccomodation contributes to an increase in employment, i.e. da * > 0 . This finding is consistent with Iversen and Soskice (1999, 2000). dβ 32 time-series data for 14 OECD economies, covering the period between 1960-199522. In related papers, I test the implications of the model for the strategic behavior and wage demands of trade unions. One of the critical results of the paper suggests that the magnitude of the impact of the tax burden on the level of unemployment depends on the structure of the wage bargaining system. The predictions of the model, summarized in Figure 5 imply a parabolic relationship between the level of centralization of the wage bargaining authority and the level of unemployment. In other words, the structure of corporatist institutions of wage bargaining has a decisive impact in explaining differences in the level of unemployment across European economies. To test these propositions we can, fortunately, rely on an extensive empirical literature measuring cross-national differences in the structure of labor market institutions. While disagreement continues to exist about the relative importance of employers’ associations in facilitating the coordination of wage demands across firms or sectors or about classification of particular countries, such as France (characterized by a weak labor movement and de facto firm-level wage bargaining, but by an a large and significant public sector)23, nevertheless, a significant consensus seems to exist about the encountered cross-national variation in the structure of corporatist institutions. Recent 22 The countries included in my analysis are Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom and the United States. For each country, the time-series data is grouped into 9 four-year intervals. 23 Most English-speaking studies classify France as a case of an economy with ‘decentralized’ labor market institutions. This paper follows this approach. It is important to point out that a large number of French industrial relations scholars disagree. See, for example, Boyer, Robert. 1994.Wage reforms imposed by the state: some paradoxes in French incomes policies, In Dore, Ronald, Boyer, Robert and Mars, Zoe, eds., The Return to Incomes Policy, London: Pinter, pp. 47- 70. 33 research has generated increasingly sophisticated measure that capture cross-national differences in the level of centralization of wage bargaining authority, the concentration of union membership and the level of union density. The measure of the centralization of wage bargaining system used in this paper averages four of the most widely-used indexes of the literature developed by Schmitter24, Cameron25, Calmfors and Driffill26 and Iversen27. Schmitter’s ‘corporatism score’ measures both the organizational centralization and the associational monopoly of the labor movement. While the first term is a measure of the level of the wage bargaining authority, the second term captures the number and importance of competing unions and each level of bargaining, or what Golden refers to as ‘union monopoly’.28 Cameron aggregates three institutional characteristics of the labor movement: “the power of the labor confederation in collective bargaining” (a proxy for the locus of decision making authority), the “organizational unity of labor” (a measure of union monopoly) and an average measure of union density29. A similar approach is used by Iversen whose measure of centralization sums the share of workers covered by a trade union at each 24 Schmitter, Philippe. 1981. Interest intermediation and regime governability in contemporary Western Europe and North America, in Berger, Suzanne, ed., Organizing Interests in Western Europe: Pluralism, Corporatism and the transformation of politics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 287- 327. 25 Cameron, David. 1984. Social Democracy, Corporatism, Labor Quiescence and the representation of economic interests in advanced capitalist society, in Goldthorpe, John H. ed., Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 143- 178. 26 Calmfors and Driffill, op. cit. 27 Iversen, 1999, op. cit. 28 Golden, Miriam. 1993. The dynamics of trade unionism and national economic performance, American Political Science Review, 87, 2, 439- 454. 29 Cameron, op. cit., p. 165. 34 bargaining level30. Finally, Calmfors and Drifill’s index measures both the level of bargaining and degree of coordination within organizations on both the union and the employer side31. Table 1 presents a rank-ordering of individual countries according to their degree of centralization of labor market institutions and averages the four indexes. TABLE 1 I begin by displaying some simple cross-tabulations, which describe some of the patterns in the data. Table 2 presents data on the employment performance of economies featuring different levels of coordination of the wage bargaining system. The countries with decentralized labor markets have an average centralization score higher than 10 and include Canada, UK, the US, France and Switzerland. Countries with a centralization score lower than 2.5 (Austria, Sweden and Norway) are ranked as highly centralized. The remaining 6 cases (Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Germany, Italy and the Netherlands) are classified as intermediately centralized32. The figures in Table 2 provide initial support of the hypotheses of the model. The employment performance of economies with intermediately centralized institutions of wage bargaining in inferior to the performance of economies with either extremely centralized or extremely decentralized labor market institutions. While the long-term unemployment has risen in all economies, it is, again, economies with intermediately centralized institutions of wage bargaining that have 30 Iversen, 1999, op. cit., pp. 51- 57. 31 Calmfors and Driffill, 1988, op. cit., p. 52-53. 32 Denmark and Finland are, of course, borderline cases. For an discussion of the “organizational fragmentation and the conflictual labour relations” in Finland, see Ebbinghaus, Bernhard and Visser, Jelle. 2000. Trade unions in Western Europe since 1945, p. 201. 35 experienced the strongest deterioration of their economic performance. Average levels of unemployment rose by 1.676 percent in economies with highly centralized labor markets, by around 4 percent in economies with firm-level wage bargaining and by 5.3266 percent in intermediately-centralized cases. TABLE 2 Next, I test of the implications of the model based on pooled cross-sectional timeseries analysis. Following a recent approach to this type of analysis, I use ordinary leastsquares (OLS) regression with lagged dependent variables and panel-corrected standard errors to take account of potential problems of heteroskedasticity in the data33. Omitting all controls, the basic regression model estimating the impact of the degree of centralization of the wage bargaining system and of existing welfare-state commitments on the level of unemployment is U i ,t = ai + b1U i ,t −1 + b2Ci ,t + b3Ci2,t + b4WELFEFFi ,t + b5 MONETNONACCi ,t + b5ε i ,t where U i,t is the unemployment rate for country i at period t , C i,t is the index measuring the level of centralization of the wage bargaining system, WELFEFFi,t is a measure of the welfare state effort of a government, MONETNONACC i ,t a measure of 33 Beck, Nathaniel and Katz, Jonathan. 1995. What to do (and not to do) with time-series cross-section data, American Political Science Review, 89, 3, 634- 647. 36 the monetary nonaccomodation and ε i,t is an error term. The predictions about the impact of the structure of wage bargaining systems of the level of unemployment imply that the signs of the coefficients b2 and b3 should be + and - , respectively. In addition to the corporatism index described above, the parameters of the model have been operationalized as follows. I have used both tax-based and expenditure-based measures to evaluate the employment consequences associated with the growth and maturation of the welfare state (WELFEFF). To capture the impact of the income and payroll taxes (Ti.t ), I have relied on the measures of “effective average rates” developed by Mendoza et al34. The time series used in this paper updates Mendoza’s average labor tax rates series and has been developed (and generously provided) by Tom Cusack. The model predicts a positive effect of this variable on the level of unemployment. A second measure of the welfare effort is total government transfers (GOVTRANSF). This measure computes expenditures on pensions, unemployment, family benefits and so on and was computed by Huber, Ragin and Stephens, using OECD Historical Statistics.35 An increase in government transfers is expected to contribute to a rise in unemployment. As a test of the impact of demographic developments, the variable PENS measures the population over 65 as a percentage of the total population and has been computed by using OECD labor force statistics data. 34 For the methodology in developing this measure, see Mendoza et. al., “Effective Tax Rates”, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 34, 1994 and NBER paper 4684. 35 See Evelyne Huber, Charles Ragin and John D. Stephens, 1997. Comparative Welfare State Data Set, Northwestern University and University of North Carolina. 37 The variable MONETNONACC operationalizes the degree of monetary nonaccomodation of the government (parameter β of the model). I have relied on Iversen’s measure of the degree of conservatism monetary policy regime36. This measure is computed as follows. First, Iversen averaged the 3 most widely used indexes measuring the degree of central bank independence (developed by Cukierman, Bade and Parkin and Grilli, Masciandaro and Tabellini, respectively)37. These indexes pay particular attention to (a) the insulation of central bankers from political influence, (b) the policy goals of the central bank as well as (c) the type of policy instruments used by the central bank and their degree of power over these policy instruments. However, as Iversen points out, “central bank independence is neither a necessary, nor a sufficient condition for commitment to a conservative monetary policy. When the bank is dependent, a credible commitment to a nonaccomodating policy may be achieved through alternative institutional avenues, such as membership in international monetary institutions or it may come about as a result of persistent policies by governments that are sufficiently secure in power to create a reputation for toughness. Conversely, when the bank is independent, policy intentions may be defeated through a combination of expansionary fiscal policies, exhortation and political threats”38. To overcome this problem, Iversen multiplies the legal index of central bank independence with a measure of the relative currency appreciation. (The relative currency appreciation is itself a good 36 For the development of this measure, see Iversen, 1999, op. cit., pp. 57- 60. 37 See Cukiermann, Alex. 1992. Central Bank Strategy, Credibility and Independence, Cambridge: MIT Press; Grilli, Victorio, Masciandaro, Donato and Tabellini, Guido, 1991, Political and Monetary Institutions and Public Financial Policies in the industrialized countries, Economic Policy, 13, 42- 92. Bade, Robin and Parkin, Michael. 1982. Central Bank laws and Inflation – A Comparative Analysis, manuscript quoted in Iversen 1999. 38 Iversen, 1999. op. cit., p. 58. 38 proxy of the degree of commitment of the government to anti-inflationary policies). The values of the Iversen’s hard currency index for the countries in the sample are presented in Table 4. I have added broad range of control variables to the analysis. To test the impact of globalization on changes in the employment performance of different economies, I have relied on three measuring trade flows and financial openness. OPEN is a measure of the trade exposure of an economy and is computed as the sum of exports and imports as a percentage of GDP. I relied on the IMF International Financial Statistics Yearbook to compute the openness measure. CAPFLOWS is a measure of cross-border capital flows as a percentage of GDP and was computed using IMF Financial Statistics Data. Finally, I have included a variable measuring the liberalization of financial markets. FINLIBERALIZ is an index measuring the legal restrictions on cross-country capital flows, computed by Quinn and Inclan. High values on this index denote the absence of government restrictions on capital mobility. Thus, one predicts a negative relationship between this variable and the level of unemployment. Two additional political variables have been added as control measures. The first variable LEFTCAB is a measure of the percentage of cabinet seats held by left-wing parties. Finally, COGRAVITY is a measure of the ‘center of gravity of the government’ computed by multiplying the share of seats of parties in government with an expert ranking of their ideological position. The scale ranks from 1 (parties on the extreme right) to 5 (parties on the extreme left). Thus, high values on this variable denote a strong presence of more extreme left-wing parties in the government. 39 TABLES 3 and 4 Tables 3 and 4 display the results of the statistical analysis. The regression results using the tax measures as a proxy of welfare state effort are reported in Table 3. Table 4 reports the results using transfer expenditures as independent variable. We find a positive (and significant) effect of the level of taxes and of the level of transfer expenditures on the level of unemployment. These results confirm the argument of the paper that the rise in the level of payroll taxes and the increase in the magnitude of social policy transfers (modeled in the paper as an increase in the term bm in equation 6) are the cause of the deterioration of the employment performance experienced by European economies during recent decades. Secondly, we find that monetary nonaccomodation has a strong negative effect on the level of unemployment. This finding confirms key proposition of Soskice and Iversen and is in general agreement with similar empirical results of Iversen. The test of the impact of the structure of wage bargaining institutions on the level of unemployment strongly confirms the hypothesis that economies with centralized systems of wage bargaining deliver higher levels of wage restraint and thus lower levels of unemployment. The coefficient of the term measuring the strength of corporatist institutions has the predicted sign (and is statistically significant from zero). Not all models support however, the hypothesis suggesting a parabolic relationship between the level of centralization of the wage bargaining system and the level of unemployment. While the sign of the coefficient of the quadratic term measuring the structure of the wage bargaining system is negative (confirming thus the predictions of the model), the term is not always statistically significant. 40 In substantive terms, the results of the benchmark model reported in the first column of Tables 3 and 4 can be interpreted as follows. An increase in the level of taxes by one standard deviation contributes to an increase in the level of unemployment by 0.65 percent. To estimate the employment impact of a centralization of the wage bargaining system assume now that a country such as Netherlands (with a 6.75 score on the corporatism index) were to centralize its wage bargaining system by one standard deviation on our measure of corporatism (4.15). As a result of this change, the Dutch system of wage bargaining would resemble Austria or Sweden (both countries have an average centralization score of 2.5). The predicted employment effect of this institutional change would be a 1.1 percent decrease in the level of unemployment. The results of the benchmark model reported in the first column of Tables 3 and 4 are robust to the introduction of additional control variables and across multiple specifications39. I first control for the effect of various changes in the level of exposure to capital and trade flows. (The results are reported in the fourth column of Tables 3 and second column of Table 4). None of the globalization measures is statistically significant from 0. In addition, I control for the effect of demographic developments and the participation of left-wing parties in government. Left wing-governments contribute to lower levels of unemployment. I test for the effect of another political variable measuring the center of gravity of a government, but this variable does not seem to have a significant effect on the level of unemployment. (Column 3 in Tables 3 and 4). These empirical findings support the propositions advanced in this paper. The level of centralization of the wage bargaining system strongly accounts for the variation 39 The results are robust to the introduction of country-dummies. Results of these analyses are available from the author. 41 in the employment performance of European economies. The growth in the level of taxes has partially undermined the ability for wage restraint of unions in economies with centralized institutions of wage bargaining and has thus contributed to the rise in the level of unemployment experienced by these economies. 42 CONCLUSION During the last two decades, the literature examining cross-national differences in the structure of labor market institutions has generated important insights for the understanding of variation in economic performance across advanced industrialized democracies. The formalization of the Olsonian logic of collective action has allowed these studies to specify the incentives for wage moderation of large wage bargaining actors and to account for the low levels of unemployment and superior employment performance of economies with centralized institutions of wage bargaining during the first decades of the postwar period. During recent years, important theoretical developments have added new dimensions of institutional complexity to earlier models, by specifying the strategic interaction between wage bargaining actors and monetary authorities. Yet while this literature has been especially successful in explaining crossnational differences in economic performance in the period until the first oil shock, it is less successful in accounting for the deterioration of the employment performance of European economies during recent decades. The most significant limitation of this literature is its inability to specify the factors that have undermined the capacity for wage moderation of unions in economies with corporatist institutions of wage bargaining and that account for the rise in unemployment in European economies during recent decades. To address these empirical questions this paper has developed a model exploring the interaction between labor market institutions and the policies of the welfare state. The crucial insight of the paper is that the wage demands of trade unions are affected by the 43 structure of welfare state commitments. We show that the rational strategy of trade unions is to deliver wage restraint in exchange for the expansion of social policy commitments if a sizeable part of these transfers affect union members and if the magnitude of the net benefits derived by unions from the provision of social policy transfers and services exceeds labor’s share of the tax burden necessary to finance these commitments. This argument, stressing the importance of social policy as a source of wage moderation formalizes a number of existing observations formulated by students of the welfare state. However, we show that the strategy of wage moderation is no longer ‘self-enforcing’ in a policy environment characterized by high levels of taxes and sizeable social policy commitments devoted to labor market outsiders. In this case, the costs imposed on social policy of unions exceed the benefits derived by unions from the provision of social services. Thus, the process of welfare state growth and maturation undermines the earlier political exchange on which welfare state expansion was premised during the first decades of the postwar period. This paper points towards two directions of social policy reform that could attenuate the negative impact of the welfare state on the employment performance of European economies. The aim of these reforms is to restore the ability of unions to generate wage restraint in exchange for the provision of social policy benefits. First, future reforms need to reduce the size of labor market outsiders. It is important that welfare states counteract the fiscal and employment consequences of unfavorable demographic developments. Policies that aim to improve the employment performance of occupational groups situated at the demographic extremes of the labor market – by stopping the trend towards early retirement or by improving the skill mix of younger 44 workers and, thus, reducing youth unemployment – could, simultaneously, lower the fiscal burden of declining labor force participation rates. Secondly, the paper points to the importance of reforms of the mode of financing of social insurance. These reforms would not only reduce the non-wage labor costs of employers but also increase the ability of unions to deliver wage restraint. 45 FIGURE 1 PREDICTIONS OF CALMFORS AND DRIFILL MODEL ABOUT THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN CENTRALIZATION OF WAGE BARGAINING AND UNEMPLOYMENT Unemployment Centralization of wage bargaining 46 FIGURE 2 IVERSEN’S PREDICTIONS ABOUT THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN CENTRALIZATION OF WAGE BARGAINING, MONETARY NON-ACOMMODATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT Unemployment Accommodating macroeconomic regime Nonaccommodating macroeconomic regime and egalitarian wage policy Nonaccomodating Macroeconomic regime Without egalitarian Wage policy Centralization of wage bargaining 47 FIGURE 3 MODELLING THE DEGREE OF CENTRALIZATION OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEM Number of firms and sectors participating in the wage-setting process Large J………………………….Small J………………………………Small J Large I………………………….Large I………………………………Small I degree of centralization Firm .level .......... .......... ...Sector − Level...................................Economy − level 1 44 44 4 42 444 444 3 144444444244444444 3 int ra −sec toral .centralization.of . wage −b arg aining − sytem int er sec toral .centralization.of . wage −b arg aining Degree of centralization of wage bargaining system 48 FIGURE 4 RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN EMPLOYMENT AND CENTRALIZATION OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEM UNDER DIFFERENT ASSUMPTIONS ABOUT THE UTILITY OF TRADE UNIONS Equilibrium employment (a*) Predicted level of employment if unions “care” about social transfers and social services, in addition to wages Effects of social policies on wage restraint. Magnitude is higher in more centralized systems of wage bargaining Employment under the assumptions of the CalmforsDrifill model (if unions maximize real wages and unemployment benefits of union members) Level of Centralization of wage bargaining system Firm-level wb…………Industry-level wb…………………………………Economy-level wb 49 FIGURE 5 PREDICTED LEVEL OF EMPLOYMENT AS A FUNCTION OF (a) CENTRALIZATION OF THE WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEM, (b) DEGREE OF ACCOMODATION OF MONETARY REGIME, (c) NUMBER OF LABOR MARKET OUTSIDERS (d) SIZE OF BUDGET DEFICIT. equilibrium employment (a*) Equilibrium employment as a function of centralization of wage bargaining system if (a) number of labor market outsiders is small (b) level of monetary nonaccomodation is high (c) fiscal deficit is large m increases D decreases β decreases Equilibrium employment as a function of centralization of wage bargaining system if (a) number of labor market outsiders is large (b) level of monetary nonaccomodation is low (c) fiscal deficit is small centralization of wage bargaining system 50 TABLE 1 Corporatism Index (VARIABLE CWB) Schmitter (1981) Austria Belgium Canada Denmark Finland France Germany Italy Norway Netherlands Sweden Switzerland UK USA 1 7 11 4 4 12 8 15 2 6 4 9 14 11 Cameron (1984) 3 4 12 6 5 15 8 11 2 7 1 10 9 13 CalmforsDriffill (1988) 1 8 14 4 5 9 6 11 2 7 3 13 10 15 Iversen (1999) 5 8 14 3 4 13 7 11 1 6 2 10 12 15 Average 2.5 6.75 12.75 4.25 4.5 12.25 7.25 12 1.75 6.5 2.5 10.5 11.25 13.5 Source: Schmitter, Philippe, 1981, p. 284; Cameron, David, 1984, p. 165, Calmfors and Driffill, 1988, pp. 52- 53, Iversen, Torben. 1999, p. 56. 51 TABLE 2 Average levels of unemployment in OECD economies under alternative wage bargaining arrangements and social policy arrangements LEVEL OF UNEMPLOYMENT Centralization of Wage Bargaining System Period Decentralized Intermediately Highly Centralized Centralized 1960-1975 3.04 3.135 1.49 1976-1995 6.986 8.4616 3.166 Highly Centralized countries: Austria, Norway, Sweden (Centralization score <2.5); Intermediately Centralized countries: Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Germany, Italy, Netherlands. Decentralized Cases: UK, US, France and Switzerland (Centralization score > 10) Source: OECD. 52 TABLE 3 OLS Estimates of the effects of wage bargaining institutions and taxes on unemployment (Pooled Cross-Sectional Time Series 1960-1995 with Panel Corrected Standard Errors) Regression Estimates and Standard Errors Variables Predicted Sign CONSTANT UNEM i ,t −1 Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 -1.3092 (1.001) 0.7938*** (0.116) -1.050 (1.447) 0.762*** (0.112) -1.8718 (1.782) 0.778*** (0.111) -1.454 1.395 0.731*** (0.121) CWBi ,t + 0.6081* (0.324) 0.463 (0.319) 0.5113* (0.313) 0.459* (0.279) 2 i ,t CWB - -0.0319* (0.018) -0.023 (0.017) -0.025 (0.017) -0.224 (0.015) MONNONACC i ,t - -3.8696** (1.662) -4.075* (1.598) -4.188** (1.645) -4.167** (2.039) TAXRATE i ,t + 0.0706*** (0.025) 0.0612** (0.022) 0.063*** (0.021) 0.0544** (0.020) 0.0097 (0.095) 0.007 (0.005) PENS i ,t + 0.0527 (0.106) OPEN i ,t - 0.0716 (0.005) 0.100 (0.117) 0.2096 (0.017) FINLIBERALIZ i ,t OFINM i ,t LEFTCABi ,t -0.010* (0.006) - 0.222 (0.376) COGRAVITYi ,t N 0.015 (0.007) 108 0.757 Adj.R 2 Note: ***p<0.01; ** p<0.05; *p<0.1 108 108 108 0.7652 0.760 0.7674 53 TABLE 4 OLS Estimates of the effects of wage bargaining institutions and government transfers on unemployment Regression Estimates and Standard Errors Variables Predicted Sign Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 -0.7543 (1.128) 0.7325*** (0.103) -2.496 (1.697) 0.7208*** (0.104) 0.5361 (1.721) 0.7106*** (0.101) -0.6814 (1.970) 0.7189*** (0.103) + 0.4705** (0.236) 0.5214** (0.242) 0.4621* (0.252) 0.4983** (0.249) CWB - -0.0234 (0.014) -0.0279* (0.015) -0.2654* (0.015) -0.0277* (0.015) MONNONACC i ,t - -4.3193*** (1.5355) -3.6682** (1.7046) -3.7346** (1.645) -3.782** (1.695) GOVTRANSFi ,t + 0.1775*** (0.059) 0.1811*** (0.0511) 0.1874*** (0.050) 0.1846*** (0.051) CAPFLOWS i ,t - 0.0162 (0.015) 0.0143 (0.015) 0.0152 (0.015) FINLIBERALIZ i ,t -0.0295 (0.125) -0.0365 (0.133) -0.0402 (0.127) OPEN i ,t -0.013 (0.0110) -0.0136 (0.010) -0.0134 (0.010) CONSTANT UNEM i ,t −1 CWBi ,t 2 i ,t - -0.0089 (0.006) LEFTCABi ,t 0.2524 (0.373) COGRAVITYi ,t N 110 110 110 110 Adj.R 2 0.789 0.7928 0.7972 0.7936 Note: ***p<0.01; ** p<0.05; *p<0.1 54 TABLE 5 Country Averages CWB MON UNEMPL TAXRATE OPEN OLD LEFTCA COGRAV Austria 2.5 .52 2.4 38.14 65.9 14.3 67.9 2.4 Belgium 6.75 .47 7.4 40.10 108.1 13.9 30.6 2.9 Canada 12.75 .35 7.6 23.4 48.4 9.3 Denmark 4.25 .42 6.1 33.55 63.2 13.6 52.3 2.9 Finland 4.5 .38 5.0 28.8 52.5 10.9 37.4 2.7 France 12.25 .39 5.4 39.36 37.3 13.2 27.5 3.5 Germany 7.25 .60 4.4 36.95 51.5 14.1 34.2 3.2 Italy 12 .29 7.9 34.5 38.2 12.2 14.2 2.8 Norway 1.75 .40 2.4 38.55 81.9 14.1 66.3 2.5 Netherl 6.5 .54 5.3 47.1 98.2 11.2 17.9 3 Sweden 2.5 .29 2.4 47.65 55.8 15.4 72.5 2.3 Switzerl 10.5 .67 0.7 29.1 66.6 12.8 29.3 3.4 UK 11.25 .15 6.4 25.7 48.9 14.1 30.1 3.4 USA 13.5 .47 6.1 27.2 15.9 10.9 Mean 7.78 0.44 4.77 33.22 57.04 12.58 32.11 3.06 St.Dev. 4.15 0.147 3.48 9.12 26.43 2.51 33.96 0.643 3.4 3.6 55 REFERENCES Alesina, A. and R. Perotti.1997. The Welfare State and Competitiveness, American Economic Review, 87: 5, 921- 939. Calmfors, L. and J. Drifill. 1988. “Bargaining Structure, Corporatism and Macroeconomic Performance, Economic Policy, 6: 1, 14-61. Daveri, Francesco and Tabellini, Guido. 1997. Unemployment, Growth and Taxation in Industrial Countries, Discussion Paper 122, IGIER, Universita die Bocconi. Ebbinghaus, B. and A. Hassel. 1999. Striking Deals: Concertation in the Reform of Continental European Welfare States, Journal of European Public Policy, 7(1): 44-62. Glyn, Andrew. Ed., 1999. Social Democracy in Neoliberal Times. The Left and Economic Policy since 1980. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hall, P. and R. Franzese. 1998. Central Bank Independence, Coordinated Wage Bargaining and European Monetary Union, International Organization 52(2): 505-535. Hicks, Alexander. 2000. Social Democracy and Welfare Capitalism. A century of income security politics, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Iversen, Torben. 1999. Contested Economic Institutions. The Politics of Macroeconomics and wage bargaining in advanced democracies, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Pochet, Philip. Ed., 1999. Monetary Union and Collective Bargaining in Europe. Bruxelles: Presses Interuniversitaires Europeennes. Regini, Marino. 2000. “Between Deregulation and Social Pacts, Politics and Society 28(1): 5-33. Scharpf, Frtiz. 1991. Crisis and Choice in European Social Democracy. Ithaca, Cornell University Press. Scharpf, F. 1998. Governing in Europe: How effective? How Democratic? Oxford, Oxford University Press. Soskice, David. 1990. “Wage Determination: The Changing Role of Institutions in Advanced Industrialized Countries.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 6(4): 36-61. Soskice, D. and T. Iversen. 2000. “The Nonneutrality of Money with large price or wage setters.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(1): 1-20. 56 Summers, L., J. Gruber, et al. 1993. “Taxation and Structure of Labor Markets: The Case of Corporatism.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108(2): 385- 411. Visser, J. and A. Hemerjick. 1997. A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands. Amsterdam, Amsterdam University Press. Wallerstein, M. 1999. Wage-setting institutions and pay inequality in advanced industrial societies, American Journal of Political Science, 43(3): 649-680.