Feminist economics as better economics! Women’s Budget Group 30 January, 2015 Susan Himmelweit susan.himmelweit@open.ac.uk Plan for the morning • Gender budgeting is the practice • Feminist Economics as the theory • Let’s do a bit of theory first! The main assumption of feminist economics • Gender relations are an important aspect of any economy • And gender is structural – differences in men’s and women’s roles not chance – but an integral part of how the economy runs – Changes in economy as conventionally understood can affect gender relations and vice versa • Gender therefore needs to be taken account in any understanding of the economy – Much mainstream economics, and also much not-so-mainstream economics, is “gender blind” – Should instead start by assuming that everything has a gender dimension • Feminist economics is therefore not economics for women but better economics The scope of feminist economics • “The economy” as traditionally understood is dependent on many activities that lie outside its scope • Feminist economics is the study of all forms of “provisioning” (Julie Nelson) • The survival and reproduction of people and society as a whole requires: – not only paid employment but unpaid domestic work too – not only production for the market but for direct use within families and communities too – not only the production of material goods, but everything that people need to grow and flourish, including the provision of care The politics of feminist economics • Economics that focuses on creating gender equality • Traditional economics is ideological and perpetuates inequality because – it normalises men’s lives and ignores much of what women do • Though in practice also provides an incomplete picture of what affects men’s lives – since men’s existence also depends on unpaid work, production for direct use and care – and many men are involved in these activities too • Even if women and feminist economics are needed to point that out! Key differences between feminist and mainstream economics Feminist economics • Doesn’t just analyse market relations – other relations just as important – there’s unpaid work too – cannot assume people behave outside the markets just like they do within it • Household is not treated the basic unit of the economy – Household members can have different interests – People live in a number of different households in the course of their lives • Rejects notion that people have preferences that are independent and unchanging – Social norms matter and they change – Maximising choice doesn’t solve everything • Rejects a model of work based on the production of physical things – Characteristics of care provision provide an alternative model that applies to much other work too – Need to redefine what is meant by infrastructure and investment Analysing market relations isn’t enough • Time spent on unpaid activities affects what else people can do with their lives – Cannot assume all workers are wage-workers, and certainly not all their lives – Women’s lives tend to be more varied in this respect than men’s • And what else the economy can do – also the revenues that can be raised by governments • Unpaid work within households is equivalent to about 1/3 to 1/2 of GDP - though not counted in it • The total economy can be growing faster or slower than that measured by GDP – Faster in recessions when people are losing their jobs and then doing more unpaid work – Slower when people are moving into paid employment Analysing market relations isn’t enough • Need to take account of potential effects of policy on unpaid as well as paid work and how they affect each other • Cannot assume people behave outside the market just like economists say they do within it • Relationship between paid and unpaid activities is not just one way – Cannot assume that unpaid work adjusts around changes in the economy • eg if women go into paid employment that how people are cared fro will seamlessly adjust – Cannot assume patterns/norms of unpaid work won’t change • eg if women go into paid employment the division of labour in unpaid work will stay the same • Unpaid activities are neither infinitely flexible and available, nor just an unchanging background to the paid economy Households are not individuals • Mainstream economics and much policy making takes the household as an indivisible unit – Eg household means testing – Couples asked to “choose” who receives payments • Decisions made by different members of the household are not necessarily consistent • Interests of members of same household may differ • Resources are not necessarily shared equally within households • Need to recognise: – People do make decisions in the context of their household/family – This is not same as saying that in doing so they are all pursuing the same goals Households are not individuals • People live in a number of different households in the course of their lives • So what is “best for the household” at point in time may not be best for all individuals within it • Eg pension planning based on the couple leaves many widows in poverty • US research shows who makes financial decisions may matter a great deal to outcomes in the long-run – Need to consider impacts on both households and individuals • Analysis at both levels can be useful – Need to take a life-course perspective for individuals – In particular, women are often the ones who sacrifice their own longer term interests to “those” of their household • may not be served well by policies assuming unified interests, equal sharing or focused too much on household's current circs People don’t have independent and unchanging preferences • Norms matter • People are not “separated selves” with fixed preferences – Identities and wishes are developed in society • Theory of how norms are formed and influence behaviour key – Cannot be reduced to • individual self-interest • either simply constraints or preferences • “Choice” is not a reliable guide for feminist policy advocacy – “what women want” depends on current options – eg part-time work in UK because childcare so expensive An example: Changing care norms: UK 1991-9 • Gendered norms about how to care for pre-school children reinforce, and are reinforced by, gendered economic opportunities • As those economic opportunities change, so do those norms 12 People don’t have independent and unchanging preferences • Economic change can be speeded up or slowed down by current norms (and vice versa) – policies that depend on behavioural change may take time to have effect • Policies that promote “choice” – tend to reinforce existing norms • Often a way just to shift responsibilities • Positive feedback between norms, behaviour and policy explains divergence between countries – Neither economics nor norms alone explains differences between countries – Policies may not be immediately transferable • Eg policies that rely on private philanthropy in societies used to having a welfare state How physical things are produced is not a good model for economics • Analysis of care is arguably the most distinctive contribution of Feminist Economics • Care has some characteristics that are typically ignored by economists: – Both the supply and demand for care are influenced by social norms, concerning: • people’s needs for care • how and by whom that care should be delivered – care involves a personal relationship between provider and receiver, that • makes raising productivity difficult • affects the skills, training, pay and conditions of care workers – carers’ motivations are intrinsic to the quality of care • making the quality of care hard to measure or evaluate from outside • Many other goods share these characteristics to a greater or lesser extent – Feminist economic analysis of care useful more generally – Feminist economics as better economics Care and care norms • Care helps people do what others can do unaided • But what is thought essential for people to be able to do is influenced by “care norms” that: – differ across societies – Are gendered within societies • And responsibilities for care provision also: – differ across societies – but tend to be highly gendered within all societies • women are expected to take more responsibility and provide more unpaid care than men within families • within paid work care tends to be seen as more suitable work for women than men • That norms about care provision are gendered is seen by many feminists as the fundamental explanation of gender differences throughout society 15 Care as a personal relationship: implications for productivity and costs • Trends in the production of other goods and services – rising productivity – outsourcing have applied less to care. Why? • In many industries labour is just an input; then – labour-saving techniques can lead to productivity growth – and so costs generally rise less fast than wages • But in other industries, “those in which the human touch is crucial”, labour is the effective output too; then – little scope for raising productivity through introducing labour-saving techniques (without reducing quality) – labour costs rise in proportion to wages • Products of second type of industry become relatively more expensive 16 (Baumol’s “cost disease”) Baumol’s example: playing a string quartet In playing a string quarter, neither cutting the number of players nor playing faster can raise the productivity of labour 17 Productivity and costs in care • Care is an example of the second type of industry: – Care is a hands-on personal service that involves building a relationship; – Cannot in general reduce time and increase productivity while retaining quality; • Cannot spread a relationship over too many people • Indeed staff/client ratios taken as index of quality – labour costs make up nearly all the cost of care • So total costs of care rise as fast as wages • The cost of care of a given quality, like listening to live string quartets, become more expensive relatively to other goods • Leading to governments’ obsession with containing the costs of care even before the current crisis 18 Current (unsustainable) systems of care provision • Most care is provided “free” by families – in practice paid for by the opportunity costs of unpaid carers, mostly women • Care also available on the market – at rising costs despite care workers low pay • Limited state budget for helping where the family and market can’t provide: – costs kept down by restrictions on who gets such help, how much help and its quality – Increasingly through the market – Such market solutions used to save costs and promote “choice” 19 Such systems depend on: • Huge amounts of unpaid care being given mostly by women • Low pay in paid care sector • Gender norms and opportunities that make these possible: – women more inclined to take on unpaid caring roles than men (in most age groups) – women’s other opportunities more limited than men’s • Inequality in labour market and in care intertwined: – makes equal sharing within families expensive – reinforces gender norms – slows down change but has not eliminated it • None of this can be taken for granted – Current pressures are making such systems unsustainable 20 Unsustainability of current care system • Rising need for care: – Demographic pressures • Falling availability of unpaid care – Rising employment levels of women • Employment opportunities for women outside care industry: – so wages in care cannot lag far behind other industries • recruitment and retention problems in care industry • Rising costs of care provision coupled with rising inequality means proportion who can pay full care costs themselves falls • Governments' unwillingness to allow state spending on care to rise to meet rising care need • Changing gender norms! 21 Nevertheless in the crisis • Women have born the brunt of austerity • Cuts have affected women’s: – jobs – employment opportunities – incomes – unpaid time more than men’s • Feminist economics can help – expose this – provide alternative strategies An example of WBG analysis: And another And some more Key differences between feminist and mainstream economics Feminist economics • Doesn’t just analyse market relations – other relations just as important – there’s unpaid work too – cannot assume people behave outside the markets just like they do within it • Household is not treated the basic unit of the economy – Household members can have different interests – People live in a number of different households in the course of their lives • Rejects notion that people have preferences that are independent and unchanging – Social norms matter and they change – Maximising choice doesn’t solve everything • Rejects a model of work based on the production of physical things – Characteristics of care provision provide an alternative model that applies to much other work too – Need to redefine what is meant by infrastructure and investment