Finance 30210: Managerial Economics Supply, Demand, and Equilibrium If we can’t have everything we want, so we need to decide what to do with the limited resources we do have. Efficiency vs. Equity An allocation of resources that maximum total welfare Under certain circumstances, the competitive market process guarantees this An allocation of resources provides a “fair” distribution of welfare Can we trust markets to produce a desirable outcome? Under what circumstances does the market process result in efficient outcomes? #1: Many buyers and sellers – no individual buyer/firm has any real market power #2: Homogeneous products – no variation in product across firms #3: No barriers to entry – it’s costless for new firms to enter the marketplace #4: Perfect information – prices and quality of products are assumed to be known to all producers/consumers #5: No Externalities –ALL costs/benefits of the product are absorbed by the consumer/producer #6: Transactions are costless – buyers and sellers incur no costs in an exchange (i.e. no taxes) Can you think of situations where all these assumptions hold? Lets try an example…suppose that you are a fisherman. Top catch larger quantities of fish, you have to go farther from shore and your catch per hour drops Zone A 50 Fish/hr 300 Max/Day Zone B 30 Fish/hr 300 Max/Day You bought a boat for $1,000 Maintenance on the boat is $50/Day You pay $16/hour in labor costs You pay $20/hour for fuel and other expenses What costs are fixed, sunk, and variable? Zone C 20 Fish/hr 160 Max/Day Lets try an example…suppose that you are a fisherman. To catch larger quantities of fish, you have to go farther from shore and your catch per hour drops Zone A Zone B 50 Fish/hr 300 Max/Day Boat = $50 Labor = $16/hr Gas = $20/hr Zone C 30 Fish/hr 300 Max/Day 20 Fish/hr 160 Max/Day Lets take this section by section… Zone A $36 / hr $.72 / Fish 50 Fish / Hr Quantity Total Cost Fixed Cost Variable Cost Average Cost Marginal Cost 0 $50 $50 $0 --- --- 1 $50.72 $50 $.72 $50.72 $.72 2 $51.44 $50 $1.44 $25.72 $.72 3 $52.16 $50 $2.16 $17.39 $.72 Let’s try and picture this… Dollars Dollars AC TC VC = $.72*F $50 FC $.72 MC # of Fish 0 # of Fish 0 Lets try an example…suppose that you are a fisherman. Top catch larger quantities of fish, you have to go farther from shore and your catch per hour drops Zone A Zone B 50 Fish/hr 300 Max/Day Boat = $50 Labor = $16/hr Gas = $20/hr Zone C 30 Fish/hr 300 Max/Day 20 Fish/hr 160 Max/Day Lets take this section by section… Zone B $36 / hr $1.20 / Fish 30 Fish / Hr Quantity TC FC VC AC MC 300 $266 $50 $216 $0.88 $.72 301 $267.20 $50 $217.20 $0.88 $1.20 302 $268.40 $50 $218.40 $0.88 $1.20 303 $269.60 $50 $219.60 $0.88 $1.20 Let’s try and picture this… TC Dollars Dollars VC =$216 + $1.20*F $266 $50 FC $1.20 MC AC $.88 # of Fish 300 # of Fish 300 Lets try an example…suppose that you are a fisherman. Top catch larger quantities of fish, you have to go farther from shore and your catch per hour drops Zone A Zone B 50 Fish/hr 300 Max/Day Boat = $50 Labor = $16/hr Gas = $20/hr Zone C 30 Fish/hr 300 Max/Day 20 Fish/hr 160 Max/Day Lets take this section by section… Zone C $36 / hr $1.80 / Fish 20 Fish / Hr Quantity TC FC VC AC MC 600 $626 $50 $576 $1.04 $1.20 601 $627.80 $50 $577.80 $1.04 $1.80 602 $629.60 $50 $579.60 $1.04 $1.80 603 $631.40 $50 $581.40 $1.04 $1.80 Let’s try and picture this… TC Dollars Dollars VC =$576 + $1.80*F $626 $50 FC $1.80 MC AC $1.04 # of Fish 600 # of Fish 600 All together… Dollars Dollars TC Slope = 1.80 Slope = 1.20 MC $1.80 Slope = .72 AC $50 FC $1.20 $.72 0 300 600 # of Fish # of Fish 0 300 600 Perfectly competitive firms are “price takers”. They see a market price and can’t change it. Suppose that the market price is $1.20. Fish Price Total Revenue Total Cost Profit 0 $1.20 $0 $50 -$50 1 $1.20 $1.20 $50.72 -$49.52 2 $1.20 $2.40 $51.44 -$49.04 3 $1.20 $3.60 $52.16 -$48.56 300 $1.20 $360 $266 $94 301 $1.20 $361.20 $267.20 $94 302 $1.20 $362.40 $268.40 $94 303 $1.20 $363.60 $269.60 $94 600 $1.20 $720 $626 $94 601 $1.20 $721.20 $627.80 $93.40 602 $1.20 $721.40 $629.60 $91.80 603 $1.20 $721.60 $631.40 $90.20 We are looking to maximize profits where profits are the difference between total revenues and total costs Dollars Dollars TC $94 TR $0 # of Fish Slope = 1.80 $50 Profit -$50 Slope = 1.20 Slope = .72 0 Profits are increasing 300 Profits are maximized # of Fish 600 Profits are decreasing 0 Profits are increasing 300 Profits are maximized 600 Profits are decreasing We could also go at this by looking at costs and benefits at the margin. For a perfectly competitive firm the market price equals marginal revenue. Fish Total Cost Total Revenue Marginal Revenue Marginal Cost 0 $50 $0 $1.20 $.72 1 $50.72 $1.20 $1.20 $.72 2 $51.44 $2.40 $1.20 $.72 3 $52.16 $3.60 $1.20 $.72 300 $266 $360 $1.20 $.72 301 $267.20 $361.20 $1.20 $1.20 302 $268.40 $362.40 $1.20 $1.20 303 $269.60 $363.60 $1.20 $1.20 600 $626 $720 $1.20 $1.20 601 $627.80 $721.20 $1.20 $1.80 602 $629.60 $721.40 $1.20 $1.80 603 $631.40 $721.60 $1.20 $1.80 Lets plot out marginal revenues and costs rather than total costs and revenues… Dollars Dollars $94 MC $1.80 $0 # of Fish MR $1.20 Profit -$50 $.72 0 Marginal revenue is greater than marginal cost 300 0 600 Marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost Marginal revenue is less than marginal cost Profits are increasing 300 Profits are maximized 600 Profits are decreasing When we talk about a supply curve we are talking about the profit maximizing decisions of individual firms at prevailing market prices Dollars Dollars MC $1.80 MR $1.20 $1.20 $.72 # of Fish 0 300 600 At a market price of $1.20, MR = MC for any quantity of fish between 300 and 600 0 300 600 At a market price of $1.20, this firm will be willing to supply any quantity of fish between 300 and 600 Now, suppose that the market price is $0.72. Fish Price Total Revenue Total Cost Profit 0 $0.72 $0 $50 -$50 1 $0.72 $0.72 $50.72 -$50 2 $0.72 $1.44 $51.44 -$50 3 $0.72 $2.16 $52.16 -$50 300 $0.72 $216 $266 -$50 301 $0.72 $216.72 $267.20 -$50.48 302 $0.72 $217.44 $268.40 -$50.96 303 $0.72 $218.16 $269.60 -$51.44 600 $0.72 $432 $626 -$194 601 $0.72 $432.72 $627.80 -$195.08 602 $0.72 $433.44 $629.60 -$196.16 603 $0.72 $434.16 $631.40 -$197.24 Again, lets plot revenues, costs, and profits… Dollars Dollars $0 # of Fish TC Slope = 1.80 -$50 Slope = 1.20 Slope = .72 TR $50 Profit # of Fish 0 300 Profits are maximized (losses are minimized) 600 Profits are decreasing 0 300 Profits are maximized (losses are minimized) 600 Profits are decreasing We could also go at this by looking at costs and benefits at the margin. For a perfectly competitive firm the market price equals marginal revenue. Fish Total Cost Total Revenue Marginal Revenue Marginal Cost 0 $50 $0 $.72 $.72 1 $50.72 $0.72 $.72 $.72 2 $51.44 $1.44 $.72 $.72 3 $52.16 $2.16 $.72 $.72 300 $266 $216 $.72 $.72 301 $267.20 $216.72 $.72 $1.20 302 $268.40 $217.44 $.72 $1.20 303 $269.60 $218.16 $.72 $1.20 600 $626 $432 $.72 $1.20 601 $627.80 $432.72 $.72 $1.80 602 $629.60 $433.44 $.72 $1.80 603 $631.40 $434.16 $.72 $1.80 Again, lets plot marginal revenues, marginal costs, and profits… Dollars Dollars $0 MC $1.80 -$50 $1.20 $.72 MR Profit 0 300 Marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost 0 600 Marginal revenue is less than marginal cost 300 Profits are maximized 600 Profits are decreasing When we talk about a supply curve we are talking about the profit maximizing decisions of individual firms at prevailing market prices Dollars Dollars MC $1.80 $1.20 $1.20 $.72 MR $.72 # of Fish 0 300 At a market price of $.72, MR = MC for any quantity of fish between 0 and 300 600 0 300 At a market price of $.72, this firm will be willing to supply any quantity of fish between 0 and 300 600 When we talk about a supply curve we are talking about the profit maximizing decisions of individual firms at prevailing market prices Dollars Dollars MC MR $1.80 $1.80 $1.20 $1.20 $.72 $.72 # of Fish 0 300 600 At a market price of $1.80, MR = MC for any quantity of fish between 600 and 760 0 300 600 At a market price of $1.80, this firm will be willing to supply any quantity of fish between 600 and 760 What if the prevailing market was $1.35? Dollars Dollars MC MR $1.35 $1.35 # of Fish 0 300 600 At a market price of $1.35, 600 fish are profitable to supply, but the 601st is not! 0 300 600 At a market price of $1.35, this firm will be willing to supply exactly 600 fish. So we can get an individual firm’s supply curve by following marginal costs! Suppose that there are 1000 fishermen in the village – all with the same costs. Dollars Dollars $1.80 $1.80 $1.20 $1.20 $.72 $.72 0 300 600 Individual Supply # of Fish 0 300,000 600,000 # of Fish Market Supply Market supply adds up the decisions of each individual firm at each prevailing market price So where do prices come from? We need to know how many fish people are actually willing to buy at any prevailing market price. Dollars Price Fish $2.00 50,000 $1.80 150,000 $1.50 200,000 $1.20 500,000 $1.00 540,000 $.72 600,000 $.50 700,000 $1.80 $1.20 $.72 0 150,000 500,000 900,000 # of Fish A demand curve is just a record of how much the market collectively is willing to buy at any given market price In equilibrium, total supply should equal total demand. If not, the price will adjust. Dollars Supply At a $1.80 price, fishermen will bring at least 600,000 fish to the market, but only 150,000 will get sold – the price needs to drop $1.80 $1.20 $.72 Demand 0 300,000 600,000 500,000 # of Fish At a $.72 price, fishermen will bring at most 300,000 fish to the market, but 600,000 are demanded– the price needs to rise Price Fish $2.00 50,000 $1.80 150,000 $1.50 200,000 $1.20 500,000 $1.00 540,000 $.72 600,000 $.50 700,000 In equilibrium, total supply should equal total demand Individual Market Dollars Dollars Supply $1.80 $1.80 $1.20 $1.20 MC MR $.72 $.72 Demand 0 300,000 600,000 500,000 The market determines the equilibrium price of $1.20 and 500,000 fish sold by the 1,000 fishermen 0 300 600 At the prevailing market price of $1.20, each fisherman supplies between 300 and 600 fish Boat = $50 Labor = $16/hr Gas = $20/hr Fish Total Revenue Total Cost Profit 300 $360 $266 $94 301 $361.20 $267.20 $94 $36 / hr $1.20 / Fish 30 Fish / Hr 302 $362.40 $268.40 $94 303 $363.60 $269.60 $94 A Few Diagnostics… Dollars Price= $1.20 - Gas Cost = $0.67 Labor’s Value Added= $0.53 * Labor Productivity = 30 Fish/Hr $16/hr = hourly wage MC $1.80 $1.20 MR Producer Surplus = $144 - Fixed Cost = $50 $144 Accounting Profit= $94 $.72 0 300 600 $94 *100 = 9.4% Return $1,000 Is this fisherman earning economic profits? Suppose that the excess returns causes 800 more fishermen (all with identical costs) to enter the market. Dollars Supply $1.80 $1.20 $.72 Demand 0 300,000 # of Fish 600,000 540,000 1,080,000 1,368,000 Price Fish $2.00 50,000 $1.80 150,000 $1.50 200,000 $1.20 500,000 $1.00 540,000 $.72 600,000 $.50 700,000 In equilibrium, total supply should equal total demand Individual Market Dollars Dollars Supply $1.80 MC $1.80 $1.20 $1.00 MR $1.00 $.72 $.72 Demand 0 300,000 600,000 540,000 The market determines the equilibrium price of $1.00 and 540,000 fish sold by the 1,800 fishermen 0 300 600 At the prevailing market price of $1.00, each fisherman supplies 300 fish Boat = $50 Labor = $16/hr Gas = $20/hr $36 / hr $.72 / Fish 50 Fish / Hr Fish Price Total Revenue Total Cost Profit 0 $1.00 $0 $50 -$50 1 $1.00 $1.00 $50.72 -$49.72 2 $1.00 $2.00 $51.44 -$49.44 3 $1.00 $3.00 $52.16 -$49.16 300 $1.00 $300 $266 $34 A Few Diagnostics… Dollars Price= $1.00 - Gas Cost = $0.40 Labor’s Value Added= $0.60 * Labor Productivity = 50 Fish/Hr MC $1.80 MR $1.00 $84 $30/hr > hourly wage Producer Surplus = $84 - Fixed Cost = $50 $.72 Accounting Profit= $34 0 300 600 $34 *100 = 3.4% Return $1,000 Let’s see if we can’t generalize this a bit. We want marginal costs to be increasing – this reflects decreasing productivity at the margin TC Dollars Dollars MC $1.80 $50 FC $1.20 $.72 0 300 600 # of Fish 0 300 600 We are still looking for where marginal revenue equals marginal costs (i.e. the slopes are the same) Dollars Dollars TC $94 TR Slope = P $0 # of Fish F* Profit -$50 # of Fish 0 300 F* 600 0 300 600 We are still looking for where marginal revenue equals marginal costs Dollars Dollars MC $0 F* P* MR Profit -$50 0 F* 0 300 600 We are still looking for where marginal revenue equals marginal costs Dollars Dollars Supply MC P* P* MR=P # of Fish 0 F* For any market price (which equals marginal revenue for a perfectly competitive firm, there is a profit maximizing quantity where MR = MC 0 F* That optimizing quantity becomes a point on that firms supply curve We still aggregate decisions across individual suppliers to get market supply (again, assume 1,000 fishermen) Dollars Dollars Supply P* 0 Supply P* F # of Fish 0 1000*F Individual Supply Market Supply # of Fish In equilibrium, total supply should equal total demand Individual Market Dollars Dollars Supply MC $1.44 MR $1.44 Demand 0 0 400 400,000* The market determines the equilibrium price of $1.44 and 400,000 fish sold by the 1,000 fishermen At the prevailing market price of $1.44, each fisherman supplies 400 fish Boat = $50 Labor = $16/hr Gas = $20/hr We can still perform whatever diagnostics we want… For this calculation to work, labor productivity must be 25 fish per hour Price= $1.44 - Gas Cost = $.80 Labor’s Value Added= $0.64 * Labor Productivity = 25 Fish/Hr $16/hr = hourly wage Dollars MC PS = (1/2)(400)(1.44)=288 Producer Surplus = $288 - Fixed Cost = $50 Accounting Profit= $238 MR $1.44 $288 $238 *100 =23.8% Return $1,000 0 400 Is this fisherman earning economic profits? Suppose that the excess returns causes 800 more fishermen (all with identical costs) to enter the market. Dollars Dollars Supply $1.44 $1.44 $1.03 Demand 0 400,000 576,000 720,000 # of Fish 0 320 400 Boat = $50 Labor = $16/hr Gas = $20/hr We can still perform whatever diagnostics we want… At 320 fish, your productivity is 35 Fish/hour Price= $1.03 - Gas Cost = $.57 Labor’s Value Added= $0.46 * Labor Productivity = 35 Fish/Hr Dollars $16/hr = hourly wage MC PS = (1/2)(320)(1.03)=165 Producer Surplus = $165 - Fixed Cost = $50 Accounting Profit= $115 MR $1.03 $165 $115 *100 =11.5% Return $1,000 0 320 Suppose that we have three fishermen with different productivities. Each bought a boat for $1,000 and have the same costs as before. Boat = $50 Labor = $16/hr Gas = $20/hr 30 Fish/hr 300 Max/Day $1.20 per fish 20 Fish/hr 200 Max/Day $1.80 per fish 10 Fish/hr 100 Max/Day $3.60 per fish Each of the above fishermen will provide fish to the marketplace as long as the market price is equal to or greater to their marginal cost All a supply curve really does is order production from lowest cost to highest cost Dollars $3.60 $1.80 $1.20 Fish 0 300 500 600 For a market price that is at least $3.60, fisherman #1 sells 300 fish, fisherman #2 sells 200 fish and fisherman #3 sells 100 fish For a market price that is at least $1.80, but below $3.60, fisherman #1 sells 300 fish and fisherman #2 sells up to 200 fish. For a market price that is at least $1.20, but below $1.80, only fisherman #1 sells fish. He can supply up to 300 Adding a demand curve will give us the equilibrium price and identify the fisherman who participate in the market as well as the fisherman’s economic profits Boat = $50 Labor = $16/hr Gas = $20/hr Fisherman #1 Producer Surplus = $540 - Fixed Cost = $50 Dollars Accounting Profit= $490 Supply $490 *100 = 49% Return $1,000 $3.60 Fisherman #2 $3.00 PS= $240 $1.80 PS= $540 Demand $1.20 Accounting Profit= $190 Fish 0 Producer Surplus = $240 - Fixed Cost = $50 300 500 600 $190 *100 = 19% Return $1,000 A Supply Function represents the rational decisions made by a profit maximizing firm(s). “Is a function of” QS S P Quantity Supplied Market Price (+) As you move up the supply curve, the rise in price encourages increased production of existing producers (intensive margin) as well as the entry of new producers (extensive margin) Price S High marginal costs are in this portion – they will make the lowest profits (if they are sold) Lower marginal costs are in this portion – they will make the largest profits Quantity Everything we talked about on the supply side is mirrored on the demand side. Just at producers are maximizing profits, consumers maximize their welfare. Welfare = Total Utility – Total Cost Dollars Welfare 0 F* P* MC MU 0 Q F* Most consumers experience diminishing marginal utility – each successive item consumed is worth less in terms of satisfaction Q By the same token, a demand curve naturally ranks potential consumers from highest valuation to lowest valuation. Suppose that we have three potential consumers. Would pay up to $2/fish. Can consume 100 fish per week. Would pay up to $1/fish. Can consume 50 fish per week. Would pay up to $.50/fish. Can consume 20 fish per week. What would this demand curve look like? Dollars If fish cost more than $2, nobody buys them! $2 If fish cost between $2 and $1, only Captain buys them! $1 If fish cost between $.50 and $1, Captain AND Andrew Zimmern buy them! If fish cost more less than $.50 , EVERYBODY buys them! $.50 Fish 0 100 150 170 Price Quantity Demanded Above $2 0 $2 0 – 100 Between $2 and $1 100 $1 100 - 150 Between $1 and $.50 150 $.50 Between 150 and 170 Between $.50 and $0 170 For any market price, we know how many fish are sold and how much each consumer benefits from the market (consumer surplus) At a market price of $1.50 Dollars Captain buys 100 fish for $1.50 apiece. He saves $.50 per fish for a total of $50 in savings (surplus) Neither the baby of Andrew Zimmern are willing to buy fish for $1.50. $2 CS = $50 $1.50 $1 $.50 Fish 0 100 150 170 For any market price, we know how many fish are sold and how much each consumer benefits from the market (consumer surplus) At a market price of $.75 Dollars Captain buys 100 fish for $.75 apiece. He saves $1.25 per fish for a total of $125 in savings (surplus) Andrew Zimmern buys 50 fish for $.75. He saves $.25 per fish for a total of $12.50 in surplus The baby still is unwilling to buy fish! $2 CS = $125 $1 CS = $12.50 $.75 $.50 Fish 0 100 150 170 A Demand Function represents the rational decisions made by a representative consumer(s) “Is a function of” Quantity Demanded QD DP Market Price (-) Price high marginal valuations are located here low marginal valuations are located here D Quantity As you move down the demand curve, the lower price encourages increased consumption by existing customers (intensive margin) as well as attracting new consumers (extensive margin) Key Point: Demand curves represent marginal utility (what we are willing to pay for one additional item). Consumer surplus measures total value. Example: The Diamond/Water Paradox Water Diamonds Price Price P* P* D Quantity D Quantity Market Equilibrium: There exists a price where supply equals demand – the market will find this price automatically. Price S At a price above the equilibrium price, supply is greater than demand. A surplus drives the price down P* At a price below the equilibrium price, demand is greater than supply. A shortage drives the price up D Quantity Q* Recall an earlier discussion about allocations of resources. Efficiency vs. Equity An allocation of resources that maximum total welfare Under certain circumstances, the market process guarantees this An allocation of resources provides a “fair” distribution of welfare Can we trust markets to produce a desirable outcome? Let’s suppose that we are talking about the market for bananas. There was a pound of bananas sold that cost $3 to supply and was valued by someone at $7. This transaction created $4 of wealth $2 went to a seller (producer surplus) and $2 went to a buyer (consumer surplus) Would this transaction be wealth creating? NO! Price S $12 $8 $7 $5 $3 $2 D $0 Quantity 1,000 There was a pound of bananas sold that cost $2 to supply and was valued by someone at $8. This transaction created $6 of wealth - $3 went to a seller (producer surplus) and $3 went to a buyer (consumer surplus) Competitive markets provide efficient outcomes in that every wealth creating transaction was undertaken. In other words, consumer surplus and producer surplus are maximized. Price $12 S Consumer Surplus = (1/2)*($12- $5)*1,000 $3,500 $5 $2,500 Producer Surplus = (1/2)*($5- $0)*1,000 D $0 Quantity 1,000 Note that $6,000 of wealth was created by this market! Example: Suppose we have the following petroleum firms. Further suppose that there is pressure from the public to reduce pollution levels. Firm Historical Emissions (Tons/yr) Marginal Abatement Cost ($/Ton) Apache 50 12 BP 50 18 Chevron 50 24 Devon 50 30 Exxon 50 36 First Texas 50 42 Gulf 50 48 Hess 50 54 Industry Total 400 How would you go about reducing emissions by 50% The cheapest way to reduce pollution by 50% would be to require the cheapest 4 firms to reduce their emissions completely and let the other four firms continue as in the past $ Per Unit Pollution Reduction Hess $54 Gulf $48 First $42 Exxon $36 Devon $30 Chevron $24 BP $18 $12 Problems: •Unfair •Requires information on abatement costs Apache Quantity of Emissions Reduction We could follow an “across the board” emission reduction program (note: pollution taxes would have the same basic effect) Firm Historical Emissions (Tons/yr) Marginal Abatement Cost ($/Ton) Tons of emission to be reduced Total abatement cost Apache 50 12 25 300 BP 50 18 25 450 Chevron 50 24 25 600 Devon 50 30 25 750 Exxon 50 36 25 900 First Texas 50 42 25 1,050 Gulf 50 48 25 1,200 Hess 50 54 25 1,350 Industry Total 400 200 6,600 Let markets work for you!!! Example: Cap and Trade as a solution to pollution reduction. Firm Historical Emissions (Tons/yr) Marginal Abatement Cost ($/Ton) Apache 50 12 BP 50 18 Chevron 50 24 Devon 50 30 Exxon 50 36 First Texas 50 42 Gulf 50 48 Hess 50 54 Industry Total 400 Could BP profit from selling a pollution permit to Gulf? What should the selling price be? The Market for pollution permits $ Per Unit Pollution Reduction $54 Hess Gulf $48 Equilibrium price range Hess Gulf First $42 S $36 First Exxon Exxon Devon Devon $33 $30 Chevron $24 BP $18 $12 Apache Chevron BP Apache D Quantity of Emissions Reduction The cap and trade program lowered the cost of pollution reduction by $2,400 (from $6,600 to $4,200). Firm Historical Emissions (Tons/yr) Marginal Abatement Cost ($/Ton) Initial Permit Holdings Permits Sold Permits Bought Final Permit Holdings Required Emission Reduction Emission Abatement Cost Apache 50 12 25 25 0 0 50 $600 BP 50 18 25 25 0 0 50 $900 Chevron 50 24 25 25 0 0 50 $1200 Devon 50 30 25 25 0 0 50 $1500 Exxon 50 36 25 0 25 50 0 $0 First Texas 50 42 25 0 25 50 0 $0 Gulf 50 48 25 0 25 50 0 $0 Hess 50 54 25 0 25 50 0 $0 Industry Total 400 200 100 100 400 200 $4,200 Note that cost of purchasing permits equals revenues from selling permits and so add no additional costs. Lets set the equilibrium permit price at $33. Firm Initial Pollution Reduction Final Pollution Requirement Marginal Abatement Cost ($/Ton) Abatement Cost Additions/ Savings Permits Bought Permits Sold Permit Cost/Permit Revenue Net Gain Apache 25 50 (+25) 12 $300 0 25 -$825 -$525 BP 25 50 (+25) 18 $450 0 25 -$825 -$375 Chevron 25 50 (+25) 24 $600 0 25 -$825 -$225 Devon 25 50 (+25) 30 $750 0 25 -$825 -$75 Exxon 25 0 (-25) 36 -$900 25 0 $825 -$75 First Texas 25 0 (-25) 42 -$1050 25 0 $825 -$225 Gulf 25 0 (-25) 48 -$1200 25 0 $825 -$375 Hess 25 0 (-25) 54 -$1350 25 0 $825 -$525 Industry Total 200 200 -$2,400 200 200 $0 -$2,400 The consumer/producer surplus represents the gains by all firms $ Per Unit Pollution Reduction $54 Hess Hess Gulf $48 S Gulf $525 First $42 First $375 $225 Exxon $36 Exxon $75 $33 $30 $225 Devon Devon $375 $24 Chevron $525 Chevron $75 BP $18 $12 Apache BP Apache D Quantity of Emissions Reduction We could do this numerically as well… QS 3P QD 100 2P Every $1 increase in price lowers demand by 2 units QD QS 100 2P 3P 100 5P P $20 In Equilibrium Price S Every $1 increase in price raises supply by 3 units QD 100 220 60 QS 320 60 $20 D Quantity 60 Consumer and producer surplus give us a numerical value of a marketplace… QS 3P QD 100 2P Note: a $50 price will set quantity demanded equal to zero. Price S Consumer Surplus 1 CS 60 $50 $20 $900 2 $50 $900 $20 $600 Producer Surplus 1 PS 60$20 $0 $600 2 D $0 Quantity 60 Demand is not simply a function of price, but is, instead, a function of many variables “Is a function of” QD DP,... •Income •Prices of other goods (Substitutes vs. Compliments) •Tastes •Future Expectations •Number of Buyers Price Demand Shifters Example: Increase in Demand At the initial price of $10, but with a new value for one of the demand shifters, quantity demanded has risen to 120 (An increase in demand) Price Holding all the demand shifters constant at some level, quantity demanded at a price of $10 is 100 $10 D(.’.) D(…) Quantity 100 120 Example: How would the loss in income during the last recession impact the hotel industry? S ... Rate per night At the current $150 market price, supply is still 50,000, but with a lower level of income, demand has fallen to 40,000 $150 DI $50,000 40,000 50,000 DI $75,000 # of Rooms At the new income level of $50,000, $150 can no longer be the equilibrium price Example: How would the loss in income during the last recession impact the hotel industry? S ... Rate per night $150 $125 DI $50,000 45,000 50,000 DI $75,000 # of Rooms The decrease in income (which causes a decrease in demand) causes a drop in sales and a drop in market price QS 4 P QD 80 2P 7 I Every $1 increase in income increases demand by 7 units With I = $20 With I = $10 80 2P 720 4P 80 2P 710 4P 220 6P 150 6P P $25 Q 80 P $36.67 Q 147 Price Price S S $36.67 The $10 increase in income raises demand by 70 $25 $25 D D Quantity 80 Quantity 80 147 Supply is not simply a function of price, but is, instead, a function of many variables “Is a function of” QS DP,... Price Supply Shifters Example: Decrease in Supply •Technology Marginal costs •Input prices •Number of sellers Holding all the supply shifters constant at some level, quantity supplied at a price of $10 is 100 At the initial price of $10, but with a new value for one of the supply shifters, quantity demanded has fallen to 80 Price S(.’.) S(…) $10 Quantity 80 100 Example: How would a drop in the wage rate in Columbia influence the price of coffee? Price per pound S w $8 S w $6 $5 D... Pounds 10,000 At the current $5 market price, supply has risen to 18,000, but demand is still at 10,000 18,000 At the wage level of $6, $5 can no longer be the equilibrium price Example: How would a drop in the wage rate in Columbia influence the price of coffee? Price per pound S w $8 S w $6 $5 $4 D... Pounds 10,000 16,000 The lower wage (which causes an increase in supply) , results in a lower price and higher sales QS 4P .5w QD 80 2P Every $1 increase in wages decreases supply by .5 units With w = $20 With w = $10 80 2P 4P .520 80 2P 4P .510 90 6P 85 6P P $14.16 Q 52 P $15 Q 50 Price Price S S $15 $14.16 The $10 increase in wages lowers supply by 5 $14.16 D D Quantity 52 Quantity 50 52 Demand curves slope downwards – this reflects the negative relationship between price and quantity. Elasticity of Demand measures this effect quantitatively %QD 20 D 2 % P 10 Price 2.75 2.50 *100 10% 2.50 $2.75 $2.50 DI $50,000 Quantity 4 5 45 *100 20% 5 Note that elasticities vary along a linear demand curve Price Q 100 2 P P Q $35 30 $34 32 $20 60 $19 62 $10 80 $9 82 D 2.3 D .61 % Change in Q % Change in P Elasticity 6.7 -2.9 -2.3 $35 $20 3.3 -5 -.61 2.5 -10 -.255 D 30 0 -1 %QD QD P D %P P QD -2 -3 -4 -5 -6 Slope -7 -8 -9 -10 12 20 28 80 60 36 44 52 60 68 76 84 Quantity 92 100 Supply curves slope upwards – this reflects the positive relationship between price and quantity. Elasticity of Supply measures this effect quantitatively Price 3.00 2.00 *100 50% 2 . 00 S $3.00 $2.00 Quantity 200 %QS 25 s .5 %P 50 250 250 200 *100 25% 200 Example: What effect would a shutdown of oil production in Iran have on oil prices? Yom Kippur war oil embargo Iranian Revolution/ Iran Iraq War OPEC Cuts Gulf War 911 PDVSA Strike Iraq War Asian Expansion Price in 2010 = $67 Iran produces around 4M Barrels per day. This represents around 4% of the total world supply. We also know that the elasticity of demand for oil is around -.05 % QD D % P With a little rearranging… %P %QD D 4 % P 80 .05 $67(1.80) = $120 It would be foolish to consider the entire oil market as perfectly competitive, but perhaps considering the non-OPEC market as perfectly competitive market is not entirely crazy Country Joined OPEC Production (Bar/D) Algeria 1969 2,180,000 Angola 2007 2,015,000 Ecuador 2007 486,100 Iran 1960 3,707,000 Iraq 1960 There are around 100 Non-OPEC countries producing collectively 55 Million Bar/D. Country Production (BBD) Russia 9,810,000 United States 8,514,000 China 3,795,000 India 3,720,000 Canada 3,350,000 2,420,000 Kuwait 1960 2,274,000 Libya 1962 1,875,000 Nigeria 1971 2,169,000 Qatar 1961 797,000 Saudi Arabia 1960 10,870,000 United Arab Emirates 1967 3,046,000 Venezuela 1960 2,643,000 Suppose that we consider the following supply demand model: Demand Competitive Supply Qd a bP Qs c dP Parameters to be estimated OPEC Supply Qs 35 Parameters to be estimated To estimate four parameters, we need four pieces of information Variable 2010 Value Market Price $67 Market Quantity (Bar/D) 90M OPEC Supply 35M Non-OPEC Supply (Bar/D) 55M Elasticity of Supply (Bar/D) .10 Elasticity of Demand -.05 Let’s start with the demand side first. We can relate the equilibrium elasticity to the parameter ‘b’ %Qd Qd P d %P P Qd Qd a bP The parameter ‘b’ represents the change in quantity demanded per dollar change in price P d b Qd A little rearranging… Variable 2010 Value Market Price $67 Market Quantity (Bar/D) 90M OPEC Supply 35M Non-OPEC Supply (Bar/D) 55M Elasticity of Supply (Bar/D) .10 Elasticity of Demand -.05 Qd b d P 90 b .05 .067 67 Now that we know ‘b’, we can find ‘a’ Qd a .067 P Again, a little rearranging… a Qd .067 P a 90 .06767 94.5 Variable 2010 Value Market Price $67 Market Quantity (Bar/D) 90M OPEC Supply 35M Non-OPEC Supply (Bar/D) 55M Elasticity of Supply (Bar/D) .10 Elasticity of Demand -.05 Qd 94.5 .067 P We are halfway home! Repeat the process with the supply side. We can relate the equilibrium elasticity to the parameter ‘d’ %Qs Qs P s %P P Qs Qs c dP The parameter ‘c’ represents the change in quantity supplied per dollar change in price P s d Qs A little rearranging… Variable 2010 Value Market Price $67 Market Quantity (Bar/D) 90M OPEC Supply 35M Non-OPEC Supply (Bar/D) 55M Elasticity of Supply (Bar/D) .10 Elasticity of Demand -.05 Qs d s P 55 d .10 .082 67 We’re estimating the non-OPEC supply, so be sure to use only the non-OPEC quantity! Now that we know ‘d’, we can find ‘c’ Qs c .082P Again, a little rearranging… c Qs .082P c 55 .08267 49.5 Variable 2010 Value Market Price $67 Market Quantity (Bar/D) 90M OPEC Supply 35M Non-OPEC Supply (Bar/D) 55M Elasticity of Supply (Bar/D) .10 Elasticity of Demand -.05 Qs 49.5 .082P That’s it! Suppose that we consider the following supply demand model: Demand Competitive Supply Qd 94.5 .067 P Qs 49.5 .082P OPEC Supply Qs 35 Let’s double check our results Qd Qs 94.5 .067 P 35 49.5 .082 P 10 .149 P P $67 Variable 2010 Value Market Price $67 Market Quantity (MBar/D) 90 Qd 94.5 .06767 90 Now, back to the original question. Suppose that Iran’s oil supply is shut down. OPEC supply drops by 4 BBD Demand Competitive Supply Qd 94.5 .067 P Qs 49.5 .082P OPEC Supply Qs 31 Now factor that into the Supply/Demand Model Qd Qs 94.5 .067 P 31 49.5 .082 P 14 .149 P P $94 Qd 94.5 .06794 88 Variable Market Price $94 Market Quantity (Bar/D) 88 Now, back to the original question. Suppose that Iran’s oil supply is shut down. OPEC supply drops by 4 BBD Price S Variable P' $120 P' $94 P* $67 D' 86 88 90 Market Price $94 Market Quantity (BBD) 88 OPEC Quantity 31 Non-OPEC Quantity 57 D Quantity The drop in OPEC supply pushes price up which gives non-OPEC countries the incentive to increase supply Partial Equilibrium vs. General Equilibrium Price Suppose that effective advertising increased the demand for lemonade. What would happen. S P* D' D Q * Quantity A rise in demand should increase sales and increase the price right? Is that all? Partial equilibrium deals with a disturbance in one market. General Equilibrium recognizes that markets interact with one another and looks at the interrelations between markets Price S A rise in demand for lemonade should increase sales and increase the price. P* D' Sugar Price Lemons S Price S D Q * Quantity D Quantity This increase in marginal costs should lower supply, right! The rise in lemonade sales should raise demand for lemons and sugar which increases their prices D Quantity Where would you rather live? South Bend or Chicago? Why? What’s better in Chicago? What’s better in South Bend? Pretty much everything is better in Chicago! It’s cheaper in South Bend! The indifference principle states that once everything is accounted for, every city must be equally desirable. Otherwise, who would choose to live in an inferior city. Lets say that the key advantage to South Bend is its low housing costs. If Chicago was still preferred, South Bend residents would start moving to Chicago – this will magnify the benefits of South Bend (cheaper housing) Median Home Price Chicago Housing Market Median Home Price South Bend Housing market S S $238,000 $86,000 D D Houses The difference between housing costs should just offset any advantages Chicago has! Houses Renting vs. Buying a House….what’s the better move? Median Home Price South Bend Rental Market Median Rent South Bend Housing market S S $600 $120,000 D D Houses Suppose that the median rental rate is $600 per month ($7200 per year) and the current mortgage rate is 6% Rentals P $7200 $120,000 .06 Can you spot the housing bubble? Easy financing, low interest rates, and expectations of housing price increases created an artificial spike in housing demand… Housing prices appreciation (2003-2007): 9%/yr Median Home Price US Housing market Housing price appreciation (2003-2010): 2%/yr S 2003 $262,000 $210,000 $185,000 D2007 D2010 D2003 Expectations of future price increases drives housing demand up… Expectations of price decreases drives demand back down Houses ….but that demand spike didn’t last. Question: Are we in an ‘Education Bubble”? Can we really justify the rapidly rising costs of college tuition or are students getting in over their heads taking out loans that they will never be able to afford? High School Labor Force College Educated Labor Force Salary S Salary S $38,000 $26,000 D D Employees Employees Universities Tuition S Can these markets be in equilibrium? $15,000 D Enrollment Consider the earnings across different ages and different education levels. Age Group Attainment 25-29 30-34 35-39 40-44 45-49 50-54 55-59 College $43,121 $55,440 $62,244 $65,973 $66,280 $64,254 $65,240 High School $28,097 $31,366 $33,443 $35,283 $36,316 $35,270 $37,573 Differential $15,024 $24,074 $28,801 $30,690 $29,964 $28,984 $27,667 x5 = $75,120 x5 = $120,370 x5 x5 x5 x5 x5 =$926,020 = $144,005 = $153,450 = $149,820 = $144,920 = $138,335 PV $15,024 $15,024 $27,667 ... $350,386 4 5 39 1.05 1.05 1.05 Lets assume that you could earn 5% elsewhere You receive the first payment 4 years from now This isn’t really right because you don’t get all this money up front What are the costs of going to college? Cost Annual Expense Tuition $15,000 Lost Wages $26,000 Books, Fees, etc $1,000 Room & Board $5,000 $36,000 x 4 = $164,000 Note: we really should discount these costs as well! This is not a relevant cost…you would have paid this anyways!!! So, a college education costs $164,000 and yields $350,386 in (discounted) lifetime benefits! Seems worth it! PV $15,024 $15,024 $27,667 ... $350,386 4 5 39 1.05 1.05 1.05 Alternatively, we can think about the annual salary differential for a college graduate like the annual payout on a bond. The annual return to a college education would be like calculating the return necessary so that the PV of the wage differential equals the cost Cost Annual Expense Tuition $15,000 Lost Wages $20,000 Books, Fees, etc $1,000 PV $15, 024 1 i 4 $36,000 x 4 = $164,000 Note: we really should discount these costs as well! $15, 024 1 i 5 ... Annual return $27, 667 1 i 39 $164, 000 i 11% Thought of as an investment, a college education pays 11% per year!! High School Labor Force College Education Labor Force Salary S Salary S $38,000 $26,000 D D Employees Employees Universities Tuition If the costs of college were truly less than the benefits, we would see more people go to school S Wage differentials would fall and college tuitions would increase $15,000 D Enrollment High School Labor Force College Education Labor Force Salary S Salary S $38,000 $26,000 D D Employees Employees Universities Tuition What we are seeing is a steady increase in demand for skilled labor as demand for unskilled labor falls S Wage differentials continue to increase as college tuitions increase $15,000 D Enrollment In the years following a divorce, statistics show that the woman’s living standard falls 27% while the man’s living standard rises by 10% Feminists such as Patricia Ireland (NOW) would argue that this proves divorce is unfair to women Couldn’t you just as easily argue that marriage is unfair to men? On December 22, 2001, Richard Reid was arrested trying to blow up an American Airlines flight from Paris to Miami with a bomb hidden in his shoes. Many human rights groups have fought heavily against the practice of racial profiling by airline security Isn’t there a better way to secure the safety of our airplanes? (Hint: could we create a marketplace?) Paul “Freck” Morgan started a website in 2001 offering a $20 Pay Per View event…..to watch him cut off his feet with a homemade guillotine. Note: The site turned out to be a hoax…Paul never actually went through with it! How should we feel about this entrepreneurial effort? (i.e. could we/should we repress this market?)