David S. Bullock University of Illinois Dept. of Consumer and Agricultural Economics Dangers of Using Political Preference Functions in Political Economy Analysis: Examples from U.S. Ethanol Policy Paper prepared for presentation at the 16th ICABR Conference, ‘The Political Economy of the Bioeconomy: Biotechnology and Biofuel’ June 26, 2012 Ravello, Italy I. PPF Political preference function approach. • Rausser and Freebairn (1974) • Empirically measure political power of interest groups. Many studies followed: • Paarlberg and Abbott (1986) • Lianos and Rizopoulos 1988) • Oehmke and Yao (1990) And continue to be published: • • • • • • • • • • • Rausser and Goodhue (2002) Redmond (2003) Simon et al. (2003) Burton, Love, and Rausser (2004) Atici (2005) Atici and Kennedy (2005) Lence et al. (2005) Lee and Kennedy (2007) Francois, Nelson, and Pelkmans-Balaoing (2008) Rausser and Roland (2008) Ahn and Sumner (2009) Typical Results “Group A was 2.72 times as powerful as group B.” Two decades ago, von Cramon-Taubadel (1992) and then Bullock (1994) published serious critiques of the PPF method. But, obviously, they had little impact on the literature This is largely my own fault. I have been known to write arcane papers. So here I present a step-bystep example of dangers of using the PPF approach. To do so, I develop a model of U.S. ethanol policy, and apply the PPF approach to it. The model is every bit as rich and descriptive of U.S. ethanol policy as are several that have recently been published in ag econ journals. The data I use are similar to those used in many other PPF models. I didn’t design this model with PPF methodology in mind. It’s just a model, like many other models in the policy literature. Multi-market, multi-policy-instrument model II. The Model I illustrate my arguments with a multi-market, multipolicy-instrument, partial equilibrium model of the U.S. ethanol policy. Crude Oil Corn-specific Refinery-specific Ethanol-specific land, capital, capital and labor capital and labor labor Petrofuel “Fuel” Livestock-specific land, capital, labor Biofuel Meat Labor (taxed for government revenues) Policy Instruments Modeled: Ten independent policy instruments tb, per-unit tax/subsidy on biofuel tg, per-unit tax/subsidy on petrofuel (gasoline) tc, per-unit tax/subsidy on corn to, per-unit tax/subsidy on crude oil tr, per-unit tax/subsidy on refiners and distributors ta, per-unit tax/subsidy on ethanol-specific resources tl, per-unit tax/subsidy on non-corn meat input resources (livestock) tf, per-unit tax/subsidy on fuel (retail) tm, per-unit tax/subsidy on meat qbman, (producers of “fuel” must use some minimum amount of biofuel) One dependent policy instrument: tw (tax on labor). Biofuels policy must be paid for. Interest groups At most disaggregated: •Corn suppliers •Crude oil suppliers •Oil Refiners/Distributors •Suppliers of ethanol-specific resources (think ADM) •Livestock suppliers •Labor suppliers (“employees”) •Labor demanders (“employers”) •Consumers of fuel and meat Leontief production technologies (goods produced by zero-profit firms): Biofuel qr Petrofuel qcm qa Non-corn biofuel resources Meat Corn to meat Corn to biofuel Refining and distribution qcb ql qo Crude oil Livestock Simple model of fuel production: petrofuel and biofuel are perfect substitutes in the production of “fuel.” Fuel Petrofuel qg qb Biofuel Feasible Welfare Manifolds Concept central to understanding PPF methodology: welfare manifolds. I discuss feasible welfare manifolds in detail in another paper. Framework n+1 interest groups: Group 0: government Groups 1, …, n: other interest groups Government’s strategies involve policy instruments x2 (Production mandate) X, set of feasible policies x´ A particular policy x1 Per-unit biofuels subsidy (tax if < 0) A vector of market parameters , (supply and demand elasticities, perhaps) Group i’s welfare depends on government policy: ui = hi(x, ), i = 0,1, … , n. Payoff vector function h maps set of feasible policies into “welfare space.” u = h(x, ) = (h0(x, ), h1(x,),…, , hn(x,)) Every place the government can send the interest groups u2 x2 h(x) X h(x´) x´ x1 H{1,2}(X) “feasible welfare manifold” {1,2} here is the set of utility-bearing groups u1 Welfare manifolds are a generalization of Josling’s (1974) and Gardner’s (1983) surplus transformation curves. “feasible welfare manifold” “feasible welfare submanifold” u2 x2 H{1,2}(T) h(x´) X T x´ x1 H{1,2}(X) u1 {1,2} here is the set of utility-bearing groups III. PPF Results using the model A. One policy instrument, two interest groups “Everybody else’s” welfare Increase ethanol tax or decrease ethanol subsidy If in PPF model we assume ethanol tax/subsidy is the only instrument: Status quo policy result: (∆U1, ∆U2) = (0, 0) Corn farmer/ethanol producer welfare Decrease ethanol tax or increase ethanol subsidy PPF weights would be: Political power “Everybody else’s” welfare weights: Farmers/ethanol producers: 0.514 Corn/ethanol industry: 0.514 Everyone else: 0.486 0.486 Everyone else: Corn farmer/ethanol producer welfare Slope = -1.059 Interpretation: “The corn/ethanol industry is just a little bit more powerful than the rest of society.” Say we had observed an ethanol tax of $1.00/gal. What would our PPF method say that the political power weights were? “Everybody else’s” welfare B Slope = -0.93 Political Power Weights Corn/ethanol industry: 0.482 Everybody else: 0.518 Because their weight droped by 0.03, corn/ethanol industry loses about $23 billion. Corn farmer/ethanol producer welfare “Everybody else’s” welfare Say we had observed an ethanol subsidy of $1.50/gal. What would our PPF method say that the political power weights were? Slope = -1.22 Corn farmer/ethanol producer welfare Political Power Weights Corn/ethanol industry: 0.551 Everybody else: 0.449 Compared to status quo, corn/ethanol industry gains about $42 billion. C D So what seems like a fairly small change in political power weights leads to a huge change in transfers! “Everybody else’s” welfare Corn farmer/ethanol producer welfare Reason: the welfare submanifold is nearly linear. What if instead of looking at the ethanol tax/subsidy, we decided to look at the gasoline tax? To a point, raising the gasoline tax improves the welfare of both groups! Status quo What’s going on? Higher gas tax allows a lower labor tax, less distortion. Positive slope! But “negative” political power weight means that government can’t be solving the max problem. Now say we assume that the policy instrument is the ethanol mandate: Increasing the mandate benefits the corn/ethanol industry, but hurts everyone else. “True” political power Your measurement of political power A little weird: surplus transformation curve is not concave. If you measure the slope to get a political power measurement, you may be using the wrong measure, because the actual solution might be a corner solution. “Everybody else’s” welfare Using instruments separately petrofuel tax/subsidy Corn farmer/ethanol Better how are these instruments best that even a very good question? Is one question: ofIsthese instruments “better” than the producer welfare combined? others? biofuel use mandate biofuel tax/subsidy Also, it should be clear that the political power measure obtained from PPF methodology very much depends on which instruments are modeled. B. Two instruments, two interest groups else’s” Instruments“Everybody used simultaneously: welfare •biofuel tax/subsidy •Petro-fuel tax/subsidy Corn farmer/ethanol producer welfare Result: 2-dimensional welfare manifold else’s” Most PPF“Everybody studies just assume away this welfare problem by having the number of interest groups be 1 more than the number of policy instruments in their models. But then the “observed” policy outcome will almost never be Pareto efficient, and therefore you can’t get PPF Corn farmer/ethanol producer welfare C. Three instruments, two interest groups “Everybody else’s” welfare Instruments used simultaneously: •biofuel tax/subsidy •petrofuel tax/subsidy •biofuel use mandate If we allow the third instrument to be used, and Corn farmer/ethanol producer our model has two interest groups, this justwelfare expands the welfare manifold, and we still can’t get PPF weights from the observed policy. D. Two instruments, three interest groups And if we disaggregate the interest groups a little more, it changes the whole picture: a 2-dimension manifold in 3-space: Now we can get PPF weights again… Welfare submanifold when only the petrofuel tax/subsidy and the biofuel tax/subsidy are used E. Three instruments, three interest groups “Everybody else’s” welfare Corn farmer/ biofuel producer welfare Petrofuel producers’ welfare unon-intervention Allowing the use of another policy instrument changes the whole picture again. Now we have 3 instruments and 3 interest groups. Again, an “observed” policy will take us to an interior point in the welfare manifold. Result: Can’t get PPF weights. Conclusions • The best way to measure the “political power” of interest groups is by examining the sizes of the transfers brought about by policy, not by measuring the slopes of a contrived surplus transformation manifold at a contrived “observed” point. Conclusions • Like this: “Group A received $x, which was taken from group B, which lost $y.” • Not this: “Group A’s political power weight is 0.xx and group B’s is (1 – 0.xx).”