.
• Typically a 3-step game of incomplete info
Step 1: Principal designs mechanism/contract
Step 2: Agents accept/reject the mechanism
Step 3: Agents that have accepted, play the game specified by mechanism
• Constant theme: Incomplete information and binding individual rationality constraints prevent efficient outcomes
• A monopolist produces good at marginal cost c and sells quantity q
• Consumer transfers T to seller and has utility u
1
( q , T , θ)= θ V ( q )T , V (0)=0, V / >0, V // <0
• θ is private knowledge for buyer
• The game:
1. Seller offers tariff T ( q ): specifies a price for qty q
2. Consumer accepts/rejects
• If seller knows θ, she will charge T = θ V ( q ), her profit, θ V ( q )cq. This is maximized at some q given by θ V / ( q )= c
• Seller’s expected profit:
Eu
0
• Seller faces two constraints: p ( T
c q )
p ( T
c q )
1. Individual Rationality ( IR ): Consumer should be willing to purchase
2. Incentive Compatibility ( IC ): Consumer should consume the bundle intended for his type
• IR
1
:
V ( q )
• IC
1
:
V ( q )
T
T
0 ; and IR
2
:
V ( q )
T
V ( q )
T
0
; and IC
2
:
V ( q )
T
V ( q )
T
• First step: To show that only IR
1 and IC
2 are binding
• First note: IR
1 and IC
2 imply IR
2
• IR
2 can’t be binding unless =0
• However, IR
1 must bind. Else seller can increase
T & T by same amount and increase revenue
• Also, IC
2 must be binding, else seller can increase
T , satisfy all constraints and increase revenue
• The high-type’s indifference curve is always steeper than the low type’s for any allocation
• This implies that high type consumes more than low type: q
q
• Eliminating transfers, principal’s objective function is: max {([ q , q p
p (
)] V ( q )
p c q )
p (
V ( q )
c q )}
• FOC wrt q :
V
/
( q )
c /( 1
p (
p
)
)
• FOC wrt q :
V
/
( q )
c
• Check that IC
1 is satisfied
• Note: Quantity purchased by high-type is optimal
Quantity purchased by low-type is sub-optimal
• Seller sacrifices efficiency for rent-extraction!
• Seller has unit of good and there are two bidders
p
• Buyer’s expected probability of getting the good are
X & X and payments are T & T
• The constraints are:
IR
1
:
X
T
0 ; IR
2
:
IC
1
:
X
T
X
T
; IC
2
:
X
T
0
X
T
X
T
• What is seller’s optimal contract?
• Seller’s expected profit is: p T
p T
• Again, IR
1 and IC
2 are binding. The seller’s profit:
Eu
0
(
p
) X
p
X
• Also, ex-ante prob of a player getting good, p X
p X
• Moreover,
X
p
p
2
1
2
• Case 1: p
. The seller sets and X
p
p
2
Optimal mechanism: Not to sell if both announce low-type; sell to hightype if they announce different types; sell wp ½ to each if both announce high type
p
X
p
p
2
Optimal mechanism: Sell to high-type if bidders announce different types, and sell wp ½ to each if they both announce high-type or low-type
•Consider a Principal and an agent who can exert costly effort, e
•Agent receives transfer, t, and has utility;
U=u(t)ψ(e), with u / >0, u // <0.
•Production is stochastic, and production level, q
{ q , q } , q
q
• Stochastic influence of effort on production:
Pr{ q
q e
0 }
0
; Pr{ q
q e
1 }
1
,
1
0
• Principal can offer a contract, {t( )}, that depends on observed, random output t q
• Let Principal’s profit with qty q be S(q)
• His profit when agent expends effort e=0 is:
V
0
0
[ S ( q )
t ]
( 1
0
)[ S ( q )
t ]
• His profit when agent expends effort e=1 is:
V
1
1
[ S ( q )
t ]
( 1
1
)[ S ( q )
t ]
• Induce positive effort and ensure participation
• Incentive constraint :
1 u ( t )
( 1
1
) u ( t )
0 u ( t )
( 1
0
) u ( t )
• Participation constraint :
1 u ( t )
( 1
1
) u ( t )
0
• Complete info or First-Best: Principal observes effort
• Principal’s problem is: max
{( t , t )}
1
( S
t )
( 1
1
)( S
t ) subject to:
1 u ( t )
( 1
1
) u ( t )
0
• Using Lagrangian, μ, and from FOCs we have,
u
/
1
( t
*
)
1
( t
*
)
0 u
/
• From the above equations, we have that: t
* t
* t
*
• Thus, Agent obtains full insurance!
• The optimal transfer is: t * = u -1 ( ψ)=h(ψ), where h=u -1
• When there is complete information
• Principal’s profit from inducing effort e=1:
V
1
=
1
S
( 1
1
) S
h (
)
• If agent exerted 0 effort, principal would earn:
V
0
=
0
S
( 1
0
) S
• Inducing effort is optimal for principal if:
S
h (
)
, where
1
0
;
S
S
S
• Principal’s First-Best cost of inducing effort is: h(ψ)
• Agent is risk-averse
• Principal’s problem, P, is:
• (P): max
{( t , t )}
1
( S
t )
( 1
1
)( S
t ) subject to:
1 u ( t )
( 1
1
) u ( t )
0 , and
1 u ( t )
( 1
1
) u ( t )
0 u ( t )
( 1
0
) u ( t )
• First ensure concavity of (P): Let u
u ( t ); u
u ( t )
• The Principal’s program can be rewritten in terms of utilities
• (P / ): max
{( u , u )}
1
( S
h ( u ))
( 1
1
)( S
h ( u )) subject to :
1 u
( 1
1
) u
1 u
( 1
1
) u
0 u
( 1
0
) u
0
• Principal’s objective function is concave in ( u , u ) because h(.) is convex, and the constraints are linear
• The KKT conditions are necessary and sufficient
• Let λ & μ be Lagrange multipliers for IC & IR
• The FOCs, upon rearranging terms, are:
1 u
/
( t
SB
)
1
1
; u
/
( t
SB
)
1
1 where, t
SB
, t
SB are second-best optimal transfers
• From these,
1
1 u
/
( t
SB
)
1 u
/
( t
SB
)
0 , so IR is binding
• Also,
1
( 1
1
) 1
( u
/
( t
SB
)
1 u
/
( t
SB
)
)
0
, so IC is binding
• The variables (
SB t , t
SB
, λ, μ ) are solved simultaneously from two FOCs, IC and IR
•
• The second-best optimal transfers are: t
SB h (
( 1
1
)
); t
SB h (
t
SB t
SB
1 t
1
)
: contract does not provide full insurance
• 2 nd Best cost of inducing effort: C SB =
SB
( 1
1
) t
SB
• Clearly, for the Principal, C SB > C FB . So Principal induces high effort (e=1) less often than in first-best
• There is under-provision of effort in the second-best
• Agent’s type
[
,
] with distribution/density P (
) / p (
)
• Type-contingent allocation is fn.
y (
)
( x (
), t (
• Defn: A decision function x :
X if
)) there exists a transfer t (.) such that allocation y (.) is incentive-compatible, i.e.
u
1
( y (
),
)
u
1
( y (
ˆ
),
),
(
,
ˆ
)
[
,
]
[
,
]
• Theorem: A piecewise C 1 decision fn x (.) is implementable only if k n
1
(
u
1
u
1
/
/
x k
t
) dx k d
0 whenever x
x (
), t
t (
) and x is differentiable at θ
• Sketch of proof: Type
ˆ
(
ˆ
,
)
u
1
( x (
ˆ
), t (
ˆ
),
)
The FOC and SOC are
(
ˆ
,
)
0 ,
2
(
ˆ
2
,
)
0
Totally differentiating the first equation,
2
(
ˆ
2
,
)
2
(
ˆ
,
)
0
The (local) SOC becomes k n
1
u
1
x k
dx k d
u
1
t dt d
0
2
(
,
ˆ
)
0
Rewrite the FOC we get, k n
1
u
1
x k
dx k d
Eliminating, dt / d θ, k n
{[
1
u
1
x k
u
1
t
u
1
t
or,
u
1
t dt d
0
u
1
x k
] /
u
1
t
} dx d
k
0
• The sorting / single crossing / constant sign (CS) condition is:
u
1
u
1
/
/
x k
t
0
• Note that
u
1
u
1
/
/
x
t k is agent’s marginal rate of substitution between decision k and transfer t
• Consider x to be output supplied by agent, i.e.,
u
1
x
0
• Then sorting condition means that the agent’s indifference curve in ( x , t ) space,
u
1
u
1
/
/
x
t
, is decreasing in θ
• If θ
2
> θ
1
, y ( θ
1
)=( x ( θ
1
), t ( θ
1
)), y ( θ
2
)=( x ( θ
2
), t ( θ
2
)), then y ( θ
2
)> y ( θ
1
)
• Theorem: If decision space is 1-dim and CS holds, then a necessary condition for x (.) to be implementable is that it is monotonic.
• What about sufficiency?
• The assumptions:
A1: u
A2: Quasi-linear utilities:
Principal: u
0
( x, t, θ )= V
0
( x, θ )t ; Agent: u
1
( x, t, θ )= V
1
( x, θ )+ t
A3: n=1, i.e., decision is 1-dim and CS holds.
2
V
1
x
0
A4:
V
1
0
A5:
2
V
0
x
0
A6:
3 V
1
x
2
0 , &
x 2
3 V
1
0
• The problem: Principal maximizes his expected utility
{ x max
(
), t (
)}
E
u
0
( x (
), t (
),
) subject to: (IR) u
1
( x ( θ ), t ( θ ), θ u θ
(IC) u
1
( x ( θ ), t ( θ ), θ )≥ u
1
( x (
ˆ
), t (
ˆ
),
)
(
,
ˆ
)
• Let
U
1
(
)
max
ˆ
u
1
( x (
), t (
),
) u
1
( x (
ˆ
), t (
ˆ
),
)
u u
1
( x (
), t (
),
)
0
• From Envelope theorem, dU
1 d
u
1
V
1
• This implies that,
U
1
(
)
u
V
1
( x
(
~
~
,
~
) d
~
• Further, u
0
= V
0
+ V
1
- U
1
≡ Social surplus-
• Principal’s objective function:
Agent’s utility
[ V
0
( x (
),
)
V
1
( x (
),
)
V
1
( x
~
(
~
),
~
) d
~
] p (
) d
[ V
0
( x (
),
)
V
1
( x (
),
)
1
P (
p (
)
)
V
1
( x (
),
)
] p (
) d
• Since monotonicity is necessary and sufficient for implementability, Principal’s optimization program becomes max
{x(.)}
[ V
0
( x ,
)
V
1
( x ,
)
1
P (
p (
)
)
V
1
( x ,
)
] p (
) d
s.t. x (.) is monotonic
• We solve the principal’s program ignoring monotonicity
• The solution to the relaxed program is
V
0
x
V
1
x
1
P (
p (
)
)
2
V
1
x
• The principal faces a trade-off between maximizing total surplus ( V
0
+ V
1
) and appropriating the agent’s info rent ( U
1
)
• When is it legit to focus on relaxed program?
When solution x * ( θ) to above eq is monotonic. Differentiating,
(
2
V
0
x
2
2
V
1
x
2
1
P (
p (
)
)
x
2
3
V
1
) dx
* d
2
V
1
x
d
[ d
(
1
P p (
(
)
)
)
1 ]
2
V
0
x
1
P ( p (
)
)
3
V
1
x
2
When Hazard rate is monotone : d d
1
p (
P
)
(
)
0