US Growth Good Core US Growth Good ............................................................................................... Error! Bookmark not defined. US Growth Good Core ................................................................................................................................ 1 US Growth Good – Democracy ............................................................................................................... 2 US Growth Good – Econ Wars .................................................................................................................... 3 US Growth Good – Econ Wars ................................................................................................................ 4 US Growth Good – Environment ................................................................................................................ 6 US Growth Good – Environment ............................................................................................................ 7 US Growth Good - Environment ............................................................................................................. 9 US Growth Good – Environment – Tech Solves.................................................................................... 11 US Growth Good – Global Warming ......................................................................................................... 12 US Growth Good – Global Warming ..................................................................................................... 13 US Growth Good – Global Warming ..................................................................................................... 14 US Growth Good – Heg ............................................................................................................................. 16 US Growth Good - Heg ......................................................................................................................... 17 US Growth Good – Poverty ...................................................................................................................... 19 US Growth Good - Poverty ................................................................................................................... 20 US Growth Good – Racism........................................................................................................................ 21 US Growth Good - Racism .................................................................................................................... 22 US Growth Good – Resource Wars ........................................................................................................... 23 US Growth Good – AT Resource Wars .................................................................................................. 24 US Growth Good – Terrorism ................................................................................................................... 25 US Growth Good - Terrorism ................................................................................................................ 26 US Growth Good - Terrorism ................................................................................................................ 27 US Growth Good – US-China War............................................................................................................. 28 US Growth Good – US-China War......................................................................................................... 29 US Growth Good – Space ......................................................................................................................... 31 US Growth Good - Space ...................................................................................................................... 32 US Growth Good – Democracy Growth key to democracy William J Baumol, professor of economics at NYU, Robert E. Litan, Senior Fellow of Economic Studies at the Brookings Institute, and Carl J. Schramm, President and chief executive officer of the Kauffman Foundation,” 2007, Good Capitalism, Bad Capitalism, and the Economics of Growth and Prosperity Now, ask the question the other way around: does economic growth lead to democracy? Certainly the experience of South Korea, which for decades after World War II was essentially a benevolent autocracy but eventually became a democratic form of government, supports this viewGlaeser et al., 2004). As incomes grow, so does a country’s middle class, which is more likely and able to demand political freedom. Conversely, here is ample evidence that countries already democratic are likely to backslide from that form of government when their economies perform poorly. It is striking, for example, that three-fourths of the collapses of democracies since 1977 were preceded by stagnant growth.2° But skeptics remain about the inevitability of democracy following strong economic growth. China has become a flash point. To some, continued growth in China may only strengthen the hand of the state and make it easier to deny political freedom (Bueno de Mesquita and Downs, 2005). Or as China gains economic strength, it will have more resources to pursue expansionist military objectives. At this point, of course, it is impossible to know whether the optimists or pessimists will prove to be correct about China. Our own view is that the odds are with the optimists— namely, that economic growth eventually will help democratize China, as it will other countries—but there can be no guarantee of this result. One reason for being optimistic is to look to America’s early history and especially the experiences of many of the country’s founding fathers, which demonstrate that business skills can hone the talents needed to achieve and maintain self-governance. Benjamin Franklin, one of the authors of the Declaration of Independence, left copious writings describing how he had developed his diplomatic skills in the course of establishing himself as a printer. Paul Revere, a silversmith, was a consummate net- worker who used business contacts to coordinate the revolutionary effort. Alexander Hamilton, who managed a clerical office while still in his teens, later applied those skills to organize the Department of the Treasury. Even Thomas Jefferson, Hamilton’s adversary, who argued that America should remain a nation of farmers, was hardly the stereotypical rustic at the plow He managed a sizable plantation and sought more scientific ways to cultivate it. In short, he was much like the best American entrepreneurs: a striver and learner, often brimming with ego and unconventional opinions, but civicminded and, in the end, a farsighted philanthropist. In short, the experience of economic freedom seems to breed both the skills and the inclination for political freedom. China’s business leaders may not be able to steer their country in the same way. Butdoes that possibility mean that other countries—the United States, in particular—should do their best to thwart economic growth in China (or in other autocratically ruled countries, for that matter)? In our view, such a course is a recipe for a much more dangerous world. Autocrats who are shunned by rich countries would thus be given easy scapegoats for their countries’ poor economic performance The politics of “blaming foreigners” has a long and unfortunately successful history. Why give autocrats such easy ammunition? We believe the better course is to urge autocracies at least to recognize economic rights—in particular, the ability to start a business and to be rewarded if successful. The odds, in our view, suggest that political rights eventually will follow. US Growth Good – Econ Wars US Growth Good – Econ Wars Growth key to interdependence – solves all wars. ValentinKrustev, Department of Political Science at Rice University, 2006, “Interdependence and the Duration of Militarized Conflict,” Journal of Peace Research, sage According to the opportunity-cost argument, interdependence promotes peace by raising the costs of militarized conflict (Polachek, 1980; Polachek, Robst& Chang, 1999). Conflict becomes more costly, in turn, because the fighting parties, in addition to bearing the costs of waging warfare, forfeit the potential gains from trading, owing to government-imposed restrictions and increased business risks. However, these conflictinhibiting effects of interdependence are not limited only to the pre-conflict phase of a dispute, and the opportunity-cost argument can explain how the prospect of further trade losses provides incentives for conflict termination as well. As some scholars have observed, any theory of the effect of interdependence on conflict should be grounded in a solid understanding of the occurrence and dynamic of conflict itself (Morrow, 1999, 2003; Gartzke, 2003b). While traditionally multiple theories of conflict have proliferated in the study of IR, recent scholarship has drawn attention to its informational origins (Fearon, 1995; Gartzke, 1999). As Fearon (1995) argues, if most conflicts end in some negotiated settlement over the disputed issue, rational states should prefer to conclude that settlement prior to incurring the conflict costs, as the bargaining range of mutually acceptable settlements is guaranteed to be non-empty when these costs are positive. A very common reason for states sometimes being unable to reach a rational pre-conflict settlement emerges in the asymmetry of information, combined with states’ incentives to misrepresent their reservation values. Conflict, on the other hand, helps states to credibly communicate these reservation values by demonstrating their willingness to incur its costs or revealing the true magnitude of the costs, as an expanding informational literature on war suggests (e.g. Wagner, 2000; Filson& Werner, 2002; Slantchev, 2003). The opportunity-cost logic implies that interdependence can enter the theoretical framework outlined above through the conflict-cost parameters, as interdependence increases these costs. Following Fearon’s (1995) discussion, higher conflict costs increase the pre-conflict bargaining range and should, therefore, decrease the probability of conflict. In their calculus, states balance the size of their demands against the probability that these demands exceed the opponent’s reservation value and are rejected. Higher conflict costs due to greater interdependence worsen states’ conflict payoffs and push them to lower their demands, which, in turn, results in a reduced probability of conflict onset.8 Signaling arguments, on the other hand, suggest that interdependence allows states to credibly communicate their resolve or reservation values by severing an advantageous economic relationship that an unresolved state would not terminate.The credible communication made possible by interdependence reduces the uncertainty existing over the bargaining range and increases the likelihood of a settlement short of war (e.g. Gartzke, 2003a,b; Morrow, 2003). Thus, if we adopt Fearon’s (1997) terminology, signaling implies that interdependence allows states to ‘sink costs’, while the opportunitycost logic is more reminiscent of ‘tying hands’; that is, interdependence affects states’ behavior by changing their incentives. The opportunity-cost argument for why interdependence inhibits militarized conflict can be easily extended to account for the effect of interdependence on the duration of conflict. If interdependence raises the opportunity costs of conflict prior to its onset, then these costs should also remain high after onset, because, at least in the short term when firms have not permanently reoriented their business operations, they will gain if hostilities cease and normal trade with the adversary is restored. Then, just as the higher prospective costs of conflict push states to lower their demands and avert conflict prior to its onset, so do these higher prospective costs push states to settle early, even if conflict has not fully served its informational purpose and states might be forfeiting the better deal they can get if they know more. That is, the purpose of militarized conflict is to overcome asymmetric information, but conflict costs are the price states have to pay to extract that information. The higher these costs are due to interdependence, the sooner are states likely to settle on unfavorable more expensive the information-revelation process is, and the terms rather than continue fighting. Statistically proven Brock Blomberg, Professor of Economics at Wellesley College, Gregory Hess, Professor of Economics at Oberlin College, February 2002, “The Temporal Links between Conflict and Economic Activity,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, sage To begin this temporal “causal” investigation, we first need to develop a statistical framework to estimate the joint, dynamic determination of the occurrence of internal conflict, external conflict, and growth. Because conflict is measured as a discrete variable, researchers typically estimate the occurrence as a probability, or if we consider both internal and external conflict, we can always estimate the joint probability distribution. But are there similar interpretations of economic activity as a discrete state? Indeed, a broad literature considers the evolution of states in the economy as the natural progression of phases. In fact, one of the key historical studies of U.S. and international business cycles, undertaken by Burns and Mitchell (1944), treated the state of the economy as either an expansion or contraction, on which the National Bureau of Economic Research’s dating procedure for recessionswas founded.4 The relevance for our study is that breakpoints in the state of the economy, either expansion or recession, are analogous to break points in peace—internal or external conflicts.5 Using an unbalanced panel of data covering 152 countries from 1950 to 1992, we therefore consider the joint determination of internal conflict, external conflict, and the state of the economy as measured by the aforementioned discrete variables.We find that the relationship between the variables is not a simple one.Conflict does appear to be highly related to the economy for the entire sample.However, it seems to be most highly related when considering certain nation-groups. For nondemocracies or in regions highly populated by nondemocracies, there seems to be an intimate link between a poor economy and the decision to go to war—both internally and externally. These results confirm much of the original hypotheses put forth in Blomberg, Hess, and Thacker (2001)—namely, that there is compelling evidence of a conditional poverty-conflict trap. US Growth Good – Environment US Growth Good – Environment Economic growth is the only way to improve environmental quality George Economides, Assistant Professor of International and European Economic Studies, and ApostolisPhilippopoulos, Professor in the Department of Economics, Athens University of Economics and Business, 1-2008, “Growth enhancing policy is the means to sustain the environment,” Review of Economic Dynamics, vol 11 no 1, Science Direct Focusing on the long run, our results are as follows. First, the Ramsey government can lead the economy to sustainable balanced growth (namely, a situation in which the economy is capable of long-term growth without damaging the environment). Thus, long-term growth is socially optimal. Second, and more interestingly, the more the representative citizen cares about the environment, the more growth-enhancing policies the Ramsey government finds it optimal to choose. Specifically, the more the citizen cares about the environment, the higher should be the share of tax revenue allocated to infrastructure vis-à-vis cleanup, the lower the income tax rate, and the higher the sustainable balanced growth rate. Third, contrary to the RSBA, in the FBA, the more the citizen cares about the environment, the more environmental friendly allocation of resources the social planner finds it optimal to choose. The intuition behind these results is as follows. In a second-best situation where private agents ignore externalities and policymakers lack lump-sum policy instruments, when private agents care about the environment, this requires extra revenue for cleanup policy and this can only be achieved by large tax bases and high growth. Ramsey-type policymakers realize all this and choose their policy instruments accordingly, in the sense that they give priority to growth. By contrast, in a first-best situation, the social planner first hits a relatively high growth rate, and in turn allocates some of the available social resources to the environment, where the degree of allocation increases with how much we value the environment relative to consumption or other goods. Therefore, not only there is no tradeoff between economic growth and environmental quality in the long run, but also only growing economies can afford to improve environmental quality. This is consistent with the general belief that to fund the governments’ policy goals on health, redistribution, the environment and the rest, we need tax receipts and this can be achieved by growth-enhancing policies.2 Dismantling the current economic system would ensure worse pollution and make a shift to solar power impossible Martin Lewis professor in the School of the Environment and the Center for International Studies at Duke University. Green Delusions, 1992 p 7 While such are the fantasies only of the most moonstruck extremists, even moderate radicals (if one may be permitted the oxymoron) espouse an ideology that would preclude the development of an ecologically sustainable economy. Most environmentalists, for instance, aver that a sustainable economy must be based on solar power. Yet the for total decentralization, deurbanization, economic autarky, a ban on most forms of high technology, and the complete dismantling of capitalism, would not only prevent future improvements in solar power but would actually destroy the gains that have already been made. While most radical greens embrace “appropriate technologies” (just as anti-environmentalists denounce “pollution”), their program would, if enacted, undercut the foundations of all technological research and development. Appropriate technology, in fact, often turns out to mean little more than well-engineered medieval apparatuses: radicals’ agenda, calling we may expect crude mechanical power from the wind, but certainly not electricity from the sun. Equally important, the systematic dismantling of large economic organizations in favor of small ones would likely result in a substantial increase in pollution, since few small-scale firms are able to devise, or afford, adequate pollution abatement equipment. US Growth Good - Environment Economic growth is key to improving the environment Sean Hackbarth, Communications Advisor for the Senate Republican Conference, 4-29-2007, “The Environment’s Best Friend: Economic Growth,” The American Mind, http://www.theamericanmind.com/2007/04/23/the-environments-best-friend-economicgrowth/ Did you know the air was getting cleaner before the first Earth Day in 1970? IndurGoklany writes, Between 1957 and 1970, particulate matter concentrations in urban areas declined 15 percent, while sulfur dioxide concentrations peaked in 1963, declining 40 percent between 1962 and 1969. Environmental diseases like malaria and typhoid decreased. How could it be that people decided to improve their environment without a call to action from environmental groups or government edict? We got richer. As the U.S. improved economically people no longer had to worry about making enough money to keep from starving and protected from the weather. With those needs satisfied people could move to satisfying desires that used to be luxuries. People got tired of smog-filled air, damaged lakes, and species near extinction. They reached a point where they could afford to protect their environment better. New technologies were employed to continue economic growth while reducing harm to the planet. The battle between the environment vs. the economy doesn’t exist. People need to reach a level of economic prosperity to care about cleaning up the world around them. Economic growth, then, is key to improving the environment. Free trade, well-defined property rights, and the rule of law won’t just make the impoverished better off, more healthy, and longerliving. It will give them the resources and desire to improve the environment. Capitalism and continued growth are the only way to generate the resources necessary for saving the environment and gaining social equality Martin Lewis professor in the School of the Environment and the Center for International Studies at Duke University. Green Delusions, 1992 p 19-20. As noted above, I believe that only a capitalist economy can generate the resources necessary for the development of a technologically sophisticated, ecologically sustainable global economy. In embracing capitalism I do not thereby advocate the laissez-faire approach of the Republican right. To say that the market plays an essential role is not to say that it should be given full sway. As Robert Kuttner (1991) persuasively argues, the laissez-faire ideology has actually placed shackles on the American economy; it has rather been the “social market” economies, like that of Germany, that have shown the greatest dynamism in the postwar period. Moreover, if the example of Japan teaches us anything, it should be that economic success stems rather from “combining free markets and individual initiative with social organization” (Thurow1985 :6o; emphasis added). At the same time, hard heads must always be matched with soft hearts (see Blinder 1987); we must never lose sight of social goals when working for economic efficiency or ecological stability But both social equity and environmental protection are, I will argue, more easily realized by working through rather than fighting against the market system and the corporate structure of late twentieth-century capitalism. Economic growth, environmental protection, and social welfare should be seen as positively rather than negatively linked; a society that demands strict pollution controls, for example, will be advantaged in industrial competition at the highest levels of technological sophistication, as will a society that continually upgrades its human resources by providing workers with skilled, well-paying jobs (Porter 1990). US Growth Good – Environment – Tech Solves Technology fixes can outpace environmental harm James GustaveSpeth, environmental NGO founder, environmental litigator, former think tank head, former environmental advisor to Jimmy Carter, former US Agency for International Development head, 2008 “The Bridge at the Edge of the World: Capitalism, the Environment, and Crossing from Crisis to Sustainability” Yale University Press A core belief of those who hold that we need not worry about growth per se, because we can green growth to acceptable levels, is that technological change of an environment-saving sort can be driven so rapidly that it more than compensates for the additional environmental stresses growth produces. The well-known “IPAT equation” helps in examining this proposition.7 I=PAT Environmental Impact=Population x Affluence x Technology This equation is actually an identity: Impact=Population x (GDP/Population) x (Impact/GDP) or Impact GDP X (Impact/GDP) where GDP per capita is a measure of affluence and where environ mental impact per dollar of GDP (or unit of output) is a reflection of the technology deployed in the economy. If GDP is going up at 3 percent a year, and if one wants to reduce environmental impacts greatly, then the environmental impacts of each dollar of GDP and each unit of economic output must decline at rates substantially in excess of 3 percent a year. To reduce environmental impacts faster than the economy is growing requires rapid technological change. That is why I and many others have called for policies that promote an environmental revolution in technology—an urgent ecological modernization of the economy that would include both the transformation of existing capital stocks and, through innovation and entrepreneurship, the creation of new environmentally friendly industries, products, and services.8 A major way to reduce pollution and consumption of natural resources while experiencing economic growth is to bring about a wholesale transformation in the technologies that today dominate manufacturing, energy, construction, transportation, and agriculture.The twentieth-century technologies that have contributed so abundantly to today’s problems should be phased out and replaced with twenty-first-century technologies designed with environmental sustainability and restoration in mind. The economy should be “dematerialized” to the fullest possible extent through a new generation of technologies that sharply reduces the consumption of natural resources and the generation of residual wastes per unit of economic output. US Growth Good – Global Warming US Growth Good – Global Warming Technological developments and market incentives solve warming better than curbing growth William J Baumol, professor of economics at NYU, Robert E. Litan, Senior Fellow of Economic Studies at the Brookings Institute, and Carl J. Schramm, President and chief executive officer of the Kauffman Foundation,” 2007, Good Capitalism, Bad Capitalism, and the Economics of Growth and Prosperity The same process of technological advance that undermined Malthus’s dire predictions may be able to quiet the concerns of the modern-day Malthusians who worry about disappearing energy, although more active involvement by governments may be necessary to address concerns about global warming. As some sources of energy are depleted—fossil fuels, in particular—their prices will rise, setting in motion several developments that will keep economies from stagnating. For one thing, consumers will cut back on their demand for fossil fuels directly (taking fewer trips, car- pooling, or even moving closer to work) or indirectly by buying things (cars, houses, and appliances) that are more energy-efficient. This occurred after the first postwar “energy crisis” of 1973. Energy use as a percentage of GDP in the United States has been cut in half largely as a result of higher prices, and it will continue to drop if fossil fuel prices (adjusted for inflation) rise in the future. Equally important, if prices of fossil fuels increase, the backers of substitute forms of energy (nuclear power, fusion, geothermal, biomass, solar, and possibly other sources) will have stronger incentives to perfect their technologies so that they can be readily used instead.4 As for global warming, there is a consensus among scientists that the problem is real and growing. Indeed, some scientists attribute the intense hurricane activity that devastated the Gulf states and parts of Florida during the 2005 season to warmer waters due to global warming. At the same time, there is an emerging consensus among economists and policy makers around the world that the best way to curb the carbon emissions that are contributing to global warming is to employ a mixture of rules and market- like incentives, perhaps the most promising being the establishment of ceilings on pollution by allocating suitably restricted limits on unavoidable emissions by producers and allowing these rights to be traded in markets.Thuspollution can be capped and growth can nevertheless continue. The “cap and trade” approach, applied globally, was the linchpin of the Kyoto agreement reached in the late 1990s but not yet implemented (due in large part to opposition by the United States). Although political and practical problems may inhibit the adoption of cap and trade on a global scale, it may be feasible on both grounds to implement the idea on a national basis.5 Those who doubt whether economic growth can continue if resources are devoted to reducing pollution need only look to the U.S. experience— where both the air and water are far cleaner today than thirty years ago, even with a substantially higher production of goods.6 If the same political energy that has so far fueled the “no growth” or “limits to growth” movements were channeled instead to persuading governments around the world to accept less socially damaging approaches, including a tradable emissions permit system, there is good reason to believe global warming concerns would be much attenuated US Growth Good – Global Warming Growth solves warming Terry L. Anderson, PhD economics, senior fellow at the Hoover Institution, adjunct professor at the Stanford Graduate School of Business, April 29 2004, “Why Economic Growth is Good for the Environment” http://www.perc.org/articles/article446.php In the March 2004 issue of Scientific American, National Aeronautics and Space Administration global-warming expert James Hansen notes that greenhouse gas emissions and global-warming projections are "consistently pessimistic." Hansen suggests that projections do not take into account the lower carbon dioxide and methane emissions that have resulted from technological advancements. He explains that the lower carbon dioxide emissions result from increased energy efficiency following the energy crisis in the 1970s and the lower methane emissions, from technological changes in agriculture. Hansen's essay concludes on an optimistic note, saying "the main elements [new technologies] required to halt climate change have come into being with remarkable rapidity." This statement would not have surprised economist Julian Simon. He saw the "ultimate resource" to be the human mind and believed it to be best motivated by market forces. Because of a combination of market forces and technological innovations, we are not running out of natural resources. As a resource becomes more scarce, prices increase, thus encouraging development of cheaper alternatives and technological innovations. Just as fossil fuel replaced scarce whale oil, its use will be reduced by new technology and alternative fuel sources. Market forces also cause economic growth, which in turn leads to environmental improvements. Put simply, poor people are willing to sacrifice clean water and air, healthy forests, and wildlife habitat for economic growth. But as their incomes rise above subsistence, "economic growth helps to undo the damage done in earlier years," says economist Bruce Yandle. "If economic growth is good for the environment, policies that stimulate growth ought to be good for the environment." The link between greenhouse gas emissions and economic prosperity is no different. Using data from the United States, Professor Robert McCormick finds that "higher GDP reduces total net [greenhouse gas] emissions." He goes a step further by performing the complex task of estimating net U.S. carbon emissions. This requires subtracting carbon sequestration (long-term storage of carbon in soil and water) from carbon emissions. Think of it this way: When you build a house, the wood in it stores carbon. In a poor country that wood would have been burned to cook supper or to provide heat, thus releasing carbon into the atmosphere. McCormick shows that economic growth in the United States has increased carbon sequestration in many ways, including improved methods of storing waste, increased forest coverage, and greater agricultural productivity that reduces the acreage of cultivated land. Because rich economies sequester more carbon than poor ones, stored carbon must be subtracted from emissions to determine an economy's net addition to greenhouse gas emissions. McCormick's data show that "rich countries take more carbon out of the air than poorer ones" and that "the growth rate of net carbon emission per person will soon be negative in the United States." Put differently—richer may well be cooler. Globalwarming policy analysts agree that greenhouse gas regulations such as those proposed at Kyoto would have negative impacts on the economy. Therefore, as McCormick warns, we should take great care that regulations in the name of global warming "not kill the goose that lays the golden eggs." Slow growth makes people prioritize growth over warming – makes heightened emissions inevitable. Richard High, independent planning consultant and member of the RTPI regeneration network, June 20, 2008, “Striking the right economic balance on consequences of climate change” SECTION: Pg. 26 Lexis Political commitment to climate change spending is being tested by the global slowdown and economists need to fight back with coherent arguments on why the figures add up in the long term, argues Richard High. After becoming headline news a year or so ago, climate change has all but vanished from the national media. The credit crunch and the threat of economic slowdown have distracted attention from a potentially life-threatening issue. US Growth Good – Heg US Growth Good - Heg Economic growth is key to heg—history proves. Anthony Pietroburgo, Political Scientist, 4-10-2009 http://ezinearticles.com/?The-End-ofAmerican-Hegemony&id=2207395 However we can learn from past hegemonic states, all of which, withered away with time just as the American one is currently in the process of doing. Great Britain was perhaps the last true hegemon before that of the United States. Back in 1890 the collapse of their empire had just began. David A. Lake's research on the issue is work that should be greatly analyzed due to the illustrious similarities between the British recession in to retirement and the United States' as well. For much of the 19th century Great Britain was dominating in the same fields as the U.S. did so in the 1950's through the late 1970's. Soon in the later 1800's The United States and Germany moved to a protectionist system to plant their economic seeds and soon after were surpassing British industries and abilities. The industrial base of Great Britain crumbled and forced them to invest heavily in the service, shipping and insurance sectors of the economy just to break-even when concerning their balance of payment statistics. For the time being the British were able to carry on with the pound as the dominant world currency. The frail system was already on the thinnest of ice, when WWI confounded the weak British economy (Lake 122). At the time of Great Britain's reign of power they also pursued operations to completely open up and liberalize the world economy. This did lead to substantial brief economic abundance but eventually the struggles of remaining a strong enough power to be considered an absolute hegemon wore off. Hegemonic powers are only sustainable during periods of constant economic growth. When growth is no longer the complete and utter status of the hegemony's economic functionality the power ceases to be consistent. We see this to be the case with Great Britain, as other world powers emerged and caught up in terms of economic status and influence, British power that was exerted was much more explicit and coercive, just like it was during the American hegemonic era under President Nixon (Lake 121). It is safe to say that the U.S. is headed down the same path that will eventually end up being the ultimate dethroning of the American empire and it's hegemonic capabilities. If you think back to all the complications that the United States is experiencing in this very moment concerning obvious financial difficulties and others in the areas of education, technological innovation and healthcare respectively. Other nations have clearly started their own catch up phase and are impeding on American power as we speak. The irony between the situations leading up to the collapse of the British hegemonic state and the current burdens that are being placed upon a contemptuous American hegemon are too similar for coincidence. It took the disaster of WWI to finally destabilize the British hegemon and the United States is one major crisis away from experiencing the same fate (Bartilow Lecture). Economic growth is key to hegemony Michael Hunt, Prof of History at the UNC at Chapel hill, 5-21-2007 http://hnn.us/articles/37486.htm If in the U.S. case empire is genetic, hegemony is an acquired characteristic. Hegemony was made possible by a rate of economic growth over the course of the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries that had no precedent in human history. This achievement created the preconditions for a U.S.-inspired, designed, and regulated international system that took shape during the first two thirds of the twentieth century. American economic and cultural clout remade societies and reshaped the practices of daily life around the world. US Growth Good – Poverty US Growth Good - Poverty Growth solves poverty. Financial Mail (South Africa), May 23, 2008 “Think tank makes case for orthodoxy” SECTION: ECONOMY, BUSINESS & FINANCE; Pg. 14 Lexis The Growth Report was released this week by the commission on growth & development, an independent think-tank made up of policymakers (including Manuel), business leaders, scholars and two Nobel prize-winning economists. It focuses on the need to achieve sustainable economic growth by analysing the strategies of 13 countries with gross domestic product growth of more than 5%. Along with debunking the notion that poverty can be alleviated in the absence of economic growth, the report offers a list of economic ideas that should be resisted. Some of these include reducing fiscal deficits by cutting infrastructure expenditure; trying to stem inflation by imposing price controls; and letting the exchange rate appreciate too quickly. Growth is key to reducing poverty William J Baumol, professor of economics at NYU, Robert E. Litan, Senior Fellow of Economic Studies at the Brookings Institute, and Carl J. Schramm, President and chief executive officer of the Kauffman Foundation,” 2007, Good Capitalism, Bad Capitalism, and the Economics of Growth and Prosperity Moreover, of particular relevance to the debate about globalization, both India and China have achieved rapid growth while opening themselves up to the rest of the world: trading more extensively and accepting more investment from rich countries. Openness to trade and investment, as we will discuss in later chapters, can be critical to facilitating entrepreneurship and, hence, growth. For now, it is essential to note only that growth and poverty reduction go hand in hand (Dollar and Kraay, 2002). Indeed, it is difficult to think of examples of countries where poverty has declined without economic growth. A rising tide truly does usually lift even the boats at the bottom. From 1978 to 2000, in particular, while the world population grew by 1.6 billion people, the number of people with incomes below $1 per day.—the lowest threshold of poverty—declined by more than 300 million (Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 2004, 9). But even if globalization did worsen inequality (as it may within certain countries, especially because it often disproportionately benefits the most- educated individuals who have skills or products to sell in a global marketplace), steps to slow down or reverse economic integration clearly would reduce growth and very likely lead to lower incomes and average standards of living around the world.7 A simple thought experiment should demonstrate why. Imagine if residents in each of the fifty states of the United States were limited to doing business only with other residents of their states. Is there any serious question that total output, and therefore incomes, in such a “disunited” America would be lower than it is now, with Americans freely able to buy and sell goods and services, send money to and receive money from, and move to any part of the “united” states, rather than being limited to conducting business only with individuals and firms in a single state? Expanding the size of the market in which individuals and firms can do business enhances prosperity, enabling individuals and firms to specialize in what they do best, insights contributed more than two hundred years ago by Adam Smith and David Ricardo. This is just as true for the United States, as it is for other countries throughout the world. US Growth Good – Racism US Growth Good - Racism Growth prevents racism William J Baumol, professor of economics at NYU, Robert E. Litan, Senior Fellow of Economic Studies at the Brookings Institute, and Carl J. Schramm, President and chief executive officer of the Kauffman Foundation,” 2007, Good Capitalism, Bad Capitalism, and the Economics of Growth and Prosperity As Harvard University economist Ben Friedman has persuasively argued, slow growth, especially when coupled with widening inequality, can provide the environment that breeds distrust and often hate (Friedman, It is not an accident, he points out, that some of the worst periods f intolerance toward African Americans and immigrants in post-Civil War United States history (the late 1800s, the 1930S, 1970s, and early 1980s) occurred during periods of slow or negative growth. The worst example of this was, of course, the rise of Nazism in Germany following World War I, when that country was mired in both hyperinflation and stagnant growth (and eventually depression). In more recent times—for example, in the last decades of slow growth and high unemployment— Continental Europe has again flirted with anti-Semitism, while hosting a strong strain of anti-immigrant sentiment. The reverse is much more likely to be true for economies that are growing. These have the good fortune to take advantage of a virtuous cycle, the young can count on a better life, assuming they work hard to .achieve it. Visitors to India or China or Ireland or Israel, for example, report a vibrancy and sense of excitement that one doesn’t hear about in Western Europe, at the rich end, or much of Latin America or Africa, at the lower end of the world income distribution. Growth opens up opportunities, which in turn unleash not only hope but also the work ethic that helps turn opportunities into reality. Much of this same energy and optimism can be found in pockets of the United States—in hightechnology clusters in parts of some American cities. The challenge will be to maintain this combination of energy and hope in coming decades, when the United States also begins to deal with the many challenges of its retiring baby generation. US Growth Good – Resource Wars US Growth Good – AT Resource Wars No risk of resource shortages—no scenario for their impact Bjorn Lomborg, Associate Professor, Department of Political Science, University of Aarhus, 2001, Environmental Conflict, p. 151-152 Often, the discussion of the environment seems similarly to be based on this bleak belief (extensively discussed and documented in Lomborg, 1998/ 2001). This chapter has focused on some of the important areas singled out by environmentalist writers to see whether the environmental stresses indeed are getting worse or not. When looking at the food supply, it is evident that not only has stress lessened, in that more people are better fed than ever before, but the evidence also seems to indicate that this trend will continue into the future, making food even more accessible. Likewise, the threat of erosion is largely based on anecdotal evidence, and when we look at the best available, global data, it seems that its effect over the next century will be negligible. When discussing energy and raw materials, there has always been a tendency to expect a Malthusian exhaustion scenario. However, when we look at the data for oil, coal, gas, and the four most important raw materials (aluminum, iron, copper, and zinc), they exhibit increasing years of consumption, despite the enormous increases in annual consumption and the amounts already consumed. Contrary to common sense, there are good reasons to expect that these resources will not get more scarce but rather more abundant with time. Looking at water it is clear that what used to be an essentially free resource now has an established cost. In this sense, it has become more scarce. But this need not lead to any significant increase in conflict. Partly, water is by no means a very limited resource and through the pricing of water, great efficiencies can be achieved at fairly low cost. Partly, since desalination sets a clear upper boundary on the benefits reaped from access to free water, it is doubtful that water could be a major objective in the acquisition of foreign resources through war. Finally, the discussion of increasing inequality, at least as based on national data, seems erroneous. When measuring the purchasing power, inequality has not increased over the last fifty years—rather, perhaps, we have witnessed a slight decrease. Consequently, although the discussion of an environmental stresses and their connection to conflict is clearly an important area of research it is important to realize that on the main issue areas, resources have not been becoming increasingly scarce but rather more abundant. US Growth Good – Terrorism US Growth Good - Terrorism Economic growth deters terrorism. Prefer our evidence because it’s reverse causal. Collapse of growth causes violence and civil war. Thomas Gries, Tim Krieger and Daniel Meierrieks, PhD economist for the Center for International Economics University of Paderborn, Germany, February 2009 “Causal Linkages Between Domestic Terrorism and Economic Growth” http://groups.unipaderborn.de/fiwi/RePEc/pdf/wpaper/WP20.pdf Economic theory argues that terrorists are rational individuals which choose their levels of violent activity according to the costs and benefits arising from their actions (cf., e.g., Sandler and Enders, 2004). Because of terrorist’ pre- sumed rationality, the opportunity costs of terror also matter. Intuitively, low opportunity costs of violence –that is, few prospects of economic activity –lead to elevated terrorist activity, whereas high opportunity costs result in the opposite (cf., e.g., Freytag et al., 2008). Times of economic success mean, inter alia, more individual economic opportunities and economic participation. Higher levels of overall growth should coincide with higher opportunity costs of terror and thus less violence. Conversely, in periods of economic downturn should be accompanied by fewer economic opportunities and participation and thus by more economic dissatisfaction. In times of economic crisis, dissidents are more likely to resort to violence as the opportunity costs of terror are low, while the potential long-run payo¤s from violence –a redistribution of scarce economic resources which is to be enforced by means of terrorism – are comparatively high (cf. Blomberg, Hess and Weerapana, 2004). To some extent, empirical evidence suggests that economic performance and terrorism are linked along the lines discussed before. The findings of Collier and Hoe- er (1998) indicate that higher levels of economic development coincide with lower likelihoods of civil war, providing initial evidence that economic success and conflict are diametrically opposed.Considering economic development and terrorism, several studies …nd that higher levels of development are obstacles to the production of transnational terrorism (cf., e.g., Santos Bravo and Mendes Dias, 2006; Lai, 2007; Freytag et al., 2008).Blomberg and Hess (2008) also …nd that higher incomes are a strong deterrence to the genesis of domestic terrorism. Furthermore, there is evidence connecting solid short-run economic conditions with less political violence (cf. Muller andWeede, 1990; Freytag et al., 2008).6 In general, the evidence indicates that terrorism and economic conditions are linked. Here, economic success seems to impede the genesis of terrorism, presumably due to higher opportunity costs of con‡ict. In other words, in times of stronger economic performance individuals simply have more to lose. US Growth Good - Terrorism Economic growth creates conditions where communities stop terrorism locally Major Miemie Winn Byrd, Deputy Economic Advisor, U.S. Pacific Command, 2006 “Combating Terrorism: A Socio-Economic Strategy” http://www.dtic.mil/doctrine/jel/jfq_pubs/4106.pdf The increased risks and uncertainties of terrorism reduce consumer willingness to spend, particularly on discretionary items and major consumer durables, thereby reducing investment in consumer goods industries and depressing growth. The travel, tourism, accom- modation, restaurant, postal services, and insurance industries are particularly susceptible. Regions and economies where these industries are concentrated suffer most, both in falling output and employment, but the threat of terrorism reduces overall investment and retards economic growth across the board. While uncontained terrorism is costly for all economies, it could impose a disproportionate cost in trade and income growth in Asia-Pacific countries. Most developing economies in the region depend heavily on trade flows, particularly with the United States. Many of these economies rely on foreign direct investment inflows. Insurance companies may impose higher premiums on cargoes and vessels traveling to and from these countries due to the inadequacy of local security. For instance, Lloyd’s of London recently increased its premiums on ships traveling through the Malacca Strait. Currency exchange rate volatility can devastate the whole region’s economy. A case in point is the Asian financial crisis in 1997, initiated by a sudden Thai bhatt depreciation. Combating Terrorism New counterterrorism measures require one-time investments, which lead to short- to mid-term increases in the costs of doing business. These costs should be viewed as an investment that will pay dividends through reduced risk premiums and increased trade efficiency. In addition to the advantages of reducing exposure to terrorism, technological advances that enhance security are likely to boost the efficiency of cargo handling and people movement, lowering trade costs and making trade flows more efficient. The benefit of preventing reduced trade flows and encouraging investment is continued regional and global economic growth. Expansion and prosperity would enable nations and organizations to fund economic development policies and activities, which would create opportunities and expand a new middle class in communities that have traditionally supported terrorist groups. As the population recognizes the economic benefits of peace, they hopefully will work to inhibit local support for terrorist activities. Sound economic development policies can be one element to fulfill the 9/11 Commission’s recommendations of identifying potential terrorist sanctuaries and preventing them from becoming operational spaces for the actors of terror.1 US Growth Good – US-China War US Growth Good – US-China War Growth solves US-China war – economic interdependence Roger Cohen, International Herald Tribune, December 13, 2006, NYT, Bush’s Distraction in Iraq Has Led to Stronger U.S.-China Ties Paulson wants the yuan to rise further against the dollar - more than the 5.7 percent it has gone up since July 2005. He may or may not get concessions during his visit. In the end, it will not really matter. China does not to seek major confrontation with Washington; it will ultimately do what's necessary to avoid that. Stability in its region is what enables China to focus on maintaining an annual growth rate of close to 10 percent. With China needing to create an estimated 24 million jobs a year to absorb newcomers to the work force, high growth is a prerequisite for the endurance of the ruling Communist Party, whose attachment to power is one of the few nonnegotiable things in the country. So China does not want to challenge the United States - not now, and probably not for a very long time - because Beijing benefits economically from Pax Americana. If the American market closes, China wobbles. If the United States were not an Asian power, China's rise would look a lot more menacing to countries including Japan, Singapore and Australia. "China welcomes the American presence in Asia," He Yafei, an assistant foreign minister, said in an interview. "We welcome the United States to play an important, positive and constructive role in the peace, stability and economic growth of Asia." There's a school of thought in the United States that scoffs at such talk. John Mearsheimer of the University of Chicago has been a forceful proponent of the view that, as the current hegemonic power, America will strive to keep China down and "behave toward China much the way it behaved toward the Soviet Union during the Cold War." China, in turn, will follow an Asian Monroe Doctrine and attempt to push American forces out of Asia. That view misses the way the world has changed since 1989. A degree of interconnectedness exists between the United States and China that would have been unthinkable between Washington and Moscow. America buys Chinese goods, China buys American debt: that's the oil greasing the global economy. "Like it or not, the United States has to accept China's peaceful rise," said JiaQingguo, the associate dean of Peking University. "The utility of force has declined because we live in a world of interconnection. China and the United States are not two separate entities. They are intertwined." Jia continued: "It's very difficult to adopt a policy that is only harmful to the other side. What U.S. sanctions would not also hurt America's own companies?" Look at the Chinese today - building bigger and higher in a ramshackle way, constructing bridges, boring tunnels, doing deals, hustling to get richer, perhaps even rich enough to join the golf club, thirsting for brand names, going nuts for new movie and Internet stars, opening giant eateries with TV screens everywhere. They're not Americans, far from it, but they're not alien to the United States either. Casual, brash, money-minded, they look across the Pacific for inspiration. Which is not to say thatChina and the United States always see eye to eye or that tensions will not flare. He, the assistant foreign minister, bristled when it was suggested to him that China does business with tyrants in places like Myanmar or Zimbabwe. "You're right in saying that our assistance to these countries has no political conditions or strings attached and in the future we will continue to do so," He said. "Our assistance to these countries is based on the interests of the peoples in these countries." Opposition to interference in the internal affairs of other countries was a core principle of Chinese foreign policy, He added, explaining, "We ourselves suffered bitterly from aggression and invasion in the past. We will not do what we ourselves don't like and other peoples don't like either." Other major powers in history had grown through "colonization and exploitation and invasion and aggression, but these methods go nowhere in the current world," He said without ever mentioning Iraq by name. The minister urged the United States to be "transparent and reasonable" in its strengthened military cooperation with other Asian countries, including Japan and Australia. "The security concerns of other countries including China should be taken into consideration," He said. Those concerns, and the existence of a hard-line Chinese school that sees conflict with the United States as inevitable, explain China's heavy military spending as it tries to make its armed forces more mobile and technologically adept. Aggressive, some would say. A reasonable form of hedging would be a better description. Chinese-American relations have quietly moved beyond the ability of the yuan's exchange rate or Taiwan tensions or strategic disagreements to bring major confrontation. There are too many links. A possible deal on North Korea before the end of the month may well illustrate the new effectiveness of those ties. No U.S. china war – economic interdependence James Mulvenon et al. Associate Political Scientist at the RAND Corporation, 2005. RAND, “China on the Move: A Franco-American Analysis of Emerging Chinese Strategic Policies and Their Consequences for Transatlantic Relations.” http://www.rand.org/pubs/conf_proceedings/2005/RAND_CF199.pdf Apart from the specific circumstances that suggest value in cooperation with the United States, the Chinese undoubtedly understand that sustainable growth will both require and foster growing economic interdependence between China and America. The two economies are quite complementary: America the source of new technology and insatiable consumer demand, and China an engine of production with a seemingly inexhaustible labor supply. True, this growing economic interdependence constrains the United States as well as China, which might embolden the Chinese to be less compliant. At the same time, awareness that the United States has an immense economic stake in China might cause the Chinese to feel that challenging the United States politically and militarily is not only fundamentally unwise but also fundamentally unnecessary. Opting to expand cooperation with the United States for the long haul would enable China to avoid a massive military buildup and thus to concentrate investment on internal development. At the same time, the Chinese can be expected to continue to expand their military capabilities, especially those relevant to the United States and Taiwan--their most powerful potential adversary and their most coveted symbol of national unity, respectively. Military modernization is not incompatible with a strategy of long-term political cooperation. Indeed, it could be viewed as important both as a hedge and as a way to avoid having to cooperate from a severely inferior position. US Growth Good – Space US Growth Good - Space Growth makes space travel possible Nader Elhefnawy, taught at the University of Miami, published widely on space and international issues, Monday, September 29, 2008, “Economic growth and space development over the long haul” http://www.thespacereview.com/article/1220/1 Nonetheless, even if one should not get carried away by seemingly staggering numbers, the fact of higher output still means an enlarged range of options. Just as China’s economic growth has made its new ambitions in space more than just a dream (even if many of its plans have yet to prove to be realistic), a space project of any given size would seem far more affordable in a world where global wealth had risen by a factor of two, three, or five. Space is key to preventing extinction James Oberg, space writer and a former space flight engineer based in Houston, 1999, Space Power Theory, http://www.jamesoberg.com/books/spt/new-CHAPTERSw_figs.pdf We have the great gift of yet another period when our nation is not threatened; and our world is free from opposing coalitions with great global capabilities. We can use this period to take our nation and our fellow men into the greatest adventure that our species has ever embarked upon. The United States can lead, protect, and help the rest of [hu]mankind to move into space. It is particularly fitting that a country comprised of people from all over the globe assumes that role. This is a manifest destiny worthy of dreamers and poets, warriors and conquerors. In his last book, Pale Blue Dot, Carl Sagan presents an emotional argument that our species must venture into the vast realm of space to establish a spacefaring civilization. While acknowledging the very high costs that are involved in manned spaceflight, Sagan states that our very survival as a species depends on colonizing outer space. Astronomers have already identified dozens of asteroids that might someday smash into Earth. Undoubtedly, many more remain undetected. In Sagan’s opinion, the only way to avert inevitable catastrophe is for mankind to establish a permanent human presence in space. He compares humans to the planets that roam the night sky, as he says that humans will too wander through space. We will wander space because we possess a compulsion to explore, and space provides a truly infinite prospect of new directions to explore. Sagan’s vision is part science and part emotion. He hoped that the exploration of space would unify humankind. We propose that mankind follow the United States and our allies into this new sea, set with jeweled stars. If we lead, we can be both strong and caring. If we step back, it may be to the detriment of more than our country.