Economic Efficiency Chapter 10 Slides by Pamela L. Hall Western Washington University ©2005, Southwestern Introduction Underlying debate between capitalism and socialism is economic efficiency as a necessary condition for maximizing social welfare In a capitalist system, if an economy or market is operating efficiently Increase in demand for a commodity will result in increase in market price • Provides incentive for firms to increase supply If an economy or market is operating inefficiently, limited resources are not allocated to their most productive markets Will reduce level of commodities available and decrease society’s welfare Aim in this chapter is to develop a criterion for measuring economic efficiency Can then evaluate perfectly competitive price system in terms of this criterion and government intervention into markets 2 Introduction Define firm economic efficiency in terms of technological, allocative, and scale efficiency Consumer and producer surplus are measures of economic efficiency • Sum, total surplus, is used as a surrogate for measuring economic efficiency Perfectly competitive market will, without government involvement, maximize total surplus • Resulting in economic efficiency Deadweight loss is a measure of economic inefficiency We investigate government-established ceiling prices and black market We discuss market price supports Consider inefficiencies of these supports along with output controls and target prices • Imposition of a tax can distort prices and result in economic inefficiencies Derive deadweight loss associated with output and sales taxes Show that amount of tax borne by firms and consumers depends on elasticity of supply and demand 3 Introduction We conclude with a discussion on inefficiency of trade restrictions Deriving deadweight loss associated with tariffs and quotas Discussing market effects of tariffs versus quotas Applied economists evaluate effect various government policies and programs have on economic efficiency Estimate price and other market effects from various programs in terms of efficiently allocating resources Suggest changes or alternative policies and programs that may result in same objectives with an improvement in resource allocation • For example, providing tax breaks for businesses located in economically depressed areas provides an incentive for businesses to relocate in these areas Stimulates private job training and employment 4 Economic-Efficiency Criteria Firm that efficiently allocates its resources can improve its position For firm economic efficiency, three criteria are required Technological efficiency • Firms are using production processes that yield highest output levels for a given set of inputs Assumed all firms are technologically efficient Allocative efficiency • Firms minimize costs for a given level of output Requires using least-cost combination of inputs for a given level of output Input prices per marginal product of all inputs are equal 5 Economic-Efficiency Criteria Scale efficiency Requires output price to equal SMC • What consumers or society are willing to pay for an additional unit of output must equal what it costs society to produce this additional unit of output Output price is how much society is willing to pay for an additional unit of output SMC is cost to society for producing this additional output If p > SMC, society is willing to pay more than it costs for additional output Efficiency is improved if more resources are allocated to production of this output If p < SMC, reduction in cost from producing less of output is more than willingness-to-pay for output Efficiency is improved if fewer resources are allocated to production of this output Perfectly competitive market meets these three criteria for economic efficiency 6 Favorable Features Of Perfect Competition Consumers’ preferences are reflected in marketplace Called consumer sovereignty • If there is an increase in demand for a commodity, market price will increase Provides incentives for firms to increase output and satisfy increased demand No government agency is required to determine level of demand and supply Society’s resources are also allocated in most efficient manner Firms attempting to satisfy some increase in demand purchase more inputs Thus, resources naturally flow in direction of consumer preferences Assuming flexible input and output prices, full employment of all resources is assured Individuals who firmly believe in free market see these favorable features of perfect competition as very important They see a very limited, if any, role for central government in markets • Instead, decentralizing decisions rests power of decision making in hands of those individual agents directly impacted by decisions In perfectly competitive markets, firms will respond to consumer preferences 7 Unfavorable Features of Perfect Competition Results in incomplete reflection of consumers’ desires Does not measure consumers’ desires for collective or public goods • Commodities where consumption by one consumer does not reduce consumption of same commodity by another consumer For example, national defense • Public goods jointly impact all consumers Private goods only impact consumer who purchases and consumes commodity 8 Unfavorable Features of Perfect Competition Joint-impact characteristic of public goods hampers market’s ability to allocate resources for its production Thus, some consumers may not purchase any amount of a public good, while other consumers do purchase it However, nonpurchasers will derive utility from public good purchased by other consumers • Called a free-rider problem • Results in a misallocation of resources • One justification for government intervention is to correct this misallocation by government supplying public goods 9 Unfavorable Features of Perfect Competition Inadequate measure of social costs and benefits Externality • Commodity that affects households’ utility functions or firms’ production functions But is out of the control of affected household or firm For example, a mill’s air pollution that affects a household is an externality Problem with externalities is market only considers production cost • Without also considering social cost, resources are potentially misallocated When externalities exist in an economy, perfect competition provides no method of correcting possible differences between social and private costs resulting from these externalities • Role for government is to correct any differences between private and social costs 10 Unfavorable Features of Perfect Competition Insufficient incentive for progress In a system where technological advances can be quickly duplicated by competing firms • Limited incentive for firms to allocate resources toward innovation In many cases government provided resources for research and development in industries that are close to perfectly competitive model • For example, in United States, land grant universities are funded by federal and state governments for agricultural research and education Level or magnitude of government involvement depends on How much weight is put on favorable features compared with unfavorable features of perfect competition • If an individual is a capitalist, she would discount the unfavorable • features of perfect competition and advocate a limited role for government A socialist sees unfavorable features of perfect competition as major concerns Suggests a major role for government for correcting these market failures 11 Consumer Surplus Measure of net benefit a consumer receives from being able to purchase a commodity at a particular price At a fundamental level, only consumer’s preferences matter for measuring a consumer’s welfare Such a measure is difficult to interpret as there is no unique way to measure a consumer’s utility As an alternative, consumer welfare is measured as Difference between maximum amount a consumer would be willing to pay and what actually is paid 12 Consumer Surplus Per-unit price of a commodity measures consumers’ marginal value of commodity (marginal utility of consumption) Additional utility consumers receive from consuming an additional unit of a commodity • Total utility or benefit consumers obtain from consuming a commodity at level Qe is area under market demand curve from zero to Qe 13 Consumer Surplus Consumer surplus measures difference between total benefits from consumption of a commodity and expenditure on commodity CS(Qe) = U(Qe) - peQe • Illustrated in Figure 10.1 Area 0ABQe is total utility, U(Qe) Actual expenditure for Qe is area 0peBQe CS(Qe) is the difference: peAB = 0ABQe - 0peBQe • Consumers are willing to pay over $10 for the first units But only have to pay actual market price of $5 Receive a surplus of marginal utility Measured as marginal consumer surplus over and above what they pay for these first units 14 Figure 10.1 Consumer surplus 15 Consumer Surplus Given a negatively sloping market demand curve As quantity demanded increases • Price consumers are willing to pay for an additional unit of a commodity declines • Marginal consumer surplus will continue to decline Consumers will continue to purchase commodity up to Qe Price consumers are willing to pay for additional units is equal to market price At this point, marginal consumer surplus is zero Consumers are indifferent in terms of purchasing the commodity or not Beyond this equilibrium quantity, consumers’ willingness to pay is less than market price Results in negative marginal consumer surplus Consumers will forgo any additional purchases because such purchases will result in a loss in surplus (welfare) 16 Consumer Surplus If equilibrium price increases from pe to p'e Difference in consumers’ willingness to pay and what they actually pay (consumer surplus) is reduced • Area pep'eBC illustrated in Figure 10.2 Equilibrium level of consumption where marginal consumer surplus is zero is reduced from Qe to Q'e • Results in an additional loss in consumer surplus Area CBD Total loss in consumer surplus, resulting in a reduction in consumer surplus from peAD to p'eAB, is pe p'eBD Reduction in price yields an increase in consumer surplus 17 Figure 10.2 Change in consumer surplus resulting from a price change 18 Consumer Surplus Centrally planned economies will often consider subsidizing prices on highly inelastic commodities such as food and housing in an effort to boost consumer welfare If they are interested in maximizing consumer welfare for a commodity Price would be zero and associated consumer surplus (welfare) would be represented by entire area under demand curve • 0AE in Figure 10.2 However, limited resources prevent society from maximizing consumer surplus across all commodities Occurs at global bliss Society must maximize social welfare subject to resource constraints Necessary condition for maximizing social welfare • Economy must operate efficiently Requires consideration of consumer surplus and welfare of producers (producer surplus) 19 Producer Surplus Producer surplus (PS) at equilibrium price and quantity is Pure profit plus total fixed cost • PS(Qe) = + TFC Pure profit at equilibrium price and quantity is = TR(Qe) – STC(Qe) Producer surplus is PS(Qe) = TR(Qe) – STC(Qe) + TFC Ultimately, producer surplus is also measured as total revenue minus total variable cost PS(Qe) = TR(Qe) – STVC(Qe) • Illustrated in Figure 10.3 Total revenue, TR, is represented by area 0peAQe and STVC by area 0(SAVCe)BQe Difference between these areas is PS(Qe) [shaded area (SAVCe)peAB] Equivalent to area below price, pe, and above SMC(Qe) • See Figure 10.4 20 Figure 10.3 Producer surplus as total revenue minus short run total variable cost 21 Figure 10.4 Producer surplus: the area below price and above the marginal cost curve 22 Producer Surplus Area below SMC curve is STVC Area above SMC and below price—producer surplus—is PS(Qe) = TR(Qe) – STVC(Qe) • TR(Qe) is area 0peBQe Producer surplus is difference between minimum amount a firm would be willing to sell a given output, SAVC, and amount they actually sell the units for Firms are indifferent between selling a unit of output or not • When p = SAVC (start of Stage II) • At any price above SAVC, firms are earning a per-unit surplus of p - SAVC Per-unit surplus is firm’s marginal producer surplus Summing this marginal producer surplus for a given output level yields firm’s welfare gain from supplying this output (producer surplus) 23 Producer Surplus If equilibrium price decreases from pe to p'e Difference in amount firms are willing to receive for a commodity and what they actually are paid (producer surplus) is reduced by area p'e peCD • Illustrated in Figure 10.5 Equilibrium level of output where marginal producer surplus is zero is reduced from Qe to Q'e Results in an additional loss in producer surplus A price enhancement yields an increase in producer surplus Examples of price enhancements • Government price supports that attempt to increase firms’ producer surplus (corporate welfare) by maintaining or enhancing output price However, such price supports will reduce consumer surplus 24 Figure 10.5 Change in producer surplus resulting from a change in price 25 Total Surplus and Economic Efficiency Government policies affecting output price or alternative market structures will either increase consumer surplus and decrease producer surplus or vice-versa Such shifts in surplus often come at the price of an overall reduction in sum of consumer and producer surplus Called deadweight loss (or excess burden) • Decrease in total surplus that is not transferred to some other agent Measure of loss in efficiency associated with a government policy or market structure Economic efficiency in a market may be defined where sum of producer and consumer surplus is maximized (where there is no deadweight loss) Sum of consumer and producer surplus (total surplus) is maximized in a perfectly competitive market • See Figure 10.6 26 Figure 10.6 Perfectly competitive equilibrium, maximizing consumer plus producer surplus 27 Ceiling Prices An established price maximum where selling price is not allowed to rise above it Effect of a ceiling price on market for rental housing is illustrated in Figure 10.7 • Price pe is free-market price for housing • Without a ceiling price, quantity supplied of housing is Qe at pe Consumer surplus is area peAB Producer surplus is area CpeB • Imposing a ceiling price above market equilibrium price Imposes no constraint on market and has no market effect 28 Figure 10.7 Ceiling price 29 Ceiling Prices When ceiling price is set below free-market price, pe, will affect market allocation of commodities With pc below pe, market price cannot increase to its free-market level • Objective of government policy However, a housing shortage may be reason for high rents • When ceiling price, pc, reduces quantity supplied from Qe to QcS and increases quantity demanded to QcD Even greater housing shortage results Consumer surplus with a ceiling price of pc is pcADE, and producer surplus is Cpc E As a direct result of ceiling price, there is a loss in efficiency Measured by difference in total surplus under a free market and a market with a ceiling price • Deadweight loss is area EDB 30 Ceiling Prices Pseudo-triangle, EDB, in Figure 10.7 Illustrates deadweight loss that appears in many models that result in efficiency loss Deadweight triangles are called Harberger triangles As a result of ceiling price, consumers capture part of producer surplus and lose surplus FDB If net effect, pcpeFE - FDB, is positive • Consumers gain in welfare by taking some of the surplus from producers This gain can make ceiling-price legislation very popular among voters Even if it results in market inefficiencies 31 Ceiling Prices Politicians who favor ceiling prices may assume that a perfectly inelastic market supply curve Quantity supplied is not responsive to a price change In Figure 10.8, consumer surplus at free-market price is peAB, and producer surplus is 0peBQe Ceiling price results in no efficiency loss, so there is no deadweight loss • Consumers capture part of producer surplus, pcpeBC Effect of ceiling price is to shift more of surplus to consumers by taking surplus away from producers. Although when SQ,p = 0 total surplus remains unchanged, there is still a problem Quantity demanded is still greater than quantity supplied • Some consumers who are willing and able to rent housing at ceiling price are unable to find a vacancy Results in a loss of satisfaction, measured by consumer surplus that would be gained if housing were supplied In Figure 10.7, this is area EDG In Figure 10.8, it is area CBE 32 Figure 10.8 Ceiling price with Q,pS = 0 33 Allocation Problem Consumers who are unable to purchase a commodity present one of the major problems with a ceiling-price policy Problem is how to allocate available supply A ceiling price results in consumers wanting to purchase more than is being offered for sale In a free market, this problem does not exist Market automatically allocates supply in such a way that quantity supplied equals quantity demanded Without a free market, some other mechanism is required Generally means that government determines the policy for allocation 34 First-Come–First-Served Without government rationing, a ceiling price results in allocation mechanism called first-come–first-served Those consumers who are first to purchase commodity are able to purchase it Once commodity is exhausted, remaining consumers who want to purchase it are unable to do so Major problem with first-come–first-served is waiting lines Results in lost productivity Labor waiting in line is not productive First-come–first-served is also not an efficient allocation method Agents with highest willingness-to-pay will not necessarily receive commodity What generally happens is some consumers will pay other consumers to wait in line for them • Effect of this is to raise price of commodity • Information market generally develops 35 Black Markets Civil disobedience can also occur when QcD > QcS There will always be market forces pushing price above ceiling price Laws and penalties restricting these market forces are required However, there will generally be some consumers willing to engage in illegal activities Purchase a commodity above ceiling price Some firms willing to supply commodity at a price above legal limit • Called a black market For example, currently in United States, a considerable black market exists for exotic animals Endangered species such as Chinese alligator and Komodo dragon have a black market price of as much as $15,000 and $30,000, respectively 36 Black Markets Black-market price and output, when a ceiling price is established, are illustrated in Figure 10.9 Black-market supply curve is AQSB Lies to left of and increases more steeply than legalmarket supply curve, QS • In a black market sellers incur greater costs and risks than in a legal market Higher costs may be in form of hiding production or sales or paying government officials not to prosecute them for their illegal activities The greater the cost of operation in black market, the steeper the supply curve 37 Figure 10.9 Black-market price and quantity for a ceiling price 38 Black Markets Black-market demand curve is represented by BQDB Curve’s lower endpoint is at B rather than C • Even at legal ceiling price of pc, some potential buyers will not buy in black market At ceiling price pc quantity demanded in black market is not total unsatisfied demand AC, but a smaller quantity AB Quantity traded in black market is QB - Qc, and quantity traded in legal market is Qc Total quantity traded is QB As a result of increased supply from black market, consumer and producer surplus are both increased • Reduces a portion of deadweight loss associated with ceiling pricing 39 Efficiency Versus Equity A ceiling-price policy is concerned with equity (the distribution of income) Designed to provide consumers greater purchasing power or real income However, ceiling-price policy also affects market efficiency Alternative solution to equity problem is a direct redistribution of income Various taxing policies and subsidy programs can be designed to redistribute it • Do not directly remove ability of free markets to allocate commodities Once a ceiling price is established and market reacts by reducing quantity supplied Becomes politically unpopular to remove ceiling price By not yielding in first place to political pressure to establish a ceiling • Governments can avoid highly unpopular act of having to resend it 40 Support Prices Established price minimum (floor) below which selling price is not allowed to fall Setting a support price below free-market equilibrium price has no effect Figure 10.10 illustrates support price, ps, with a free-market equilibrium price, pe, and quantity, Qe • Results in quantity supplied being greater than quantity demanded • Maintaining this support price requires a government agency to purchase surplus supply And keep it out of market Consumer surplus is reduced and producer surplus is increased Consumer surplus for free market is represented by area peAC with producer surplus DpeC Support price increases commodity price from pe to ps Reduces consumer surplus to psAB Producer surplus increases from DpeC to DpsE 41 Figure 10.10 Support price 42 Support Prices Major objective of most support prices is to increase producers’ profits In Figure 10.10 producer profits increase by pe psEC Producers capture some of consumer surplus, pe psBC, and receive additional surplus, BEC Cost to taxpayers is value of commodity surplus that must be purchased—area QSDBEQSS Support price results in production of commodity beyond quantity demanded Surplus production is stored • Usually with intention of releasing it in times of drastic reductions in supply Producers do not support such releases due to negative effect on commodity price Surpluses are seldom released in times of a supply shortfall 43 Support Prices Result in an economy producing more of a commodity than society demands For example, U.S. agricultural policy In past century, most major U.S. agricultural commodities received some type of price support • Agricultural interests justify support prices in terms of parity Parity in agriculture is a price of an agricultural commodity that gives the commodity a purchasing power equivalent to what it had in a previous base year Slutsky-type compensation for producers of agricultural commodities Contends that even if relative worth of an agricultural sector is declining Relative income within this sector should be maintained Generally, as an economy develops, relatively fewer resources need to be allocated to production of agricultural commodities Agricultural sectors’ relative worth, in terms of resource allocation and commodities produced, decline relative to other sectors • If any sector’s relative worth is declining, it is difficult to justify why its relative income should be maintained For national security reasons nations may attempt to maintain an agricultural sector larger than a free market would provide 44 Acreage Controls Agricultural Adjustment Act (AAA) in 1933 was established under Franklin D. Roosevelt’s New Deal program Attempted to control farm prices by reducing supply of basic crops (wheat, cotton, rice, tobacco, corn, hogs, dairy) Empowered Secretary of Agriculture to • Fix marketing quotas for major farm products • Take surplus production off market • Reduce production of crops by offering producers payments in return for voluntarily reducing crop acreage 45 Acreage Controls Partly due to AAA, farm prices increased by 85% from 1932 to 1937 Programs as acreage controls avoid problem of surpluses Designed to raise agricultural prices by limiting acreage on which certain crops can be grown Acreage controls assume a relatively inelastic demand curve for agricultural products • Increase in price and associated decrease in quantity result in increased TR and profit If demand is elastic, TR will fall • Farmers would need to be paid to reduce acreage 46 Acreage Controls Acreage controls are where reduced supply results in supply curve shifting leftward Illustrated in Figure 10.11 • Decreases quantity and increases price • Consumer surplus is reduced • Producer surplus is increased Inefficiency of acreage controls is represented by deadweight loss Shaded area EBC Generally, acreage controls require farmers to take some land out of production However, producers will generally take marginal, relatively unproductive land out of production and • Increase their labor and other variable inputs, including pesticides and fertilizers, in an attempt to maintain production Supply curve may not shift to left as much as policy intended 47 Figure 10.11 Acreage controls 48 Target Prices In early 1960s price supports on major commodities were dropped Farmers’ incomes were protected by direct payments on fixed quantities of products A target price promises producers a deficiency payment Equal to difference between target price and market price Producers will produce output QSt • Decreases price from pe to p1 for consumers • Producer surplus is increased • Consumer surplus increases Difference in price consumers pay and price producers receive • Paid to producers by government • Called deficiency payment Loss in efficiency is shaded area BDE • However, increased agricultural production from target pricing provides an abundant supply of relatively low-cost agricultural products 49 Figure 10.12 Target price 50 Target Prices Once established, subsidies are extremely difficult to remove In 1996, U.S. Congress passed Freedom to Farm Act • Eliminated agricultural subsidies in favor of fixed payments to farmers • However, legislation failed to decrease payments to farmers By 2000 aid to farmers was over $22 billion—three times 1996 level A new federal farm bill in 2002 abandoned 1996 goal of reducing farm payments and generally increased subsidies 51 Subsidies United States continues to subsidize disposal of surplus farm products under Public Law 480 (Food for Peace) program Began in 1954 to dispose of surplus agricultural products as a direct result of commodity price supports Export enhancement program established in 1985 is another subsidy for U.S. farm products to compete with subsidized products from other countries A target price is a form of a government subsidy (negative of a tax) on a commodity 52 Subsidies With a subsidy, government generally sets some price level that consumers will pay for commodity Then subsidizes firms to a level where they will satisfy quantity demanded at this price Results in same efficiency losses as a target price Problems arise when subsidies are removed Firms must cut back on production, given the lower price In short run, may result in price dropping to below SAVC for some firms • Forcing these firms to shut down Adjustment process can be hard on an economy where a large share of industry had been subsidized and all subsidies are removed at once Significant short-run unemployment of resources may occur 53 Taxes Opposite of a subsidy is a commodity tax on a firm’s output May be either an output tax (quantity tax) • Such as an excise tax Generally levied by states on commodities such as cigarettes, motor fuel, distilled spirits, wine, and beer Conventionally, an excise tax is a tax per physical unit (per pack of cigarettes, per gallon of motor fuel, or per ounce of alcohol) Varies by state For example, in July 2002 cigarette excise tax was highest in New York at $1.50 per pack Compared with only $0.03 in Kentucky Or a sales tax • Value tax or ad valorem tax • Levied on retail purchases • Varies by state Common method for state and local governments to obtain revenue Have effect of increasing cost to consumers for purchasing a commodity 54 Taxes Per-unit tax, t, is equal to per-unit price of a commodity times sales-tax percentage For example, a 5% sales tax on a $1.00 item results in a per-unit tax, t, of $0.05 • Illustrated in Figure 10.13 Shifts supply curve leftward Equilibrium quantity decreases from Qe to Qt • Firms receive pf per unit of output and consumers pay pc • Difference is amount of tax per unit of output Consumer and producer surplus is reduced Government collects area pf pcBD in total tax revenue • Net loss in producer plus consumer surplus is DBC Deadweight loss as a result of sales tax 55 Figure 10.13 Sales tax, T 56 Taxes Tax revenue collected by government may be used to finance public goods As long as net benefits from these public goods exceed deadweight loss from sales tax • Welfare is improved as a result of tax Sales tax is borne by both consumers and producers Share of sales tax borne by consumers and producers depends on elasticities of supply and demand 57 Taxes Per-unit tax t is difference between price consumers pay, pc, and price firms receive Same output and prices will occur with a shift in demand curve Illustrated in Figure 10.14 • Welfare effects are the same, and portion of tax borne by consumers and producers is the same Does not matter whether tax is collected by producers with a resulting supply curve shift or paid by consumers with a resulting demand curve shift However, sales taxes are generally collected by firms, considering lower transaction costs of collection from firms 58 Figure 10.14 Investigating the effect of a perunit sales tax, T, by shifting the demand curve 59 Taxes If demand curve is perfectly inelastic Results in per-unit tax borne totally by consumers (Figure 10.15) If demand is perfectly elastic Results in per-unit tax borne totally by firms If supply curve is perfectly inelastic Results in per-unit tax borne totally by firms (Figure 10.16) In long run, as supply becomes more elastic, producers’ share of sales tax is reduced If supply is perfectly elastic All of tax is shifted to consumers 60 Figure 10.15 Sales tax with a perfectly inelastic demand curve … 61 Figure 10.16 Sales tax with a perfectly inelastic supply curve … 62 Trade Restrictions International trade restrictions on steel and other products result in market inefficiencies Generally result of policymakers trying to discourage domestic consumers from purchasing foreign instead of domestic commodities Increases domestic production • Decreases reliance on foreign production Maintains foreign currency reserves for purchase of foreign commodities deemed of higher value by government Such trade-restriction policies are costly in form of market inefficiencies However, in name of national security, they are very common 63 Trade Restrictions Illustration of market inefficiency associated with trade restrictions Consider a country with an unrestricted free market for a commodity • Assume country has no influence on world price Equilibria with and without international markets are depicted in Figure 10.17 • With no international trade, point D, country’s domestic equilibrium price and quantity are pe and Qe • Assuming world price, pW, is below this domestic price With international trade domestic price will then fall to this world price Increases quantity demanded from Qe to Q1 Reduces domestic quantity supplied from Qe to Q2 64 Figure 10.17 Free trade 65 Trade Restrictions With a domestic supply of Q2, excess demand is supplied by imports from foreign firms International trade results in an increase in consumer surplus • Area pWpeDF • Welfare gain for consumers within this country Area pWpeDA is a transfer of some producer surplus from producers to consumers within this country • Price producers receive for their output falls from pe to pW Directly depresses producers’ profit This fall in price is a gain for consumers within this country • They gain all lost producer surplus and all of pure increase in welfare from free trade, area ADF 66 Trade Restrictions Introduction of low commodity prices through opening of domestic markets to international trade can severely harm domestic industries In an effort to avoid damaging its domestic industries Countries may adopt protectionist policies with programs designed for restricting trade Common forms of trade restrictions are Tariffs • Tax on imports that directly increases price of imported commodities Quotas • Restriction on volume of an imported commodity Effects on price and quantity imported are same for both tariff and quota trade restrictions Illustrated in Figure 10.18 67 Figure 10.18 Tariff or quota trade restrictions 68 Tariffs With a tariff of t per unit of commodity imported Price of imports will rise Small size of this country results in its imports having no effect on world price All the tariff is borne by country’s consumers World supply curve facing these consumers is perfectly elastic Consumers facing higher price will decrease their quantity demanded for commodity • With an associated welfare loss in consumer surplus Represented by area pWpRRF in Figure 10.18 Loss in consumer surplus is partially offset by a gain in producer surplus 69 Tariffs Tariff increases domestic price of commodity Domestic producers respond by increasing quantity supplied from Q2 to Q4 • This increase maximizes domestic producers’ increase in producer surplus Area pWpRBA Gain in producer surplus is a transfer of some consumer surplus to producers An additional amount of lost consumer surplus is transferred from consumers to government • Government collects revenue generated from tariff Area CBRD Not all of the loss in consumer surplus from the trade restriction is transferred • Remainder is deadweight loss Sum of deadweight loss areas ABC and DRF is market inefficiency associated with a tariff 70 Quotas If an import quota is set at level of imports resulting from levying tariff Quota as a trade restriction has a very similar effect as a tariff • Q3 - Q4 in Figure 10.18 Domestic price, output, and consumption are all the same • Results in same efficiency loss, represented as deadweight loss areas ABC and DRF in Figure 10.18 However, with a quota trade restriction, government does not collect any revenue Loss in consumer surplus, area CBRD, is transferred to agents who are given rights to supply Q3 - Q4 of imports • Rather than to government These agents could be foreign producers or import agents who purchase foreign commodities for domestic consumption 71 Free Trade Trade negotiations under General Agreement of Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and free-trade zones such as European Common Market and North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) Have either eliminated or greatly reduced trade tariffs and quotas However, governments still attempt various protectionist measures For example, under guise of food safety or environmental protection, a country may refuse entry of foreign commodities or require expensive testing before entry is allowed Such trade restrictions can be investigated with same model employed for tariffs 72 Spillover Efficiency Loss A general economic application occurs when governments attempt to address higher domestic prices that result from protecting domestic industries By placing ceiling prices on commodities • Introduces further government restrictions on market with additional cost in terms of market inefficiencies The extreme, where most if not all markets are severely restricted, yields a centrally planned economy This chapter has measured efficiency loss associated with market interventions in a partial-equilibrium framework Ignoring spillover effects price changes have on other markets • Not necessary to consider spillover effects into undistorted free markets when measuring deadweight loss 73 Spillover Efficiency Loss Price and quantity changes in undistorted free markets do not affect efficiency Marginal utility of consumption is equal to marginal cost of production • No loss in efficiency In contrast, if one market is affected by some distortion, there may be spillover efficiency losses in other markets As an example, consider how a tariff on one commodity can spill over into market for another commodity distorted by a ceiling price • Illustrated in Figure 10.19 In absence of a tariff on a substitute commodity, a ceiling price will reduce market price from free-market equilibrium pe to ceiling price of pc Deadweight loss is area EDB A tariff on a substitute commodity will shift demand curve to right for ceilingpriced commodity, from QD to QD' Resulting deadweight loss is increased by area DGHB 74 Figure 10.19 Spillover deadweight loss, ceiling price with a tariff … 75