EH1: SB TOPIC 2 Wages, Prices and the Great Divergence TOPIC 2: WAGES, PRICES AND THE GREAT DIVERGENCE: LECTURE OUTLINE • • • • • A. SILVER AND GRAIN WAGES 1. The Great Divergence Debate 2. Wages and Prices in Europe 3. Wages and prices in Asia 4. Explaining Europe-Asia Wage-Price Differences 2 1. THE GREAT DIVERGENCE DEBATE 1. WHEN DID THE GREAT DIVERGENCE BEGIN? • Recent emergence of group of revisionist “world historians”, many based in California, who claim “Great Divergence” between Europe & Asia occurred only after 1800 3 1A. CONVENTIONAL VIEW • Although Industrial Revolution saw shift to continuous steady state growth of per capita income circa 1800, Early Modern period 15001800 saw levels effect from capital deepening • Huge literature examined institutional developments underpinning this: rise of market economy with incentive structures for accumulation and innovation • Policy implications: development is difficult since institutional frameworks hard to change 4 1B. CALIFORNIA SCHOOL VIEW • Conventional view is Euro-centric • Deny any divergence between Europe & Asia before 1800 • Explanations of post-1800 development: • Pomeranz: coal deposits & colonies • Parthasarathi, Frank: exploitation of colonies 5 1C. CRITICAL ASSESSMENT • Broadberry/Gupta: • Great Divergence began during Early Modern period • Advanced parts of Asia on same development level as European periphery by 1800 6 1D. CONCEPTS • Silver wage: daily money wage in terms of silver content. • Silver is world currency. Debasement possible by reducing silver content, but all prices here corrected for this. • Grain wage: amount of grain that daily silver wage can purchase 7 1E. FINDINGS • Although grain wage in most advanced parts of Asia close to NW European level until 1700, silver wage much lower (as in European periphery) • High silver wages in NW Europe not simply monetary phenomenon (inflow of bullion from New World), but result of high productivity in traded goods sector (services & industry) 8 Findings • Early existence of key features of relationship between developed country and LDC: – Wages in LDC meet food needs of population at LDC food prices, but not at developed country prices – Manufactures produced in LDC relatively expensive at LDC prices but competitive on world market because of low wages in developed country prices 9 2. WAGES AND PRICES IN EUROPE 2A. SILVER WAGES AND GRAIN WAGES • TABLE 1: Daily wages of unskilled and skilled building workers in terms of silver content: silver wage – Substantial silver wage growth in NW Europe, with GB overtaking Netherlands during C18th. – Considerable fluctuations, less trend growth in S. Europe, starting from same level as NW Europe in 1500 – Fluctuations & only weak trend growth in central & E. Europe, starting from lower level in 1500 – Regional variation similar for unskilled & skilled workers; skill premium 50% in NW, 100% in south, central & E. Europe 10 TABLE 1: Silver wage (grams of silver per day) A. Unskilled labourers Northwestern Europe London Southern England Amsterdam Antwerp Paris Southern Europe Valencia Madrid Milan Florence Naples Central & eastern Europe Gdansk Warsaw Krakow Vienna Leipzig Augsburg 150049 155099 160049 165099 170049 175099 180049 3.2 2.5 3.1 3.0 2.8 4.6 3.4 4.7 5.9 5.5 7.1 4.1 7.2 7.6 6.6 9.7 5.6 8.5 7.1 6.9 10.5 7.0 8.9 6.9 5.1 11.5 8.3 9.2 6.9 5.2 17.7 14.6 9.2 7.7 9.9 4.2 --2.9 3.3 6.6 6.3 -3.8 3.5 8.8 8.0 5.9 4.7 5.3 6.9 -4.1 -4.8 5.7 5.1 3.2 -4.8 5.1 5.3 2.9 -3.8 -8.0 3.1 -3.8 2.1 -1.9 2.7 -2.1 2.1 2.5 2.9 2.6 1.9 3.1 3.8 3.2 3.4 4.4 3.5 4.0 4.3 2.7 2.9 3.5 3.9 4.7 3.8 1.9 2.2 3.2 3.7 4.2 3.7 3.4 2.9 3.0 3.1 4.3 4.8 4.9 2.4 2.1 4.4 -- 11 Silver wage • Silver wage shows conventional pattern: NW Europe pulls ahead of previously more developed South, with central & E. Europe continuing to lag behind • Strong positive correlation with urbanisation ratios 12 Grain wage • TABLE 2: Grain wage = volume of wheat or rye that daily silver wage buys. Regional pattern of grain wage is mirror image of silver wage: – Negative trend in all regions – Highest level of grain wage in central & E. Europe 13 TABLE 2: Grain wage (kg of grain per day) A. Unskilled labourers Wheat Southern England Antwerp Paris Valencia/Madrid Florence/Milan Rye Amsterdam Krakow Vienna Leipzig/Augsburg 150049 155099 160049 165099 170049 175099 180049 10.1 8.8 6.8 10.7 4.7 6.3 7.2 4.9 7.4 3.4 4.0 7.7 6.0 6.3 4.4 5.4 7.4 7.2 7.6 6.1 8.0 9.8 7.2 8.6 5.2 7.0 9.6 6.0 4.8 3.3 8.6 -8.4 -2.8 10.3 48.7 18.6 9.6 8.6 27.9 7.6 5.6 11.5 15.7 9.9 6.0 13.3 18.7 9.0 9.5 17.8 22.7 8.0 8.4 14.0 23.0 7.0 6.1 10.7 -3.1 5.8 14 2B. RELATIVE PRICES AND REAL CONSUMPTION WAGES • High silver wages in NW Europe did not lead to high grain wages before C19th • Real consumption wages may still have risen through increased consumption of non-agric goods & services. • TABLE 3: Real consumption wage of unskilled building labourers, based on basket of commodities, with London 1500-49 = 100 (Allen) 15 TABLE 3: Real consumption wage (London 1500-49=100) Northwestern Europe London Amsterdam Antwerp Paris Southern Europe Valencia Madrid Florence/Milan Naples Central & eastern Europe Gdansk Warsaw Krakow Vienna Leipzig Augsburg 150049 155099 160049 165099 170049 175099 180049 100 97 98 62 85 74 88 60 80 92 93 59 96 98 88 60 110 107 92 56 99 98 88 51 98 79 82 65 79 -62 73 63 56 53 54 62 51 57 69 53 -51 -- 51 58 47 88 41 42 35 50 --26 33 78 -67 88 -62 50 75 74 60 34 50 69 66 65 61 35 39 72 72 67 63 57 63 73 45 58 61 53 55 61 64 63 50 44 50 40 82 40 27 53 -- 16 Real consumption wage • TABLE 3 removes some perplexing aspects of grain wage data in TABLE 2: – Real consumption wage data show opening gap between NW & rest of Europe, as with silver wage data – High grain wages of central & E. Europe don’t translate into high real consumption wages since urban wage earners bought bread not grain & other non-grain items were expensive 17 Real consumption wage • But real consumption wage data still show declining living standards in Europe, 15001800. Divergence due to constant real wage in NW & collapse in periphery. • TABLE 3 based on assumption of constant annual number of days worked. But what about “Industrious Revolution”? 18 2C. STRUCTURAL CHANGE • Allowing for Industrious Revolution is one way of producing modest upward trend of real wages in NW Europe (< 0.2% p.a.) • Structural change would be another way, with shift to higher paying jobs in cities 19 Urbanisation • Already noted correlation between silver wages and urban development. TABLE 4: MIDDLE AGES: • 2 main urban centres in late medieval period, in Low Countries and N. Italy • Urban development lagged in central & E. Europe 20 TABLE 4: European urbanisation rates (%) Scandinavia England (Wales) Scotland Ireland Netherlands Belgium France Italy CN Italy SI Spain Portugal Switzerland Austria (Czech, Hung) Germany Poland Balkans Russia (European) EUROPE 1300 -4.0 -0.8 -18.2 5.2 18.0 9.4 12.1 3.6 3.0 0.6 3.4 1.0 5.2 2.1 5.4 1400 -2.5 -2.1 -21.9 4.7 12.4 3.3 10.2 4.1 2.0 0.5 3.9 1.3 4.6 2.3 4.3 1500 0.7 2.3 2.3 -17.1 17.6 5.0 16.4 12.7 11.4 4.8 2.8 0.8 5.0 5.4 7.7 2.0 5.6 1600 2.1 6.0 1.5 1.0 29.5 15.1 6.3 14.4 18.6 14.5 11.4 2.7 1.6 4.4 6.6 13.3 2.2 7.3 1700 4.3 13.2 5.3 5.1 32.5 20.2 8.7 13.0 16.1 9.6 9.5 3.3 1.7 5.4 3.8 14.0 2.1 8.2 1750 4.6 16.4 11.5 5.1 29.6 16.5 8.7 13.6 19.4 9.1 7.5 4.6 2.6 5.7 3.4 12.3 2.5 8.0 1800 4.6 22.1 23.9 7.3 28.6 16.6 8.9 14.2 21.0 14.7 7.8 3.7 3.1 6.1 4.1 9.8 3.6 8.8 1870 5.5 43.0 36.3 14.2 29.1 25.0 18.1 13.4 26.4 16.4 10.9 8.2 7.7 17.0 7.8 10.6 6.7 15.0 21 Urbanisation EARLY MODERN PERIOD • Urbanisation stalled in N.Italy after 1500 • Brief surge in Portugal and Spain following voyages of discovery • But most dramatic growth in early modern period in NL and GB • Urban development continued to lag in central & E. Europe 22 KEY QUESTION • Were advanced parts of Asia more like NW Europe (as claimed by Pomeranz & Parthasarathi), with high silver wages but modest grain wages? • Or were they more like peripheral Europe, with low silver wages as well as modest grain wages? 23 3. WAGES AND PRICES IN ASIA 3A. SILVER WAGES AND GRAIN WAGES IN INDIA • TABLE 5: daily wages of unskilled & skilled workers in terms of silver content & amount of grain they could buy. 24 TABLE 5: Indian silver and grain wages, 1595-1874 A. Northern and western India Silver wage (grams per day) Unskilled Skilled 1595 0.67 1.62 1616 0.86 1623 1.08 1637 1.08 2.37 1640 1.29 1690 1.40 1874 1.79 5.27 B. Southern India Silver wage (grams per day) Unskilled Skilled 1610-13 1.15 1600-50 1.15 1680 1.44 2.44 1741-50 1.49 1750 (3.02) (7.56) 1779 0.86 1790 1.44 Wheat grain wage (kg per day) Unskilled Skilled 5.2 12.6 3.0 3.8 3.8 8.3 4.5 4.3 2.5 7.5 Rice grain wage (kg per day) Unskilled Skilled 3.1 7.5 2.4 2.9 2.9 6.5 3.5 Rice grain wage (kg per day) Unskilled Skilled 5.7 3.2 3.9 6.9 2.1 (4.2) (10.5) 1.1 1.8 25 NORTH & WEST INDIA • Broad trend for silver wage to rise, with skilled wage double unskilled wage. • Silver wages failed to increase as much as grain prices, so grain wages trended downwards 26 SOUTH INDIA • Southern figures generally accord well with Northern data, but Parthasarathi’s figures for 1750 in parentheses. Difficult to square with other data • Parthasarathi claims support from work of Brennig. But: – Parthasarathi finds high grain wage as result of high money wage and conventional grain price – Brennig finds high grain wage as result of conventional money wage but low grain price • Neither Parthasarathi’s high money wage nor Brennig’s low grain price fits into the wider picture of trends over time and across regions 27 3B. AN ANGLO-INDIAN COMPARISON • TABLE 6: Direct Anglo-Indian comparison of silver wages & grain wages for unskilled workers SILVER WAGES: • Great Divergence already well established by C16th: • Indian silver wage little more than one-fifth English level in late C16th, falling to c. oneseventh of English level during C18th • Even if included Parthasarathi’s estimates, Indian silver wage still only 40% of English level 28 TABLE 6A: Anglo-Indian comparison of silver wages A. Silver wages (grams of silver per day) Date Southern India Indian wage as % England of English wage 1550-99 3.4 0.7 21 1600-49 4.1 1.1 27 1650-99 5.6 1.4 25 1700-49 7.0 1.5 21 1750-99 8.3 1.2 14 1800-49 14.6 1.8 12 29 GRAIN WAGES • • • Indian grain wage remained close to English level until end of C17th Sharp divergence in C18th , as result of rise in English grain wage as well as decline in Indian grain wage India looks more like peripheral parts of Europe than developing NW Europe 30 TABLE 6B: Anglo-Indian comparison of grain wages B. Grain wages (kilograms of grain per day) England India Date (wheat) (wheat) (rice, on wheat equivalent basis) 1550-99 6.3 5.2 1600-49 4.0 3.8 1650-99 5.4 4.3 1700-49 8.0 3.2 1750-99 7.0 2.3 1800-49 8.6 2.5 Indian wage as % of English wage 83 95 80 40 33 29 31 3C. SILVER WAGES AND GRAIN WAGES IN CHINA • Detailed data on grain prices available by region for Qing dynasty (1644-1911) as result of monthly reporting system • No systematic money wage data, since money wages typically supplemented by substantial food allowances (even among urban building workers). Have to rely on scattered estimates for agricultural labourers • Focus on Yangzi delta region, claimed by Pomeranz to be on same development level as England in 1800 32 Yangzi delta • TABLE 7: Silver & grain wages in Yangzi delta: – Small drop in silver wages between Late Ming & Mid Qing periods – Unskilled silver wage in China about same as in India, small fraction of silver wage in NW Europe – Price of rice increased between Late Ming & Mid Qing periods, so grain wage declined sharply • Grain wage in Yangzi delta similar to Indian grain wage 33 TABLE 7: Daily wage of hired farm laborers in the Yangzi delta, 1573-1850 Money wage (taels) Silver wage (grams of silver) Grain wage (kg of rice) Late Ming 1573-1644 0.04 1.5 3.0 Mid Qing 1736-1850 0.033 1.2 1.5 34 Anglo-Chinese comparison • TABLE 8: Anglo-Chinese comparison, similar to Anglo-Indian comparison: – Silver wage already much lower in Yangzi delta than in England by Late Ming period. – Yangzi delta grain wage close to English level in Late Ming period, but had fallen decisively behind by Mid Qing period. 35 TABLE 8: Anglo-Chinese wage comparison A. Silver wages (grams of silver per day) Date Southern Yangzi Chinese wage as % England delta of English wage 1550-1649 3.8 1.5 39 1750-1849 11.5 1.7 15 B. Grain wages (kilograms of grain per day) England Yangzi delta Date (wheat) (rice) (rice, on wheat equivalent basis) 1550-1649 5.2 3.0 4.5 1750-1849 7.8 2.0 3.0 Chinese wage as % of English wage 87 38 36 3D. URBANISATION AND STRUCTURE OF THE CHINESE ECONOMY • TABLE 9: Urbanisation ratio in China compared with Europe. Rozman’s data for all urban areas adjusted onto basis of cities of > 10,000 inhabitants, for comparison with Europe: – Urbanisation already higher in Europe than in China during Ming dynasty – Europe’s advantage had grown substantially by early C19th (esp in England & Wales). 37 TABLE 9: Urban shares of the population in China and Europe, 618-1820 (%) China All urban Cities > 10,000 Europe Cities > 10,000 Tang 618-906 Song 960-1279 Ming 1368-1644 Early Qing 1644-1736 Early 19th century 4.7 3.0 5.2 3.7 6.5 4.9 6.8 6.0 5.9 3.8 -- -- 7.6 9.2 10.0 38 Chinese urbanisation • TABLE 10: Regional breakdown of urbanisation ratios for China suggests much flatter development gradient than in Europe: – Most developed part of China (Yangzi delta) is in Jiangsu, in east central China – Urbanisation ratio highest here, but scale of difference with poorer regions not large • Urbanisation data, like wage data, suggest Yangzi delta on same development level as peripheral parts of Europe, not the NW core. 39 TABLE 10: Regional variations in the Chinese urbanisation ratio in the mid-19th century (%) Northern China Shandong Shanxi Henan Northwestern China Shaanxi Gansu East central China Anhui Jiangsu Zheijiang Central China Hubei Hunan Jiangxi Southeastern China Fujian Guangdong Guangxi Southwestern China Guizhou Yunnan Sichuan All urban Cities >10,000 4.4 4.0 5.0 2.6 2.0 2.2 7.3 4.3 4.5 2.3 4.0 7.4 6.1 1.9 5.6 4.1 6.0 5.2 6.3 4.0 2.8 3.8 8.2 6.7 6.1 5.3 5.0 3.3 5.8 4.4 6.0 3.3 2.5 3.6 40 4. EXPLAINING EUROPE-ASIA WAGEPRICE DIFFERENCES 4A. BULLION FLOWS AND PRICE INFLATION • Although silver wages in India & China much lower than in NW Europe as far back as C16th, grain wages quite close until end of C17th. Could this just be a monetary phenomenon? • One possible explanation could be flow of precious metals from New World into Europe during C16th. Quantity Theory of Money would suggest higher prices & wages without any real effect on standard of living 41 Bullion flows and inflation • There was price inflation in Europe during C16th, attributed by some writers to bullion flows (e.g. Hamilton; Braudel & Spooner) • But this does not work as explanation of much higher silver wages in Europe cf Asia. Bullion also flowed to Asia. • Higher silver wages result of real economic development. This clear when consider regional patterns within Europe, since although prices moved together closely, wages diverged 42 CONVERGENT PRICES • • • • • Bullion flows entered Europe through Spain, but prices moved closely together in all European countries (Abel) This consistent with classical price-specie-flow mechanism: initial increase in Spanish prices leads to reduction in exports & increase in imports, & hence to Spanish BOP deficit Spanish BOP deficit outflow of bullion from Spain rising price level in bullion receiving countries Problems with timing of bullion flows & inflation in particular countries reformulation in terms of monetary approach to BOP Law of one price: price of traded goods increases increase in money demand 43 DIVERGENT WAGES • • • While prices rose along same trend in all European countries, Spain lost its position as high silver wage country, while England saw biggest long run gains Suggests shift of silver wage leadership from S. Europe to NW Europe reflected real economic forces rather than monetary forces India & China look more like stagnating parts of European periphery than NW core 44 4B. ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND THE REAL EXCHANGE RATE • Development economists see rel between PPPconverted & ER-converted levels of p.c. income as conditioned upon real factors affecting structure of economy (e.g. Kravis; Bhagwati) • We see relatopnship between grain wages & silver wages on comparative basis as related to these same structural characteristics • Key results can be shown in 2-country, 2commodity Ricardian model, with constant returns to single factor of production, labour 45 Model assumptions • Applying model to early modern international economy: • Treat grain as non-tradable commodity & cloth as tradable commodity. • Grain bulky & costly to transport so price not equalised between Europe & Asia • Cloth widely traded between Europe & Asia • 2 countries, Asia and Europe (i = A, E) 46 Results • One international price for tradable good measured in common unit of account, silver. piT = pT • With single factor, labour, silver wage equal to revenue productivity of labour: wi = pT αiT (1) Hence country with higher productivity in tradable sector has higher silver wage • Wages equalised across sectors within each country, so this is also silver wage in grain sector. 47 Price of non-tradables • Price of non-tradable commodity equal to silver wage divided by productivity in nontradable sector: piN = wi / αiN (2) • Substituting for wages from (1): piN = αiT pT / αiN (3) • Price of non-tradable commodity reduced by high productivity in non-tradable sector as well as increased by high productivity in tradable sector 48 Grain wage • Grain wage is silver wage divided by price of non-tradable commodity. Rearranging (2): wi / piN = αiN (4) • Grain wages affected only by productivity in non-tradable sector, not by productivity in tradable sector 49 Real consumption wage • Consumption price given by weighted geometric average of prices of tradable & non-tradable goods. Real consumption wage given by: wi / pi = (αiT)β(αiN)1-β (4) • If grain wage equal in England & India but silver wage higher in England, real consumption wage lower in India by factor depending on weight . • Low silver wages in Asia reflected low productivity in cloth sector. Asian countries produced cheaper grain as result of lower silver wages, so grain wages almost as high as in NW Europe 50 CONCLUSIONS • Prosperous parts of Asia 1500-1800 look similar to stagnating parts of European periphery rather than developing NW core • Although Indian & Chinese grain wages comparable to NW Europe, silver wages substantially lower. This is exactly pattern observed in less developed parts of Europe • Great Divergence well underway before 1800. • Need to understand higher productivity in European traded goods sector at this time as reflecting developments in distribution as much as production (e.g. EIC and VOC) 51 TOPIC 2: WAGES, PRICES AND THE GREAT DIVERGENCE: LECTURE OUTLINE • • • • • B. WELFARE RATIOS 1. The respectability basket 2. The subsistence basket 3. Welfare ratios in Europe and Asia 4. Welfare ratios within Asia 52 WELFARE RATIOS • Allen (2001) introduced a novel way of comparing wages across countries , which has caught on • He asked if money wages were sufficient to buy the goods needed to sustain life for a family • Allen did this by first working out the cost of a basket of goods, with expenditure weights derived from the budget studies of Sir Frederick Eden and other social investigators from the late C18th and early C19th 53 Welfare ratios • The welfare ratio is the number of such baskets that can be purchased with a worker’s daily wage • The basic idea is that if this ratio is above one, then a society is living above subsistence and is able to reproduce, and as the ratio increases further, to thrive • Allen et al (2011) compare Europe and Asia using this welfare ratio methodology, and find, like Broadberry and Gupta, that from the C18th, the richest parts of Asia were on a par with the periphery of Europe, rather than the core 54 1. THE RESPECTABILITY BASKET • In the first basket of goods that Allen (2000) worked with, a working adult was assumed to require 2,500 calories per day, with bread supplying over 1,500 calories • A substantial share of calories was obtained from products that the respectable worker would want to consume: meat, dairy produce and beer • The protein intake was also considered in arriving at this basket • In slightly modified form, this has come to be known as the “respectability basket” 55 TABLE 1: The respectable lifestyle: basket of goods Quantity per person per year Bread Beans/peas Meat Butter Cheese Eggs Beer Soap Linen Candles Lamp oil Fuel Total 234 kg 52 litres 26 kg 5.2 kg 5.2 kg 52 each 182 litres 2.6 kg 5m 2.6 kg 2.6 litres 5.0 M BTU Price, Spending Nutrients/day grams of share (%) Calories Grams of silver per protein unit 0.693 36.0 1,571 64 0.477 5.5 370 28 2.213 12.8 178 14 3.470 4.0 104 0 2.843 3.3 54 3 0.010 1.1 11 1 0.470 20.0 212 2 2.880 1.7 --4.369 4.8 --4.980 2.9 --7.545 4.3 --4.164 4.6 --450.956 100.0 2,500 112 Soure: Allen (2009: 36) 56 Welfare ratios using the respectability basket • Allen (2000) assumed that since women and children required less calories than a working male adult, a family of a father, mother and 3 children required 3 baskets, with an additional allowance of 5% for rent • He then calculated the welfare ratio as the silver wage divided by the silver cost of 3.15 respectability baskets • A problem which Allen encountered in his (2000) paper was that for much of the time in most European countries, welfare ratios for unskilled building labourers were below one 57 TABLE 2: Welfare ratios: building labourers Antwerp Amsterdam London Florence/Milan Naples Valencia Madrid Paris Strasbourg Augsburg Leipzig Vienna Gdansk Krakow Warsaw 1500-49 1.40 1.37 1.42 0.92 1.04 1.15 -0.89 1.27 0.92 -1.24 1.07 0.97 -- 1550-99 1.28 1.07 1.26 0.78 0.77 0.90 0.80 0.87 0.74 0.72 0.49 0.89 0.73 1.06 1.11 1600-49 1.36 1.34 1.16 0.73 1.01 0.89 0.74 0.85 0.70 0.58 0.61 0.88 0.96 0.92 0.93 1650-99 1.28 1.42 1.37 0.72 -0.76 -0.87 0.56 0.93 0.80 0.91 1.05 0.96 1.01 1700-49 1.34 1.55 1.58 0.70 0.96 0.75 0.87 0.80 0.57 0.80 0.75 0.87 1.05 0.85 0.67 1750-99 1.28 1.41 1.42 0.51 0.75 0.59 0.64 0.74 0.61 0.71 0.64 0.71 0.89 0.88 0.93 1800-49 1.21 1.13 1.41 0.39 0.47 -0.95 1.08 0.85 -0.80 0.54 0.62 0.60 1.18 Source: Allen (2000: 428) 58 2. THE SUBSISTENCE BASKET • If welfare ratios were less than one for sustained periods of time, this implied that workers were not earning enough to work and reproduce • This was clearly an unsatisfactory conclusion to reach, since Europe managed over this period to make the transition to modern economic growth • Allen’s solution was to come up with the subsistence or “bare bones” basket 59 TABLE 3: Subsistence incomes: baskets of goods Sorghum Oats Beans/peas Meat Butter/oil Soap Cotton/Linen Candles Lamp oil Fuel Total European oats Nutrients/day Quantity per person per Calories Protein year ---72 1,657 155 kg 14 187 20 kg 3 34 5 kg 0 60 3 kg --1.3 kg --3m --1.3 kg --1.3 ltr --2.0 M BTU 89 1,938 Beijing sorghum Nutrients/day Quantity per person per Calories Protein year 55 1,667 179 kg ---14 187 20 kg 2 21 3 kg 0 67 3 kg --1.3 kg --3m --1.3 kg --1.3 ltr --2.0 M BTU 71 1,942 Source: Allen (2009: 37). 60 Subsistence basket • Workers with low wages did not consume large amounts of meat, dairy produce and beer • Furthermore, in Europe, they got most of their calories from cheap grains such as oats, rather than from expensive wheat bread • In Asia, poorer unskilled workers consumed sorghum rather than rice 61 3. WELFARE RATIOS IN EUROPE AND ASIA • Allen et al (2011) fist compare the welfare ratio of unskilled male labourers in Beijing with 4 European cities in the C18th and C19th (Figure 1, here) • During the C18th, Beijing’s welfare ratio trended downwards from a just under 2 to just above 1 by the beginning of the C19th, where it fluctuated until the 1870s • Living standards in C18th Beijing were roughly on a par with the peripheral parts of Europe, represented here by Milan and Leipzig 62 FIGURE 1: Welfare ratios for unskilled male workers Source: Allen et al. (2011: 27). 63 Welfare ratios in Europe and Asia • Welfare ratios in London and Amsterdam were already substantially ahead of the rest of Europe, with a value of 3 to 4 in the C18th • This does not mean that those workers ate 3 or 4 times as much oatmeal as they needed to survive • Rather they consumed higher quality foodstuffs (beef, beer and bread) and a wider range of non-food items • By this stage, even most unskilled workers in London and Amsterdam could afford the respectability lifestyle 64 4. WELFARE RATIOS WITHIN ASIA • It is also useful to compare welfare ratios within Asia (Figure 2) • The first point to note is that welfare ratios were no higher in the Suzhou than in Beijing. This is significant because Suzhou was in the Yangzi Delta • Canton in southern China also had welfare ratios fluctuating between about 1 and 2 65 FIGURE 1: Welfare ratios in Asia 66 Welfare ratios within Asia • Allen et al. also bring India into the analysis, finding that welfare ratios in Bengal were about the same as in other parts of Asia • Finally, Kyoto/Tokyo also fluctuates around the same level as the other Asian cities • These conclusions confirm the findings of Broadberry and Gupta (2006): NW Europe was already substantially ahead of the rest of Europe and Asia by the C18th 67 Early Modern Great Divergence • Contrary to the claims of the California School, the Great Divergence was therefore already underway well before 1800 • It is therefore necessary to reach back at least into the early modern period to understand the origins of the Great Divergence 68