Increasing Returns to Scale in Thailand’s Manufacturing Industry By Nat Tharnpanich 23/09/09 Thailand’s spatial inequality Manufacturing establishments tend to be in a large scale and concentrated in the same area (Arayah 2006). Population growth rate in Bangkok metropolitan area is three times as high as those in other mega-cities in developed countries (World Bank 2009) and has produced around one-half of the nation’s GDP (Wisaweisuan 2009). Evidence of catch-up behaviour is found in the Central plain and the East with thriving industrial activities while other regions are still stagnated (Wisaweisuan 2009). Increasing Returns to Scale (IRS) Static and internal or firm-level - reduction in average cost Dynamic - learning by doing as a function of cumulative output External - agglomeration economies which explains why cities exist “Backyard Capitalism” (Krugman, 1991) Objectives of this presentation To measure the degree of returns to scale in Thailand’s manufacturing industry To discuss the role of the degree of returns to scale in economic growth History of IRS Adam Smith (1776) – the Wealth of Nations – Division of labour depends on the extent of the market Marshall (1920) – Within-industry Allyn Young (1928) – Between-industry Why were IRS ignored? Lack of mathematical tools to model IRS CRS and diminishing returns to factors of production became increasingly popular in mid 19th century. Perfect competition and convexity are needed to prove the uniqueness of Walasian general equilibrium It has increasingly received more attention in economics literature such as New Urban Economics and New Economic Geography Neoclassical growth model Assumptions – CRS in production – Perfect competition – Perfect factor substitutability, K/L is determined solely by wage-rental ratio. – Well-behaved aggregate production function – Diminishing marginal productivity wrt capital and labour Growth accounting by Denison (1962) also relies on these assumptions. Supply-side model Predicts convergence Shortcomings of Neoclassical growth model Unsatisfactory empirical support Ignoring contribution of demand factors No explanation as to how supply-side factors are different Closed economy Very sectorally neutral IRS in neoclassical theory Limited to the context of theory of cost Firm-level Static and internal Production Function Approach Cobb-Douglas or CES production function Qt = AeλtLαKβ qt = c + αlt + βkt Usually CRS or small IRS are found with a very good fit. Weaknesses of the Production Function Approach When using time-series monetary data, it merely captures the income identity (Felipe et al. 2004). Qt ≡ wtLt + rtKt qt ≡ aφwt + (1-a)φrt + alt + (1-a)kt qt = c + αlt + βkt Thus, the α and β will always equal factor shares which add up to unity which indicates the existence of CRS. Cumulative Causation Theory Growth is demand-determined. Factors of production are endogenous. Capital accumulation (technique of production or K/L ratio) is determined primarily by the scale of production rather than by wage-rental ratio, causing circular and cumulative growth process. IRS as a lynchpin of cumulative growth process Manufacturing as an engine of growth Surplus labour Export-led growth model What determines growth of demand in the first place? It is export demand. qt = γ(xt) pt = a + λqt rdt = wt – pt - τt xt = η (rdt - rft) + εzt xt qt rdt pt Export-led growth model -pd=f2(r) This is an equilibrium model. r Verdoorn’s law r = f1(q) wt rdt t p ft zt q 1 * t Predicts sustained or widening regional disparities q* q -pd Export demand x = f3(-pd) Sustained growth x q = f4(x) Verdoorn’s law pt = a + λqt where λ ≈ 0.5 Measures IRS broadly defined It is a source of regional disparities when other parameters are the same between regions. Also serves to amplify the existing regional disparities. Data Industrial Census 1997 and 2007 from NSO Cross-region within a country 23,677 and 34,625 establishments throughout the kingdom with 10 and 11 persons or more engaged respectively Variable Proxy Gross output Value added Labour Total workers and total working hours Capital Book value fixed assets less value of land Verdoorn’s law specifications Specifications Condition Degree of returns to scale et = a1 + b1qt b1 < 1 1/b1 et = a2 + b2qt+ c2kt b2 < 1 1/b2 tfit = a3 + b3qt where tfit=αlt–(1α)kt b3 < 1 1/b3 Outliers and leverage points are detected by using DFITS statistics Results: et = a1 + b1qt Industry Degree of returns to scale Total manufacturing b1 0.359** Food and allied 0.154*** 6.49 Textiles 0.297*** 3.37 Apparel and related 0.297*** 3.37 Paper and related 0.253*** 3.95 Chemicals and allied 0.040*** 25.00 Rubber and plastic 0.706*** 1.42 Non-metallic mineral 0.249*** 4.02 Metal 0.129*** 7.75 Machinery and related 0.275*** 3.64 Motor vehicles and allied 0.602*** 1.66 Wood and furniture 0.219*** 4.57 2.79 Results: et = a2 + b2qt+ c2kt Industry b2 c2 Degree of returns to scale (1/b2) Total manufacturing 0.377** 0.065 2.65 Food and allied 0.144*** 0.261 6.94 Textiles 0.279*** 0.191 3.58 Apparel and related 0.248*** 0.293*** Paper and related 4.03 0.057 0.303*** 17.54 Chemicals and allied 0.041** -0.003 24.39 Rubber and plastic 0.476*** 0.039 2.10 Non-metallic mineral 0.259*** 0.096*** 3.86 Metal 0.097** 0.046 10.31 Machinery and related 0.182*** 0.300 5.49 Motor vehicles and allied 0.637*** 0.005 1.57 Wood and furniture 0.235*** 0.203** 4.26 Results: tfit = a3 + b3qt Industry Degree of returns to scale Total manufacturing b3 0.379*** Food and allied 0.102** 9.80 Textiles 0.517*** 1.93 Apparel and related 0.256** 3.91 Paper and related 0.552*** 1.81 Chemicals and allied 0.525*** 1.90 Rubber and plastic 0.663*** 1.51 Non-metallic mineral 0.383*** 2.61 Metal 0.215*** 4.65 Machinery and related 0.483*** 2.07 Motor vehicles and allied 0.863*** 1.16 Wood and furniture 0.478*** 2.09 2.84 Augmented Verdoorn’s law Proxy Other determinants of productivity growth Technological diffusion from high- lnTFP0 where to low-technology regions TFP = Qj/LjαKj 1-α Q Density (Ciccone and Hall 1996) log j H j Specialisation (Marshall-ArrowRomer) Diversity (Jacobs 1969) Q ij Q j Q iT QT N Q Q k i j kj Q ij H j Q iT H T Q kj Qj 2 N k i tfp = β0+β1qt + β2lnTFP0 + β3Density + β4Specialisation, β5Diversity) Augmented Verdoorn’s law Industry qt lnTFP0 DEN SPEC DIV v ( 1/(1β1) Total 0.369*** -0.674*** 0.228*** na na 1.59 Food 0.820*** -0.520*** 0.172** -0.015 0.923 5.56 Textiles 0.691*** -4.310** 1.592** -0.129 -16.644 3.24 Apparel 0.638*** -5.703*** 0.981*** -0.009 -1.273 2.76 Paper 0.360*** -1.124*** 0.169 -0.0002 -0.292 1.56 Chemicals 0.415*** 1.166*** -0.120 0.014 -7.991 1.71 Rubber and plastic 0.183*** -0.426* 0.058 -0.016 -1.054 1.22 Non-metalic mineral 0.567*** -0.345** -0.130 0.008 -0.173 2.31 Metal 0.762*** -0.559** 0.024 0002 -1.015 4.20 Machinery 0.632*** -2.141*** 0.380 -0.027 0.374 2.72 Motor vehicles 0.043 -0.974*** 0.254*** 0.004 3.013 1.04 Wood 0.405*** -1.481*** 0.925*** -0.086 3.988 1.68 Verdoorn’s law controversies Simultaneous equation bias Static-dynamic Verdoorn law paradox Simultaneous equation bias Supply-side specification qt = a4+b4tfit or tfpt = a5+b5tfit b4 > 1 or b5 > 0 CRS or DRS are usually found The use of cross-regional data makes it possible to assume away the supplyside constraint. Output growth Productivity growth Results: tfpt = a4+b4tfit Industry tfi Degree of returns to scale Total manufacturing -0.627*** 0.373 DRS Food and allied -0.667*** 0.333 DRS Textiles -0.681*** 0.319 DRS Apparel and related -0.552*** 0.448 DRS -0.144 0.856 CRS -0.623*** 0.377 DRS Rubber and plastic -0.038 0.962 CRS Non-metallic mineral 0.074 1.074 CRS 1.207*** 2.207 IRS Machinery and related -0.01 0.99 CRS Motor vehicles and allied -0.061 0.939 CRS Wood and furniture -0.209 0.791 CRS Paper and related Chemicals and allied Metal The static-dynamic Verdoorn law paradox Dynamic version (tfi = a + bq) strong IRS are found Static or log-level version (lnTFI = a + blnQ) CRS or small IRS are found The biased result is caused by Spatial Aggregation Bias (McCombie and Roberts, 2007) Spatial Aggregation Bias The ideal spatial production unit is Functional Economic Area (FEA) At FEA-level, Verdoorn’s law is a power 0.5 relationship. TFI = cQ . However, values of each FEA are summed arithmetically. Spatial Aggregation Bias, TFI = cQ 0.5 Region No.of FEAs TFIj Qj lnTFIj lnQj 1 1 10 100 ln10 2ln10 2 2 20 200 ln2+ln10 ln2+2ln10 3 3 30 300 ln3+ln10 ln3+2ln10 . . . . . . . . . . TFI0*nj Q0*nj lnj+ln10 lnj+2ln10 j nj(=j) 6 Cross-sectional static VL 5 t=0 4 2 3 lnTFI t=1 5 6 7 8 lnQ Cross sectional lnTFIi = α+βlnQi + εi Cross sectional with time dummy lnTFIi = α+βlnQi +ψDt+ εi Time fixed effects lnTFIit = αt+ βlnQit + εit All yield biased Verdoorn relationship 6 Time series static VL R=1 t=1 4 R=2 2 3 lnTFI 5 t=0 4 6 8 10 12 lnQ Time-series lnTFIt = α + βlnQt + εt Regional fixed effects lnTFIit = αi+ βlnQit + εit Both yield unbiased Verdoorn relationship. However, it merely captures Okun’s law. Nothing is related to IRS. Data should be cross-regional in dynamic version VL. Fixed effects static VL Industry Time Region Two way lnQ v lnQ v lnQ v Total 0.170*** 1.20 0.723*** 3.61 0.749*** 3.98 Food 0.284*** 1.40 0.828*** 5.81 0.815*** 5.41 Textiles 0.161*** 1.19 0.370*** 1.59 0.380*** 1.61 Apparel 0.148*** 1.17 0.401*** 1.67 0.508*** 2.03 Paper 0.165*** 1.20 0.378*** 1.61 0.390*** 1.64 Chemicals 0.200*** 1.25 0.540*** 2.17 0.546*** 2.20 Rubber and plastic 0.169*** 1.20 0.412*** 1.70 0.410*** 1.69 Non-metalic mineral 0.202*** 1.25 0.473*** 1.90 0.502*** 2.01 Metal 0.121*** 1.14 0.517*** 2.07 0.518*** 2.07 Machinery 0.137*** 1.16 0.529*** 2.12 0.571*** 2.33 Motor vehicles 0.177*** 1.22 0.271*** 1.37 0.270*** 1.37 Wood 0.178*** 1.22 0.440*** 1.79 0.470*** 1.89 Conclusion The existence of IRS, broadly defined, is indisputable. With IRS, virtuous circle of growth is possible, causing regional disparities. Growth is supply- as well as demanddetermined. Policies that can effectively manage both demand- and supply-side factors are needed to eliminate regional disparities. Suggested Further Reading Thirlwall, A. P. (2002). The Nature of Economic Growth: An Alternative Framework for Understanding the Performance of Nations. Cheltenham : Edwards Elgar. McCombie, J. S. L., Pugno, M., and Soro, B. (2002). Productivity Growth and Economic Performance : Essays on Verdoorn’s Law. Basingstroke, Palgrave Macmillan. McCombie, J. S. L. and Thirlwall, A. P. (1994). Economic growth and Balance-of-Payments Constraint. Basingstroke, Macmillan.