04/07/15(text9269w;total=11,462w) CHILE SINCE 1999: FROM COUNTER-CYCLICAL TO PRO-CYCLICAL MACROECONOMICS* Ricardo Ffrench-Davis** Abstract: In the 15 years from 1999 to 2013, Chilean GDP growth averaged 3.9%. Although this was above the 3.2% Latin American average, it represented a sharp drop from the country's sustained 7% annual growth recorded in 1990-98, the first nine years after its return to democracy. This article seeks to explain this significant outcome reversal. Given the absence of deep backwards steps in the microeconomic approach, we focus on macroeconomic policies. Two cycles are distinguished: a) 1999-2007, between contagion from the Asian crisis and a peak in economic activity in 2007 before the contagion from the global crisis, and b) 2008-2013, between the start of recession in 2008 and a GDP peak in 2013, just before a significant new deceleration. We show that the adoption of inflation targeting combined with full opening of the capital account and exchange-rate liberalisation successfully kept inflation low and avoided balance of payments crises, but implied that the economy was usually operating below potential output, while the exchange rate and current account became extremely unstable. Pro-cyclical financial markets and the price of copper again became active channels of transmission of external instability to domestic macroeconomic markets. On the other hand, fiscal policy moved from being rather neutral to effectively counter-cyclical in 2009-10, but it became pro-cyclical in 2011-13. Macroeconomic pro-cyclicality discouraged capital formation and productivity. Real macroeconomic instability was a determinant variable underlying the worsened growth outcome. The paper concludes with some policy proposals for speeding development convergence. JEL E63, O11,O23,N16,F31,F62 macroeconomic policies, cycles, real stability, development, Chile INTRODUCTION During the late 1990s, macroeconomic policies in Chile underwent a deep change with respect to the approach adopted immediately after the return to democracy in 1990.1 In the early 1990s, the new authorities implemented a quite comprehensive counter-cyclical macroeconomic approach that included systematic prudential regulation of capital inflows, actively managed exchangerate flexibility and a monetary policy concerned with not only inflation but also * To be published in Comparative Economic Studies, September 2015, Palgrave Journals; online since April 2. I appreciate the research support of Nicolás Fernández and Simón Ballesteros and the highly useful comments of the editor Paul Wachtel and a referee. ** Professor of Economics, University of Chile; PH.D. University of Chicago. 1 Economic reforms, policies and outcomes in Chile since the military coup of 1973 are covered in Ffrench-Davis (2010c); an update in Spanish is in Ffrench-Davis (2014). 1 sustained growth, implying balances in the external and fiscal sectors and of employment. This approach was highly successful, delivering a 7.1% average GDP growth in 1990-98, with a sharp reduction in poverty, higher employment and some improvement in income distribution. That outcome was in marked contrast to the 2.9% average GDP growth and rise in poverty and inequality seen during the previous 16 years under the Pinochet dictatorship.2 A key feature of the neo-liberal experiment of those years was high stability of consumer prices (CPI). However, during most of the period, this was accompanied by great real economic disequilibria, severe unemployment, external imbalances and unstable aggregate demand. In this context, depressed capital formation was the main variable determining the meagre 2.9% GDP growth achieved in 1974-89.3 The successful record of the 1990-98 period was broken by contagion from the Asian crisis. In the fifteen years from 1999 to 2013, average growth declined from the previous 7.1% to 3.9%. Although above the 3.2% average for Latin America,4 this implied a sharp drop with respect to Chile's track record in the 1990s. In this chapter, I seek to explain this significant reversal. Given that there were not important backwards steps as regards microeconomic policies, it focuses on macroeconomic policies stressing the quite significant changes between the two periods. We show that the adoption of inflation targeting combined with full opening of the capital account and full liberalisation of the exchange rate was successful in keeping inflation low and avoiding balance of payments crises, but implied that the real economy --the production and use of GDP-- usually operated below potential output and the exchange rate became extremely unstable, both of which depressed the sources of economic growth.5 The causes of the significant change in policy approach are explored. 2 The economy experienced two deep recessions (in 1975 and 1982) and overheating in 1989, with GDP growth fluctuating between plus 10% and minus 17%, with the 2.9% cumulative average for the 16 years (Ffrench-Davis, 2010c, Chapter I). 3 Between 1973 and 1989, the development gap with respect to the G-7 increased. Per capita income (PPP) in Chile fell from 29% of that of the G-7 in 1973 to 25% in 1989; in other words, development divergence prevailed. 4 Interestingly, Latin America's GDP growth was similar in 1990-98 and in 1999-2013. In the first period, Chile far outpaced the region while, in the latter, it tended to converge with the region's poor performance. 5 There is a series of outstanding works by Latin Americans on an approach concerned with the real economy, beyond the CPI. I cite three of them: ECLAC (2010) on economics and inequality; Ocampo 2 Four macroeconomic policies are analysed: the monetary, exchange-rate and capital-account policies of the Central Bank and the fiscal policy of the Finance Ministry, as well as the degree of coordination between both institutions. After a brief description of the macroeconomic framework (Section 1), two cycles are distinguished in the evolution of policies and outcomes: i) 1999-2007, from the peak of economic activity before contagion from the Asian crisis through the five-year recession that followed and the subsequent recovery, led by rising commodity prices, up to a peak in 2007 before the start of contagion from the global crisis (Section 2); and ii) 2008-13, from contagion by the global crisis through the 2010-13 recovery process (Section 3). Section 4 concludes with some policy lessons for speeding development convergence. 1. The macroeconomic framework When a democratically-elected government came to power in March 1990, there was a new “independent” Central Bank, established in December 1989 by General Pinochet, a week before the presidential election that was evidently going to be won by the opposition to the dictatorship. Since then, the Bank has been headed by a board with five members --one of whom is replaced each two years-- nominated by the President with the approval of the Senate. In the initial board, “negotiated” with the opposition, there were two representatives of the dictatorship, two of the democratic opposition and one “independent”. The Bank is responsible for the stability of the currency and the normal working of domestic and foreign payments. While the first objective has been understood as stability of the CPI, interpretation of the other two objectives has varied. Monetary policy is implemented mostly through the monetary policy interest rate which applies to Central Bank operations with commercial banks. Until 1996, the Central Bank cooperated closely with the Finance Ministry and together they implemented a set of counter-cyclical or prudential macroeconomic policies. Subsequently, however, the Bank stressed its “independence”. (2011) on macro/micro links and Frenkel and Rapetti (2011) on exchange rate policy. An excellent related book is Ocampo and Ros (2011). I summarise my views on macroeconomics for development in Ffrench-Davis (2010b). 3 In 1990, in parallel to the return to democracy in Chile, capital inflows into Latin America increased sharply. The Chilean authorities reacted with countercyclical measures consistent with their objective of developing exports with value-added and maintaining equilibrium of the real economy with a non-outlier real exchange rate and a level of aggregate demand consistent with potential GDP. Counter-cyclical regulation dealt particularly with capital inflows. The Central Bank imposed an un-remunerated reserve requirement (URR, encaje in Spanish) on all capital inflows (except FDI capital), that fluctuated between 20% and 30% of the incoming amount and had to be held at the Bank for 90-360 days. The intensity of the regulation (rate and time retained) was related to the strength of the supply of inflows and the gap between aggregate demand and potential GDP (Ffrench-Davis, 2014, Chapter VIII; Magud and Reinhart, 2007). Given the Chilean economy's apparent immunity to the Mexican (Tequila) crisis in 1995 and an international fashion in favour of open capital accounts, the URR was gradually weakened and then suspended in 1999. Since 1986, the banking sector has been strictly regulated and supervised. This followed the severe banking crisis of 1982, associated with an unregulated privatisation and liberalisation of the domestic financial sector in 1975. Notwithstanding strong pressures for relaxation of regulation in around 1990, after several Latin American countries adopted the Washington Consensus, the Chilean authorities maintained a rather prudential stance. The exchange rate was subject to a crawling-peg regime (Williamson, 2000; Edwards and Rigobón, 2009), with a band managed by the Central Bank and was, in general, linked to the evolution of both domestic and trade partners' inflation and the current account. The fiscal budget showed an average surplus of 2% of GDP in 1990-98. Increased social expenditure and public investment was financed with a tax reform launched in the first months after the return to democracy. The private pension administrators (AFPs) created in 1981--an increasingly important institutional agent--, were gradually authorised by the Central Bank to invest part of their assets abroad, with the percentage of total portfolio rising from 6% to 12% by 1997. In practice, however, they invested less than 1% abroad, principally because they considered the domestic market more profitable, with expectations of exchange rate appreciation as a determinant variable. 4 Table 1 summarises several macroeconomic indicators. Figures are presented for the successful 1990-98 period; the cycle that started in 1999 and ended in 2007 before contagion from the global crisis; and the cycle that started in 2008 and ended in 2013. Within these two cycles, the figures for the recessive 1999-2003 and 2009 sub-periods are shown. Table 1 2. In between the Asian and global crises a) A recessive macro environment dominated by a procyclical capital account: 1999-2003 In the late 1990s, the Central Bank gradually weakened the successful countercyclical policies it had adopted at the start of the decade. In September 1999, amidst contagion from the Asian crisis, it renounced to the managed flexibility of the exchange rate (ER) and adopted a fully free floating rate.6 During the previous couple of years, the exchange rate had appreciated significantly, contributing to anchor inflation. Now, however, given the negative external shocks, there was an evident need for a large devaluation which, announced as a permanent commitment of the Bank to a fully flexible rate, was left to the market. By that time, there was already an important relevant recessive gap (the output gap between potential GDP and actual GDP, or recessive gap, RG) which deterred the pass-through effect of the devaluation that took place. At the same time, counter-inflation was taking predominance over other macroeconomic targets, with a gradual move towards formal inflation targeting. The adoption of this approach, now in agreement with the Finance Ministry,7 was announced in 1999, defining a 2-4% annual target as from 2001, with the aim of permanent convergence to a 3% rate within a 12-24 month period (Massad, 1999; Central Bank, 2007). The 12-24 month period was intended to take account of the lags in the effects of monetary policy and to allow inflation to gradually accommodate to 6 The managed flexibility implemented in 1990-95 gradually lost consistency in 1996-97, allowing an appreciation led by pro-cyclical capital inflows (Ffrench-Davis, 2010c, Chapters VIII and IX). On the effectiveness of managed flexibility see Edwards and Rigobón (2009). 7 After close coordination in 1990-95 in implementing a set of counter-cyclical policies, several expressions of lack of coordination emerged in 1996-98, particularly with respect to exchange-rate policy, with the government criticising its pro-cyclical bias. However, by 1999, the Finance Minister appeared to have accepted the formal adoption of “inflation targeting”. See http://www.bcentral.cl/politicas/sesionesconsejo/pdf/Sesion794E.pdf. 5 deviations from the target, thus avoiding the costs to economic activity in cases of fast convergence with the target (Corbo, 2004; de Gregorio, 2006). Finally, among other monetary reforms, the policy interest rate used by the Bank was changed from a real rate (linked to the CPI) to a nominal one. The Bank declared that, with a freely floating exchange rate,8 it had gained monetary policy independence, while ER fluctuations eased the economy's adjustment to shocks and avoided misalignments of the rate. The first was partly true; the latter was quite wrong as events later showed. One determinant factor of misalignments was the full opening --for both foreign inflows and residents' outflows-- of the capital account in 2001.9 The increasing relaxation of the regulation of AFP outflows was of particular importance. In the midst of contagion from the Asian crisis, --which naturally implied great scarcity of foreign currency-- the ceiling on AFPs' investments abroad was raised from 12% to 16% of their total portfolio in January 1999 (Figure 1) when the domestic economy was already suffering the recessive effects associated with the binding external restriction (BER) generated by the contagion. Indeed, in 199899, there was a huge outflow of funds by the AFPs, as shown in Figure 1, in a highly pro-cyclical behaviour, implicitly encouraged by the policy design. Figure 1 In those days the belief that opening the capital account implied importing macro stability was fashionable internationally. In line with that “conventional wisdom”, the Central Bank completed the liberalisation of the capital account in April 2001, restating its commitment to a fully free exchange rate. In contrast to the expectation of “importing stability”, actually a recessive environment prevailed until 2003, led by a BER that was reinforced by a net outflow of domestic portfolio equivalent to 3% of GDP in 2002-03. Chilean investors, in fact, joined international markets in their pro-cyclical behaviour. The binding external restriction generated a sharp depreciation trend, which led the Bank to intervene twice in the foreign exchange market, in 2001 The Bank usually used the expression “flexible”, implicitly implying “fully flexible” with only exceptional interventions and no explicit exchange-rate or current account “targeting”. 9 It should be noted that the policy tool of the reserve requirement on capital inflows, systematically used in 1991-95, is still available to the Bank (though with some bounds), if it decides to make use of this counter-cyclical regulation in the case of future capital surges. 8 6 and 2002. Before the second intervention in October 2002, the price of the dollar had increased 61% (to $742 per USD) 10 since the liberalisation of the exchange rate and the subsequent opening of the capital account. Arguing that there was too much volatility,11 the Bank intervened through programmes of auctions of foreign currency and paper indexed to the price of the dollar and payable in pesos, that were announced for several months ahead. This was the opposite of a discretionary intervention seeking to guide the exchange rate. In the meantime, the recessive gap persisted, with actual GDP growing less than the periodic official estimate of the increase in potential GDP. The foreign exchange market started to change in the second quarter of 2003, when the price of copper began to show an upward trend. By December, it had jumped 40% and the exchange rate again retook a significant appreciation trend. The gap started falling under the pull of the income and expectations effects of commodity prices on domestic demand. Monetary policy was active but highly gradual, notwithstanding the recession's abrupt arrival in 1999. The Central Bank's behaviour reflected its inflation-targeting priority. Figure 2 shows that, during the recessive years, the CPI was usually below the centre of its target band. After sharply increasing the monetary policy rate (MPR) to 14% (over the CPI) in 1998, in a bid to deter capital outflows in the face of Asian crisis contagion, the Bank started to reduce the rate gradually. In July 2001, in a significant policy shift, the real MPR was replaced by a nominal rate, fixed at 6.5%.12 Gradual reductions continued until early 2004 when the rate reached 1.75%. Figure 3 compares the Chilean MPR and that of the United States. Figures 2 and 3 10 Note that we mention the nominal price of the dollar but the relevant figure is that of the real exchange rate of a basket of currencies of Chile's main trade partners, as calculated by the Bank monthly. This is the data used in the curve in Figure 6, below. The peaks and minimums of the basket and the dollar coincide when the stronger force is the position of the peso and not that of the dollar with respect to the euro or other currencies. 11 See press release of October 10, 2002 at http://www.bcentral.cl/prensa/comunicados-consejo/otrostemas/. 12 The MPR was indexed to the CPI (actually, to the Unidad de Fomento, UF, linked to the CPI with one month lag), which was replaced by a nominal interest rate in a quest for further reductions in inflation. A discussion in favour of the change can be found in Morandé (2002). See Shiller (2008) for a strong argument in support of the UF in Chile as an effective tool for generating segments of long-term savings and lending. 7 In order to address the mismatch in recessive situations between the public resources required for social programmes and temporarily depressed tax revenue, a structural fiscal policy was implemented in 2001(Ffrench-Davis, 2010a). This implied maintaining an expenditure level consistent with sustainable medium-term fiscal revenue as calculated using estimates of future GDP and copper price trends. This instrument allowed the authorities to avoid public expenditure curtailments in depressed periods and avoid increases when the economy is overheated and tax revenue exceed their structural level. This innovative fiscal rule was accompanied by three features that are not intrinsic to this policy tool. One was the definition of a target of a structural surplus of 1% of GDP which, after some time, would inevitably lead to a net creditor position, probably a non-desirable situation for a developing economy.13 Second, it defined Chile's trend GDP including the intense recessions it has suffered, assuming that upward deviations are equal to downward deviations. Consequently, average trend GDP tends to move below potential GDP or the productive frontier.14 Thirdly, the features of the Chilean rule implied a neutral fiscal policy with respect to the economic cycle by maintaining a stable path of expenditure. This represented progress on the traditional pro-cyclical norm of balancing the actual fiscal budget on an annual basis, but stopped at neutrality without reaching counter-cyclicality. In fact, up to late 2008, the new rule did not move decidedly towards including counter-cyclical changes in public expenditure and taxes when the economy was in recession or overheated. An existing Copper Stabilisation Fund (CSF) represented an outstanding factor of macroeconomic stabilisation. It contributed to the implementation of the structural budget, thus allowing a move from pro-cyclical to neutral fiscal policies during the recessive years. This valuable “credibility asset” was, however, underutilised in 1999-2003 because, as discussed below, the authority refused to move to a comprehensive counter-cyclical macroeconomic policy. Nonetheless, it contributed to stabilise fiscal expenditure, improving its 13 By 2008, the Treasury was a heavy creditor, particularly in foreign currency. It had accumulated US$22.7 billion in funds equivalent to 13% of GDP (Table 3). Correspondingly, in a belated decision, the structural surplus target was reduced to 0.5% of GDP in 2008 and to 0% in 2009. 14 Conventional measurements use a sort of Hodrick-Prescott filter, assuming symmetrical deviations of actual GDP above and below trend GDP. In the real world --particularly under the globalization of financial volatility--, actual GDP tends to fluctuate mostly below potential GDP. See Ffrench-Davis (2014, Annex I) where estimates are presented of a production function excluding time series observations in which actual GDP is evidently out of equilibrium. 8 quality and moving fiscal policy from pro-cyclical to neutral.15 The evidence provided by the 1999-2003 recession shows that there was a need to move further towards effective counter-cyclical policies in order to contribute to faster recovery of economic activity in recessive situations. After 1999 it became increasingly evident that the macroeconomic pull from abroad anticipated by the authorities, had been delayed, increasing the social and economic costs of the RG. In this context, gradual monetary policy and the neutral fiscal policy were unable to provide a strong boost to domestic demand. It can be argued that a domestic shock should have then been implemented, taking advantage of the accumulated strength of the Chilean economy: (i) a government with minimal debt, an actual fiscal surplus of 1.8% of GDP (average 1990-98) and a significant sovereign fund; (ii) a moderate total external debt, with a low share of short-term liabilities; (iii) a Central Bank without external liabilities and with high net international reserves; (iv) a low actual and underlying inflation rate, persistently below the centre of the inflation target;16 (v) real exchange rate appreciation that, along with the excessive external deficit of 1998, had already been corrected in 1999, and (vi) a private sector able to produce some 5-7% more than it was contributing to GDP in those years.17 However, as indicated, the economic authorities rejected the proposal of a positive public domestic shock, arguing that “markets would evaluate such an action negatively” (by “markets”, of course, meaning financial markets). The negative impact of downgraded risk ratings and higher spreads for Chilean borrowers would, they asserted, outweigh the positive reactivating effect. Most business media and the opposition supported and praised this official stance. Moreover, some criticised the actual fiscal deficit resulting from implementation of the structural 1% surplus. Fortunately, the government was able to sustain the structural principle adopted formally in 2001, thus progressing from a pro15 There were some counter-cyclical components, such as emergency job programmes when unemployment rose and, in 2002, an unemployment insurance scheme was launched. This is financed by contributions by both private-sector workers and employers to the worker's individual account and government contributions to a "solidarity fund". In September 2009, some 85% of private-sector payroll employees were contributing to the scheme. This high coverage was accompanied by modest benefits and a minimal use of the solidarity fund (see Ffrench-Davis, 2010c, Chapter VII). 16 Annual CPI inflation averaged 2.2% in 2001-04, below the 3% centre of the target band. 17 Actual GDP growth averaged 2.6% in 1999-2003, while most estimates of the rise in capacity were around 4% or somewhat above. Note that potential GDP had grown about 7% per year in 1990-98. 9 cyclical to a neutral fiscal policy by maintaining the trend of expenditure notwithstanding the drop in revenue seen during that recessive situation. As indicated above, it did not, however, moved towards a strong counter-cyclical increase in expenditure. Actual GDP rose just 2.6% in 1999-2003 (Table 1, above), a poor performance but better than the 1.3% recorded by Latin America as a whole under contagion from the Asian crisis. It is revealing of the failure in the macroeconomic approach adopted since 1999, that over 85% of the drop in GDP growth between1990-98 and 1999-2003 was located in the domestic market which depends directly on domestic macroeconomic policies (3.9 points out of 4.5 points; Table 1). The effect of the recessive gap on capital formation was a determining variable of the much weaker growth performance. A significant gap between actual GDP and the production frontier is usually followed by a drop in productive investment. In fact, the gross investment ratio diminished substantially and, in 2003, was still three points below the 23% ratio recorded in 1998.18 That was a consequence of an economy that had a high output gap that averaged some 6% of GDP in those years (Figure 5.A, below and FfrenchDavis, 2010c, Table IX.1). That gap reflects a real imbalance because the economy was underutilising a significant share of the available productive resources. As shown repeatedly, the larger the recessive gap the larger tends to be the drop experienced by investment ratios. As well as depressing the future growth of potential GDP, lowered capital formation tends to reduce the quality of the labour market. It should be stressed that RG remained high for a whole quinquenium, in an economy with a minor public debt, fiscal responsibility and a stabilisation fund linked to the copper price. b) Recovery led by a positive terms-of-trade shock, 2004-07 The international commodity boom that started in 2003 implied a large positive shock for the Chilean economy. Its terms of trade, led by the copper price, 18 These figures for gross fixed investment ratios are from the National Accounts calculated by the Central Bank with base year 2003. The depreciation of the capital stock represented around 13% of GDP. Thus, these three points implied a 30% fall in net capital formation. It should be remembered that the estimate of trend GDP fell from 7% to a 4% plateau. 10 improved by the equivalent of 6% of GDP between the recessed year of 2003 and 2004. A significant share of this improvement leaked into greater transfers of profits abroad but a surplus equivalent to around three points of GDP remained. This surplus eliminated the BER and fuelled recovery of depressed domestic demand, permitting an increase in the utilisation rate of productive capacity. The boom in export prices intensified further in the years through to 2008. In 2007, the net positive effect of improvement in the terms of trade, after discounting a higher outflow of profits, jumped to 9% of GDP, supporting the rise in domestic demand. Given the large output gap prior to this positive external shock, domestic supply was able to respond with rising GDP and low inflation pressures (inflation remained below the centre of the 2-4% target band set by the autonomous Central Bank). Thus, the exogenous shock contributed to a major jump in actual GDP growth from its 2.6% average in the recessive quinquenium of 1999-2003 to 5.6% in 2004-07,19 without any significant reform of domestic macroeconomic or microeconomic policies. The generalised improvement in the terms of trade directly enhanced the spending capacity of the private sector, reduced the output gap and improved the fiscal budget, with expectations once again showing broad optimism. After the usual lag, productive investment also began to rise. Recovery continued gradually so that, by the beginning of 2008 before contagion from the global crisis began, the recessive gap had been reduced, albeit not fully eliminated. It had been present since 1998, in sharp contrast with 1991-97 when it was practically absent. In the meantime, the Central Bank once again allowed the real exchange rate to appreciate. Between early 2003 and 2008, the nominal price of the US dollar fell by almost 40%, contributing to anchor inflation and further increase (distorting) domestic purchasing power with a fast rising imports share (Table 1, row 6, above). Consequently, the macroeconomic disequilibrium implied by the output gap was also associated with that of the exchange rate. Given some import 19 It is noteworthy that actual GDP growth also climbed in Latin America from 1.3% in 1999-2003 to 5.7% in 2004-07. 11 liberalisation and large exchange rate appreciation, the increase in domestic demand was strongly biased toward imports. In fact, imports doubled the speed of export volume in 2004-08 (Figure 4), but the trade imbalance was hidden by the high copper price (Table 2). Indeed, the foreign currency market was operating with a highly short-termist bias, behaving as if the current copper price were sustainable; the consequence was a mal-adjustment of the free exchange rate. Figure 4 and Table 2 Notwithstanding the Bank´s bias for a free exchange rate, it intervened in April 2008, buying dollars in public auctions in the face of strong pressure from some analysts and exporters. The reason it gave for this intervention was not an excessive appreciation of the exchange rate but the need to increase international reserves during the rest of the year (again a programme, but now to purchase an amount of foreign currency equivalent to 5% of GDP), given the worsening of the international environment that was becoming apparent. In parallel, the Bank was raising the MPR (Figure 3, above). The auctions were suspended in September with the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers.20 The international scenario played a relevant role, naturally enhanced by the openness of the Chilean economy. There were positive features for Chile such as the spectacular price of copper and other key exports which, as indicated above, allowed the Treasury to accumulate sizable savings against possible future bad years. In addition, world trade volume was dynamic up to the arrival of the international financial crisis. On the other hand, international food prices were climbing and, from mid-2007 to mid-2008, the price of food in the Chilean CPI increased by 22%, generating significant inflationary pressures and explaining about half of the nearly 10% annual inflation recorded at the peak of the commodities boom (by the third quarter of 2008; see Ramos, 2008). This was mainly imported inflation but, by late 2008, when monthly inflation in Chile was already negative, the monetary policy interest rate (8.25%) exceeded that of the United States by over seven points. The Central Bank's measures consistently revealed that its priority was the inflation target at the expense of growth and employment. 20 The nominal exchange rate depreciated 17% between the first auction in April and the last one in September 2008. Depreciation then accelerated as a result of contagion from the global financial crisis. 12 Chile's leadership within Latin America on economic growth was lost in 2004-07 when its average GDP growth was similar to that of the region as a whole. c) The 1999-2007 cycle in brief In all, growth in this cycle was low compared with the potential of the domestic economy and highly positive external shocks. Average growth in this cycle was a modest 3.9%, with the recovery as from 2003 offset by the economy's meagre performance between 1999 and 2003. There prevailed a combination of the excessive priority given to inflation -supported by a distorting unstable real exchange rate, a sliding of the economic policy approach towards a more neutral stance and the belief that actual GDP was already too close to potential GDP. This was an approach that received frequent support from the neo-liberal specialists. In particular, Chile received strong praise from the IMF for implementing plain "inflation targeting" and a free exchange-rate policy. In 2010, the IMF authorities were to recognise that they "were wrong" in much of their previous economic focus to which, unfortunately, Chile had adhered since 1999.21 Chile experienced a large and long-lasting recessive gap arising from a binding external constraint that predominated over the domestic macroeconomy for five years. If one believes in the working of markets, it is hard to deny that those five years must have weakened “animal spirits”. The recessive gap (RG) only started to diminish in late 2003 under the pull of commodity prices. The important recovery that followed, without significant microeconomic or political changes, confirms the previous macroeconomic weakness since, as indicated above, the merits of the Chilean economy were already present in 1999-2003. Thus, the conditions for a domestic reactivating shock had been at hand since the previous excessive external deficit and over-appreciated exchange rate of 1998 --usually obstacles to a recovery of economic activity-- had been corrected in 1999. As from 2003, an opportunity was, therefore, again, lost to implement an abrupt positive domestic shock, now in an over-optimistic international 21 See Blanchard et al. (2010), for a highly relevant “regret” from the IMF. 13 environment and with notable fiscal surpluses --5.4% of GDP in 2004-07 (Table 2, below). In fact, it took four more years for the economy to approach its production frontier. A mix of factors directly explains that weak recovery process as from 2004. One ingredient is located in the Central Bank which overshot the rise of the interest rate and allowed the exchange rate to revalue quickly, further discouraging production of tradables. In addition, the Finance Ministry sterilised “too much” of the positive impact of the copper price jump whilst allowing most of the negative impact of increasing oil prices to penetrate the domestic economy. A great virtue --the existence of the stabilisation scheme-- overshot, sterilising in excess. When contagion from the global crisis reached Chile in 2008, actual GDP had not yet touched potential GDP.22 Public expenditure rose faster than GDP, but was insufficient for an abrupt recovery. Over and above that lost potential GDP, the fact that the drop in economic activity was abrupt and recovery was quite gradual implied significant forgone output during the downward and recovery stages (Figure 5.A). The persistent RG during the whole period meant that both labour and capital were underutilised. That fact, moreover, deterred productive investment and productive spirits, with an impact on both future potential and actual GDP. Figures 5.A and 5.B Clearly, the exchange rate remained an outlier, with high mid-term instability and a strong tendency towards overshooting (towards sharp depreciation in the downturn and sharp appreciation in the boom). Over the course of the cycle, the nominal price of the dollar moved between $476 (1/1999), $743 (2/2003), $514 (12/2005) and $443 (03/2008). These wide fluctuations illustrate the exchange rate's considerable instability, with a predominant trend towards excessive appreciation as from 2003 as shown by the evolution of trade volume (Figure 4, above on trade, and Figure 6, below on evolution of the real exchange rate). 22 The sharp rise in the CPI in 2007-08 could be interpreted as an overheating generated by the rise in domestic demand. However, as discussed above, it was mostly related to the jump in international food prices. 14 3. The approach since the global crisis a) Contagion from the global crisis and early recovery, September 2008-2009 When contagion from the global crisis reached Chile in 2008, the main domestic macroeconomic variables experienced significant recessive adjustments.23 The capital account reverted abruptly and the price of copper dropped from US$4 per pound in early 2008 to US$1.40 in December. The international financial turbulence of the last quarter of 2008 and acute deterioration of the volume and value of exports had a direct impact on economic activity. After growing at an average 8% in 2004-08, domestic demand fell by 8% in the first semester of 2009 over the same period in 2008, while GDP contracted by 3%. In response, the government implemented an outstanding policy shift. In 2008, it had already progressively implemented an active counter-cyclical fiscal policy. During 2009, the effects of the strong negative external shock produced by the financial and trade ramifications of the international crisis were gradually displaced by the positive pull of domestic policies focused on mitigating the adverse effects of the crisis on economic activity and social indicators. In fact, although fiscal income fell by 10% in 2008 and 20% in 2009, reflecting depressed domestic demand and reduced revenue from copper, spending was increased by a vigorous 17% in 2009 (and 9% in 2008). The public sector managed an actual (as opposed to structural) deficit of 4.4% of GDP, thanks to the policy space created by the solid budgetary position built up in previous years (Table 2). In the stimulus measures adopted, there was an emphasis on lowincome housing and massive investment in public works. In addition, CODELCO, the state copper producer, was capitalised with a government contribution equivalent to 0.6% of GDP, designed to finance its investment projects, while the capital of Banco Estado, the state bank, was augmented by 50%, allowing it to increase lending to small and mid-sized firms (SMEs). 23 The impact on the domestic economy and the policy response are discussed in Ffrench-Davis and Heresi (2015). 15 A number of taxes in key sectors, including on fuel, borrowing and SMEs, were temporarily reduced. Families in the lowest 40% income bracket received two vouchers, each for the equivalent of 30% of the minimum monthly wage per non-working family member. In addition, the solidarity pillar of the pension system, which had been created prior to the crisis under a reform implemented in 2008, was strengthened in 2009, expanding coverage of solidarity pensions to 50% of the population (Arenas, 2010). While this was a structural distributive measure, it also contributed to economic recovery. A subsidy was introduced for the hiring of low-income young people, providing an incentive for employment of this highly vulnerable group. In 2009, the extent of the unemployment insurance scheme and access to its solidarity fund were enhanced, including workers with short-term contracts, while countercyclical features were introduced in its benefits. The capital account saw a significant repatriation of the savings held in sovereign funds to finance the fiscal deficit of 4.4% of GDP, reducing the over US$20 billion accumulated by 2008 to US$11 billion in late 2009 (Table 3). This counter-cyclical behaviour on the part of the Treasury was accompanied by spectacular outflows on the part of residents, principally the AFPs.24 This again confirmed that the liberalisation of residents´ capital flows played a negative pro-cyclical role as had also been the case in 1998-99. Table 3 The autonomous Central Bank embarked on a gradual reduction of the MPR only in January 2009 (Figure 3, above). After a series of cuts, it reached 0.50% in July 2009. However, the cost of credit remained high for several months before the cuts in the MPR were slowly transferred to credit users, particularly SMEs. There is an asymmetry in the speed of increases in the cost of loans during the boom and of decreases during the recessions, with an antiSMEs bias.25 Meanwhile, commercial banks reported annual rates of return of over 20%, while GDP and employment had fallen. 24 The AFPs recorded net outflows equivalent to 10% of annual GDP in 2009. See Ffrench-Davis (2014, Table X.1). 25 For instance, for small loans (up to the equivalent of around US$7,500), the spread over the annual MPR rose from an already huge 27 percentage points in 2007 to 33 points in 2009, while for larger loans (over US$190,000), it increased from 2.6 to 4 percentage points (SBIF, 2014). 16 It is important to note that a 1% drop in GDP in 2009 was determined by the decrease of the quantum of exports, while the domestic economy, which only contracted slightly in late 2008 and during the first semester of 2009, experienced a smaller impact. This was in contrast to the previous recession when the external shocks had stronger recessive multiplying effects on the nonexport economy (Table 1, rows 3 and 4). These external negative shocks were given data but the government was able to sustain production for the domestic market, halting the negative multiplier effect of the imported recessive forces in the third quarter. During the last couple of months of 2009, GDP exhibited an increase of 3.9% (change over 12 months).26 It was domestic market activity, supported by the counter-cyclical fiscal policy that led the recovery of economic activity in the final months of the Bachelet administration. Undoubtedly, the copper price boom, which had restarted by mid-2009 (with a jump to a high US$3.35 per pound in January 2010), contributed to the recovery of private expectations and fiscal income, driving up domestic demand. In addition, once the greatest uncertainties on international financial markets dissipated in 2009, large firms gradually regained access to bond markets. In all, the rather neutral structural fiscal balance (SFB) became effectively counter-cyclical, with the financial support of the sovereign fund, and the government was able to execute the budget in a rather timely and efficient way. b) Continued recovery with external and fiscal imbalances, 2010-13 The recovery of economic activity and actual GDP was interrupted temporarily by an earthquake and tsunami on 27 February 2010 (27F). Following this severe interruption --which, according to the Bank, destroyed an estimated 1.01.5% of potential GDP-- there was, however, still a wide recessive gap or policy space for substantial recovery of economic activity during several further quarters. A few weeks after 27F, now at the beginning of the administration of President Piñera, recovery restarted. The already higher domestic demand that had resulted from the counter-cyclical policies of 2009 increased further due to 26 Monthly Central Bank estimate of economic activity (IMACEC). For more details, see Ffrench-Davis (2014, Table X.4). 17 Treasury spending on post-earthquake reconstruction. Given that there was still significant underutilised installed capacity, accelerated public spending, pulling up domestic demand, was consistent with a movement towards macroeconomic balance as long as this recessive gap remained. Recovery continued through to 2012, giving a 5.7% average growth of actual GDP in 2010-12. In order to understand what happened, it is important to distinguish between reuse of available productive capacity and the creation of new capacity and to look at what occurred with the sustainability of the recovery process. This involves diverse macroeconomic variables such as external balance and fiscal budget trends and their link to productive development. In 2010-12, domestic demand expanded faster than output, boosting actual GDP without creating inflationary pressures. This implied moving towards a fundamental real macroeconomic balance; that is, using available potential GDP. Naturally, the gap decreased during the adjustment process, raising employment and stimulating capital formation. As the gap narrowed, with actual and potential growth converging, the speed diminished and actual GDP growth weakened to 4.1% in 2013. A new cycle started then. It is evident that the 5.7% increase in actual GDP between 2010 and 2012 included a significant recovery of capacity that was underutilised at the peak of the recession. In order to avoid the common mistake of disregarding what happened before recovery, it is necessary to measure performance between comparable GDP peaks, given their proximity to installed capacity. If the 2007 peak is taken as a base, actual GDP growth to the peak of 2013 averages 3.9%;27 and if we correct for the destruction caused by the earthquake, the average growth in 2008-13 appears to be 4.1%.28 This is identical to 2013, slightly above the rate achieved in the previous decade (1999-2007) but much lower than the 7.1% recorded in 1990-1998. Recovery and reaching the production frontier had positive impacts on employment and capital formation. Despite the persistence of multiple expressions of precariousness, there is no doubt that unemployment dropped 27 Over the course of 2008, there was evidence of the effects of the crisis; GDP only grew 3.3%, below estimates of the increase in potential GDP. Consequently, 2007 is used here as the previous annual peak. 28 Given that this destruction was not due to economic policy, an estimate of the negative impact of the earthquake --1.0-1.5% of potential GDP, according to the Central Bank-- must be added to the increase in actual GDP in order to measure the effectiveness of economic policy. 18 and formalisation of employment improved. For instance, up-to-date payments into the social security system (the private AFPs) increased from 54.5% of the labour force in 2008 to 59.6% in 2013, returning to their pace of formalization in the years before contagion from the global crisis.29 The investment ratio experienced a recovery with respect to its depressed level in 2009. However, in current pesos, it was running at 23.6% of GDP in 2013, down from a peak of 24.7% in 2008. In constant pesos, on the other hand, there was an increase from 24.7% in 2008 to 25.8% in 2013, explained by the Central Bank's calculation that the average relative prices of investment had decreased such that a given monetary expenditure permitted the acquisition of 9% more in equipment, machinery and construction.30 The volume of exports remained depressed, reflecting the effect of slowing international trade, the burden of the exchange-rate policy failure and the persistence of an absence of productive development policies. In this cycle the annual increase in volume of exports reached just 1.3% (Table 4). In addition, diversification into higher value-added activities and linkages with the rest of the domestic economy weakened. As such, the weight of recovery of economic activity continued to be carried by the domestic market. In fact, around 5/6 of the increase in output recorded in 2010-12 were demanded by the domestic market.31 Naturally, given that effective demand was reaching the level of potential output in 2012, completing the recovery of domestic output, it sharply lost speed in 2013. Table 4 In the transition towards the elimination of the recessive gap, an outlier exchange rate appreciation soon reappeared and some new permanent fiscal expenditure were created without a corresponding increase in permanent fiscal income. After the exchange rate experienced a strong appreciation to $443 per dollar in March 2008 (when over-optimism still predominated), there was a sharp devaluation to $649 in late 2008 (Figure 6, below). A period of fluctuations then ensued, reflecting prevailing uncertainty but with the 29 There had been an increase of 9 percentage points between 2002 and 2008. Calculations based on the new 2008 chain mobile base of national accounts. 31 See Ffrench-Davis (2014, Table X.4). 30 19 expectation that Chile was emerging from the crisis. As a result, the rate appreciated to $463 in 2011. Naturally, the free market rate was equilibrating the balance of payments but des-equilibrating the current account, resulting in great uncertainty and misleading information to the producers of tradables. Figure 4, above, and Table 4 show that imports grew much faster than exports as they had done in 2004-2007. While the quantum of imports climbed by 46% between the peak of 2007 and 2013, the quantum of exports rose by a meagre 8%. Part of the difference was covered by the notably high price of copper while the remainder appeared as a current account deficit of 3.4% of GDP in both 2012 and 2013. As regards fiscal policy, a 7% health insurance tax on pensions was partially eliminated, taxes on lending and on personal income were reduced and a maternity leave subsidy was increased while the tax on companies' profits rose from 17% to 20%.The net effect was that the SFB exhibited a 1.2% deficit, despite benefiting from a fast-rising estimate of the trend copper price (Table 2, row 4). As a result, when the recessive gap was disappearing in 2012 and early 2013, two macroeconomic imbalances prevailed: an outlier appreciated exchange rate and a fiscal budget based on an excessively high copper price. This is reflected in the real trade disequilibrium. At the same time, in 2012, the government used revenue from mining firms that were equivalent to a current copper price of US$3.30 per pound as compared to less than US$1 used by the Finance Ministry in 2004-07 (Table 2).32 c) The 2008-13 cycle in brief In contrast to the approach in force since the late 1990s, the government adopted a set of strong counter-cyclical policies at the start of this new cycle, taking advantage of the assets and credibility that the Chilean economy had accumulated, including the sovereign stabilisation funds. Notwithstanding the drop in tax revenue, fiscal expenditure was increased and some taxes were temporarily reduced. This strong counter-cyclical fiscal policy was the main force compensating for the negative external shocks and did so quite quickly. By the last quarter of 2009, economic activity was exhibiting a significant 32 The SFB, measured with a nominal trend copper price of US$1.00 per pound, exhibited a surplus of 1.2% of GDP in 2004-07. 20 recovery. Subsequently, there was also a faster recovery of economic activity in comparison with the previous cycle. By late 2012, the RG had disappeared, implying a smaller cost in foregone output as shown in Figure 5.B in contrast with Figure 5.A above. Beyond this initial counter-cyclical progress, fiscal responsibility deteriorated as the economy recovered. The government raised some permanent expenditure without a matching increase in permanent fiscal income. Even, although the copper price was quite high, there was an actual deficit in 2013. Also, the SFB moved from a surplus in the first cycle to a deficit in the second one, despite the positive impact of a fast-rising estimate of the trend copper price (Table 2, row 4).33 In the case of trade and growth, there was a striking weakening of export performance. After several years in which Chile's real exports had risen faster than world trade,34 exports expanded by a weak annual 1.3% in this cycle, while world trade grew by 2.5%. More worryingly, exports other than copper rose by even less (0.9%, see Table 1), implying a step-back in diversification, a sign of “Dutch disease”. Evidently, world trade was depressed, but Chile's exports were even more depressed. One explanatory variable is exchange-rate policy, with the rate's instability and tendency to appreciate whenever a recovery stage appears. Exchange-rate policy, of course, also underlies the fast rise of imports (and their negative impact on SMEs).35 The Central Bank generally has argued that the actual real exchange rate was close to “the historical average”; the data it offers uses to disregard significant changes in import tariffs and export subsidies. Figure 6 presents the evolution of the real exchange rate since its liberalisation in 1999, the reduction of import tariffs from 11% to an average 1% and the elimination of a 10% 33 This is the main, albeit, simplified outcome. The relevant copper price is that in real terms (deflated by the international inflation relevant for Chile, measured monthly by the Central Bank and estimated at 71% in 1999-2013). In addition, climbing copper production costs, mostly related to falling ore grades, must be considered. Nonetheless, in all, the real proceeds for Chile from copper have been more favourable in recent years than in the 1990s. 34 For instance, the quantum of exports rose by 9.9% annually in 1990-98 while world trade increased 6%. 35 Due to the many free trade agreements signed by Chile in the past decade, SMEs face imports with a practically zero tariff, minor non-tariff restrictions and an unstable RER. At the same time, the net effect of the set of policies appears to be negative for export diversification, notwithstanding the preferences received in the free trade agreements. 21 subsidy for non-traditional exports.36 After taking into account both policy changes, Figure 6 shows that the RER was usually below the adjusted curve. In addition, the RER has experienced mid-term instability, with deep appreciation during the two recovery stages. For investors in the production of tradables, this has tended to offset the favourable investment and credit mood of recovery periods.37 One evident proof of the outlier evolution of the RER is the gap between the evolution of the volume of imports and that of exports as seen in Figure 4, above. Figure 6 Finally, average growth of actual GDP was rather similar in both cycles -close to 4%-- and the RER and the current account behaved pro-cyclically in both cases. Factor productivity and product diversification also stagnated, in marked contrast to the 1990s. This backwards step in economic development dynamism is common to the two episodes. 4. Final remarks After a promising start in the early 1990s when the Chilean economy experienced nine years of 7.1% average GDP growth, it departed from what can be termed macroeconomics for development.38 During the 15 years between 1999 and 2013, effective demand exhibited ups-and-downs that had a significant impact on the real macroeconomy in terms of both the rate at which potential GDP was utilised and its actual growth rate. Those pro-cyclical failures were reinforced by pro-cyclical instability of the exchange rate and the current account. It can be argued, and correctly so to a degree, that, since the late 1990s, there have been two severe negative external shocks. The fact is that they 36 The fact that --after a significant increase in the 1990s when GDP grew by 7.1%--, total factor productivity slowed sharply as from 1999 was also disregarded. This change affects the sustainable level of the “equilibrium” RER. 37It is fashionable to repeat that, with the adoption of a floating exchange rate, the domestic economy became immune to external shocks. The fact is that foreign exchange crises are eliminated but at the expense of transferring great instability to the real economy, particularly the allocation of resources between tradables and non-tradables, and to the level and composition of aggregate demand, deterring development. On convergent views on the link exchange rate/development see Frenkel and Rapetti (2011); Rodrik (2008), Williamson (2000) and (2008). 38 Also used in the Latin American literature are the expressions “financierism” or “nominal stability” for the neo-liberal approach and “productivism” or “real economy” for a “neo-structuralist” or macro for development approach. See ECLAC (2010, Chapter II), Ffrench-Davis (2010b) and Ocampo (2011). 22 implied macroeconomic instability that made the implementation of countercyclical policies more, rather than less, necessary. Chile, however, dismantled most of what it had created in the 1990s, instead of improving it. In addition, Chile benefited from notably high copper prices that were far more favourable for the Treasury and private exporters than in the 1990s. We have, therefore, to explain why the excellent performance of 1990-98 was followed by two cycles in which GDP growth averaged less than 4%. Obviously negative external shocks have some negative effects on growth; but it is unsustainable to assert that all of over three points of GDP, in 15 years, are fully explained by negative external shocks. That would coincide with the most extreme “dependentism” of the 1960s. The focus of this paper --the issue of macroeconomics for development-reveals that the domestic macroeconomic environment worsened as from 1999. For instance, a rather close balance of aggregate demand and potential GDP was achieved only in 1989, 1991-98, 2007 and 2012-13, with a relevant recessive gap prevailing for the rest of the time, while the current account in constant prices and the ER were extremely unstable. Notwithstanding significant domestic “policy assets”, the macroeconomic situation was driven by a volatile capital account and volatile copper prices. Both these macroeconomic evils had been avoided in the early 1990s but, as from 1999, the authorities adopted both, paying the price in terms of two costly cycles with significant instability of the real economy. The persistent RG during the two cycles meant that both labour and capital were underutilised, with a drop in actual total factor productivity. The RG also deterred productive investment to the detriment of future GDP. The Chilean economy is quite open policy-wise. Nonetheless, valueadded by exports accounts only for close to 30% of GDP and 70% of GDP is consumed or invested in the domestic economy. This is the part of GDP where the output gap is mostly located; the performance of this major share of GDP is directly affected by domestic macroeconomic policies. This implies that, for a good performance of actual GDP, there must be an active macroeconomic policy, involving an economy working near the productive frontier and with right or sustainable macro-prices, particularly the exchange rate which determines the main relative price between tradables and non-tradables. The longer the 23 recessive gaps, the deeper the structural damage for job creation, capital formation, fiscal revenue, and worsened balance sheets of firms, throwing some of them into unfair and inefficient stagnation or even bankruptcy. The RER is a crucial allocating variable. Following the adoption of the free exchange rate in 1999, a severe inconsistency has prevailed between exchange-rate policy and the apparent consensus of fostering exports with higher value-added, while SMEs have faced external competition under reduced import tariffs and an appreciated exchange rate. There is a need to rebalance the targets of macroeconomic policy, taking into account four inputs beyond the priority for CPI inflation: first, consider the evolution of the composition of the CPI, without ignoring the incidence of an appreciated exchange rate on the price of tradables; second, taking note of the sustainability of the evolution of the exchange rate (does it respond to the evolution of relative productivities à la Balassa-Samuelson or rather to the short-term balance of payments?); third, concern for the evolution of the output gap, seeking to achieve “low inflation” with “high” employment, a sustainable exchange rate and sustained GDP growth; and, last, the need for deep coordination between the monetary and fiscal authorities. In order to avoid the usual conflict between a counter-cyclical monetary policy and a pro-cyclical exchange rate produced by an open capital account with a free exchange rate, an additional policy tool is required and countercyclical regulation of the capital account becomes unavoidable. One policy tool still available to Chile is the reserve requirement that can be imposed by the Central Bank while a complementary tool would be counter-cyclical regulation of institutional investors such as the AFPs. Finally, it is necessary to strive for a fiscal policy that moves forward towards a strong counter-cyclical approach.39 39 A related issue is the tax burden and its composition. Only minor and, in some cases, regressive adjustments were made after the major overhaul introduced in 1990. The government which took office in 2014 considered that the current tax burden was insufficient to finance the public goods required for inclusive development and the composition of revenue was not progressive. There were three main challenges: (i) the need to dismantle clearly regressive exemptions and channels for tax avoidance and to combat evasion, (ii) to increase taxation of wealth and profits, and (iii) to enhance pro-productive development linkages of public expenditure and revenue. Some of these challenges were addressed by a tax reform enacted in 2014. 24 It is essential to find the way back to sustainable real macroeconomic equilibrium. Along with deep microeconomic development-friendly reforms (proSMEs and pro-employment), this would allow Chile to return to sustained higher rates of GDP growth and achieve a progressive reduction in inequality. Beyond low inflation and fiscal responsibility, this implies an active macroeconomic policy that focuses on the real economy, working close to potential GDP, with sustainable external balances and exchange rates that are functional to productive development. Prolonged recessive cycles structurally damage job creation, reduce fiscal income and place costly burdens on entrepreneurship and, particularly, small businesses. Real macroeconomic failures are a determinant variable underlying the slowered Chilean development convergence. REFERENCES Arenas, A. (2010), Historia de la reforma previsional chilena: una experiencia exitosa de política pública en democracia, OIT, Santiago. Blanchard, O., G. Dell’Ariccia and P. Mauro (2010), “Rethinking macroeconomic policy”, IMF Staff Position Note, SPN/10/03, Washington, D.C., International Monetary Fund, February. Central Bank (2007), “La política monetaria del Banco Central de Chile en el marco de metas de inflación”, Banco Central de Chile, Santiago. ______ Informe de Política Monetaria (IPOM), quarterly issues, Santiago. Corbo, V. (2004), “La Estabilidad de Precios y la Autonomía de los Bancos Centrales”, Conference of President of the Central Bank, October. De Gregorio, J. (2006), “Objetivos Inflacionarios: Una Nota Aclaratoria”, Banco Central de Chile, Presentaciones de Consejeros del Banco Central, Santiago. DIPRES (2014), “Indicadores del Balance Cíclicamente Ajustado, Metodología y Resultados 2013”, Dirección de Presupuestos, Santiago. DIPRES, Informe de Finanzas Públicas, several issues, Ministerio de Hacienda, Santiago. ECLAC (2010), Time for Equality: closing gaps, opening trails, United Nations, Santiago. Edwards, S. and R. Rigobón (2009), “Capital controls on inflows, exchange rate volatility and external vulnerability”, Journal of International Economics 78, pp. 256-67. Ffrench-Davis, R. (2014), Chile entre el neo-liberalismo y el crecimiento con equidad, quinta edición, JCSáez Editor, Santiago. ______(2010a), “The structural fiscal balance in Chile”, Journal of Globalization and Development (Berkeley Electronic Journals), Vol. 1, No 1, January. ______(2010b), “Macroeconomics for development: From ‘financierism’ to ‘productivism”, CEPAL Review, No. 102, December, pp. 7-26. ______(2010c), Economic reforms in Chile: from dictatorship to democracy, Palgrave Macmillan, London and New York. 25 ______ and R. Heresi (2015), “La economía chilena frente a la crisis financiera: respuestas contra-cíclicas y desafíos pendientes”, in J.L. León, ed., Crisis global, respuestas nacionales. La recesión en América Latina y Asia Pacífico, Observatorio América Latina Asia Pacífico, Montevideo, pp. 248-75. Frenkel, R. and M. Rapetti (2011), “Exchange rate regimes in Latin America”, in Ocampo and Ros (2011). Magud, N. and C. Reinhart (2007), “Capital controls: an evaluation”, in S. Edwards (ed.), Capital controls and capital flows in emerging economies: policies, practices and consequences, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp. 645-74. Massad, C. (1999), “Exposición del Presidente del Banco Central de Chile al Senado con Ocasión de la Presentación del Informe Anual 1999”, Presentaciones de Consejeros del Banco Central, Santiago. Morandé, F. (2002), “Nominalización de la tasa de política monetaria: Análisis y Debate”, Cuadernos de Economía, Año 39, Nº 117, pp. 239-52, Santiago. Ocampo, J.A. (2011), “Macroeconomy for development: Countercyclical policies and productive transformation”, CEPAL Review, No. 104, pp. 7-35, August. ______ and J. Ros (2011), eds., The Oxford Handbook of Latin American Economics, Oxford University Press, New York. Ramos, J. (2008), “La economía chilena actual: adios al milagro, bienvenido el blindaje”, El Mostrador(electronic media, Santiago),October. Rodrik, D. (2008), “The Real Exchange Rate and Economic Growth: Theory and Evidence,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. _____ and A. Subramanian (2008), “Why did financial globalization disappoint”, draft, March. SBIF (2014), “Tasas de Interés Promedio del Sistema Bancario”, Superintendencia de Bancos e Instituciones Financieras, Santiago. Data available in SBIF, Información Financiera: http://www.sbif.cl/sbifweb/servlet/InfoFinanciera?indice=4.0 Shiller, R. (2008), The Subprime Solution, Princeton University Press, NJ. Williamson, J. (2000), “Exchange rate regimes for emerging markets: reviving the intermediate option”, Policy Analyses in International Economics 60, Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC. _____ (2008), “Do development considerations matter for exchange rate policy?”, in K. Cowan and S. Edwards (eds.), Current account and external financing, Banco Central de Chile, Santiago. 26 Table 1 Selected macroeconomic indicators, 1990-2013 (average rates of growth, and % of GDP) 1990-98 5.4 1999-13 2.8 (1999-03) 1.4 1999-07 2.7 (2009) -2.0 2008-13 2.9 GDP 7.1 3.9 2.6 3.9 -1.0 3.9 3 GDP exported 9.9 4.3 5.5 6.4 -4.5 1.3 (2.0) (1.4) (1.4) (1.6) (-1.1) (0.3 ) 4 GDP non-exported 6.5 3.8 1.7 3.1 0.1 4.9 (5.1) (2.5) (1.2) (2.3) (0.1) (3.6) Non-copper exports 10.3 4.9 7.1 7.6 -3.6 0.9 Non-traditional exports* 14.1 - 7.9 8.5 -10.3 - 6 Imports 12.7 7.5 3.0 8.3 -16.2 6.5 7 Current account (% of current GDP) -3.0 0.0 -0.9 0.9 2.0 -1.3 8 88 148 96 123 165 185 25.1 21.5 20.9 20.6 21.8 22.9 13.1 12.1 11.9 12.2 10.7 12.0 11 Terms of trade index (1989 = 100) Gross investment ratio (% of current GDP) Net investment ratio (% of real GDP)** Fiscal expenditure 6.6 6.2 4.0 5.4 16.5 7.3 12 Fiscal balance (% of current GDP) 1.8 1.1 -1.0 1.8 -4.4 0.0 13 CPI (Dec. to Dec.) 11.2 3.2 3.4 3.8 -0.6 2.9 14 Real average wage 3.9 2.1 1.7 1.9 4.8 2.5 15 Real minimum wage 5.3 3.5 4.8 3.6 4.8 3.2 1 GDP per capita 2 5 9 10 Sources: Abridged from Ffrench-Davis (2014, Tables I.7 and VI.6), based on Central Bank and National Institute of Statistics (INE) data updated to 2013. All growth rates are in real terms. Figures in brackets in rows 3 and 4 represent the contribution of exports and non-exports to GDP growth, respectively. * Excludes from non-copper exports nine groups of large items; at present includes about 5,000 items. **Net investment in fixed capital at constant prices was adjusted in 2010 for an estimated 3% drop in the stock of capital due to the destruction caused by the 27F earthquake; it reduced the 1999-2013 average ratio by 0.5 points and that of 2008-13 by 1.2 points. 27 Table 2 Fiscal indicators, 2001-2013 2001-03 2004-07 2008 2009 2010-12 2013 1. GDP actual (% annual real change) 3.2 5.6 3.3 -1.0 5.7 4.1 2. GDP trend (% annual real change) (previous year consultation)* 3. Copper price actual (nominal US$/Lb) 4. Copper price mid-term trend (nom. US$/Lb) 5. Fiscal balance actual (% of current GDP) 6. Structural fiscal balance (% of current GDP) 7. Fiscal income (% annual real change) 8. Fiscal income (% of current GDP) 9. Fiscal expenditure (% annual real change) 10.Fiscal expenditure (% of current GDP) 4.2 0.74 0.90 -0.7 0.9 4.1 20.4 3.8 21.1 4.6 2.31 1.00 5.4 1.2 18.2 23.5 7.2** 18.1** 5.0 4.9 3.16 2.34 1.37 1.99 3.9 -4.4 0.0 -1.2 -9.5 -20.4 24.2 19.0 9.3 16.5 20.3 23.4 4.7 3.68 2.58 0.5 -1.2 13.7 22.1 4.8 21.7 5.0 3.32 3.06 -0.6 -0.5 -1.4 21.0 4.1 21.6 Sources: Ffrench-Davis and Heresi (2015), based on data from the Central Bank and DIPRES (2014). Notes: Values correspond to a simple annual average for each period. Real GDP growth figures are from the National Accounts in 2003 prices; as from 2006, the rates of change of the new chained base, reference 2008, are used. All rates of change are in real terms. For figures presented as % of GDP, the GDP at current prices, reference 2008, is used. * Trend GDP corresponds to calculations of the Finance Ministry, based on inputs provided by the Advisory Committee on Trend GDP. The figures in row 2 correspond to estimates from the annual consultation of trend GDP for the budget of the next year. Given that the Trend GDP Committee delivered the first estimate for the next budget year in 2002, the values used for 2001 and 2002 are the estimates presented in the 2002 report. **Fiscal expenditure in constant prices rises faster than GDP, but falls as share of current GDP, because this variable increases notably due to the boom of export prices in this 2004-07 period with respect to 2001-03. Table 3 Sovereign funds, 2008-2013 (US$ current millions) 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 FEES FRP FEES+FRP (% of annual GDP) 20,211 11,285 12,720 13,157 14,998 15,419 2,507 3,421 3,837 4,406 5,883 7,335 12.6% 8.5% 7.6% 7.0% 7.8% 8.2% Source: DIPRES and Central Bank. Notes: Consolidated Treasury assets at the end of each year in the Economic and Social Stabilisation Fund (FEES) and the Pension Reserve Fund (FRP). The last column shows the total amount accumulated in both funds as a percentage of GDP of the respective year. GDP in US$ corresponds to the series at current prices, reference 2008, divided by the average nominal exchange rate of the year. 28 Table 4 Macroeconomic disequilibrium indicators, 2008-2013 (indexes 2007=100; and average annual % changes) 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 103.7 102.6 108.5 114.8 121.0 125.9 Average annual growth (%) 3.9 2.Quantum of exports 99.3 94.8 97.0 102.3 103.5 107.9 1.3 3.Quantum of imports 111.2 93.2 117.4 135.7 142.4 145.6 6.5 4.Real fiscal expenditure 109.3 127.4 135.7 139.9 146.5 152.4 7.3 5.Real fiscal income 90.5 72.0 92.4 103.0 104.4 103.0 0.5 6.Real fiscal non-copper income 101.5 91.8 107.7 123.6 132.0 136.1 5.3 7.Domestic demand 108.3 102.2 116.1 126.8 135.6 140.2 5.8 1. GDP Source: Taken from Ffrench-Davis (2014, Table IX.5), updated to 2013. Based on Central Bank figures for GDP, exports, imports and domestic demand from the chained base, reference 2008 series. Nominal fiscal figures from DIPRES (2014), deflated by the annual average CPI, here scaled to 2007=100; rows 4 to 6 correspond to the central government, row 6 excludes fiscal revenue from CODELCO and the ten largest mining companies. Figure 1 Pension fund outflows and real exchange rate, 1995-2000 (% of total portfolio, 1986=100) Appreciation zone Depreciation zone RER Investment abroad limit Investment abroad Sources: Taken from Ffrench-Davis (2010, Table IX.1), based on Central Bank and Pension Fund Superintendency figures. 29 Figure 2 Actual and target inflation, 1999-2013 (12-month % change in CPI) Source: Based on figures from Central Bank for inflation target and from National Institute of Statistics (INE) for monthly rates of change of the CPI. Notes: In 1999 the Central Bank defined a target of 4.3% for the year and of 3.5% for the following year. It then established a 2% to 4% band, centred on a 3% target as from 2001. Figure 3 Chilean and US monetary policy rate, 1998-2013 (annual %) Source: Based on monthly Central Bank figures. Notes: The Monetary Policy Rate (MPR) in Chile has been set in nominal terms since August 2001. Prior to this date, the MPR was expressed as an annual percentage over the CPI. 30 Figure 4 Evolution of exports and imports of goods and services, 2004-2013 (cumulative changes, index 2004=100) 42% 25% Sources: Based on Central Bank figures in prices of 2003. As from 2006, growth rates of the chained 2008 series are used. Exports and imports correspond to the volume (quantum) of goods and services. The figures between the two curves show the cumulative excess of imports over exports since 2004, as a percentage of exports. 31 Figure 5 A. Potential and actual GDP, 1997-2007 (millions of constant US$) B. Potential and actual GDP, 2008-2013 (millions of constant US$) Sources: Adapted from Ffrench-Davis (2010c, appendix to Chapter I), updated with data from Central Bank for actual GDP and stock of capital. 32 Figure 6 Chile: Real exchange rate (RER), 1999-2014 (index 1986=100) 115 743 110 649 105 613 100 RER 95 90 475 85 472 443 80 75 70 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 RER RER Average 1986-2004 Average adjusted by changes in Tariffs and "Reintegro Simplificado" 1999-2004 Sources: Ffrench-Davis (2014, Figure A.3), based on Central Bank monthly average figures for the real exchange rate of a broad basket of currencies of Chile's trade partners, DIPRES for the collected effective tariff and "simplified reimbursement" to non-traditional exports. Notes: The gap between the straight and the dotted lines show the compensatory adjustment to the RER necessary to maintain the competitiveness of tradables production, considering the 10 percentage point drop in import tariffs and the eliminated 10% reimbursement for non-traditional exports (which are the share of exports with higher price elasticity). The numbers presented in the RER curve correspond to the monthly average of nominal Chilean pesos per dollar at the corresponding dates. 33