A Threat of GSM Monopoly in the Mobile Market Intermediate Microeconomics The University of Akron Eric Tannehill May 4, 2011 On March 20th, 2011 AT&T Incorporated and Deutsche Telekom announced that they had entered into an agreement in which AT&T will purchase competing mobile network T-Mobile USA from Deutsche Telekom. The acquisition will proceed with the trading of roughly thirty-nine billion U.S. Dollars worth of cash and stocks from AT&T to Deutsche Telekom. This merger, which is among the largest worldwide acquisitions in the past year, is under severe scrutiny from the United States government. This paper will go discuss the terms and conditions of this agreement while assessing the potential economic effects that it will have on the mobile phone industry in the United States. The acquisition of T-Mobile USA will provide AT&T with many desirable assets. With the recent boom in mobile data subscribers there has been an increasing strain on network providers to supply enough bandwidth in which their customers can operate. The purchasing of T-Mobile by AT&T will provide the latter with an optimal combination of network assets to add capacity to their dataproviding infrastructure. This appears to be an easier method of growth for AT&T than by expanding upon their own towers and network. AT&T has experienced a growth in their mobile traffic of 8,000% (or eighty times) over the past four years. By 2015 they are projected to experience continued growth in data consumption of up to an additional ten times that of the 2010 mark (White, 2011). AT&T is claiming that it will require additional data spectrum before any new spectrums become available, hence their eagerness in the purchasing of T-Mobile USA. AT&T and T-Mobile are capable of merging due to the common data transmission that they share. In the United States there are two primary networks in which data is transmitted wirelessly (excluding the recent introduction of fourthgeneration technologies): Code Division Multiple Access (CDMA), which is utilized by Verizon Wireless and Sprint Nextel, and Global Systems for Mobile Communications (GSM) which both AT&T and T-Mobile operate on (GSMA, 2011). Although both of the vested companies use different GSM frequencies, they use same base technology, which would allow for the simple integration of similar products. This acquisition will push AT&T into the first place for the largest mobilephone provider in the United States, resulting the swapping of positions with Verizon Wireless who would fall to the second largest provider. That will leave Sprint Nextel, who was already in third place nationally, as the smallest of all major U.S. carriers by a wide margin. The case of a single-carrier GSM market has been a cause for concern for many people, which has resulted in what will likely be a lengthy investigation by the United States Federal Communications Commission. This committee is concerned that the deal will reduce the market competitiveness. If this were the case, consumers searching for a GSM network provider will most certainly end up facing increased prices along with more limited options. Gigi Sohn, president of the Washington-based consumer advocacy group Public Knowledge vehemently opposes the buyout. “We know the results of arrangements like this – higher prices, fewer choices, and less innovation.” (Thomson, 2011). As the GSM technology is the most popular type of data network used worldwide, Americans who need phones capable of use in other countries will be forced to either join the ranks of the merged AT&T- T-Mobile corporation or to buy an unlocked separately. Unlike competitive firms, organizations functioning as a monopoly operate at a point along the industry demand curve that yields economic inefficiency. The monopolist firm will produce at the point where their marginal cost of production is equal to the marginal revenue from selling the last unit. Generally this functional point is different from the average total cost curve and can yield indefinite above normal profits. By producing at this level there will be a certain guaranteed level of deadweight loss, which is the summation of potential gains that go neither to the consumers or the producers. This deadweight loss arises from a pricing point that is not at the equilibrium level of demand and supply (in this case the pricing point will be above the equilibrium level) and buyers lose out on some of their consumer surplus at the extent of the producers. The Federal Communications Commission annually complies a Mobile Wireless Report in which they present the findings regarding the state of competition in the mobile services industry. Their primary goal of function is to promote competition in the market. For the year 2009 they suggested that key inputs in the mobile marketplace, including data spectrum, must evolve in order to ensure a superior level of competition in the future. On the subject of firm exits in this industry, the Federal Communications Commission states that the exit of firms, through mergers, acquisitions, or discontinuance, has both positive and negative effects on competitive performance and consumer welfare. “The main potential negative effect of the exit of a competitor is that with fewer competitors remaining in the marker, there is an increased possibility of higher prices, reduced quality of services, or slower rate of innovation” (Federal Communications Commission, 2010). In continuance, the FCC states that if there is firm consolidation that results in the substantial increase of firm size, there could be reduced competitive pressure placed on the firm. This is clearly stated to have the potential of higher prices for consumers and lower incentive to improve consumer services. In previous years there have been cases of mobile firm acquisitions, many of which have resulted in the divestiture of wireless assets to other firms in order to maintain reasonable competition (Federal Communications Commission, 2010). In the case of the AT&T and T-Mobile acquisition there will be only one GSM network provider in the United States. However, if one were to look at the entire mobile phone industry there would only be two major players. AT&T and T-Mobile combined account for 39% of the market, while Verizon operates on 31.1%. Sprint, who would now be in a far-reaching third place, holds 12% of the U.S. mobile market (Bode, 2010). With two goliaths dominating the market and a handful of other small providers it is likely that the mobile industry could begin to stagnate due to decreased competition and low innovation. Some smaller network providers such as Boost Mobile and Virgin Mobile, who do not offer coverage across all of the United States, would not be able to keep up with the nation-wide leviathans that will now be setting more stringent price points and production levels to maximize profits. There is a general belief that this acquisition will not be passed as is; there will likely be a slew of concessions imposed upon AT&T in order for this deal to go through. It is expected that government officials would require the combined corporation to sell off assets such as cell towers, wireless spectrum, and possibly even customers in some markets that may be deemed too concentrated to smaller network providers to increase competition. Other practices that are already considered to be anti-competitive may have to go. Some include imposing large fees on customers that terminate their contracts before they expire and the blocking of certain online applications. This is similar to the laws of net-neutrality (which deems it unlawful to ban certain internet content), however these are not imposed upon mobile network providers (Tessler, 2011). The federal government is also expected to set implications that support smaller wireless providers who may not be able to compete with a merged AT&T – T-mobile corporation. These could involve data-roaming obligations that require AT&T to allow regional wireless companies to use its network in areas that are not supported by the latter. This would be an important aspect of the merger, as smaller rival wireless providers would likely not be able to compete with nation wide coverage, therefore preventing them from being immediately forced out of the market. With the ever-rising dominance of data-hungry phones such as the iPhone and phones operating on the powerful Android operating system, carriers have been struggling to meet data demands. AT&T sees opportunity to appease their customers’ demand for data by acquiring T-Mobile’s spectrum. However, AT&T is using this as an alternative to the option of systematically building up their own network. This natural growth could be a strong source of job growth in a technical industry, which could give the U.S. economy a much-needed boost. AT&T sees fit to take the easy route, the path yielding far less job creation and production. Going past the effects on the average consumer, the merging of AT&T and TMobile will likely produce negative externalities for the corporations supplying inputs to the industry. Phone handset makers, such as the likes of HTC, Motorola, and Samsung, are likely to take a hit, as they will see the carriers who purchase their GSM-based phones shrink from two to one. They will have less ability to control the prices of their handsets, as there will now only be a single buyer that dictates which GSM phones enter the market. Similarly, network equipment suppliers such as Alcatel-Lucent and Nokia Siemens, who supply gears and other equipment to both T-Mobile and AT&T, will lose nearly all of their bargaining power with a single customer and their profit margins could take a major hit (Malik, 2011). Sprint, who is currently the third largest North American wireless provider, has expressed its dissent over the proposed acquisition. They believe that this deal will alter the industry dramatically by having two carriers holding nearly eighty percent of the total customers. Consumers may quickly see their most cost-effective wireless option disappear as soon as the integration of AT&T and T-Mobile networks goes live, as T-Mobile currently has some of the cheapest wireless rates. For comparison, in 2010 both T-Mobile and Sprint offered unlimited voice, text, and data services for $99.99 per month while Verizon and AT&T offered the same services for $119.99 per month (Federal Communications Committee, 2011). Sprint and T-Mobile’s more aggressive pricing structures has been able to keep the larger companies’ pricing plans in check. With the removal of T-Mobile from the market Sprint will likely experience severe pressure from existing companies, and with a small percentage of the market share impeding on their profit margins they may be forced to raise prices closer to that of AT&T and Verizon. This is probably a worstcase scenario, however it would leave American consumers without any competitive options. The Federal Communications Commission (2010) has provided a map of coverage density in the United States. The darkest region depicts areas covered by four or more wireless providers. The merger of AT&T and T-Mobile will bring nationwide coverage to a maximum of three service providers, therefore resulting in fewer options per area, which in turn yields less competition. As we learned in our microeconomic theory, among the negative implications of a monopoly such as economic inefficiency (deadweight loss), there is another possible harmful outcome that is harder to describe; this is known as x-inefficiency or laziness. With a merger resulting in a GSM monopoly (or perhaps oligopoly from an industry-wide perspective) these operating firms will have less incentive to be ‘good’ producers. Price making monopolies operate at a point where prices are greater than their long-run average costs. This x-inefficiency consists of behaviors such as empire building or a lack of innovation that end up increasing the firm’s average total cost. Because a non-competitive firm can set their price above the equilibrium supply and demand level they need not worry about minimizing costs. This x-inefficiency is a detriment to the economy in the sense that a firm’s laziness due to low competition causes them to operate in a way that increases total costs, causing further divergence from the economically efficient level. This acquisition proposed by AT&T Incorporated involves many moving pieces that will have serious implications for the overall health of the American mobile market. The rapid growth of the wireless data industry has resulted in the desperate need for increased bandwidth for service providers. The merger of AT&T with T-Mobile will offer greater network capabilities for AT&T’s data-hungry consumers, however there is strong reason to expect decreased competition and negative effects for consumers and competing firms alike. In summation, if approved by the Federal Communications Commission it can be expected that this acquisition will drastically change the landscape of the United State’s wireless industry. Works Cited White, Gregory. "AT&T Buys T-Mobile." Business Insider. <http://www.businessinsider.com/att-buys-t-mobile-2011-3>. March 210, 2011. GSMA. "GSM World." GSM World : Home of the GSM Association. <http://www.gsmworld.com/technology/gsm/index.htm>, 2011. Thomson, Amy. "AT&T Deal May Get a Year of Regulatory Scrutiny Even With Disposal Pledges." Bloomberg - Business & Financial News. <http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2011-03-21/at-t-has-to-fend-offscrutiny-to-win-nod-for-unthinkable-t-mobile-bid.html>, Mar 4, 2011. Bode, Karl. "Wireless Market Share By Device And ISP." DSLReports. <http://www.dslreports.com/shownews/Wireless-Market-Share-By-DeviceAnd-ISP-108292>, May 7, 2010. Tessler, Joelle. "Monopoly Worries Plague AT&T's Purchase of T-Mobile." TheSunNews.com. <http://www.thesunnews.com/2011/03/22/2053664/monopoly-worriesplague-purchase.html>, March 22, 2011. Malik, Om. "In AT&T & T-Mobile Merger, Everybody Loses." GigaOM · Tech News, Analysis and Trends. <http://gigaom.com/2011/03/20/in-att-t-mobilemerger-everybody-loses/>, March 20, 2011.