Uploaded by bangtansun

Econ 7

advertisement
Economics in Global Environment
Purchasing Power Parity and Foreign Exchange Rates in Long Run
Chapter Seven
In the long run, prices and exchange rates will always adjust so that the
purchasing power of each currency remains comparable over baskets of goods
in different countries.
This hypothesis provides another key building block in the theory of how
exchange rates are determined.
In the last chapter we have learned how the spot and forward exchange rate are
determined in short run. In this chapter we are going to look at the long run to
see how the expected future exchange rate is determined.
If investors are to make forecasts of future exchange rates, they need a
plausible theory of how exchange rates are determined in the long run.
The theory we are going to develop in this chapter has two parts. The first part
involves the theory of purchasing power, which links the exchange rate to price
levels in each country in the long run.
In the second part of the chapter, we explore how price levels are related to
monetary conditions in each country.
Combining the monetary theory of price level determination with the purchasing
power theory of exchange rate determination, we emerge with a long-run
theory known as the monetary approach to exchange rates.
The goal of this chapter is to set out the long-run relationships between money,
prices, and exchange rates.
Purchasing Power Parity and Goods Market Equilibrium
1
Just as arbitrage occurs in the international market for financial assets, it also
occurs in the international markets for goods.
The result of goods market arbitrage is that the prices of goods in different
countries expressed in a common currency tend to be equalized.
Applied to a single good, this idea is referred to as the “law of one price”
applied to an entire basket of goods, it is called the theory of “purchasing
power parity.”
Our goal is to develop a simple yet useful theory based on an idealized world of
frictionless trade where transaction costs can be neglected.
We start at the microeconomic level with single goods and the law of one price.
We then move to the macroeconomic level to consider baskets of goods and
purchasing power parity.
Law of One Price
The law of one price (LOOP) states that in the absence of trade frictions (such as
transport costs and tariffs), and under conditions of free competition and price
flexibility (where no individual sellers or buyers have power to manipulate prices
and prices can freely adjust), identical goods sold in different locations must sell
for the same price when prices are expressed in a common currency.
By definition, in a market equilibrium there are no arbitrage opportunities. If
gold can be freely moved between New York and London, both markets must
offer the same price. Economists refer to this situation in the two locations as
an integrated market.
The exchange rate between two currencies should equal to the ratio of the
countries’ price levels: When the “Law of One Price” is applied internationally to
a standard consumption basket, we obtain the theory of “Purchasing Power
Parity (PPP).” This theory states that the exchange rate between two currencies
of two countries should be equal to the ratio of the countries’ price levels.
2
$
𝑷$
οΏ‘
𝑷
S( )=
οΏ‘
For example, if an ounce of gold costs $300 in the U.S. and £150 in the U.K.,
then the price of one pound in terms of dollars should be:
$
𝑷$
οΏ‘
𝑷
S( )=
=
οΏ‘
$πŸ‘πŸŽπŸŽ
οΏ‘πŸπŸ“πŸŽ
=
$𝟐
￑𝟏
Suppose the spot exchange rate is $1.25 = €1.00. If the inflation rate in the U.S.
is expected to be 3% in the next year and 5% in the euro zone, then the
expected exchange rate in one year should be $1.25×(1.03) = €1.00×(1.05).
Inflation is the rate of increase in prices over a given period of time. Inflation is
typically a broad measure, such as the overall increase in prices or the increase
in the cost of living in a country.
The euro will trade at a 1.90% discount in the forward market based
Forward/spot price relationship and PPP theory:
$
$𝟏.πŸπŸ“∗(𝟏.πŸŽπŸ‘)
𝑭( )
€
$
𝑺( )
€
=
€πŸ.𝟎𝟎∗(𝟏.πŸŽπŸ“)
$𝟏.πŸπŸ“
€πŸ.𝟎𝟎
=
𝟏.πŸŽπŸ‘
𝟏.πŸŽπŸ“
=
𝟏+ 𝝅$
𝟏+ 𝝅
€
Relative PPP states that the rate of change in the exchange rate is equal to
differences in the rates of inflation—roughly 2%= 5% - 3%
Absolute PPP and Relative PPP
Absolute PPP: The same basket of goods should cost the same everywhere.
If a standard basket of goods costs €100.00, and the USD/EUR exchange rate is
$1.3158/€, then that standard basket of goods should cost $131.58 in U.S.
3
Relative PPP: The exchange rates between currencies should reflect their
inflation rates. If the spot USD/EUR exchange rate is $1.3158/€, the (annual)
USD inflation rate is 4% and the (annual) EUR inflation rate is 2%, then the
expected spot exchange rate in one year later should be ($1.3158 × 1.04) / (€1
× 1.02) = $1.3416/€.
PPP and IRP
Notice that our two big equations equal each other:
PPP
IRP
$
$
𝑭( )
€
=
$
𝑺( )
€
𝟏+ 𝝅$
𝟏+ 𝝅
𝟏+ π’Š$
=
𝟏+ π’Š
€
€
𝑭( )
=
€
$
𝑺( )
€
Expected Rate of Change in Exchange Rate as Inflation Differential
We could also reformulate our equations as inflation or interest rate
differentials:
$
𝑭( )
€
$
𝑺( )
𝟏+ 𝝅$
=
𝟏+ 𝝅
€
𝑭(
$
€
€
$
)− 𝑺 ( )
€
$
𝑺( )
=
€
𝑭(
E(e)=
$
€
𝟏+ 𝝅$
𝟏+ 𝝅
-1=
€
$
)− 𝑺 ( )
€
$
𝑺( )
€
=
𝟏+ 𝝅$
𝟏+ 𝝅
𝝅$− 𝝅
𝟏+ 𝝅
4
€
€
€
-
𝟏+ 𝝅
𝟏+ 𝝅
€
€
β‰’ 𝝅$− 𝝅
€
𝑭(
E(e)=
$
€
$
)− 𝑺 ( )
€
$
𝑺( )
=
€
π’Š$− π’Š
𝟏+ π’Š
€
β‰’
π’Š$− π’Š
€
€
𝝅$− 𝝅
€
β‰’ π’Š$− π’Š
€
PPP Deviations and the Real Exchange Rate:
Whether PPP holds or not has important implication for international trade.
If PPP holds and thus the differential inflation rates between countries are
exactly offset by exchange rate changes, countries’ competitive positions in
world export markets will not be systematically affected by exchange rate
changes.
However, if there are deviations from PPP, changes in nominal exchange rates
cause changes in the “real exchange rates”, affecting the international
competitive positions of countries. This, in turn, would affect countries’ trade
balances.
The real exchange rate, q, which measures deviations from PPP, can be
defined as follows:
g
= ( E$ / € PEUR
)/

g
qUS
/ EUR
ο€±ο€²
ο€³
Relative price of good g
in Europe versus U.S.
European price
of good g in $
PUSg

U.S. price
of good g in $
First, note that if PPP holds (PPP conditions are met/satisfied), that is,
𝑬
𝑷𝑬𝑼𝑹=𝑷𝑼𝑺 , the real exchange rate will be unity, q = 1.
π’ˆ
$/€
π’ˆ
When PPP is violated, however, the real exchange rate will deviate from unity.
Suppose, for example, the annual inflation rate is 5% in the U.S and 3.5% in the
euro zone, and the spot dollar/euro rate is 1.009.
Then the real exchange rate is 0.99:
q = (1.009)*(1.035)/(1.05) = 0.99
5
In the above example, the dollar depreciated by more than is warranted by PPP,
strengthening the competiveness of U.S industries in the world market.
If the dollar depreciates by less than the inflation rate differential, the real
exchange rate will be greater than unity. Weakening the competitiveness of U.S
industries.
To summarize,
q = 1 : Competitiveness of the domestic country unaltered.
q < 1 : Competitiveness of the domestic country improves.
q > 1 : Competitiveness of the domestic country deteriorates.
Or put it another way,
(1) If the real exchange rate q
US/BP
is below 1 by x%, then Foreign (UK) goods
are relatively cheap, x% cheaper than Home (US) goods. In this case, the Home
currency (the dollar) is said to be strong, the British Pound is weak, and we say
the B Pound is undervalued by x%.
(2) If the real exchange rate q
US/BP
is above 1 by x%, then Foreign goods are
relatively expensive, x% more expensive than Home goods. In this case, the
Home currency (the dollar) is said to be weak, the euro is strong, and we say
the euro is overvalued by x%.
The relative price of the baskets is one of the most important variables in
international macroeconomics, and it has a special name: it is known as the real
exchange rate.
The U.S. real exchange rate q
US/EUR
=E
$/€
P
EUR
/P
US
tells us how many U.S. baskets
are needed to purchase one European basket; it is the price of the European
basket in terms of the U.S. basket.
The exchange rate for currencies is a nominal concept. The real exchange rate
is a real concept; it says how many U.S. baskets can be exchanged for one
European basket.
6
The real exchange rate has some terminology similar to that used with the
nominal exchange rate:
(1) If the real exchange rate rises (more Home goods are needed in exchange
for Foreign goods), we say Home has experienced a real depreciation.
(2) If the real exchange rate falls (fewer Home goods are needed in exchange
for Foreign goods), we say Home has experienced a real appreciation.
Evidence on PPP
PPP probably does not hold precisely in the real world for a variety of reasons.
Haircuts cost 10 times as much in the developed world as in the developing
world.
Film, on the other hand, is a highly standardized commodity that is actively
traded across borders.
Shipping costs, as well as tariffs and quotas, can lead to deviations from PPP.
PPP-determined exchange rates still provide a valuable benchmark.
Economists have found a variety of reasons why PPP fails in the short run:
(1) Transaction costs. Include costs of transportation, tariffs, duties, and other
costs due to shipping and delays associated with developing distribution
networks and satisfying legal and regulatory requirements in foreign markets.
On average, they are more than 20% of the price of goods traded
internationally.
(2) Nontraded goods. Some goods are inherently nontradable; they have
infinitely high transaction costs. Most goods and services fall somewhere
between tradable and nontradable.
(3) Imperfect competition and legal obstacles. Many goods are not simple
undifferentiated commodities, as LOOP and PPP assume, but are differentiated
products with brand names, copyrights, and legal protection. Such
7
differentiated goods create conditions of imperfect competition because firms
have some power to set the price of their good. With this kind of market
power, firms can charge different prices not just across brands but also across
countries.
(4) Price stickiness. Prices do not or cannot adjust quickly and flexibly to
changes in market conditions.
The Exact Fisher Effects
Fisher Effects
An increase (decrease) in the expected rate of inflation will cause a
proportionate increase (decrease) in the interest rate in the country.
For the U.S., the Fisher effect is written as:
1 + i$ = (1 + $ ) × E(1 + $)
Where:
$ is the equilibrium expected “real” U.S. interest rate.
E($) is the expected rate of U.S. inflation.
i$ is the equilibrium expected nominal U.S. interest rate.
International Fisher Effect
If the Fisher effect holds in the U.S.,
1 + i$ = (1 + $ ) × E(1 + $)
and the Fisher effect holds in Japan,
1 + i¥ = (1 + ¥ ) × E(1 + ¥)
and if the real rates are the same in each country (empirical studies show that
real interests among nations are similar to each other), so we can safely assume
$ = ¥
then we get the International Fisher Effect:
8
𝟏 + π’Š¥
𝟏 + π’Š$
𝑬(𝟏 + ¥)
=
𝑬(𝟏 + $)
If the International Fisher Effect holds,
𝟏 + π’Š¥
𝟏 + π’Š$
𝑬(𝟏 + ¥)
=
𝑬(𝟏 + $)
and if IRP also holds
𝑭
𝟏 + π’Š¥
𝟏 + π’Š$
=
οΏ₯⁄
$
𝑺
οΏ₯⁄
$
then forward rate PPP holds:
𝑭
οΏ₯⁄
$
𝑺
οΏ₯⁄
=
𝑬(𝟏 + ¥)
𝑬(𝟏 + $)
$
9
Download