The Design Of /1,2 Fiscal Rules Davide Lombardo International Monetary Fund Turkish Banks’ Association Seminar February 26, 2009 1/ The views expressed in this presentation are the author’s, and not necessarily the IMF’s. 2/ Based on the December 1-2 2008 workshop organized by the Treasury, SPO, and MOF together with the Fiscal Affairs Department of the IMF. In particular it borrows on the presentations by Debreu and Debreu and Kumar (available on the website of the Turkish Treasury—see press release dated 18 Dec 2008). Outline First principles: (Definition, Rationale, Function) Taxonomy Design trade-offs Basic properties of selected rules Monitoring and enforcement Fiscal rules around the world: EU sample Broader sample Lessons from stylized facts Conclusions Definition Mechanism placing durable constraints on fiscal discretion through numerical limits on budgetary aggregates (expenditure, revenue, budget balance and/or public debt). Any fiscal policy rule is made of 3 parts: Numerical target/ceiling on one or more specific fiscal indicators Explicit cost for non-complying policymakers A monitoring/enforcement procedure. What is not a fiscal policy rule? The annual budget is not a rule, as it only applies for one year. An IMF-supported program, as it is not expected to be a permanent feature of fiscal policy. The new UK “rule”: “To set policies to improve the cyclically-adjusted current budget each year, once the economy emerges from the downturn, so it reaches balance and debt is falling as a proportion of GDP once the global shocks have worked their way through the economy in full.” Rationale: why constraining discretion? Unconstrained fiscal policy may be perceived as systematically deviating from desirable policies. In practice: pro-cyclical and/or unsustainable policies. Reasons why unconstrained policies can be biased: Time-inconsistency Fiscal federalism/monetary union Political economy: Myopia, re-election concerns, fiscal illusion, distributive conflicts, and coordination failures. Other disciplining mechanisms? Markets: yes, but unreliable (comes too late and to strongly) Delegation to non-partisan technical agencies: poses considerable issues in terms of democratic accountability. Functions of fiscal rules Rules are commitment devices: they make deviations from socially desirable targets too costly for policymakers. Rules are signaling tools: they can help policymakers signal their genuine commitment to sustainable and stabilizing policies. Rules can also serve to anchor expectations, thus reducing uncertainties and risk premia. Principles of a taxonomy Many parameters enter the design of an actual fiscal policy rule: fiscal target(s) nature of costs in case of deviation monitoring/enforcement escape clauses, etc. A good rule must imply good policies in most (if not all) circumstances the policy response induced by the rule to a variety of shocks is therefore key. Key feature of the rules: response to shocks Limits to discretion make sense, but they should NOT: Prevent adequate responses (e.g., let automatic stabilizers play in bad times) Force inadequate responses (e.g., force a fiscal contraction in response to a temporary spike in interest rate, or depreciation of the exchange rate) Let the bias unchecked in specific circumstances (e.g., allow for procyclical expansions). The design of fiscal rules There is no one-size-fits-all fiscal policy rule. Much depends on: Constellation of shocks prevalent in the economy Nature and magnitude of policy bias under discretion. A good rule is (Kopits and Symansky, 1998): …simple …transparent …coherent with the final goal …but mindful of other goals of public policy: • Not discouraging structural reforms • Allowing for fiscal stabilization (time-frame, cyclical adjustment) • Avoiding low-quality adjustments (undue tax hikes, cuts in quality/priority spending). Two key trade-offs Credibility-flexibility: allowing for greater responsiveness to shocks could undermine credibility of attaining the final goal. Flexibility-simplicity: combinations of rules can relax somewhat the credibility-flexibility trade-off, at the cost of simplicity and transparency. The devil is in the details Other design issues Coverage of the government sector Policy coordination in federal/decentralized systems Legal foundations Need for adequate budgetary procedures (preparation, execution, and ex-post auditing of budgets) Need to limit scope for creative accounting Pros and cons of selected rules Simple rules: Debt rules Budget balance rules Expenditure rules Revenue rules Combined rules: e.g., debt objectives coupled with binding deficit ceilings, debt/budget balance objectives coupled with binding medium-term expenditure ceilings Deficit Rules Balanced budget and overall deficit limits Pros: pin down asymptotic properties of debt directly address the deficit bias can be simple and transparent (unless cyclical considerations, escape clauses, etc). Cons: procyclical (unless cyclically adjusted or “over the cycle”) could force cut in investment… • golden rule, but these open door to manipulations, and do not guarantee debt sustainability. Overall vs. primary balance? Primary is more robust to volatility in interest payments. Debt Rules Upper limit (or desirable time path) for gross or net public debt Pros: Directly tackle debt sustainability Can be transparent and simple Can accommodate large shocks if debt is well below the ceiling Cons: Lack controllability Can force procyclical and undesirable responses to interest rate and exchange rate shocks if debt is close to the limit Borrowing constraints generally applied at regional and local levels Expenditure Rules Set expenditure ceilings (nominal or in terms of GDP) or limits on growth (nominal or real). Pros: tackle one of main source of deficit bias translate directly into budget preparation minimizes pro-cyclicality risks fosters medium-term planning Cons: May leave room for discretionary tax cuts sustainability? complex to design (nominal vs. real, exclusions,…) Best used in combination with deficit or debt rules. [Revenue Rules] Rules imposing limits on revenues with a view to: Pros: Contain size of the public sector / tax burden Allocate ex-ante revenue windfalls (e.g., due to surprisingly high growth) Can reduce procyclicality in good times Cons: Limited impact on deficit bias if not coupled with other rules Can be procyclical in case the rule targets a given revenue-toGDP ratio (due to the progresssivity of the tax system) Combination of rules Drawbacks with individual rules have led most countries to adopt combination of rules Most common combinations: Debt and overall deficit ceiling and overall balance target (e.g., Maastricht) Overall balance and expenditure ceilings (Sweden, Finland, Netherlands, etc). Monitoring Ex-ante Is the government proposed fiscal policy consistent with the rule and its objectives? Ex-post auditing: assessment: Was the rule implemented? • Analysis of underlying policies • Certification role: track attempts to resort to creative accounting • Assessment of ex-post adjustments to the target (CABs,…), activation of escape clauses, etc. A key pre-requisite Budgetary transparency: Fiscal data need to be accessible, timely, and reliable Comprehensive periodic reporting requirements Clarity about the budget preparation and execution procedures Clarity about roles and responsibilities of different levels of government Fiscal councils Independent institutions with country-specific mandates adequate and highly qualified staff guaranteed multi-year budget. Can contribute to greater transparency and accountability of fiscal policy. Can help monitoring and enforcing a rule. The case of Chile Fiscal institutional setup designed to buttress fiscal sustainability and dampen cyclical fluctuations. Rule: maintain a structural surplus of 1 percent of GDP for the central government. Fiscal expenditures follow the dynamics of structural revenue. Two independent expert panels provide key projections: 1. 2. the inputs (growth of the labor force, real investment, and total labor productivity) for estimating trend GDP ten-year forecasts of the price of copper. Independent panels enhance policy credibility, while allowing some policy flexibility. The case of the Netherlands The Central Planning Bureau plays a key role in the budgetary process: Provides projections and forecasts Estimates desired structural budget balance Vets the programs of all political parties (which are thus subject to reputational sanctions) Undertakes analysis of specific budgetary projects. High credibility borne out of tradition Fiscal Rules: International Experience Stylized facts for EU (EC database: annual data over 1990-2005), and the rest of the world (IMF-FAD database on the design and implementation of fiscal rules) Worldwide: 81 countries identified as having fiscal policy rules, with complete information for 77 of them Growing appetite for fiscal rules (EU) 0.90 Maastricht SGP EMU 0.80 0.70 Raw index 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 EU-15 Euro-11 0.10 NMS Big-4 0.00 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Emerging Market and LICs are catching up with industrial countries Number of fiscal rules by category of countries: 1990-2008 80 70 Industrial EU-27 Emerging 60 LIC's 50 40 30 20 10 0 1990 1995 2000 2008 Budget-balance and debt rules dominate, but expenditure rules are increasingly popular Number of countries with at least one fiscal policy rule (by type of rule) 80 70 Budget balance Debt Expenditure 60 Revenue 50 40 30 20 10 0 1990 1995 2000 2008 Expenditure and revenue rules are thus relative newcomers Median duration of existing fiscal rules (in years) 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Budget balance Debt Expenditure Revenue Same trends in EU sample 60 50 Revenue Rules Expenditure rules Debt Rules Budget balance rules 40 30 20 10 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Budget balance rules appear stronger and have wider coverage Selected features of rules-based fiscal frameworks by type of rule (common features only) 1.00 Budget balance Debt 0.90 Revenue 0.80 Expenditure 0.70 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 0.00 Independent enforcement (relative frequency) Independent monitoring (relative frequency) Coverage (median Statutory basis (median relative to maximum relative to maximum possible score) possible score) This is reflected in synthetic measures of strength and coverage Indices of strength (max= 6) and of coverage (max=4) by type of rule 3 4.0 Strength Coverage 3.5 2.5 3.0 2 2.5 1.5 2.0 1.5 1 1.0 0.5 0.5 0 0.0 Budget balance Revenue Debt Expenditure Strength and coverage relatively similar across countries Indices of strength (max= 6) and of coverage (max=4) by country category 3.0 Strength 4.0 Coverage 3.5 2.5 3.0 2.0 2.5 1.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 1.0 0.5 0.5 0.0 0.0 Industrial Resource rich LICs Emerging markets Features by country groups Selected features of rules-based fiscal frameworks (relative frequencies by country groups) 1.00 0.90 Industrial Emerging LIC's Resource-rich 0.80 0.70 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 0.00 Independent M TEF Independent FRL (all rules) Provision(s) enforcement (relative to forecasts (all for fiscal procedure (all BBR and DR) rules) stabilization rules) (relative to BBR) Exclusion of Independent high-quality monitoring (all spending rules) (relative to BBR and ER) Fiscal rules lower interest rates (EU-25) Table 2. Determinants of Long-Term Interest Rates in the EU-25 (1990–2005): Selected Sub-Samples Arellano-Bond Estimator: EU-15 Long-term interest rate (lagged) Non-EU15 Enlargement (dummy) 0.55 (8.77) 0.26 (4.23) -0.08 (-2.44) 0.01 (0.73) 0.13 (3.04) 0.22 (2.10) … Election year (dummy) … … Stability and Growth Pact (dummy) … … Government stability … … Ideological range of governing coalition … … -0.16 (-1.58) 0.10 (0.10) 213 15 0.93 1.00 47 10 0.16 1.00 Short-term interest rate Cyclically-adjusted primary balance Public debt (lagged) Real GDP growth Inflation Fiscal Rule Index Number of observations Number of countries Test for 2nd order autocorrelation (p-value) 2/ Sargan test (p-value) 3/ *** 0.35 *** (4.26) *** 0.58 *** (16.99) ** -0.01 (-0.03) 0.00 (0.22) *** -0.01 (-0.06) ** -0.07 * (-1.77) … Euro Non-euro Fixed effects 1/ High debt -0.11 0.53 *** (-1.44) (5.67) 0.50 *** 0.23 *** (10.52) (3.07) 0.00 -0.03 (-0.26) (-0.39) -0.01 0.00 (-0.85) (0.27) 0.04 ** 0.11 ** (2.14) (2.38) 0.11 ** 0.22 * (2.12) (1.92) … 0.03 (0.07) 0.08 ** 0.38 (2.17) (1.40) … … 0.47 (9.98) 0.26 (11.32) -0.07 (-1.77) 0.01 (0.46) 0.26 (4.29) 0.45 (4.22) … -0.03 ** (-1.89) -0.02 (-1.53) -0.09 * (-1.63) -0.17 * (-1.85) 0.13 * (1.90) -0.16 (-0.93) -0.21 *** (-3.75) … 72 12 0.10 1.00 155 25 0.38 1.00 107 15 0.25 1.00 Low debt *** 0.31 *** (6.35) *** 0.50 *** (13.49) * -0.04 (-0.82) 0.00 (0.08) *** 0.04 (0.91) *** -0.04 (-1.07) … … … … … -0.17 (-1.37) 0.03 (0.24) … Delegation 0.39 (4.52) 0.40 (4.29) -0.07 (-1.34) 0.02 (2.04) 0.06 (1.93) 0.01 (0.17) … *** *** ** ** 0.26 (1.48) … -0.31 ** (-2.48) -0.18 *** (-3.69) -0.14 (-1.42) -0.10 (-1.06) 153 22 0.21 1.00 72 9 0.55 1.00 No delegation 0.39 (4.58) 0.23 (2.56) -0.05 (-0.88) 0.01 (0.61) 0.09 (1.39) 0.33 (2.70) -0.61 (-1.40) 0.28 (1.00) -0.29 (-1.30) -0.16 (-1.61) 0.11 (2.71) -0.41 (-2.03) *** *** *** *** ** Stable gov. Unstable gov. 0.56 *** 0.13 (6.41) (1.53) 0.12 0.43 *** (0.92) (6.93) 0.03 -0.04 (0.56) (-0.72) 0.00 0.01 (-0.29) (0.88) 0.07 0.11 * (1.63) (1.80) 0.26 * 0.09 (1.88) (1.18) … … 0.47 * (1.76) 0.13 (0.56) 0.14 (0.59) 0.10 (1.52) -0.06 (-0.50) 0.02 (0.11) -0.96 ** (-2.13) -0.08 (-1.19) 0.15 (1.65) -0.43 (-1.59) 148 24 … … 104 21 … … 148 19 0.45 1.00 Note: The t-statistics are reported in parentheses (with superscripts *, **, and *** denoting statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels respectively). They are robust to cross-sectional heteroskedasticity. All models include a constant and country effects (not reported). The latter are jointly significant at conventional confidence levels in all equations. The enlargement dummy is equal to 1 for new member states, after they joined the EU. The SGP dummy is equal to 1 for euro area member states after 1998. 1/ Arellano-Bond estimation could not be obtained for one of the subsamples (lagged dependent variable highly insignificant and evidence of second-order autocorrelation). The comparison is thus based on fixed-effects estimates. 2/ Arellano-Bond test of the null hypothesis of no autocorrelation of residuals. 3/ Test of the null hypothesis that identifying restrictions are valid. Debrun and Joshi (2008) Fiscal rules lower interest rates (EU-25) Table 3. Impact of the Fiscal Rules on Long-Term Interest Rates: Specific Features of the Rule (EU-25, 1990–2005, Non-Excessive Public Debt) Specific dimensions of fiscal rules as captured by sub-indices: Statutory basis -0.47 ** (-2.07) Independent body monitoring the rule's implementation -0.48 ** (-2.07) Independent body contributing to rule's enforcement -0.52 ** (-2.01) Strength of enforcement procedure -0.40 ** (-2.03) Media impact of the rule -0.47 ** (-2.23) Memorandum items: Overall fiscal rule index -0.45 ** (-2.09) Expenditure rule index 0.05 (0.29) Notes: The t-statistics are reported in parentheses (with superscripts *, **, and *** denoting statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels respectively). Given that subindices are only available for the overall fiscal rule index and the expenditure rule index, the results, obtained with model (6) in Table 1, use the overall index but control for the effect of expenditure rules. Debrun and Joshi (2008) All key dimensions matter Effective rules deliver lower interest rates. Lessons Historical preference for deficit and debt rule But recently emergence of expenditure rules (in combination with BBRs and DRs) What explains the trends for more rules and more expenditure rules? Increasing realization that purely discretionary fiscal policies are inconsistent with sustainability (growing public debt) Mounting pressures from long-term issues: aging, global warming, etc. Regional monetary unions. Conclusions Well-designed fiscal rules can help improve fiscal performance on average… …thus lowering risk-premia and interest rates on long-term government bonds. But: political commitment is key As are adequate public financial management, monitoring and enforcing systems.