Markets and Market Structure: The Structure-ConductPerformance Paradigm (I. Bobel 2011) Economists use the abstract notion of a “market” to describe how individuals (such as buyers and sellers or firms) but also groups of firms (industries – the microeconomic dimension) and groups of people (even nations as a whole – the macroeconomic dimension) interact and trade with each other. Typically a market consists of (at least) two parties who are involved in such a mutually beneficial interdependent activity: a seller and a buyer. There is a market for nearly everything in the economy! When dealing with markets, textbook- economics concentrates on the following three types of markets: the goods market (where goods and services are traded), the input or factor market (where factors of production – like land labor or capital – are bought and sold), and the market for foreign trade (where domestically produced goods are exported and foreign produced goods are imported). The ultimate outcome of each of these different market transactions is always determined at such a point where buyers and sellers come to a final agreement and close the deal. We call this the “market equilibrium” which is characterized by an “equilibrium price” and the “equilibrium quantity” of the respective good or service traded. Depending on the market under consideration the price carries a different name: on the goods market it is called “the goods price”, on the labor market the resulting price is “the wage”, on the capital market it is “the interest rate”, and on the market for foreign trade it is “the exchange rate”. From a microeconomic, managerial perspective it is important to note that markets and industries can be distinguished according to the degree of market power that each individual participant involved in the market transaction possesses. At the same time this indicates how competitive the overall market or industry ultimately is. Market power is defined as the ability of any market participant to actively influence the market price. In fact, this is – besides many other features that can be listed to distinguish market structures – the single most important criterion. An incomplete list of criteria (because there are too many) to distinguish market structures would include: the number of firms in the market; the degree of product differentiation; the degree of market churn (turnover of customers); the concentration ratio (size of market share); the nature of costs (are sunk costs important?); the degree of vertical integration, barriers to entry, and many more. The spectrum of market structures runs between two extremes (which we shall analyze in detail in Units 6 and 7): at the one end of the spectrum we find firms that have no market power whatsoever and who produce homogeneous products (such as agricultural products like milk or grain). Such a scenario where many totally powerless firms and many buyers are dominating the market is called “perfect competition”. All firms take the market price as being given – they are price takers and face a horizontal market demand curve. The opposite extreme case is is a case of “imperfect competition” and is called “pure monopoly” where only one single firm dominates the entire market - it can set the market price and faces a (downward sloping) market demand curve for a differentiated product that it offers. Such a firm is obviously a price maker. Both extreme cases (perfect competition and pure monopoly) rest on extreme assumptions and rarely show up in reality. However, they are widely used as benchmarks (for ex. by antitrust authorities) against which real-life cases are tested to prove anti-competitive behavior exerted by firms on specific markets (now relax for a minute and listen to Tim Wu (2011)– he talks about the development of market dominance and the rise of information monopolies). More realistic practically relevant cases of market structures, the cases of oligopoly and monopolistic competition, are mixtures of these two extreme cases. Oligopolistic firms can be found in markets that are dominated by a few large companies that possess market power, sell some branded product - but are mutually interdependent when developing their individual business strategies. Such firms have to take into account the likely reactions and conduct on any price or non-price competitive actions that they perform. The digital media player industry or the soft drink industry (where few giant firms dominate), the market for sports footwear or crude oil and the refining of petroleum products are examples. Finally, the most frequently found market structure is the case of monopolistic competition where many (smaller) firms are selling slightly differentiated goods so that they have at least some degree of market power. The market is easy to enter and can be highly competitive (as it is in the cases of small restaurants located in city centers, coffee bars, drug retailing or pizza delivery services). Typically individual firms are assumed to follow the goal of profit maximization, that is, making the difference between revenues (price times quantity) and costs as large as possible. There is an important conceptual tool to analyze differences in the degree of competitiveness among companies and industries which dates back to the classic, standard Industrial Organization (IO)approach in the Bain-Scherer tradition (Scherer and Ross, 1990). This approach embraces firms, industries and the economy as a whole as it applies the so called “Structure – Conduct Performance Paradigm” (SCP Paradigm) as a theoretical tool whereby the terms “market” and “industry” are used interchangeably. “This paradigm was originally developed to help governments identify industries within which social-welfaremaximizing perfect competition dynamics were not unfolding” (Barney 2002, p. 54). The graphical scheme below is selfexplaining and describes the conceptual framework (the following discussion draws on Scherer 1996, pp. 2-5). The structure of an industry determines the conduct of buyers and sellers and, by implication, its performance along such dimensions as profitability, efficiency and innovativeness (Ghemawat 1997). Market Structure (especially the number of competitors and the degree of rivalry between the competitors) is the principal influence on a company’s behavior (Market Conduct) whereby market structure itself depends on the external conditions of supply and demand and results in the attempt of firms to influence the Intensity of Competition. At the same time Public Policy might have a direct impact on both Market Conduct and Market Structure. An example might be public utilities competing with private sector firms. Incentive systems (like taxes and subsidies) are frequently tailored to the conditions of individual industries. A company’s conduct will be influenced by the way how government regulates a market (for example, through price controls or other interventions). The final outcome (Performance) centers around the “big trade off” between equity and efficiency. “Good performance is what a nation’s citizens ultimately seek from their industries” Scherer 1996, p. 3) There is an obvious feedback-effect (as shown by the dotted lines in the graph below) incorporated in this process as Market Conduct, for ex., will also impact the Basic Conditions while the Market Structure will, in turn, shape the Basic Conditions of Supply and Demand. This implies that the chain of causation does not run in only one direction. Pricing and product strategies can have an impact on the structure of the market, while legal tactics (like lobbying) can have an impact on public policies or on entry into the market. Bain and Scherer advanced the research program of uncovering general relationships between industry structure and performance through an extensive set of empirical studies for the US. The same was done in Europe by Manfred Neumann, Ingo Bobel and Alfred Haid (1982; 1983) who published a number of empirical studies on the question why some industries were more profitable than others.