Week 7: Antitrust and Intellectual Property BA 107 Review ► Justifications for Government Intervention Market Failures ►Public Goods ►Externalities ►Natural Monopolies ►Information Asymmetry ►Imperfect Competition Regulatory Capture Intellectual Property The KaZaa Case Background Facts ► What is KaZaa? Kazaa.com, Kazaa Media Desktop and Kazaa Plus are products of Sharman Networks. Sharman Networks is a proactive, virtual, global technology and publishing company, focused on delivering peer-to-peer software. – Kazaa website What is (are) the nonmarket issue(s)? ► What is the controversy? “Theft” vs. “Harmless appropriation” ► What is the primary nonmarket issue? Market Failure ► Who are the stakeholders? ► What are their interests? ► “Slippery Slope” argument Discussion Questions ► 1. What is the economic rationale for the existence of intellectual property? Discussion Questions ► 2. The Recording Industry Association of America has argued that users of Napster, KaZaa, Morpheus and other free digital music exchanges are “stealing” the intellectual property of record companies and artists What arguments can be made to support their position? How would you build a case against the RIAA viewpoint? (Why should file-sharing services remain legal?) Discussion Question ► 3. To what extent is the music industry representative of other digital content industries, and how is this likely to affect “solutions” to the intellectual property questions raised by file-sharing services? Discussion Question ► What is likely to happen to the development of the Internet and Internet-based industries if the music industry is successful in shutting down all file-sharing services? Intellectual Property ► Rationale Economic Natural Right ► Legal Basis Constitution ► Article 1, Section 8, Clause 8. The Congress shall have power … to promote the progress of … useful arts, by securing for limited times to … investors the exclusive right to their … discoveries Patent Act, USC (35 U.S.C.) Copyright Act (17 U.S.C. §§ 101 – 810) (Trademarks) (Unfair competition) Copyright Act 17 USC ► Federal legislation enacted by Congress pursuant to the Constitution to protect the writing of authors ► Technological advances led to expanding scope of “writings” Now include: architectural design, software, the graphic arts, motion pictures, and sound recordings ►A copyright gives the owner the exclusive right to reproduce, distribute, perform, display, or license his work Copyright Act 17 USC ► To be covered by copyright a work must be original (no need to be novel; Bleistein v. Donaldson Lithographing Co. (1903); Time Inc. v. bernard Geis Association (1968); ”work of one man’s alone”; Matthew Bender & Co. v. West Publishing Co. (1998); “sweat of the brow,” “minimal creativity”) and in a concrete "medium of expression." (cf. choreography, typefaces) ► Under current law, works are covered whether or not a copyright notice is attached and whether or not the work is registered. KaZaa case: copyright infringement and liability ► Technical Background on P-2-P technology Three methods of indexing available files on disparate PCs serving as “server-client” (1) Centralized Indexing (Napster) (2) Decentralized Indexing (StreamCast, Gnutella) (3) Supernode Indexing (KaZaa) KaZaa Case ► Legal Reasoning Contributory or Vicarious Infringement (Sony Corp. v. Universal Studios 464 U.S. 417 (1984); Ellison v. Robertson, 357 F.3d 1072, 1076 (9th Cir. 2004)) Contributory Infringement (knowledge & material contribution) ► Knowledge of Infringement If D can show substantial or commercially non-significant non-infringing uses, knowledge or infringement cannot be imputed to D. Burden of proof then rests on P Grokster I, 259 F.Supp.2d at 1035, trial court found (capability of) substantial noninfringing use. “Wilco,” “Project Gutenberg” P failed to carry burden of proof; so Sony Corp applied P failed to show D “had specific knowledge of infringement at a time at a time they contribute[d] to the infringement and fail[ed] to act upon that information.” P’s notices of infringement irrelevant because they arrive when D can do nothing to stop the alleged infringement Because of software design, D had no control over indexing, so there can be no contributory infringement KaZaa Case ► Legal Reasoning (Contributory Infringement) ►Knowledge of Infringement (from prior slide) ►Material Contribution Napster I: Indexing resided on D’s computer. Swap meets have been held to materially contribute to infringement of copyrighted materials (Fonovisa v. Cherry Auction Inc., 76 F.3d 259, 261, 264 (9th Cir. 1996) KaZaa does provide the site and facilities KaZaa Case ► Vicarious Infringement Direct Infringement by a primary party Direct financial benefit to the defendant Right and ability to supervise the infringers ►KaZaa does not have ability to block access of any individual user Patent Act 35 USC ► Federal legislation enacted pursuant to Article I of US Constitution ► Patents grant an inventor the right to exclude others from producing or using the inventor's discovery or invention for a limited period of time. ► In order to be patented an invention must be novel, useful, and not of an obvious nature. See §§ 101 - 103 of Title 35. ► Changing technology has led to expansion of definition of “human made product” – e.g., genetically modified mice; plants. Patentable Inventions ► “Novelty” Foreign, domestic anticipation ► Usefulness No particular quantum of benefit required (Anderson v. Natta (1973) Specific utility (open-ended patents may lead to “monopoly of knowledge” Brenner v. Manson (1996)) ► Nonobvious Just because it was never actually invented does not mean it was not hypothetically inconceivable. Sakraida v. Ag Pro, Inc. (1976) Antitrust Law ► Rationale: Correct market failure of monopolies ► Federal legislation enacted pursuant to the Commerce Clause of the U.S. Constitution Sherman Act (1890) Section 1. Trusts, etc., in restraint of trade illegal; penalty ► Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal. Every person who shall make any contract or engage in any combination or conspiracy hereby declared to be illegal shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by fine not exceeding $10,000,000 if a corporation, or, if any other person, $350,000, or by imprisonment not exceeding three years, or by both said punishments, in the discretion of the court. ► Section 2. Monopolizing trade a felony; penalty ► Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by fine not exceeding $10,000,000 if a corporation, or, if any other person, $350,000, or by imprisonment not exceeding three years, or by both said punishments, in the discretion of the court. ► Court Interpretation ► Per Se Rule (bright line tests) Act is illegal whether or not there was any harm Price-fixing; geographic market division Established in Northern Pacific Railroad Co. v. U.S., 356 U.S. 1 (1958) Rigid, modern courts tend not to favor ► Rule of Reason To engage in illegal monopolization, D must possess power in a relevant market and must have used improperly exclusionary acts to gain or protect that power Rule of Reason Analysis ► Monopoly power Product market (Cellophane Case) Geographic market ► “Bad Act” Monopoly power alone is not illegal. There must be some bad act But distinguishing monopolizing intent from permissible business activity of a firm with massive market power is not easy Two questions: (1) is the conduct in question truly exclusionary? (2) If so, does that justify an inference of illegal purpose and intent? Courts have been all over the map Other Antitrust Statutes ► Clayton Act of 1914 (15 USCA 12-27) Attempted to remedy lack of guidance of Sherman Act by declaring four business practices illegal – tying and exclusive dealing contracts; price discrimination; corporate mergers; interlocking directorates (but only if effect would substantially lesson competition). ► Federal Trade Commission Act (1914) (15 USCA 45) Prohibition against “unfair methods of competition in or affecting commerce, and unfair or deceptive acts or practices in or affecting commerce” ► Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of 1976 Enforcement Agencies ► Department of Justice Has authority to enforce the Sherman and Clayton Acts All suits are brought in federal courts Has sole authority to enforce criminal provisions of the federal antitrust laws Almost all criminal suits arise from Section 1 of the Sherman Act ► Federal Trade Commission Shares responsibility with the Justice Department for civil enforcement of the Clayton Act Has exclusive authority to enforce Section 5 of the FTC Act (prohibition of unfair methods of competition)