EFFICIENT PRICING WITH INCREASING RRETURN TO SCALE AND EXTERNAALITY Utility theory provides the indispensable framework for public policy analysis. How much the railroad should be subsided ? How much should be paid for pollution control ? It depends to the values which citizens place on these activities. Railroad should be subsidized so long as people collectively would be willing to pay for the cost involved. Pollution should be controlled so long as people collectively would be willing to pay for the cost. Distributional consideration has been ruled out in the analysis of this chapter. What happens if the activities with increasing return to scale(railroad travel), or externality (pollution) could be left to be handled with market forces? W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 1 EFFICIENT PRICING WITH INCREASING RRETURN TO SCALE AND EXTERNAALI Because of falling marginal and average cost the increasing return to scale activities would be prone to(natural) monopolies, if it were left to be handled by the free market. Because of the difference between private and social cost, pollution will not be optimally controlled(there would be too much pollution), if it will be left to be handled by the free market. Because , one man’s actions affect others without his being forced by the price mechanism to take the effects into account. In the case of externality the efficient amount of output will be found from Σ MRS = MRT, which can not be achieved by the free market operation In this chapter we examine the meaning of efficient pricing in different activities, and different situation(externality and increasing return to scale). W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 2 First – Best Pricing and investment. Typical increasing return to scale activity ; building the bridge. The bridge cost f units of y to build and is able to provide up to g un-congested crossing per period . The demand curve(compensated and uncompensated) for crossing is p= a – bx (a/b<g) , where p is the price per crossing (in units of y) and x is the number of crossing per period. Should the bridge be built and what price should be charged per crossing? The social value of the bridge depends on how much the bridge is used, and this depends , in turn, on the price that is charged ; First ; Determine the optimal price if the bridge is built. Second ; Determine whether it is worth building the bridge, given the price that is charged. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 3 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. First; The efficient number of crossing x* will be found from the following relationship; MRSyx(x) = MRTyx(x,f) MRSyx ; the amount of y that people are willing to sacrifice for an x, extra crossing (compensated price). MRTyx ; the amount of y that society has to sacrifice for an extra amount of x, extra crossing (marginal cost) After finding the x* , optimal price(p*) could be found by substituting x* in to the demand curve. MRS=p=a – bx , MRT= Marginal cost of one extra pass of x = 0 a – bx = 0 , x* = a/b p*= 0 W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 4 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. Px(y per x) SMC MRS = p = a – bx B(X*) p*= 0 W & L CH 6 a/b=x* g EFFICIENT PRICING x 5 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. Second ;whether the bridge should be built or nor ? We have to find out if the net welfare gain with x* number of passing is positive or not. Net welfare gain= ΔW= Benefits(x*)–Costs (x*) Benefits = B(X) = ∫0X* MRSyx(x)dx Costs = C(X) = ∫0X* MRTyx(x,f)dx + f = f ΔW=∫0a/b (a – bx)dx – f =| ax – (½)bx2 |0a/b - f ΔW = [(a2/b) – (1/2) (a2/b)] – f = (1/2)(a2/b) – f This can be illustrated easily by the following diagrams; W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 6 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. y Fixed cost y y0 STC(X) B(x*)=(1/2)(a2/b) I0 Transformation curve Y0 - f ΔW>0 B(x) f x1 =y0 – B(X) =y0 X*=a/b a/b g - ∫ (a – bx)dx x =y0 x1 - | ax – a/b (½)bx2| 0 W & L CH 6 X*=a/b EFFICIENT PRICING 0 x g =y0 – (1/2)(a2/b) 7 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. As is seen from the diagram ; at optimum x(x*) we have [B(X) – C(X)] is maximized. That is , B’(X)=C’(X) ,or MRS=MRT. SO; 1- To ensure the optimum utilization we should find x* such that B’(X*)=C’(X*). Then price x at p*=C’(X*) to ensure that x* is consumed. Optimal price (p*) is the marginal cost of x* and its demand price(which equals its marginal benefit, MRS). 2- Evaluate B(X*) – C(x*) and do the project if this was positive. We are dealing with SMC which includes no allowance for capital cost(fixed cost) because of the nature of the short run analysis . Will we not get excessive consumption of a good if we include no allowance for its capital cost in the price?. The answer is no provided we never expand capacity more than optimum one. What is important is that variable cost is the determinant of price (in short run ) and not capital or fixed cost. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 8 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. If there is a facility with fixed capacity, and optimal output equals full capacity output, then the optimal price is the demand price for the full capacity output. SMC y per x SMC P’ D’ P* P’ P* D D’ D x x* g g=x* Notice that in both cases the optimal price equals the demand price for the output being consumed , since this ensures that the available quantity is allocated to those who value it most .When D shifts to D’, price should increase to P’ to ensure that those who value the x most will get it. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 9 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. Q6-1: A bridge could be built across a river. The cost per week (in terms of interest charges on a permanent loan to finance the construction) is $800. The bridge has a capacity of 2500 crossing per week and is uncongested up to that point. The (compensated) demand for crossing per week is x= 2000 – 2000 p where p is measured in dollars. (I) what is the optimal price? (ii) Should the bridge be built? (iii) what price would maximize the revenue? (iv) would a private entrepreneur be willing to build the bridge? (v) If the revenue-maximizing price were charged, should the bridge be built? (vi) Suppose capacity were only 1500 crossings. What would be the optimal price? W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 10 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. g=2500 g=1500 P 1 3/4 1/2 1/4 500 W & L CH 6 1000 1500 2000 EFFICIENT PRICING 2500 X 11 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. (I) MRS=MRT MRS= P =(2000 – x)/2000 = MRT = 0 x* = 2000 p* = 0 (ii) p*=0, CV=∫ 1 (2000-2000p)dp = 1000 0 CV =1000>800, the bridge should be built . (iii) TR=pq= p(2000-2000p)=2000 p-2000 p2 (dTR/dp)=0 p=1/2 (iv) profit maximizing revenue is TR=(1/2)(2000-2000(1/2))=500 TR=500<C=800 No, private entrepreneur is not willing to build the bridge. 1000 * (v) if p =1/2, then B(x=1000)= ∫ [(2000-x)/2000] dx=750 0 W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 12 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. B(X)=750<C(X)=800 , the bridge should not be built. (vi) when g=1500 , then , MRS=MRT at x=1500 , P=1/4 W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 13 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. Deficits and surplus Whether the marginal cost pricing rule will generate a financial surplus or deficit for the agency which applies it. A – Technology will provide an infinitely large number of different sizes of plants. Deficit will result from marginal cost pricing under increasing return to scale, and surpluses under decreasing returns to scale. Under increasing return to scale p=MC<AC, and under decreasing return to scale, p=MC>AC. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 14 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. SMC3 P,C p2 LMC SMC1 SAC1 LAC SAC3 SMC2 SAC2 P1 Q1 W & L CH 6 Q2 EFFICIENT PRICING Q Q3 15 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. In many industries there is sharp discontinuities in size of the plant, and generalization becomes more difficult. In these cases cost-benefit analysis should be calculated for each plant size, and that one should be chosen which has the highest net benefit . Like the following example; Two possible size of the bridge; 1- One lane bridge with a capacity of 10 crossings per period and costing $50. 2- two lane bridge with a capacity of 20 crossings per period and costing $75. Demand curve for crossing the bridge is p=20 – x . Where x is the crossing per period and p is price per crossing. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 16 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. x B(X) =∫ 0 Capacity 10 20 p (20 – x )dx=20x –(1/2)x2 price = MRS cost No of journey price B(X) S= B(X)–C(X) 50 10 10 150 100 75 20 0 200 125 C2 $ g=10 g=20 200 C1 20 150 S2=125 10 S1=100 100 10 W & L CH 6 20 x B(x) 75 50 EFFICIENT PRICING 10 20 17 x 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. Extracting the consumers’ surplus How is it that an activity which is justified can not be made to pay for itself. If there were only a single user of the bridge. We could perfectly find the maximum amount which he is willing to pay for using the bridge , if we charge him for the right to use the bridge in an all or nothing pricing method (in an auction manner) , but not for any individual journey that he made. If all or nothing payment he was willing to pay for the bridge exceeded the cost , the bridge should be built, otherwise it should not. But when we move to many users we can not do this, for we cannot force each individual to reveal how much he would be willing to pay for being able to use the bridge. If asked he will tend to understate this, for what he think is unlikely to affect whether the bridge is built, and if it is built, he wants to pay as little as possible. This type of problem sometimes called FREE-RIDER PROBLEM . W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 18 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. It is possible in these cases to charge a fixed amount in addition to marginal cost, but this kind of pricing is not efficient. Thus for all goods subject to increasing return to scale (decreasing MC) and used by many users there is problem arising from the fact that users can not be charged as much as they are willing to paynot because they can not be physically excluded from use of the good, but because any system of charging that covered cost would be inefficient (because the marginal cost is decreasing and MC is small and charging MC can not reveal the willingness of the users for using the service ). A so-called pure public good is a special case of such a good , where the marginal cost of providing an extra unit of services to an individual is zero for all units. Theoretically if it is possible to make the consumers to reveal their preferences , it is possible to practice full price discrimination, but this is not practical. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 19 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. Q6-2 : Should the people be charged for; (I) Listening to a particular radio program . Nothing should be charged ,since this is a pure public good with zero marginal cost. (ii) Having the right to listen to radio programs in the following cases; (a) There is no way of preventing un authorized listeners. (b)It is possible by scramblers to prevent unauthorized listening. Nothing should be charged since, marginal cost of providing the program is zero, whether it is possible to find-out unauthorized listeners or not. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 20 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. Suppose I live in a remote area outside the transmitting range of the local broadcasting station. ( I) I can be brought within the range of broadcasts by building a new transmission tower. Would it be efficient if I was asked to pay for it? (ii) Suppose instead that I could receive broadcasts if the power of transmission were increased. This would cost $x for each hour of transmission at extra power. What would be an efficient system of operation? Solution ; (i)Yes, because providing the service for my use, needs more expenditure. (ii) I should pay when I want transmission at extra power and pay $x for each such hour. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 21 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. Q6-4 : Suppose there is a railroad from A to B . Only one trains per day runs from A to B and back, and all passengers trip are round trips. The cost of operating the train for each round trip is $500 . Plus $100 per carriage. Each carriage holds 100 passengers. The daily demand for passenger trip (x) is P= 20 – 0.01x , where p is the price per trip ($). (I) What price should be charged per trip? (II) Suppose railroad pricing and investment was optimal. Would you expect the railroad system to make financial surplus ? Solution ;(I) for any given number of carriages the price should be just sufficient to fill the marginal carriage. In order to find optimum x we have to maximize B(X) – C(X) B(X) = 20x – 0.005x2 C(X) = 500 +x d[B(X)–C(X)]/dx=d(20x – 0.005x2 – 500 – x )/dx=19 – 0.01x=0, x*=1900 p*= 20-0.01(1900)=1 p*=MC=1 (ii)- not necessarily . Optimal pricing means p=MC. Having surplus or deficit depends on the magnitude of fixed and variable cost ,and the level of prices. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 22 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. Joint costs; Given elements of costs automatically makes more possible more than one type of output. Electricity generator can provide electricity during peak hours and off-peak hours. A bus can make a trip from A to B, also provides a trip from B to A. How is the cost of increase in capacity to be allocated between the prices of two outputs, and how is the optimal allocation ( optimal capacity) should be determined? Take the Boss example; Bout(X) ; benefit from x number of tickets(passengers or seats) going from A to B. Bback(x); benefits from x number of tickets( passengers or seats) coming back from B to A B(X) = Bout(X) + Bback(X) ; total benefit from x number of tickets . W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 23 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. Max B(X) – C(X) → d[Bout(X) + B back (X) - C(x)]/dx =0 B’out(X*) + B’back(X*)=C’(x*) Σ MRSyx(X*) = MRT(X*) [B’(X) = MRSyx)] p ΣD The whole cost of marginal round trip would be born by the demander of the trip out , since it is solely on account of his demand that the round trip is being provided Dout MC B’out(X*)=p0ut Dback MC’ B’back(X*)= pback X(round trip) X* W & L CH 6 X*1 EFFICIENT PRICING 24 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. Q6-5 ; suppose that there are two types of electricity( peak and off-peak) and half of the day is peak, and half day is offpeak. To produce a unit of electricity per half a day requires a unit of turbine capacity costing 8 cents per day(interest charges on a permanent loan). The cost of a given capacity is the same whether it is used at peak times only or off-peak also. In addition to the cost of turbine capacity, it costs 6 cents in operating costs (labor and fuel) to produce one unit per half a day. Suppose the demand for electricity per half a day during peak hours is Pp= 22 – 10-5 x and during off-peak hours is pop=18 – 10-5 x , where x is units of electricity per half a day and p is price in cents. What is the efficient price for peak and off-peak electricity? What if the cost of a unit of capacity were only 3 cents per day. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 25 6-1 First – Best Pricing and Investment. Q6-5 (I) total demand price for capacity to produce x units per half a day is the demand price for a unit minus the operating cost per unit . 22 – 10-5x - 6 = price demand for one unit of capacity during peak 18 – 10-5x – 6 = price demand for one unit of capacity during off peak Σ MRS = (22 – 10-5x - 6 ) + (18 – 10-5x – 6 ) = 28 – (2)10-5x Σ MRS=MRT =8 → 28 – (2)10-5x=8 → x*=106 Ppeak= 22 – 10-5+6 = 12 = capacity cost(6)+ operating cost(6) Poff peak= 18 – 10-5+6 = 8 = capacity cost (2) + operating cost(6) (ii) If the marginal cost of capacity is 3 cents per day, the off-peak should not be charged for any increment to capacity. MRSpeak=22-10-5x –6 = MRT=3 → x*=(13)105 , ppeak*=22-(10-5)(13)(105)=9= capacity cost (3) + operating cost(6) Poffpeak*= 6 = capacity cost (0) + operating cost (6) . W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 26 $ Σ MRS p=22 – 10 -5x -6 P=18 – 10 -5x –6 28 Ppeak= 22 – 10-5+6 = 12 = capacity cost(6)+ operating cost(6) Poff peak= 18 – 10-5+6 = 8 = 16 capacity cost (2) + operating cost(6) 12 MC1 8 6 4 3 2 MC2 capacity 12 W & L CH 6 16 EFFICIENT PRICING 105x 27 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes Second – best ; the economy is full of distortions(monopolies, irrational subsidies, externalities). Policy usually has to be made on the assumption that one or more of these distortions is given. The optimum in these situation is called second-best solution. Suppose that road transportation is subsidized in such a way that price is less than marginal cost ; it is also politically infeasible to remove the subsidy. Then is it right to price at marginal cost on the railways? Or should they too charge less than marginal cost? An un – thinking person might imagine that it would still be right to equate price to marginal cost in the rest of the economy. But this is not so; First-best; Max u*=u(x0,…xn) – λT(x0,….xn) , then ui=λTi ( i= 0,1,2,…..n) T(x0,x1,…..xn)=0 MRSij=(ui/uj)=(Ti/Tj)= MRTij W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 28 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes Second-best; Suppose that , there is a distortion in the first market in such a way that u1 ≠λT1 , but u1= θT1 , θ≠λ , the optimum is Max u*=u(x0,…xn) – λT(x0,….xn) – μ(u1 - θT1) ui = λTi + μ(u1i - θT1i) (ui/uj)=[ λTi + μ(u1i - θT1i)]/[λTj + μ(u1j - θT1j)]≠MRTij Theory of second best. If one of the standard efficiency conditions Cannot be satisfied , the other efficiency conditions are no longer desirable. When Lipsey and Lancaster formulized the theory of second- best they tended to imply that there are a few a priori propositions that economics can offer to policy makers that are of any help in a world full of constraints. But, during the last 20 years it has been shown that in principle it is possible to compute a second-best optimum price structure for any number of constraints. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 29 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes Efficient commodity taxes; Prices must now be optimized , subject to government balancing its budget. Unless Lum-sum taxes are adequate,which generally are not, some arrangement is needed by which the consumer prices of some commodities exceed their marginal factor cost. Leisure Taxable : Equiproportional Taxes But which prices should exceed marginal cost?Should all prices be an equiproportional markup over marginal cost? Suppose all goods produced by labor(measured only in terms of labor consumed). The economy is endowed with T0 of time , which can be devoted to leisure x0 or to the production of the other n private goods. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 30 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes Resource constraint of the economy is; c0x0 + c1x1 + …..+cnxn + R0 = T0 , (1) ci=marginal cost of good i in terms of time (ci=1) Government budget constraint is ; (p0 – c0)x0 + ….+(pn – cn ) xn= R0 (2) Household budget constraint is ; p0x0 + ….. +pnxn = T0 (3) = (1) + (2) The problem is how to find a proportional tax rate [(pi/ci) – 1] which will lead to maximization of aggregate utility subject to resource and household budget constraint. Max u=u(x0 , x1 , ,x2, .. xn) S.T. C0x0 + …….+cnxn + R0 = T0 p0x0 + ….. +pnxn = T0 If all goods are taxable , the two above constrains could be reduced to one if we set (pi/ci) = [T0/(T0 – R0)] . W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 31 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes So , the maximization problem will be reduced to ; Max u=u(x0 , x1,x2, .. xn) S.T. C0 T0/(T0 – R0) x0 +….+cn T0/(T0–R0) xn = T0 Which is equal to ; Max u=u(x0 x1,x2, .. xn) S.T. c0x0 + c1x1 + …..+cnxn + R0 = T0 The result of this optimization is first best optimum ; that is →(Pi/Pj) =(Ui/Uj) =(ci/cj)=MRTij → equi-proportional taxes will lead to first-best optimum If all goods including leisure can be taxed , they should be taxed equi-proportionately. The solution is first-best optimum . W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 32 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes This is the line of reasoning behind the value added taxes. But the problem is that there is no way in which leisure can be taxed , because it can not be observed accurately by government . Even if hours at work could be recorded (so leisure can be estimated) , there are other dimensions of work (such as effort) which can not be recorded. This would not matter if we tax every one the same amount . But we want taxation to be related to individual ability to pay. Ideally , we should measure this by the individual’s original endowment rather than by anything over which he has control , such as earnings (his wage rate times his hours of work) if instead , we levy a proportional tax on earnings, this is equivalent to tax on goods levied at the same rate (assuming no saving) . It fails to tax leisure . W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 33 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes Leisure un-taxable and no cross– effect:The inverse elasticity rule ; The theory of second best tells us that if we can not tax leisure, we can do better than by taxing all other goods equiproportionately Intuitively one would suppose that if leisure can not be taxed , the next best thing is to concentrate taxes more heavily on goods that are complementary to leisure (sport gears, entertainments) When we have to delete leisure from the set of variables, in order to find the optimum we can not maximize the utility function (which contains leisure as a variable), so ; Max B(X) – C(X) C(x) = Σj=1n cjxj S.T. Σj=1n (pj – cj)xj = R0 W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 34 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes Max B* = B(x1, x2 , …xn) - Σj cjxj + Φ[Σnj=1 (pj – cj)xj - R0] No cross effect, so, (∂xj/∂ pi)=0 , for all i≠j (∂B/∂xi) (∂xi/ ∂pi) - ci (∂xi/ ∂pi) + Φ[(pi – ci)(∂xi/ ∂pi) +xi ]=0 ,(∂B/∂xi) =pi (pi – ci)(∂xi/ ∂pi)= - Φ [(pi – ci)(∂xi/ ∂pi) +xi ] (pi – ci)(∂xi/ ∂pi)= ∂[B(X) - C(X)]/∂pi= - Se [(pi – ci)(∂xi/ ∂pi) +xi ]=∂R/∂pi = Sf – Se {∂[B(X) - C(X)]/∂pi}/(∂R/∂pi) = - Φ for all I (pi – ci)/pi = -[(Φ)/(1+ Φ)](xi/pi)[1/(∂xi/ ∂pi)]=[(Φ)/(1+ Φ)](1/|Єii|) Tax rate should inversely proportional to the elasticity of demand. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 35 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes Inverse elasticity rule; If leisure is un-taxable and there are no cross effects in consumption , the proportional tax rate on a good should be inversely proportional to its elasticity of demand. X0 per xi Sf negligibl Se Pi+1 (p – c )(dx / dp )= d[B(X) – C(X)] /dp - Se pi i i i i i [(p – c )(dx / dp ) +x ]=dR/dp = Sf – Se i i i i i i ci -(dxi/dpi) xi W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 36 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes The inverse elasticity rule insures that the consumption of all good decrease by the same proportion. Δxi=(∂xi/ ∂pi) Δpi=(∂xi/ ∂pi)(pi – ci)=(∂xi/∂pi)[-Φ/(1+Φ)]xi(∂pi/∂xi)] Δxi =[-Φ/(1+Φ)]xi (Δxi/xi)= [-Φ/(1+Φ]= constant for all I When leisure can not be taxed , we should tax leisure’s complements more highly in comparing to other commodities. The inverse elasticity rule insure this. If xi is inelastic, when pi increases then (pixi) will increase too. , (∂xj/∂pi)=0 , so xj will not change and remains constant. So ( m – pixi) will decrease and less will remain to be spend on other goods such as leisure. So it is just like xi is a complement for leisure. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 37 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes. Leisure un-taxable : Tax complements to Leisure: If we allow cross effects, the change in social surpluses when pi changes includes the effect of changes in pi on the social surplus in respect of other goods. ∂(B – C)/∂pi = (pi – ci) ∂xi/ ∂pi + Σ (pj – cj) ∂xj/ ∂pi (∂R/ ∂Pi)= [(pi – ci)(∂xi/ ∂pi) +xi ]j≠i + Σi≠j (pj – cj) ∂xj/ ∂pi [∂(B – C)/∂pi]= - Φ (∂R/ ∂Pi) j≠i Solving the above equation for [(pi – ci)/pi], we get; (pi – ci)/pi =[ -(Φ)/ (1+ Φ)] (xi/pi) [1/(∂xi/ ∂pi)] -Σ[ (pj – cj)/pi][(∂xj/∂pi)/ (∂xi/∂pi)] j≠i It can be shown that , If good i has a higher elasticity of substitution with leisure x0 than has good j(σi0>σjo), it should have a lower tax rate , and vice versa. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 38 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes Suppose that in the single factor case there were rising marginal costs, so that ci is no longer constant but rises with xi. It can be shown that [(pi – ci)/pi]=Ψ[(1/|Єii |)+(1/ηiis)] , ηiis = is he elasticity of supply Suppose that some agency of the government rather than the government itself wants to operate in such away that , the net social benefit is maximized and also, agency get a profit equal to Π0= p1x1+p2x2+…..pnxn – C(x1,x2, ….xn) . MaxB*= B(x1,x2,…xn) - C(x1,x2,…xn) + θ [Σj (pjxj) - C(x1,x2,…xn) - Π0] ∂B*/∂pi=(∂B/∂xi)(∂xi/∂pi)-(∂C/∂xi)(∂xi/∂pi)+θ[xi+pi (∂xi/∂pi)-ci(∂xi/∂pi)]=0 (∂B/∂xi )=pi (∂C/∂xi)=Ci ∂B*/∂pi= Pi (∂xi/∂pi) -Ci (∂xi/∂pi)+ θ [xi+ (∂xi/∂pi)(Pi – Ci )]=0 (pi – ci)(∂xi/ ∂pi)= - θ [(pi – ci)(∂xi/ ∂pi) +xi ] As it can be seen even if we do not have constant marginal costs, this has the solution like before. Does this section really answer the problem of optimal tax? Unfortunately not . For it altogether ignores the question of equity. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 39 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes Q6-6 Suppose that a nationalized coal industry sells coal to two markets (domestic and commercial). The demand curve are as follows ; domestic = x1= 1 – (1/2)p1 commercial = x2= 1 – p2 The marginal cost of coal is constant at 1/3 and the agency has a fixed cost of 11/32. 1- Check that the price structure , p1=3/4, and p2=1/2, is optimal if costs must be covered. 2- What would the industry charge if it were a profit-maximizing monopoly. 3- What is the ratio of marginal social loss to marginal profit for each price in (i) and (ii) . W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 40 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes Q6-6 solution; 1-Optimality requires that [(p1-c1)/p1]/[(p2-c2)/p2]=| ε22|/| ε11| ε11=(dx1/dp1)(p1/x1)=(-1/2){(3/4)[1/(1-(1/2)(3/4))]}=-3/5 ε22=(dx2/dp2)(p2/x2)=(-1)[(1/2)/(1/2)]=-1 [(p1-c1)/p1]/[(p2-c2)/p2]=[(3/4–1/3)/(3/4)]/[(1/2-1/3)/(1/2)]=5/3= | ε22|/|ε11 | To balance the budget we need ; (p1 – c1)x1 + (p2 – c2)x2 = fixed cost (p1 – c1)x1 + (p2 – c2)x2= (3/4 – 1/3)[1 – (1/2)(3/4)]+(1/2 – 1/3)(1/2)= (5/12)(5/8) + (1/6)(1/2)=11/32=fixed cost. 2- Max Π= p1x1+p2x2 – (c1x1+c2x2+11/32) ∂Π/∂p1 = x1 +p1(∂x1/∂p1) – c1(∂x1/∂p1)=[1-(1/2)p1]+(-1/2)(p1-c1)=0 p1=1 +(1/2)(1/3) = 7/6 ∂Π/∂p2 = x2 +p2(∂x2/∂p2) – c2(∂x2/∂p2)=(1-p2)-(p1-c1)=0, p2=2/3 Note that the price of less elastic good is higher than of more elastic good. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 41 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes (iii)In (i) ∂(B – C)/∂p1 = (p1 – c1)(dx1/dp1)=(3/4 – 1/3)(1/2)=-5/24 (∂Π/∂p1)=x1+(p1 – c1) (∂x1/∂p1)=5/8 – 5/24 = 10/24. - [∂(B – C)/∂p1]/(∂Π/∂p1)=(1/2). we could check that - [∂(B – C)/∂p2]/(∂Π/∂p2)=(1/2). In (ii) (∂Π/∂p1)= (∂Π/∂p2)=0 - [∂(B – C)/∂pi]/(∂Π/∂pi)=∞ Q6-7 (i) What are the arguments in the indirect utility function for a consumer facing the household budget constraint x0 + p1x1 +…..pnxn = T0 , and having the direct utility function u(x0, x1, …xn)? W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 42 6-2 second-best problem and efficient commodity taxes (ii) Maximize the indirect utility function subject to (p1-c1)x1 + ……( pn – cn)xn =R0 , confirm that you obtain inverse elasticity rule if (∂xj/∂pi)=0 all i≠j Solution Q6-7 ; (I) U(p1,p2,….,T0) , since p0 is fixed at one . (ii) Max U(p1,p2,….,T0)+μ[Σ(pj-cj)xj – R0] , (∂u/∂pi) + μ [(pi –ci ) ∂xi /∂pi+xi]=0 all i by Roy’s identity xi =-[(∂u/∂pi)/ (∂u/∂T)]=-(∂u/∂pi)(1/λ) λxi =-(∂u/∂pi) , λ= (∂ud/∂T) , {ud(x0,x1,,,,xn)+ λ[Σ ni=1 pixi - T0]} thus ; μ(pi – ci)[∂xi/∂pi]= λxi – μxi Hence ,(pi – ci)/pi = [(λ - μ)/μ][(xi/pi)/(∂xi/∂pi)] W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 43 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods Externality is the main source of market failure. Decision of one agent affect the consumption or production opportunities open to another directly, rater than through the prices which he faces. The price system is efficient in allocating resources when prices measure marginal opportunity cost. Social cost , or social benefit of an action might deviate considerably from the private cost or benefit. But the problem arises when cost of negotiation between parties is high enough. If the output of a good affect n individuals, then its output level is efficient if the amount which the individuals affected are willing to sacrifice for an extra unit equals the amount that has to sacrificed; Σi=1n MRSiyx = MRTyx . In other words the sum of marginal net benefits mest be equal to zero. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 44 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods The price mechanism can often bring about the desirable state of affairs . For example; If x is the number of sheep and MRS1(x) ; the value of xth sheep’s wool MRS2(x) ; the value of xth sheep’s mutton , the price mechanism ensures that ; MRS1yx(x) + MRS2yx(x) = MRTyx(x) The problem of externality arises when there is not only jointness but a lack of institutions which ensures that individuals pay for the cost of their actions and are paid for the benefits resulting from their actions. For example consider the factory that makes more smoke the more x it produces. This smoke pollutes the environment and increases the laundry cost of the community. Bf = net benefits of factory owner = Bf(x) > 0 BR= net benefits according to the rest of the community = BR(x) <0 W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 45 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods If x* is the optimum output , the efficient output is when; Bf(x) + BR(x) = B(x) is maximized. That is ; Bf’(x*) + BR’(x*) = 0 , or, Bf’(x*)=- BR’(x*) Bf’>0 , Y per x Bf’2 Bf’ , Bf’(x*)=-BR’(x*) -BR’ Bf’1 x2 W & L CH 6 BR’<0 . x* EFFICIENT PRICING -BR’(x*)=tax x x1 46 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods What should be done to secure x* ; 1-If there is no restriction for the level of the output of factory owner( the right is given to the factory owner), how much the factory owner will produce? The simple answer is x1 , where marginal net-benefit is zero. In this situation the straightforward answer for reaching x* is to tax the factory owner an amount equal to [-BR’(x*)] . In this situation ,the [-BR’] curve will shift to the left by a vertical distance equal to [-BR’(x*)] and the net marginal benefit for the factory owner is where x=x* , Is this the optimum policy ? We will see that it is not in the following cases; A- If the houses were owned by the factory owner , there would be no question of the free market producing a misallocation of resources. The total benefit of the factory owner who is also the owner of the houses is to produce x* not more or less. No tax is needed. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 47 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods B – if the houses were not owned by the factory owner , but the owner of the houses owned by a single landlord.(the transaction cost is negligible) . We could imagine two cases in this situation; B-1 first; the right is given to factory owner to produce as much as he wants. How much he produce? Is it right to think that he produces x1, and there would be too much pollution? We will shortly see that the production will stop at x* . For any level of production between x* and and x1 , say x3 , benefit of factory owner from the production of x3 is less than the disbenefit of its production for the landlord Bf’(x3)<- BR’(x3). So the landlord could convince the factory owner not to produce x3 if he offers him any amount greater than the factory owner’s benefit (ab),and less than his loss from the production of x3(ac). He will benefit from this deal , because he will save an amount equal to the difference between his loss from the production of x3(ac) and his payment to factory owner (ab<payment<ac). The production will be set at x* which is optimum. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 48 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods Y per x Bf’2 Bf’ , Bf’(x*)=-BR’(x*) -BR’ c c’ Bf’1 E b’ E’ x2 W & L CH 6 x0 - BR’(x*) b a’ x4 x* EFFICIENT PRICING x3 a x1 x 49 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods B-2 the right is given to the landlord , and factory owner should get the permission of the landlord for production. Is it right to think that he will not let the production to increase more than x2 . We will see that it is not true. The production will increase to x* as a result of free negotiation. For any level of production between x2 and x* , (for example x4) , the disbenefit of production for landlord (a’b’) is smaller than the benefit of production for the factory owner(a’c’). So , the factory owner is willing to pay any amount greater than a’b’ and less than a’c’ in order to get the permission to produce the x4 th unit , and the landlord is also willing to give the permission. With the same manner , the factory owner will get the permission to produce any unit between x2 and x* and the production will stop at x*. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 50 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods Coase theorm ; If costless negotiation is possible, rights are well specified, and redistribution does not affect marginal values, 1- the allocation of resources will be identical , whatever the allocation of legal rights. 2- The allocation will be efficient . So there is no problem of externality. 3- if a tax is imposed in such a situation , efficiency will be lost.(the new equilibrium point is E’ rater than E and the output will be set at x0 rather than x*) Suppose there are transaction cost; These transaction cost involve the use of real resources. Which may prevent the arrangement of the bargain . State intervention in this cases is justified if the transaction cost of state activity are lower than the private transaction costs by an amount at least as great as the benefit of transaction. Suppose there are many landlords and many factory owners. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 51 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods There are large number of house owners. Each can not negotiate for his own supply of clean air(since , clean air is public good) . The contractual arrangements must be concluded trough some sort of collective action of house owners. Each individual household may be asked to contribute to the payment to the factory owner to ensure that the soot level is reduced. But , each household will have an incentive to be a free rider . Under the widespread ownership , the free rider problem will tend to ensure that there is too much smoke. The owners may find it advantageous to sell the houses to a single household(In order to decrease the transaction cost). The new landlord may be the factory owner itself. The individual household realizes that , if he waits his time , the single landlord will be willing to offer more than the existing market price and in fact anything up to the capitalized value of the higher , soot-reduced rent. But if many household hold out for prices this high, it will not be worth the single landlord’s going ahead with this plan. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 52 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods However ,regulation or state intervention may be thought as a solution. But we should include the intervention and administration costs into account. Another problem is the possibility of threat and counter-threat, bluff and double bluff, which might well affect the outcome not in terms of distribution of wealth , but also in the allocation of resources , and these will change the optimum level of output. For example , the factory owner may deliberately make smoke and soot, not as a byproduct of his production process, but in order to extract an even larger payment from the un-fortunate landlord, provided that he is not liable for the smoke. This action will shift the BR’ curve to the right to BR” and the resource allocation and optimum level of output will change. These arguments suggest that the nature of the liability law is certainly not a matter of indifference with respect to the allocation of resources. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 53 6-3 Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods Nevertheless , Coase theorem , states that with , no transaction costs and no legal restriction on contracts, any misallocation of resources would be put right by bargains in the market, is as an important one. One of the interesting and much discussed cases of externalities was the Fable of the Bees. Chaung carried out a proper empirical study of the problem. He discovered that ,instead, contractual payments were characteristic bee keeping and fruit farming. Cheung has provided a dramatic and evocative example of the application of the Coase theorem. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 54 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods Congestion Externalities Congestion externalities arises from the fact that the government does not charge for scare services of some facilities (roads, beaches, museums. Etc)that it provides. The individual will decide on the basis of his own costs whether or not to take a trip, but his own costs do not include the additional congestion cost he imposes on others. For example take the case of road congestion. Suppose that the only cost is time. The average cost per journeys rises with the number of journeys. When an individual makes an extra journey , he rises the average cost which everyone pays. This external dis-benefit is the marginal cost to society as a whole minus the average cost (which the traveler pays himself anyway). W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 55 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods X number of passing Acp Travel time for every one 1 5 2 6 3 7 4 (x*) 8 5 9 6 (x1) 10 7 11 8 12 W & L CH 6 TC total time of the travel for the society 5 12 21 32 45 60 77 96 MCs marginal cost of each extra travel to the MCs- Acp P marginal external disbenefit time willing to be spent by society for an extra journey(demand price society in terms of time) 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 12.5 12 11.5 11 10.5 10 9.5 9 EFFICIENT PRICING 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 56 MCs Y per x AC’p=Acp+3 ACp 12.5 11 Tax=3 10 7 p 5 1 W & L CH 6 2 4=x* X1=6 EFFICIENT PRICING x 57 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods The same problem may arise with any resource that is freely available, like Fishing, hunting , and parking the car. Public goods Additional consumption of one person does not imply reduced consumption by another, and once it is produced no one could be excluded from the use of it. Type 1 ;Individual can vary his use of the facility , like television or uncongested parks and museums . Type 2 ; individual cannot vary his use ,like national defense, clean air, public health. The optimum level of public good(x); ΣMRS(x)=MRT(x) In type 1 , we need to charge the optimum price to secure the optimum utilization. For pure public goods this price will be zero. In type 2 , the optimum price is zero, since the marginal cost of extra unit is zero. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 58 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods For both type of public goods there would be no harm in charging MRSi(x) to each of the individual i , if we could only get him to reveal his preferences. This is very hard since, non-revelation principle is the first basic problem in these situations. In type 2 it is not possible to make access to benefits conditional on payments. In type 1 the direct cost of exclusion might be very high, so as the government might not worth doing it. So we are left with the state paying for the public goods. To do this efficiently it has to make guesses about individual preferences. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 59 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods Q6-9 (I) suppose that there is a road from A to B. The demand from A to B depends only on time taken , according to the function; p=20 – 0.001x , where x is trips per day and p is the time per trip in hours. The more trips are made in total , the slower they are ,because one person’s extra journey slows down the other derivers. The relation of time taken to trips made is given by p=2+0.001x . There are no other costs of travel , and the value of time is $1 per hour for all trips (a) What is the optimal number of trips ? (b) What money tax should be levied on derivers for a trip in order to ensure optimal utilization? (c) The following system of road pricing has been proposed for London: any car traveling in inner London on any particular day must have a license to do so costing $1 . Would such a system be efficient? Discuss the advantages and disadvantages. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 60 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods Q6-9 solution (i)Optimality requires that we maximize B(x) – C(x) . Both measured in hours. P=20 – 0.001x B(x) = 20x – 0.0005x2 C(x) =(Acx)(x)=(2+0.001x)x=2x+0.001x2 d(B – C)/dx = 20 – 0.001x –2 –0.002x = 0 , x*=6000 P*=20 – 6 = 14 p*=MCs , ACp=2+6=8 Tax=14-8=6 (ii) The system is not efficient since a fixed cost is charged.Those who travel more should pay higher prices. The advantages of this system is that at least some price has been charged. The disadvantages of it is that it is fixed. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 61 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods Q6-10 two prisoners are locked in different cells , each accused of same offence. Each is told that the following sentences await him: “A If the other prisoner confesses , you will get 20 years if you confess and 30 years if you deny guilt.” “B If the other prisoner denies guilt, you will get nothing if you confess and 2 years if you deny guilt .” (I)What prisoner do , assuming they do not trust each other? (II)If a private voice tube linked their two cells, what would they agree on? (III)If there were no tube but the prisoners trusted each other , what might they do? (IV)What conclusion do you draw from the parable of prisoner’s dilemma about the problem of achieving social efficiency in one country , and of achieving international peace? W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 62 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods For each prisoner we have the following pay-off matrix self self Confess deny W & L CH 6 other confess 20 30 other deny 2 0 EFFICIENT PRICING 63 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods (i) If the individual decides on basis of what is best for himself. Taking the other’s action action as given, he will confess. The result is that both prisoners get 20 years. (ii) if the individual can agree at all , they will agree to a plan which has the same effect on each of them. They will prefer both getting 2 years to both getting 20 years. So both will deny guilt. But note that each could do best for himself by confessing while the other denied guilt(behaving as a free rider problem ). (iii) If they trusted each other , they might work out that situation (ii) was better for both of them than solution (i) and therefore deny guilt on the assumption that the other would do the same. (iv) The reasoning in (iii) may be quite widespread within society. So people may in fact follow rules of self-restraint even though it is not in their self-interest as a free rider . In international relations the same may apply, though there is perhaps less evidence of this. The lower the costs of negotiation, the better , according to this theory. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 64 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods Q6-11, consider the following map firms A B C D E river 1 2 sea 3 4 5 households (a) Each household likes swimming in clean water and is willing to pay $1 for every gallon of detergent less that there is in the water. (b) Each firm could avoid producing detergent if it put its effluent through a filter costing $25 per period. (c) Each household could install its own swimming pool at a cost of $40 per period. (d) Each firm exudes 12 gallons of detergent (x) per period, which follows the downstream. (i) What private arrangement , if any , do you expect to emerge if the firms are not liable? (ii) What if anything , do you think the state should do ? What more information , if any , is relevant? W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 65 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods BY TO W & L CH 6 A B C D E Total 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 2 12 0 0 0 0 12 3 12 12 0 0 0 24 4 12 12 12 0 0 36 5 12 12 12 12 0 48 Total 48 36 24 12 0 120 EFFICIENT PRICING 66 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods (i) (ii) It would therefore be worthwhile for household 2, ,3 , 4, 5 to pay $25 to A to get rid of him. Each will pay $6.25(25/4) dollars to avoid $12 loss It would therefore be worthwhile for household 3, 4, 5 to pay $25 to B to get rid of B.Each will pay 25/3 or $ 8.33 to get rid off $12 loss. So each of the 3 ,4, 5, will pay $14.58 to get rid of A and B Household 2 will pay $6.25 to get rid of A. The matrix payoff will reduce to the red one . No more arrangement is possible anymore. It is not worthwhile for 5 to build a private swimming pool right at hand, because in that case he would save $8(48-40) , while in the private mentioned arrangements he would save $11.42 48 - (6.25+8.33+12+12) ). W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 67 6-3Externality, Transaction costs, and Public goods (ii) The state , if it had available information (a) could force the two firms to install filters (b) Tax the firms equal to their damage, which may derive out them out of business(depending on their cost structure). (c) Force the household to pay for the cost of filters, which is not common. the sate could be influenced by the relative wealth of the different groups and implement income distribution polices. Whether an outcome is efficient or not depends on the distribution of the rights. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 68 6-4 Welfare effects of non-price allocation and price control In many economies the free bargaining of the price system has been abrogated in the allocation of some resources and commodities. For example imported goods of many kind in some countries, and rented accommodation in England. The free bargaining of price system must be somehow banned by law , the authorities then must be decided to determine how the goods are to be allocated. There could be infinite number of allocation criteria. Three will be examined ; 1- Queuing 2- Administrative rationing 3- price control W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 69 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control Queueing Goods are distributed in limited , well specified bundles. The consumer has the opportunity of spending a certain time in the queue in order to acquire the right to buy a specific quantity of goods or services ( for example x0) only once. Suppose that the demand curve for commodity x for a typical consumer is given by the following curve; px Dx A aa b W & L CH 6 Demand for a typical consumer x0 EFFICIENT PRICING x1 qx 70 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control Also suppose that the ration batch which the consumer could get is x0 units of x . The typical consumer is willing to pay area (a+b) in an all or nothing situation. (he can either stay in queue and get x0 or do not stand in line not getting anything). Suppose that the value of his time for one hour is $v0, and the area (a+b) worth $W0 . Therefore, the maximum number of hours which he is willing to stand in queue iv T0=W0/v0 Finding different hours for different individuals , we will get the aggregate demand curve for x in terms of time(as shown in the following figure). As it is shown we could get an standard downward sloping demand curve with batches of x (x=x0) in the horizontal axis. Every one gets only one batch , so there will be one person who would like to stand in queue more than any one else and there is one who would like to stand in queue less than any one else. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 71 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control As it shown in the figure when number of batches is equal to the number of population (each person could get only one batch) , the minimum length of time which any one in the population is willing to stay in queue is T1 hours.. the higher is the length of time which the people has to stand in line the smaller is the number of individuals who is willing to stand in line. Note that each individual could receive only one batch , and number of batches is equal to number of individuals who get the rationing batches. Queuing time per batch T1 N W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING batches 72 6-4 Welfare effects of non price allocation and price control Now suppose that in Figure a there are S0 of batches available for distribution. So the number of individuals who could get the batches is equal to S0 . Only those who are willing to stand less than Ts number of hours in the queue can not get the ration. Queuing time per batch Dx Queuing time per batch Figure a Dx Figure b T* Ts T1 batches S0 W & L CH 6 N EFFICIENT PRICING batches S0 N 73 6-4 Welfare effects of non-price allocation and price control We can compare the welfare effects of queuing and price rationing directly with market mechanism in the case when all individuals are willing to spend the same time to gain access to batches.(figure b) In this kind of rationing all consumer surpluses have been dissipated. Since the individual is able to queue and get x0 or he does not queue and get nothing. In resource time , of course , real resources have been used in the process of allocation, which is not the case in costless exchange in which money passes between the people. Given identical demands, all surplus is dissipated by any form of non price allocation in which the individual can take action to qualify himself for the ration and the cost of such action is the same for all individuals. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 74 6-4 Welfare effects of non-price allocation and price control If to qualify one’s children for certain type of school , one has to live in a particular area, some of the surplus which such schooling might provide is dissipated by choice of otherwise less preferred locations for residence. If instead , the individual could rejoin the queue as many time as he wanted, it would follow that , even if individuals are identical, surpluses would accrue if the number of batches exceeded the number of people. For though the individual gets no surplus in the marginal batch , he would get some on his intramarginal ones. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 75 6-4 Welfare effects of non-price allocation and price control Q6-12 (i) “A household that would not be willing to buy as much as x0 on a normal market at any positive price would not be willing to queue for x0 at a zero money price.” True or false? (ii) Suppose that in a queuing situation the size of the batch was reduced . Would this reduce the loss of surplus?(assume identical demand curve and identical time values for all individuals). (iii) It is often argued that with single batch queuing system the poor are more likely to get the good than the rich. Show that , if the income elasticity of demand is higher than the price elasticity of all or nothing demand curve , this will not be so. Assume that a person’s value of time is proportional to his income.(try using an individual all or nothing demand curve as x=ap-bmc. (iv) if batches are small and rejoining is possible, compare the consumption of the poor in the following cases; (a) When a given supply is rationed by queue (b) When the same supply is sold at a market-clearing price. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 76 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control Q6-12 solution False ; P0=0 T0=SA/vA >0 vA=value of one hour for individual. px A x0 x (ii) No, only if it led some individuals to obtain more batches than before. (iii) x=ap-bmc. x P=(1/x)∫ p(x)d(x)= all or nothing demand curve. 0 P=TV , V=km , P= money willing to pay for one x in an all or nothing situation , T= time willing to queue for getting batch of one X W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 77 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control x=ap-bmc x= a(kTm)-bmc = a(kT)-bmc-b if c>b , increase in m should be accompanied by increase in T in order to make x equal to the fixed amount of the ration. Higher income will spend more in line. (iv) The poor will consume a higher fraction of any given supply under queuing , because the effective income elasticity across person has been reduced from c to c-b . W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 78 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control Administrative rationing(cupon rationing); The allotment may be equal for all individuals or it may differ according to some administrative assessments of need (gasoline) Px Px D=DB+DA DA h a b c Z W & L CH 6 S0 DB g p0 Px f x0A xA x0B d e Z bbb EFFICIENT PRICING xB X0=xA+xB 79 6-4 Welfare effects of non-price allocation and price control Under the market system p=p0, and under the rationing p=0 (people could buy goods only by coupons without paying money or every one can pay the money piece , so price is actually equal to zeros) Under the market system( price system) A is consuming more than B. So the rationing would be in such a way to let B to consume more . So A is allocated a ration equal to x0A – Z , and B is allocated a ration equal to x0B + z . At first case assume that , there is no market for coupons ; Change in consumer surplus situation Consumer A market a+g rationing change b+g (b+g)-(a+g)= (b-a) W & L CH 6 Consumer B h h + f +e (h+f+e)-h= (f+e) Supplier of x Total [(x oB+Z)+(xo A - Z)]p0= (d+f+e+b) 0 -(d+e+f+b) EFFICIENT PRICING -(a + d) 80 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control Now suppose that there is a market for coupons ; Pcoupons =demand price for x(=p0)–money price of x (=0)= p0 In this situation coupons worth as much as the price of x. so, market system is effective again. Consumer A is willing to consume more x by an amount equal to Z. and consumer B is willing to consume less of x by an amount equal to Z. So A would buy Z amount of x from B and pays him ZP0=C. B would also willing to sell Z amount of x to A and receive an amount equal to ZP0=(d+e). So A’s consumption of x would be x0A again and B’s consumption of x would be x0B again. There is a transfer of money from A to B . W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 81 6-4 Welfare effects of non-price allocation and price control consumer surplus situation market Consumer A Consumer B a+g h rationing ( a +c+ b + g) (h + f ) + Zp0(d+e) – Zpo(c) = = (h + f + d + e ) ( a +b+g) Change in welfare (a+b+g) (a+g)=b (h+f+d+e) – h = (f+d+e) Supplier of x Total [(x0+Z)+(x0-Z)]p0= (d+f+e+b) 0 0 - (d+e+f+b) 0 As`it can be seen , welfare total change in welfare is equal to zero. It means that the only effect of rationing is the transfer of money from A to B . Both are consuming as before rationing and market system is effective. (in this example we have not included the resource cost relating to dealers in the market for coupons , otherwise we would expect loss in welfare) W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 82 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control Price control What price control means is to put a ceiling on price level so that no one should sell more than that .First we assume that supply is fixed. In this case there is only efficiency loss in demand side , As it is seen , price is controlled at P1 . There is excess demand for x In such a way that for x0 amount of x there is x1 demand . We do not know how x0 will be Distributed among x1 number of people. It depends to the decision of sellers of x . This is not efficient. Because some people with lower MRS might get the good, and some with Higher MRS might not. In this situation consumer surplus is reduced to an area less than (a+b). S Px P0 P1 ab dead weight loss ba D x0 W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING x1 x 83 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control Suppose that supply is variable. In this situation there would be two sources of inefficiency. Because not only supply is reduced because of price control but also the available supply will be allocated inefficiently between customers. So both the consumer and producer surplus will reduce. P1 ; controlled price x1x2 = excess demand . producer surplus is reduced Px S to area c. Consumer surplus is less D than area b. reduction in total welfare Is equal dead weight loss to area d for sure. b P0 P1 W & L CH 6 d c EFFICIENT PRICING x2 x0 x1 84 x 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control In every case the group in whose favor a price is controlled are likely to gain from this(when group is taken as a whole). But the gain will often be uneven , and some members of the group may loose . Like tenants who can not find homes, or workers who can not find jobs. Taxes and subsidies do not raise the problem of arbitrary allocation that we have just mentioned. Of course matter would be different if beneficiaries could negotiate between themselves. In large societies there are many fruitful negotiations that simply do not occur because of their high negotiation cost. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 85 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control Q6-13 , What assumption has been made about income effects in the analysis in figure 6-10. It has been assumed that the income effect is zero,otherwise, the demand curves will shift and comparison of different areas is not straightforward . Q6-14 , Suppose that the quantity of oil reaching a non-oilproducing country is reduced , but the import price remains constant. Compare the efficiency and the distributional effects of (i) i - Rationing with sale of coupons illegal, and the maximum retail price controlled at its previous level. (ii) ii - Rationing with sale of coupons legal and the maximum retail price controlled at its previous level. (iii) iii - No rationing , no price control but an increased tax on oil high enough to keep the net price at which importers sell constant. (iv) iv - No rationing , no price control, no tax increase. (v) What would you do if you were the government. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 86 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control P S’ S Q6-14 solution (i) Inefficient,market system does not work . Everyone whose allotment p’ is less than his previous quantity of x a a b 0 p purchased looses.tax payers are D unaffected x (ii) Efficient. Market system works q’ q0 Everyone whose allocation is less than his previous quantity of x purchased loses. Others gain.Taxpayers are unaffected. (iii) Efficient., market system works. Every one using x looses . Reduction in consumer surplus is equal to a+b . Taxpayers gain a. (iv) Efficient. Every one using x looses. Importers gain a . It is better for the government to choose (iii) W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 87 6-4 Welfare effects of non price allocation and price control Q6-15 we have not so far considered the case where all goods are rationed . Suppose there are two goods in given supply and two groups of people with different tastes. A market mechanism is replaced by one where an equal amount of each good is allocated free to each person. Are the following statements true or false? (i) If both groups had the same money income under the price mechanism , both become worse off. (ii) Even if both had different incomes, both become worse off. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 88 6-4 Welfare effects of non price allocation and price control Before rationing Q6-15 solution X UA UB XA Budget constraint YB oB E After rationing F U’A XB U’B oA YA Y (i)True. Both become worse off. W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 89 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control Before rationing Q6-15 solution X Budget constraint oB YB E XA F U’B oA U’A UB UA XB After rationing YA Y (i) False., A becomes worse off and B becomes better off W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 90 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control Q6-16 , Now suppose we have a freer system , in which each consumer is given an equal number of ration points , P0 . To acquire any good an individual must handover a number of points specified by the government. The goods also have a money price, and the consumer has to satisfy his money budget constraint , as well as his ration constraint/. Are the following true? (i) If both groups have the same income, each will necessarily be better off if points can be bought and sold than if they can not . (ii) If both groups have different income, each will necessarily be better off if points can be bought and sold than if they can not . W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 91 6-4 Welfare effects of non-price allocation and price control Q6-16 solution: Budget constraint; m=xpx +ypy Ration constraint ; R=xp’x+yp’y M = money income, ( px,py ) = money prices R = ration points (p’x, p’y)= ration prices When there is no market for ration points There could be three cases; First , the individual is very rich , and the binding constraint is money constraint, and ration y point constraint is not binding. M = $ 6000 , Px = $200 , Py = $400 Budget constraint R = R 10 , P’x =R 5 , P’y = R 5 X=10 , Y=10 If he will use all his ration points he could only buy one x and one y and he should buy the rest of his needs by money income . So the ration points Ration constraint are not binding and he can choose points above ration constraint 92 x 6-4 Welfare effects of non-price allocation and price control second , the individual is very poor, and the binding constraint Is the Ration point constraint, and money constraint is not binding. M = $ 10, Px = $5 , Py = $5 R = R 60 , P’x =R 2 , P’y = R 4 X=10 , Y=10 If he will use all his money income he could only buy one x and one y and he should buy the rest of his needs by ration points. So money income is not binding. He can choose points above budget constraint . W & L CH 6 y EFFICIENT PRICING Budget constraint Ration constraint x 93 6-4 Welfare effects of non-price allocation and price control Third , the individual is neither very Poor or very rich. Both constraints are binding. y M = $ 1000, P = $200 , P = $400 x y R = R 60 , P’ =R 10 , P’ = R 30 x y X=3 , Y= 1 If he will use all his money income he could buy one 3x and one y . If he will use all his Ration points he could also buy 3x and one y . So both money income and Point rationing is binding. If x=6 and y=2 (a point like T )he should spend all his money income and ration points for buying a basket of 6x and 2y. R R=xp’x+yp’y m T By choosing a point like T he is able to buy all his needs by spending all his money income and all his ration points . R’ W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING m’ x m=xpx+ypy 94 6-4 Welfare effects of non-price allocation and price control Now if points can be bought and sold , then two constraints shrinks to a single one . Because ration points worth money and it has the same effect as money income. If z= coupon price then y m+zR=(p +zp’ )x+(p +zp’ )y x a x y y If m/Px > R/P’X then , it can be easily shown that m/PX >(m+Rz)/(PX+zP’X)>R/P’X R=xp’x+yp’y The combined constraint line should pass through point T and it lies between the two previous constraint. As it is seen the feasible area has increased , which means improvement in the welfare level.(both groups have the same income, they can not interfere the market b T m=xpx+ypy a’ b’ x situation for each group when their income are equal EFFICIENT PRICING 95 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control (ii) False. The preceding analysis assumed that the money prices px and py are fixed, since with no income differences there is no reason why money prices should change when points become salable. But if there are income differences, the pattern of demand will be drastically altered if the rich can use money to release their point constraint. If money prices increase , the poor who are bounded by their money constraint may be worse off y R As is seen the money constraint has shifted left. m R’ m’ W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING x 96 6-4 Welfare effects of nonprice allocation and price control Q6-17 Suppose the demand for x(housing) is p=1 – x . The price is controlled below its equilibrium level. Assume that the available supply is rationed out randomly among those who demand it at the going price . Now price control is abolished. Show that; (i ) the consumer as a whole lose. (ii) there is a potential Pareto improvement Solution ; next page W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 97 6-4 Welfare effects of non-price allocation and price control Before abolishing the price control p Consumer surplus was greater Than area b and less than area (a+b). After abolishing , consumer surplus reduces to area b. So it will diminish. (ii) Consumer surplus reduce By less than area a , and b Producer surplus increases by p1 Area a . There is a potential pareto improvement a S0 Free market price level Controlled price level p0 P=1-x The end x x0 W & L CH 6 EFFICIENT PRICING 98