Fiscal Alchemy? An International Perspective Jeffrey Frankel Seminar on Macroeconomic Policy Harvard Economics Department April 28, 2015 “Fiscal alchemy”? • Eric Leeper had it backwards: – "Monetary science, fiscal alchemy" (Jackson Hole, 2010). • It should be Monetary alchemy, fiscal science: • Under post-2008 conditions, we could have been more confident that countercyclical fiscal policy would have speeded the recovery than countercyclical monetary policy. Fiscal multipliers are relatively high under post2008 conditions: low output, low inflation, & ZLB. • Martin Feldstein (2009) “Rethinking the Role of Fiscal Policy,” American Economic Review 99, 2, 556-9: “Some of the past problems in using fiscal policy to stimulate demand may be less of an impediment in the current circumstances.” • Econometric studies • Aizenman, Joshua, & Yothin Jinjarik (2012), “The Fiscal Stimulus of 2009-10: Trade Openness, Fiscal Space and Exchange Rate Adjustment,” in NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics 2011, J.Frankel and C.Pissarides, eds. (University of Chicago Press). • Auerbach, Alan, & Yuriy Gorodnichenko (2012a), "Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal Policy," American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 4(2), 1-27, May. • Auerbach, Alan, & Yuriy Gorodnichenko (2012b), "Fiscal Multipliers in Recession and Expansion," in Alberto Alesina and Francesco Giavazzi (eds.) Fiscal Policy after the Financial Crisis (University of Chicago Press). • Baum, Anja, & Gerritt Koester (2011), “The Impact of Fiscal Policy on Economic Activity Over the Business Cycle - Evidence from a Threshold VAR Analysis” Deutsche Bundesbank, Disc. Paper Series 1: Economic Studies, 3. • • • • Baum, Anja, Marcos Poplawski-Ribeiro & Anke Weber (2012), "Fiscal Multipliers and the State of the Economy," IMF Working Paper 12/286. Blanchard, Olivier, and Daniel Leigh (2013), “ Growth forecast errors and fiscal multipliers,” American Economic Review, 103(3) May. Fazzari, Steven, James Morley, & Irina Panovska (2012), “State-Dependent Effects of Fiscal Policy”, Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics . Ilzetzki, Ethan, Enrique Mendoza & Carlos Vegh (2013), "How Big (Small?) are Fiscal Multipliers?" Journal of Monetary Economics. • But consider country cases below. – Japan. – Euroland. – Emerging markets. Monetary policy is of course relatively less powerful at Zero Lower Bound. • even though it is still worth doing, via channels other than short-term interest rate: – Exchange rate • if particular countries need more stimulus than others; – Expected inflation; – Long-term bonds, equities, and real estate. • Coordination of monetary policy is not especially needed, despite “currency wars.” How had Keynesian fiscal policy been discredited? • Not lack of knowledge, • nor lack of effectiveness. • Rather: political failure to pursue stimulus only counter-cyclically. • But that is no excuse for politicians who pursue fiscal policy pro-cyclically, • as was the norm in developing countries before 2000, • and the pattern among some in advanced countries since 2000. • “Secular stagnation” is not needed to explain recent slow growth; pro-cyclical fiscal policy can do it. Recent cases 1) Japan 2) Euroland 3) Emerging Market economies (Case 1) Japan • The three arrows of Abenomics – Monetary stimulus (2% inflation target + QQE) – Fiscal policy (?) – Structural reform (?) Japan’s monetary easing (QQE) raised the exchange rate (Yen/$) and stock market HR dissolved, Nov. 2012 => “Abenomics” “Outlook 2014 - Recovery on a shaky footing,” Special , Economic Research Dept., Rabobank November 13, 2013, https://economics.rabobank.com/publications/2013/november/outlook-2014-recovery-on-a-shaky-footing/ But effects on growth (& inflation) were disappointing. • Because the 2nd & 3rd arrows haven’t been fired? • I’d say the 2nd was fired in the wrong direction: – Abe went through with the scheduled increase in the consumption tax taking effect April 1, 2014, – from 5% to 8%. – As many had warned, Japan went back into recession, i.e., growth turned negative for next two quarters. Abenomics seemed to boost growth, at first. But Japan went back into recession in 2014 Q2, perhaps because of a big increase in the consumption tax. Nov. 2012 => “Abenomics” April 2014 => Consumption tax ITF220 - Professor J.Frankel Can Japan address its serious long-term debt problem, while avoiding contraction in the short term? Proposal: Replace the immediate discrete rise in the consumption tax with a pre-announced committed gradual path of increases, e.g., 0.25% every year until reaching 10%. Advantages: • If the path is credible, it will preclude a loss of confidence in the sustainability of Japan’s debt. • The short-term impact will not be contractionary. • Indeed, it will help generate expectations of inflation. (Case 2) Euroland • The three arrows of Mario Draghi (Jackson Hole 8/22/2014) – Monetary stimulus: • QE, launched Jan. 22, 2015. – Fiscal stimulus: • Those with space should spend. – Structural reform: • esp. labor markets. When the ECB launched QE in 2015, the euro depreciated immediately (2% in 3 hours) But fiscal policy was pro-cyclical, especially in Greece: expansion in 2000-08, contraction in 2010-14 Source: IMF, 2011. I. Diwan, PED401, Oct. 2011 14 EU fiscal austerity has been contractionary. Source: Paul Krugman, May 10, 2012. What about the critique that fiscal policy responded endogenously (and negatively) to the magnitude of the countries’ difficulties? The bigger the fiscal contraction, the bigger the GDP loss relative to what had been officially forecast => true multipliers > than multipliers that IMF had been using. Europe: Growth Forecast Errors vs. Fiscal Consolidation Forecasts Source: Olivier Blanchard & Daniel Leigh, 2014, “Learning about Fiscal Multipliers from Growth Forecast Errors,” fig.1, IMF Economic Review 62, 179–212 Note: Figure plots forecast error for real GDP growth in 2010 and 2011 relative to forecasts made in the spring of 2010 on forecasts of fiscal consolidation for 2010 and 2011 made in spring of year 2010; and regression line. In 2015 periphery economies remain weak. Source: Jeffrey Anderson and Jessica Stallings, Feb. 13, 2014, “Euro Area Periphery: Crisis Eased But Not Over,” Institute of International Finance, Chart 3 Fiscal austerity hasn’t even achieved the supposed goal of restoring debt sustainability: debt/GDP ratios continued to rise sharply. Declining GDP outweighed progress on reduction of budget deficits. 200 Public Debt (% GDP) 180 160 France Germany Greece Ireland Italy Portugal 140 120 100 80 60 40 Spain 20 0 . From Rémi Bourgeot, Fondation Robert Schuman Data source: IMF WEO (October 2014). (Case 3) Emerging Markets Fiscal policy in some EMs • turned from pro-cyclical to countercyclical after 2000, – -- e.g., Chile, India, Malaysia, Korea, China, Botswana -- • taking advantage of 2002-08 boom to strengthen their budgets, • and so making “fiscal space” to moderate the 2008-09 recession. = the opposite from some Industrialized Countries. Some major EMs are more vulnerable to the next shock – because they have backslid on cyclicality since 2010, • e.g., Brazil, India, Thailand. – or never did graduate from pro-cyclicality at all, • e.g., Argentina, Venezuela. Correlations between Gov.t Spending & GDP 1960-1999 procyclical Adapted from Kaminsky, Reinhart & Vegh (2004) Pro-cyclical spending countercyclical Countercyclical spending G always used to be pro-cyclical 20 for most developing countries. procyclical Correlations between Government spending & GDP 2000-2009 Frankel, Vegh & Vuletin (JDE, 2013) countercyclical In the last decade, about 1/3 developing countries switched to countercyclical fiscal policy: 21 Negative correlation of G & GDP. Appendices • (1) Japan’s Abenomics • (2) Euroland • (3) Which Emerging Market countries achieved fiscal counter-cyclicality? – and how? (1) Japan’s monetary easing weakened the yen, 2012-13 House of Representatives dissolved, Nov. 2012 => “Abenomics” Takatoshi Ito, “Abenomics: Progress, prospects and how the 2020 Tokyo Olympics can help solve Japan’s debt problem” ADB Institute DEC.30, 2013 http://www.asiapathways-adbi.org/2013/12/abenomics-progress-prospects-and-how-the-2020-tokyo-olympics-can-help-solve-japans-debt-problem/ (2)Unemployment in the euro periphery remains high Source: Jeffrey Anderson and Jessica Stallings, Feb. 13, 2014 , “Euro Area Periphery: Crisis Eased But Not Over,” Institute of International Finance, Chart 1 (3) Emerging Markets Adapted from Frankel, Vegh & Vuletin (JDE, 2013) In the decade 2000-2009, about 1/3 developing countries switched to countercyclical fiscal policy: Negative correlation of G & GDP. DEVELOPING: 43% (or 32 out of 75) countercyclical. The figure was 17% (or 13 out of 75) in 1960-1999. INDUSTRIAL: 86% (or 18 out of 21) countercyclical. The figure was 80% (or 16 out of 20) in 1960-1999. Latest update of Correlation (G, GDP): Back-sliding among some countries, 2010-2014. Thanks to Guillermo Vuletin DEVELOPING: 37% (or 29 out of 76) pursue counter-cyclical fiscal policy. INDUSTRIAL: 63% (or 12 out of 19) pursue counter-cyclical fiscal policy. The correlation for 2000-09 vs. 2010-14 Who achieves counter-cyclical fiscal policy? Countries with “good institutions” IQ ”On Graduation from Fiscal Procyclicality,” Frankel, Végh & Vuletin; J.Dev.Economics, 2013. 29 The quality of institutions varies, not just across countries, but also across time. 1984-2009 Worsened institutions; More-cyclical spending. Improved institutions; Less-cyclical spending. Good institutions; Countercyclical spending Frankel, Végh & Vuletin,2013. 30 How can countries avoid pro-cyclical fiscal policy? • What are “good institutions,” exactly? • Rules? – Budget deficit ceilings (SGP) or debt brakes? • Have been tried many times. Usually fail. – Rules for cyclically adjusted budgets? • Countries are more likely to be able to stick with them. But… • An under-explored problem: – Over-optimism in official forecasts • of GDP growth rates & budgets. • Frankel & Schreger (2013), "Over-optimistic Official Forecasts and Fiscal Rules in the Eurozone," Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv. • Frankel (2011), "Over-optimism in Forecasts by Official Budget Agencies and Its Implications," Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 31 Countries with Balanced Budget Rules frequently violate them. BBR: Balanced Budget Rules DR: Debt Rules ER: Expenditure Rules Compliance < 50% International Monetary Fund, 2014 To expect countries to comply with the rules during recessions is particularly unrealistic (and not even necessarily desirable). Bad times: years when output gap < 0 International Monetary Fund, 2014 US official projections were over-optimistic on average. F & Schreger, 2013 34 Greek official forecasts were always over-optimistic. Data from Greece’s Stability and Convergence Programs. F & Schreger, 2013 35 German forecasts were also usually too optimistic. 36 Most European official forecasts have been over-optimistic. Figure 1 (F&S, 2013): Mean 1-year ahead budget forecast errors, European Countries, Full Sample Period For 17 Europeans, the bias is even higher than others, averaging: 0.5% at the 1-year horizon, 1.3% at the 2-year horizon, 2.4% at the 3-year horizon 37 Figure 2 (F&S, 2013): Mean 2-year ahead budget forecast errors, European Countries, Full Sample Period 38 The case of Chile • 1st rule – Governments must set a budget target, • 2nd rule – The target is structural: Deficits allowed only to the extent that – (1) output falls short of trend, in a recession, – (2) or the price of copper is below its trend. • 3rd rule – The trends are projected by 2 panels of independent experts, outside the political process. – Result: Chile avoided the pattern of 32 other governments, • where forecasts in booms were biased toward optimism. Frankel (2013), “A Solution to Fiscal Procyclicality: The Structural Budget Institutions Pioneered by Chile,” in Fiscal Policy and Macroeconomic Performance, edited by Luis Céspedes & Jordi Gali (Central Bank of Chile). 39 Chile’s official forecasts have not been over-optimistic. 40