Multinational Enterprise Locations: A European Study July 2012 Erasmus University Rotterdam Erasmus School of Economics Author: Albena Gradeva Student Number: 329851 Supervisor: Dr. Yvonne Adema E-mail address: ag03@student.eur.nl 1 ABSTRACT This paper analyses the complex location decision for multinational firms who situated outside of their parent country. Besides the extensively researched effects of economic factors, this study also explores the effects of some social variables on the number of foreign controlled enterprises (FAT) across 21 European host countries, over the period 2006-2009. As theoretically predicted, the tax rate has a negative effect on the number of FATs per country. The size of the country in GDP, low wages, a skilled labour force, and the importance of university education in the hosting country has a positive effect on the number of FATs. Inconclusive results are obtained on the effects of the number of foreign languages spoken per tertiary educated person, as the data shows a surprising negative effect of this variable on the number of FATs. The results regarding the effect of the percentage of the population with a tertiary education also display an astounding negative relationship. 2 Contents 1. Introduction ......................................................................................................................... 4 2. Theoretical Background ......................................................................................................... 6 i) Tax effects ........................................................................................................................... 6 ii) Agglomeration effects ...................................................................................................... 11 3. Methodology......................................................................................................................... 16 i) Data ............................................................................................................................... 16 ii) Empirical Specification ................................................................................................. 18 4. Estimation Results ................................................................................................................ 20 i) Description of the data ...................................................................................................... 20 ii) Binary Logistic Regression Results and Assumption Tests ...................................... 22 ii) OLS results and Assumption Tests............................................................................ 26 5. Conclusion ............................................................................................................................ 28 6. References ............................................................................................................................ 30 7. Appendix .............................................................................................................................. 33 3 1. Introduction As more globalization takes place it seems that international borders have become a problem of the past. Governments worldwide are adopting more lenient migration policies, the most astounding of which is that of the European Union (EU). In its Council Directive of 29 April 2004, the EU declared free migration and residence of member citizens in all its territories a right. Since many multinational enterprises, MNEs, operate in many places outside their parent countries, it only seems reasonable as to why these MNEs would choose Europe for their host location, with its rather unrestrictive migration policy. In an article in the Fortune Magazine of 2007, out of the top ten cities with the most headquarters, six of the ten are European including Paris, London and Munich among others.1 Furthermore, Van Dijk et al. (2000) studied how firms choose to relocate within the Netherlands. About one third of total firm demographics are concerned with firm relocations, whether of MNEs or local businesses. This proves the inevitable importance of the firm’s location decision. The location choice for multinationals is a complex decision that depends on many different determinants. This study seeks to find which different economic and social factors affect the probability of hosting foreign affiliates, FATs, of multinational enterprises in different countries. The effects of these variables on the number of FATs are also analyzed. Over the past two decades much relocation of large MNEs has occurred from the US and Europe to other European countries. Especially Western EU countries, with their welldeveloped and maintained infrastructures, are more than reasonable choices when deciding where to situate. According to Bruinsma and Rietveld (1993), those cities among the top ten regarding accessibility by air, rail and road are mainly located in the UK, France, Germany the Netherlands and Belgium. Although Western Europe could seem more attractive for MNEs due to these findings, some MNEs also situate in Eastern Europe. Evidence on this is provided in Faggio (2001). After MNEs have chosen to locate in Eastern Europe, they calculate the probability of choosing one of three Eastern EU members to locate to. Many European countries have been trying to compete for foreign direct investments, FDIs, a part of which consists of foreign affiliates, FATs. Many nations have taken different approaches to attract large foreign firms. A major factor on which European states are competing for FDIs is through applying different tax policies. A vast amount of the literature is on the location of multinationals and the effects of taxes, especially on the US case. 1 Fortune global 500 2007 http://money.cnn.com/magazines/fortune/global500/2007/cities/ 4 Slemrod (1990), Hartman (1984) and Swenson (1994), among others, have studied the tax effects on MNEs located in the US. As taxes seem to be of vital importance to the location decision, they have also been included in this study. Although tax is an important factor to consider, it is not the only factor on which multinationals base their location. Another economic factor which has been extensively researched is that on agglomeration economies and their effects on the location choice for MNEs studied by Crozet et al (2003), and Brülhart et al (2012). As suggested by Davis and Henderson (2003), the assortment of services available as well as the presence of other firm headquarters attracts MNEs to situate at these sites, which weakens the tax effect on this location decision. Some research has been done by Basile et al (2008) and Hajkova et al.(2006) on social factors affecting the locations of subsidiaries, but less research has been done compared to taxes. In the study by Hajkova et al. (2006), she states that when border and labour policies are considered along with taxes, the size of the tax effect is also tremendously reduced. This is one of the main reasons why social factors are a main focus of this study. A major concern for US investors is also the level of education. In a study on location choices of R&D MNEs locating in Europe by Siedschlag et al (2009), they find that when education levels are included, the amount of taxes charged becomes a less important factor when deciding where to locate. The educational attainment per country is included to examine whether the tax effects on the probability of MNE location is changed. Another rather neglected but potentially important aspect for MNE location is the ease of communication as suggested by Welch et al. (2005). When people speak the same language, it is much easier to get the desired message across to employees. Perhaps the number of languages spoken by the residents of a country makes it easier for different cultures to integrate into the host society. Factors regarding the labour market also seem to suppress the effects of taxes regarding the site choice for subsidiaries, as discussed in Faggio (2001). Plenty of research exists on the country level, where MNEs need to decide in which region of a country to locate, after already having picked the country. However, less literature exists to explain how the country location is chosen. In this study the focus is on 21 European countries, including countries from the North and South, as well as the East and the West. The structure of this thesis is as follows: in the following section, some of the related literature on the subject is discussed. Section 3 describes the data and methodology used. The 5 results are presented in Section 4, and finally the conclusions and recommendations for future research can be found in Section 5. 2. Theoretical Background In this section, an overview of the main literature related to the subject studied on multinational enterprise locations is provided. Much of the literature has focused on the effects of taxes on different types of foreign direct investment. This is discussed in the first subsection. The second subsection shows that when other factors are included, especially agglomeration effects, the effects of taxes on the location decision of foreign investment are weakened. i) Tax effects In recent years, quite some research has been done on MNEs and their location choice. In a study by the OECD (2007), “Taxation and Foreign Direct Investments”, the OECD provides an overview of the existing literature on taxes up until 2007. An analysis is given on the first major studies carried out on time series, cross sectional, panel and discrete choice models. One of the first studies done in the field of FDI´s locations was on taxation by Hartman (1984). A basic time series specification is built to test whether tax rates in the US have any explanatory power for the sites FDIs choose to situate at. He took this data on US MNEs for the period 1965-1979. In his methodology, he regresses the FDI on variables in logarithmic forms, such as the rate of return on inbound FDI and a variable measuring the after tax rate of return on US capital. In this specification, only FDI financed by new equity is used, instead of FDI which is financed by retained earnings. Due to this, there are no mixed effects between completely new FDI entering the country for the first time and already existing FDI. His findings empirically confirmed that a higher after-tax rate of return stimulates higher FDIs. Also, the higher the amount of retained earnings, the more attractive a location becomes for FDI. Another interesting finding is that the personal income tax rate as a percentage of the corporate tax rate has a negative effect on the amount of FDI. The downside to Hartman’s research is that it only uses data on the aggregate level for all FDI in the US. FDI may consist of different investments, i.e. new foreign affiliates, mergers and acquisitions and plant expansions. Special rules may apply to each specific type of investment, so conclusions drawn about the effects of taxes should not be drawn for both physical and capital FDIs. 6 The findings for the times series studies seem to be in line with those on a crosssectional basis. The cross sectional studies also find evidence to support the assumption of distortive tax effects on the amount of FDI. Slemrod (1990) uses data from 1960-1987 studying the US tax rate on inbound FDI, which adds to the literature by including investments made by countries from all over the world. Two groups are compared. The first group consists of Canada, the Netherlands, France and the former West-Germany, and the other group includes Italy, the UK and Japan. This study focuses on the repatriation of foreign sourced income, where a distinction is made between countries who exempt FDI from taxes and those who use a credit tax system. Three consecutive effective marginal tax rates, EMTRs, for the host country, the US, are included in this study. The EMTR is defined as the marginal tax rate applied on a single investment, unlike the effective average tax rate, which takes an average value for a number of different projects. Also specified is the difference between home and host country taxes on corporate and personal income. He finds that the EMTR has a negative effect on FDI. Tax exemption in the home country is an insignificant predictor for the amount of FDI in the hosting US. However, a larger host (US) tax rate, results in fewer FDI funds being sent to the host country. In sum, the amount of FDI from each of the countries is negatively affected by the US, host country’s tax rate. Interestingly enough, inbound FDI financed by retained earnings are not affected by the host tax rate. Grubert & Mutti (1991) also specify a model studying the effects of taxes on property, plant and equipment, where physical rather than capital investments are analyzed. The data covers US MNEs from the manufacturing sector investing in 33 host countries. They find that outbound investment is negatively affected by the host country tax rate. However, time series analyses have their drawbacks. The highest number of significant tax elasticities has been found on the panel basis, amounting to two thirds of all studies on panels in the paper of the OECD (2007). Swenson’s (1994) study shows the effects of US tax reforms on the foreign and native investor. A total of 18 industries over the period 1990-1991 have been examined, with data distinguishing between physical and capital investments. The investors studied have been split into two groups. The first group accounts for investors using international laws for their financial reporting. The other group consists of investors who use national accounting rules. Swenson has used logarithmically transformed variables to model FDI on the average tax rate (ATR), the exchange rate, industry dummies and time fixed effects. Remarkably, a larger ATR has been linked with a larger amount of FDI, which is in line with the prediction by Scholes and 7 Wolfson (1990). This result may be due to the fact that non-tax predictors have been added to the equation. The sign of the effect of tax rates on FDI may change when one or all of these variables is accounted for. Furthermore, Pain and Young (1996) have studied German and UK outbound FDI between the periods 1977-1992 into other, mainly European countries. Among other logarithmic variables, a first order lag of previous FDI has been regressed to determine the effects of independent tax rates on the FDI. Only for the UK, and not for Germany, it is found that the larger the home country tax the more sensitive an MNE is to the host country tax rate. Finally, discrete choice models are considered, where the decision to locate is mutually exclusive. As in the current estimations that follow in section 4, the studies in the OECD Tax Policy Studies examine the effect of host country taxes on the probability of a foreign affiliate choosing a location. Swenson (2001) studies the different types of FDI; new plants, plant growths, mergers and acquisitions, joint ventures and the FDI due to the increase in equity of firms. Instead of studying dollar terms of FDI, count data on the number of firms per location is used. The effects of statutory tax rates, which are the legally allocated tax rates in a country, are examined. A total of 46 countries investing into 50 different US states have been sampled. It is found that the FDI in its physical form is also negatively affected by state tax rates, especially for the new plants and growth of plants. Stöwhase (2003) uses a sample from 1991-1998 to study how outbound German FDI is affect by the taxes in 8 European countries. A number of fixed effects are included, namely the size of the country, labour costs and the amount of government expenditure on investment in the sectors of production and services. The average tax rate has a negative effect on new production plants being set up in a specific country. For the FDI in the service sector, the statutory taxes also have a negative effect on the investments made in new plants opened under the service sector. In conclusion, the OECD study finds that not only the amount of capital invested in a country, but also the location specifically chosen for a subsidiary is negatively impacted by tax rates Other studies besides those reviewed in the OECD provide diverse results. Devereux et al. (2003) find similar results. They analyze data for the US from 1979-1999 on investments on simple plant and machinery in European countries like France, the UK and Germany. Like Slemrod (1990), in their methodology they use a weighted average of effective average tax rates (EATR), the effective marginal tax rate (EMTR) and the applicable statutory tax rate. They specify a range for the possible taxes due on the different earnings of 8 projects unlike specifying only the EMTR, which is limited to the analysis of a single project only. The UK seems to be the most favoured location, especially for highly profitable investments due to high tax credits offered on repatriation of foreign income. Hines et al (1996) examined what effect different corporate tax rates among 50 US states had on the FDI location of MNEs. Evidence is found supporting the hypothesis that foreign MNEs are sensitive to the foreign tax rates of the countries hosting them. Voget (2011) studied the probability of parent companies to relocate given an increase in the tax rate. Data is available on an international level, so a large country-comparison can be made. The data included in this study extends over the period 1997-2007 for a worldwide database of 33 countries. His main finding was that an additional tax on income from abroad, after paying taxes for income produced within the home country, would make countries less attractive to locate headquarters at. In this study, a comparison is made between two groups of MNEs, mainly those that were taxed on worldwide profits and those exempted from paying these taxes. An interesting methodology is used. The probability of relocating or not, a binary outcome variable, is predicted using a logistic regression. A number of explanatory variables are used in different specifications, including a ratio of MNE tax payments on their income, dummies denoting whether foreign tax credits are provided and whether more than 95% of dividend repatriations are exempted from taxation. This method is very similar to the one which will be used in this paper’s empirical specification in section 4. The MNE may decide to relocate either to avoid controlled foreign company legislation (CFC laws) such as taxes on royalties or dividends, or to avoid restrictive rules which do not allow tax deferral until the repatriation of foreign income. A dependent variable reports the value 1 if the headquarter has relocated in the recent past, and 0 otherwise. The independent variables included are the EATR and the presence of CFC legislation in the specific year of interest. The market value of the MNE, leverage ratio, earnings over total assets as well as whether or not a firm is positioned in the high tech sector are the variables included to control for any firm specific effects. The results show that CFCs increase the chances of an MNE’s headquarter to relocate. A foreign country with a lower foreign tax rate would have a higher chance to attract the headquarters of an MNE to relocate to it. Barrios et al. (2009) use European level data, for both parent and subsidiary plants from 1999-2003. Out of the 33 countries considered, a total of 906 parent and 3,094 subsidiaries companies are included. In this sample, the UK, France and the Netherlands have 9 the most parent companies with 144, 116 and 89 respectively. They study the effects of host and home country taxation on the location decisions of MNEs. Both types of taxes have a negative effect on MNE locations. A higher host tax rate would make a place less desirable to locate to. Regarding taxation on parent firms in the home country, taxation has a highly discriminatory nature. An important finding of this paper is that particularly double parentcountry taxation on MNE income has a negative impact on the attractiveness of a site to a firm. In their final conclusion, they find that countries with lower taxes on foreign-source income are more appealing to locate to. This is the case especially for parent firms, as worldwide profits from subsidiaries are repatriated here. Only a limited amount of studies are available which not only include more factors which possibly influence where MNEs locate their subsidiaries, but that also include a crosscountry evaluation. One such study is done by Hajkova et al. (2006). It includes both different plausible factors influencing this choice, as well as a rather large country-level data set comprising of 28 OECD countries. Both policy and non-policy related issues are taken into consideration when evaluating the attractiveness of a specific country for an MNE. In accordance with previous research in this field, it is concluded that taxes have a significant explanatory power on how desirable a site is to position at. However, when accounting for policies regarding the labour market (especially concerning labour costs), as well as border and product market restrictions, tax elasticities have a significant but smaller impact on the selected location. On a cross-sectional level, where the attractiveness of different US states for FDIs is inspected, it is still found that higher taxes repel foreign firms from locating at these sites. This paper is further discussed in the following section. For obvious reasons, cross-sectional analyses have their limitations too; hence Swenson (1994) decided to approach the field by carrying out a panel study. Swenson proposed that changes in the US Tax Reform Act of 1986 could have different effects on investors from within and outside America. This reform largely impacted the tax rates due by home investors, but less so for foreign ones. Foreign investors would be taxed on their foreign source income in their country of origin, regardless of the one in the US. It is also found in this study that depreciation of the US dollar has a positive effect on foreign investments in the United States. This research added to this field greatly as it compares the difference between foreign and local investors, and also between different time periods, before and after the change in tax policies had been made. 10 When choosing a location, some have proposed that locating in an urban area is more attractive, especially for large corporations who need the developed facilities of agglomerated areas. In a study by Laamanen et al. (2012) the reason why urban areas are chosen is examined: mainly due to a highly developed, broad set of different services. The research has been able to include multi-country data on a European level. They limit their research to headquarter locations only. Having other headquarters in the surrounding improves the likelihood of choosing a certain location. It can undoubtedly be assumed that their location decisions depend on many more factors than for subsidiaries, as the headquarters’ success is key to the firm’s survival and overall success in the business world. Still, the importance of taxes is highly significant when a location is considered. International variation is also examined in the present research, not only since different taxes are studied, but cultural differences are also included in the analysis. ii) Agglomeration effects Many studies have been done on the effects agglomerations have on the location choice of MNEs. Basile et al. (2003) use a nested logit model to study the location choice of 5,761 foreign subsidiaries from 1991-1999 in 55 regions of 8 European countries. It is found that firms perceive differences on an international scale larger than differences across country regions. Nations rather than regions compete for MNEs. The Cohesion policy, which transferred extra funds to laggard regions, mitigates agglomeration effects of network economies. US firms are attracted to areas with highly skilled labour whereas European firms seek to take advantage of the large labour supply available in highly unemployed areas. A major limitation of the studies mentioned previously is that they tend to overlook other policies besides taxes, and therefore overstate their importance for inward and outward FDI. Hajkova et al. (2006) empirically test whether this is indeed true on a sample of 28 OECD countries from 1991-2000. They also apply the EATR as it applies to investments that earn profit and don’t simply break even, as Devereux et al (2003) have done. However, they use both the EATR and EMTR in their estimations for robustness reasons. Besides the tax policy applied per country, they include other policies such as trade barriers, as well as regulations on the goods and labour markets. They consider some social factors in the analysis such as the GDP representing the size of the market and the average education level of the population. A semi-parametric model is used to account for unobservable effects such as the 11 historical and cultural association between countries. In their estimations, they find that an increase in the EMTR causes a decrease in the amount of FDI stock. An even larger, negative effect for the EATR measure is found. Besides taxes, other policies seem to have a significant effect too. Membership of more free trade areas seems to positively affect the amount of FDI found per country. The results show that strict labour regulation and tough anti-trust laws have a negative effect on FDI. Regarding the non-policy factors, a positive relationship between the market size and FDI is found. Overall, the study finds that bilateral taxes are highly overstated, and their effects are mitigated once other policy and non-policy factors are included. In a more recent study, Basile et al. (2008), a rather large dataset of 5,509 foreign subsidiaries is used to study how firms located across 50 regions within a total of 8 European host countries during 1991-1999. They estimate the probability of these subsidiaries to locate in one of these territories using a mixed logit model. The models specified in my paper uses a similar methodology to the one used by Basile et al. Such a model specifies a discrete choice set, as investments are usually mutually exclusive, and it does not rely on the assumption of a normal distribution, which is often violated with such data. This method is preferred compared to a nested logit framework, because the mixed logit can make more clear distinctions between different regions. Their specification includes the number of residents per country, how far the subsidiaries’ headquarter is from the country and whether or not the MNE has previous business experience in the region. They find that agglomeration effects play an important role for the location decision. Also, European MNEs locate to low income areas with higher unemployment and larger market potential. In contrast, non-Europeans rather locate to high income areas with lower taxes on the production factors of capital and labour. In addition, this study finds that Cohesion funds allocated to laggard regions have managed to attract foreign investors to smaller scale regions, which weaken the effects of agglomeration economies. Devereux et al. (2007) studied how MNEs decide between different British sites when making the decisions on where to situate new offices. Their approach is quite different, as they focus mainly on the effects of policies implemented by the British government in attracting FDIs. Specifically, they found that money granted to foreign companies is important in determining which region they choose within Britain. However, when agglomeration effects are simultaneously accounted for, grants have a positive but lower 12 effect on choosing a location. Clearly, the existence of network economies makes territories more attractive. For the French case, Crozet et al. (2003) also reach a similar conclusion to Devereux’s findings. Crozet et al. (2003) find that for inward FDI in France, an area’s attractiveness increases along with the number of competitor’s in the area. A suggested explanation for this result is that spill-over, learning effects are present. Foreign firms learn from the pre-existing MNEs in the location. From experience, they have more information on the best available sites; hence knowledge of other MNEs can also be transferred more easily to new MNEs when they are located close to pre-existing ones. These results have been estimated using both conditional and nested logit models. It seems that when hosting international firms instead of local, French ones, a site becomes more attractive for MNEs. It is also found that over time, being located in an agglomeration becomes less important, and being closer to the market for the final product is more important. In Faggio (2001), a conditional logit model is used to study micro-data from 19941997.Here the probability to locate to Romania, Poland or Bulgaria is determined, given that the MNE has decided to locate in Eastern Europe. They take a rather unorthodox approach in their empirical specification.. The nationality of the parent firms and agglomeration factors played a role when deciding between these three developing countries. They control for social effects like the culture and region of the potential host location as well as tax effects and how close the location is to financial institutes. Their specification includes information on the size of the hosting country, the wage paid to the labour force, the rigidness of the labour market policies, the market concentration of other MNEs and the level of development of the R&D sector. Less strict employment conditions seem to be favourable, as not only entrance but exit costs for the firm are considered when locating. Once agglomerations are accounted for, American firms weigh the amount of demand for their product or service heavily. The larger the demand in the country, the more likely they are to locate to it. The German MNEs rely largely on low wage locations. In a similar study by Konings et al. (2004), a sample for European parent MNEs from 1993-1998 is used. They find that higher labour costs in Northern-European affiliates have a significant negative effect on employment by the parent company in these countries. Perhaps this is due to the fact that the labour force is more skilled in these countries, and hence one person from Northern-Europe is relatively more productive than a worker from outside the 13 Northern-European boundary. With such a result, one can assume that employment in the Northern-European countries (with higher labour costs) is substituted by higher employment in the other countries. Although intuitive, no concrete evidence to prove this has been found. For the Southern, Central and Eastern part of Europe, no labour substitution took place due to lower wages compared to Northern-Europe. For Swiss municipalities a similar effect of agglomerations is found in Brülhart et al. (2012).A dataset of Swiss municipalities from 1999-2002 is used. Brülhart et al. study how the count data on the number of new firms established per municipality and sector are affected by different region specific factors, including the tax rate. Although taxes are thought to have a major influence on the location decision, it has been proven by this paper that their importance has been highly overestimated. Here, agglomeration effects are included alongside the corporate tax rates to re-estimate their importance on location decisions. Evidence is found to support the hypothesis that the inclusion of agglomeration effects mitigates the importance of the tax levels at a specific site. It is shown that other possible explanatory factors should not be neglected. Though many similar studies have been done on the national level, this is rather limiting when it comes to the robustness of conclusions on an international level. Davis et al. (2003) also seem to find agglomeration effects for headquarters a significant determinant. It is preferred to locate to a place abundant with other headquarters. A large variety of available services is also an attractive quality for headquarters choosing between different locations. Guimarães et al (2000) use data on all newly created affiliates in Portugal between 1985 and 1992. They also found that agglomeration economies with a large number of preexisting MNEs make a location attractive when deciding where to locate within Portugal. Labour costs do not seem to be a major concern but the level of development of the firm’s specific industry and urbanization spill-over effects as well as proximity to large urban areas is of importance. In the paper by Guimarães et al. (2000), agglomeration effects are decisive factors for MNEs considering different Portuguese regions. Especially with regard to the level of development of the service sector within a district, agglomeration effects play an important role on where they decide to situate their premises. However, as shown in Van Dijk (2000) the opposite is found to be true. The relocation of firms within the Netherlands is more 14 affected by the internal environment of the firm itself, rather than the site specific characteristics in each Dutch region. Siedschlag et al. (2009) researched the effects of agglomerations on the R&D sector within different European countries, with data used from 1999-2006. This study makes use of a nested logit model which controls for the correlation between the different location choices called ‘nests’ where comparable regions are grouped to allow for some dependence among alternatives. This model allows for the assumption of Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives (IIA) within each nest to hold. Unlike the conditional logit model, the nested logit controls for the fact that the error terms for specific alternatives can be correlated. The outcome variable is represented by 1 if a subsidiary locates in an area due to its higher expected profit relative to alternative areas. MNEs are more likely to locate to markets with high demand for their products, agglomerated networks, and low costs of manufacturing and less strict labour policies. A site with a plentiful and skilled workforce, as well as a highly developed infrastructure and technological advancement makes locations more attractive. Moreover, it is found that North American affiliates are more sensitive to agglomeration economies than European ones. Lastly, in a study by Mariotti et al (1995) it is researched how investors from abroad chose between different regions within Italy. They conclude that agglomeration economies are one of the major deciding factors when choosing where to locate. Pre-existing MNEs are a signal that the location is a good option, which decrease the asymmetry costs faced by the foreign MNEs. Also, they state that the distance from the home country has a negative effect on the location of FDIs. Although intuitive, providing government grants has no effect on the location decision of MNEs locating to Italy. 15 3. Methodology i) Data In this paper, we account for MNEs as a part of FDI. A total of 21 European countries acting as hosts for the FATs are included. The countries analyzed are Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Lithuania, the Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden and the UK. The data available for the multinational enterprises which are present in the host countries have been obtained from Eurostat. This data can be found in Table 1 in the Appendix. All the countries for which data was available for on the site have been included in the analysis. This site provides official statistical data for potential and present members of the European Union. The data from this site can be used for inter-country comparison. The number of inward FATs, or foreign affiliates, has been extracted from this database. FATs are ‘enterprises or branches’ under the control of foreign divisions resident outside of the country in which the FAT is located. According to Eurostat, an enterprise is defined as a unit which is autonomous, in at least some respect, in the decision making process, especially with respect to the use of available resources. In the Eurostat metadata, further explanation is given on the definition of control; i.e. the controlling unit has more than half of the shareholder’s voting rights or company shares, and has the power to appoint the board of directors. The FAT data available per country stretches over the period 2001-2009. Before 2006, this data was sent on a voluntary basis only from some European Member states. Data accumulation has only been harmonized from 2007 onwards, in agreement with the European Parliament and the Council on Community statistics on the structure and activity of foreign affiliates. However, as is shown in Table 1, there are only a few more missing data points for the year 2006, compared to 2007. For 2006, 5 data points are missing, whereas for 2007, 3 points are missing. Also, as shown in Table 2, the specifications with beginning date 2006 shows a better model fit compared to that starting from 2007. The data specification including the year prior to harmonization, 2006, shows a larger Chi-Square for the Omnibus test, a smaller Hosmer & Lemeshow and a larger Cox & Snell R-square. Also, upon visual inspection of the data from 2006 compared to that for 2007, there seem to be no major differences in the minimum and maximums which appear between these two years. As a larger data set with more points is preferable to a smaller one, and due to all the above mentioned reasons, the data range used for this study ranges from 2006-2009 16 Two other variables have been obtained from the Eurostat database. For the first, the number of foreign languages known is expressed as a percentage of the population who has obtained tertiary education and speaks at least one foreign language, up to a maximum of three. This data is available only for the year 2007. However, as stated in Mejer et al (2010), the number of foreign languages that has been studied in upper secondary schools has not significantly changed between the periods 2000 and 2008.Therefore, it is reasonable to assume that the self-reported number of languages known did not change over the period studied. As an example of how this data is reported, if 35.4% of tertiary education graduates speak 1 language, 36.6% speak 2 languages and 12.9% speak 3 languages, the sum of these percentages is taken. This means that 85.9% of the tertiary education graduates speak at least one foreign language. A dummy variable has been created to show whether the country’s percentage of the population is below or above the EU27 average of 91.2%. However, as these figures are self-reported, it could very well be that people over or understate their abilities and the languages they consider themselves to know proficiently. Data for this variable is not available for Ireland, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom, hence when interpreting any results from this variable; this should be taken into consideration. The other variable reports the persons with tertiary education as a percentage of the total population between the ages of 15 and 65. Some more independent variables have been obtained from the IMD World Competitiveness database. Firstly, some economic factors have been extracted. Data on the corporate tax rate before profit has been taken as a percentage of total profit. As a fixed effect, to control for the size of the different countries under analysis, the GDP in US$ billions has also been included. Some socio-economic factors have also been considered. The productivity of labour has been measured by the amount of GDP one worker can produce in an hour, measured in US $. The availability of skilled labour in each country has been provided on the scale from 0 to 10, with 10 scoring the highest for this ranking. The next factor measures whether having a university degree improves the competitiveness of the country’s economy at hand, i.e. university education importance, on the same scale from 0, being the lowest score, to 10, being the highest. The variable language skills are meeting the needs of enterprises measures whether or not the language skills of the inhabitant people meet the needs of enterprises also on a 1-10 scale. A final variable has been included to estimate the total salary that workers obtain, including wages and other benefits. This variable is coded as compensation level (hourly) and represents the total income per hour in US$. 17 ii) Empirical Specification As many MNEs are of US origin, much research has been done mainly on the United States. In this paper, the probability of a country having a low or high number of FATs is studied for a number of European countries, when certain exogenous variables are accounted for. The study by Faggio (2001) focuses on the probability of locating a subsidiary in one of 3 Eastern-European regions, given that the multinational has decided to locate in the Eastern Europe region, but the exact country has not been chosen yet. The current study takes a different approach. It studies what effects certain factors have had on the location decision. The firms studied have already located in these countries, i.e. the location decision has already been made. Hence, unlike the study by Faggio, which uses a conditional logit model, here a binary logistic regression is specified. Most studies, like those by Slemrod (1990) and Swenson (1994), have specified linear regressions. In accordance with this previous research, an Ordinary Least Squares regression like the one in equation (1) has been specified. Fewer papers, however, have used the logistic methodology to study the effects of certain factors on FATs; hence, like in the study by Voget (2011), a logistic regression is estimated to further add to the literature. The methodology on the binary logistic regression used in this paper is taken from the book by A. Field (2009). A binary logistic regression studies the probability of a certain categorical variable being chosen out of a set of 2 alternatives. The binary logistic regression has been used as only two possible outcomes are studied, having a low or high number of FATs, which would be easier to interpret and base policy recommendations on. A binary logistic regression is similar to a simple multiple regression analysis like the one below: (1) 𝑌𝑖𝑡 = 𝑏0 + 𝑏1 𝑋1𝑖𝑡 + 𝑏2 𝑋2𝑖𝑡 +. . . 𝑏𝑛 𝑋𝑛𝑖𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖 t where the simple multiple regression studies the size effect of each factor 𝑥𝑛 on the outcome variable 𝑌𝑖𝑡 , with constant term 𝑏0 and error term 𝜀𝑖𝑡 during each time period 𝑡 . Here n represents the number of exogenous factors used in the model, and i represents the number of possible outcome variables, which in this case are 2. The logistic regression predicts the probability of 𝑌𝑖 occurring, given a number of n independent predictor variables: (2) P(Yit) = 1 1+𝑒 −(𝑏0+𝑏1𝑋1𝑖𝑡+𝑏2 𝑋2𝑖 + … 𝑏𝑛 𝑋𝑛𝑖𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖𝑡) 18 where P(Yi) represents the probability of Y occurring, e is the base of the natural logarithm to the power of a multiple linear regression equation, of the form described in equation (1). Although similarities exist between the linear and logistic regression, there is one major difference. The outcome variable for a logistic regression is categorical. This variable is defined by a name rather than a number, and therefore can be placed into different groups. Due to this categorical nature of the outcome variable, the assumption of linearity for the normal, linear regression is violated. However, the logistic model corrects for this violation by transforming this variable into logarithmic form. Another major difference between linear and logistic regression is on the interpretation of the independent variables. Where linear regressions predict the size effect as well as the direction in which it affects the dependent variable, the logistic regression is limited to only predicting the direction in which the independent variables affect the outcome. In this case, the outcome variable is whether a low or a high number of FATs is present in a country. To create a categorical variable for the outcome variable, the number of foreign controlled enterprises has been grouped into two clusters. To do this, percentiles have been used to divide the data into appropriate ranges. They have been divided as follows: Country Label Low: High: Range 0 < y ≤ 5,895 5,895 ≤ y ≤ 25,835 where a country is labelled low if the number of foreign controlled enterprises is between 0 and 5,895. Here, 0 is not included as there are ten years for which certain countries have no reported data. Hence, the value 0 is used as a proxy for missing data when doing the statistical computation. All other countries lie within the top half of the percentile distribution. Specifically for this study, a binary logistic regression has been chosen as there are two categories into which the outcome variable can fall into. The outcome variable for this regression can be interpreted as the probability of either having a low or a high number of FATs in a country. The probability of having a high or low number of FATs is calculated in the following way: (3) P (event occurring) = 1 1+e−(b0 +b1(Economic_Factors)1it +b2 (Social Factors)2it + εit ) 19 where economic and social factors are studied and their effects on the odds of the number of foreign affiliates being high or low for a country. Four economic factors are studied, i.e. (i) the effect of the corporate tax rate (in percentage), (ii) the GDP in US$ Billions, (iii) the labour compensation level (in US$), (iv) and the labour productivity (in GDP per capita). The social factors which have been analyzed include: (i) the availability of skilled labour, (ii) the persons with tertiary education, (iii) university education importance, (iv) the number of foreign languages known, and (v) whether language skills meet the needs of enterprises. Finally, the odds of the outcome variable occurring are calculated as follows, as is done by A. Field (2009): P(event occurring) Odds = (1−P(event occurring)) (3) where the odds ratio is: Odds after a unit change in predictor Δ Odds = Odds before a unit change in predictor If the odds ratio is greater than 1, then as the predictor increases, so do the odds of the outcome occurring. However, if the odds ratio is smaller than 1, the odds of the outcome occurring decrease as the predictor increases. The results for this binary regression as well as the linear regression follow, where the assumptions for both models have been tested. 4. Estimation Results i) Description of the data A sample of 21 European countries across 4 years, ranging from 2006-2009, has been used. The descriptive statistics of the data can be found in Table 3. The number of statistics is excluding the number of missing values for each variable. For the FATs (foreign controlled enterprises) 73 cases are present, with a mean of 8,800; standard deviation of 5,895; a minimum of 753 and a maximum of 25,835 (in units of enterprises). Simply by visually inspecting the data, it can be seen that all of the variables are skewed in some way. As can be expected the FAT and GDP present larger means compared to their medians. This means that these distributions are skewed to the right, with a few, large values for the number of FATs as 20 well as GDP. Among the countries with the largest GDP, are France, the UK, Spain and Italy. This is a reasonable result as these countries are relatively large by size. Also, as can be expected, the variables skilled labour is readily available and university education meets the needs of a competitive economy are also skewed to the right. Few countries have reached a high level of development which also score very well compared to other, laggard regions. As all these values display larger means compared to their medians, it can be expected that a high number of FATs is related to the GDP level, the skilled labour availability and the university educational quality. An example of one of the more developed economies studied is France. For the year 2008, it portrayed the largest GDP of the whole data series of 3,632 US $ Billion, which is larger than the mean value of 760.08. Also, a rather high compensation level of 26.66 is found, which is also above the average of 16.12, as well as one of the largest labour productivities of 53, compared to the sample mean of 35.77. Skilled labour is more readily available than in other countries, with a score of 6 compared to the mean of 5.37. University education importance as well as the population with a tertiary education level is above the mean, with a score of 6.25 and 21.18 respectively. All the other variables are skewed to the left. Bulgaria had the tenth lowest GDP for the whole sample in the year 2006, with a score of 33.21. As a laggard region, it scored 15 for the tax rate, an hourly wage of $1.15 was paid, and the labour was also not so productive with a score of $12 for its product per person. The labour force seems to be under-educated with a score of 18.2, which is lower than the mean. The language skills seem not to be meeting the needs of a competitive environment with a score of 5.33, which is below the average of 5.84. As both the predictors and the number of FATs have skewed distributions, evidence in support of the notion that the data is not normal is provided. This is one reason why specifying an Ordinary Least Squares regression for the sample would be rather limiting. 21 ii) Binary Logistic Regression Results and Assumption Tests When performing logistic analysis, several methods are available. The Backward Likelihood Ratio stepwise method has been used here. Initially a full model is estimated, including all the variables in the regression. At each step, one by one, it excludes the variables which are insignificant from the model. It tests which variables to remove by inspecting whether the removal of one of the variables increases or decreases the explanatory power of the model. The first explanatory variable which will be removed is the one which has the smallest effect on the model fitting the data. This method is preferred over other methods which start the model with only the constant, and test each variable and its explanatory power for the model individually. It is preferred because of so called ‘suppressor effects’, which means that variables may only be significant once other factors are kept constant. Therefore, the Backward L.R. method is better as it is less likely to make a Type II error of rejecting a variable from the model as insignificant when indeed it is significant. Each step differs from the previous by one degree of freedom, as one variable is excluded at each step. A total of 4 steps have been regressed. The high number of FATs range is taken as the reference category, so the regressions are used to explain the low number of FATs. The results from the first stepwise regression are presented in Table 4. The Wald statistic tests whether or not the independent variables used in the regression significantly add to the model. From the 9 predictor variables used in the regression, only 3 are significant; the corporate tax rate (p=0.020), number of foreign languages (p=0.016) and the GDP level (p=0.036). The corporate tax rate has a positive B-coefficient of 0.452. This means that the higher the corporate tax rate charged on income, the higher the probability a low number of FATs in a country is present, as is found in Voget (2011). This seems sensible, as FATs would be discouraged to locate in countries where their income is highly taxed. Furthermore, the amount of GDP a country produces has a Bcoefficient of -0.002. If a country has a large economy and produces a large amount of domestic product, then the probability of having a low number of FATs in a country is low. A strong economy can attract FATs as it can help drive more revenue. Usually, a large economy has an efficient infrastructure and a large number of efficient enterprises, so these FATs can gain from agglomeration effects of other firms as well as other market efficiencies as is found in Crozet et al (2003). The variable number of foreign languages known is also significant (p= 0.028), with a B-coefficient of 2.543, which suggests that the more foreign languages that the society knows, the higher the probability of having a low number of FATs located in a 22 country. The data for this variable is only on people who have a tertiary education, which may bias the results. There is no specific rule that FATs only hire people with a university education. Also, the number of foreign languages is measured to be at least one or more foreign languages. However, FATs will most probably base their hiring decision on the proficiency in the language most used by the FAT. As long as the person can speak the language which the FAT uses, this may be sufficient to hire that person. These results should be interpreted with caution as there may also be a problem with suppressor effects. The constant of the model is insignificant, but interpreting it would be unreasonable as many variables with different measurement levels have been included. The results from the 4th model can also be found in Table 4, after most of the insignificant variables have been removed. A total of 6 predictors are significant. The factors corporate tax rate (p=0.003), number of foreign languages (p=0.029) and the GDP level (p=0.011) are significant once again, and their effects can be interpreted the same way as in for Model 1. What is interesting of this model is that the Compensation Level US$ (p=0.088), Productivity of Labour US$(p=0.027) and University Education Importance (p=0.025), at the 10% significance level, are also significant once the Availability of Skilled Labour and Persons with Tertiary Education % are excluded from the model. The B-coefficient for the Compensation Level US$ is 0.194 which means that as the wage increases so does the probability of having a low number of FATs. This result is quite intuitive, as the high wages would cause the returns on the invested amount on the new subsidiary to be relatively low. This is in line with previous research done by Faggio (2001), where it is found that German MNEs consider locations with lower wages more attractive. It seems the variables Availability of Skilled Labour and Persons with Tertiary Education %, which are excluded from the analysis, have suppressing effects on the wage level, especially since they are also social factors which influence the work force. The B-coefficient for the Productivity of Labour US$ is -0.258 and University Education Importance has a B-coefficient of -0.901, which means that an increase in these variables decreases the probability of having a low number of FATs. This finding is in line with those of Siedschlag et al. (2009), who find that education is a major concern for R&D multinationals. It is reasonable to assume that the factors excluded have an effect on these newly significant variables. As these variables were not significant while the other social factors were included, the new findings of Model 4 should be interpreted with caution. 23 The odds ratio, Exp(B) can also be found in Table4. They serve the same purpose as the B-coefficient, only that their size effects are interpreted differently. The Exp(B) for the significant variables in Model 4, corporate tax rate (1.704), compensation level US$ (1.214) and number of foreign languages (8.440) ,are greater than 1. This indicates that as these variables increase, the odds of having a low number of FATs increase. Further research is required to make any assumptions regarding these outcomes, especially for the number of languages spoken. FATs do not necessarily have to make their hiring decision on the number of foreign languages a person speaks. As long as the candidate is proficient in the language most widely used by the company, the candidate may stand a chance to be hired by the FAT. For the GDP (0.998), Productivity of Labour US$ (0.772) and University Education Importance (0.406), the Exp(B) coefficients are smaller than 1. This means that as these variables increase the chances of having a low number of FATS decreases. It could be assumed that a larger marketplace with a larger GDP may attract more FATs. This may lead to agglomeration effects as found in Crozet et al. (2003) and Brülhart et al (2012). Also, if the labour is more productive and can produce more per hour than other countries, FATs may choose to locate in these countries over others. Furthermore, if firms in a country consider a university diploma to be of high value in order to make an economy strong, then the government may invest more in educational policies in order to make university education free or relatively cheap. University education may then be made available for all, or a relatively large portion of the population. Due to these reasons, FATs may wish to situate themselves in regions which apply similar policies as the population may be better educated. With regards to which model better explains the dependent number of FATs per country, Model 1 is preferred over 4. The tests for goodness of fit can be found in Table 5. The Omnibus Chi-Square statistic supports this preference, as Model 1 has a statistic of 32.435 (p=0.000) which is greater than that of Model 4 with 30.547 (p=0.000). Similarly, the Hosmer & Lemeshow test also show evidence in favour of Model 1. This test favours models with a higher significance level than 0.05 or a lower Chi-square statistic. For Model 1, a smaller statistic of 5.158 (p=0.741) is found compared to 8.631(p=0.576) which shows evidence for this choice over Model 4. In Table 5, R Squared information for each model has been provided to seek further evidence for this choice. The -2 Log Likelihood for Model 1 is lower than that of Model 4 with a statistic of 42.300 compared to 44.239, respectively, suggesting that Model 1 is better at predicting the outcome variable. The Cox &Snell and Nagelkerke R Square statistics also show proof that Model 1 is more powerful in predicting 24 the outcome. The Cox & Snell R Square shows a larger value for Model 1 of 0.452 compared to 0.432 for Model 4. This means that Model 1 can explain 45.2% of the resulted low or high number of FATs, which is greater than that of Model 4 with 43.3%. Likewise, the Nagelkerke R Square shows that Model 1 can explain 60.3% of the outcome variable, whereas Model 4only explains 57.6%. This surprising result may simply be due to the fact that Model 1 includes more variables, and therefore explains the data set in a better way. For a logistic regression to hold, a number of possible problems need to be tested for. Firstly, the assumption of linearity should hold. To test this, interaction terms are specified where the continuous variables are multiplied by their corresponding logarithms. If the interaction effects of the variables are significant, these variables are not linear. The variables population with tertiary education and language skills meet the needs of the enterprise are not linear as their significance levels are smaller than the critical value of 0.05. These results can be found in Table 6 in the Appendix. As these variables have been insignificant in the models specified above, overall, the assumption of linearity holds. Another assumption which should hold is that of multi-collinearity. To test whether this holds, a linear regression with the same predictor variables has been regressed. The results in Table 7 show that multi-collinearity is not a major problem. In accordance with the suggestion made in A. Field (2009) that correlation larger than 0.8 is a cause for concern, none of the variables seem to exceed this value. The Eigenvalues and Condition Indices have also been inspected to test for multi-collinearity. The results for these estimates are in Table 8. For Model 1, the last Eigenvalue is 0.005 which is smaller than 0.01 so this may be a cause for concern. For the same 10th dimension, the Condition Index shows a value of 42.326 which is great than 30. This shows that multi-collinearity may be a problem. Furthermore, in Table 9, the Tolerance and Variance Inflation Factors (VIFs) have been inspected. The VIF indicates whether a variable has a linear relationship with any of the other variables. The Tolerance statistic is simply the reciprocal of the VIF. The VIF values higher than 10 show multi-collinearity. For Model 1, except for the Productivity of Labour (US$), with a VIF of 11.873, none of the other variables seem to suffer greatly from collinearity. Also, no tolerance value for any of the other variables, except Productivity of Labour US$ with a value of 0.084, are lower than 0.1. It has been found that the higher the labour productivity the higher the probability of having a high number of FATs in a country. This variable only became significant once other social factors on the labour force were 25 removed. The VIF and Tolerance values also provide evidence that labour productivity is correlated to other explanatory variables in the model. Although it seems logical that a productive work force increases the probability of having a high number of FATs in a country, policy implications should be concluded from this result with caution. ii) OLS results and Assumption Tests The OLS results can be found in Table 9. A similar backward stepwise model has been used as with the binary logistic regression, where the variable which adds the least to the explanatory power of the model is excluded at each step. Table 9 shows the three variables which were significant in the first model of the binary logistic regression which are also significant in Model 1 of the OLS estimation. The corporate tax rate (p=0.057) and the number of foreign languages known (p=0.000) have a negative effect on the number of FATs. An increase in either the tax rate or the number of foreign languages known decreases the number of FATs that are present in a country. This result seems rather intuitive for the tax rate. The results for the number of foreign languages spoken is rather surprising, just like for the binary logistic regression. Increasing the number of foreign languages spoken decreases the number of FATs in a country. This result should carefully be considered. It is possible that such a surprising result may be due to the fact that this data is self-reported. It may also be the case that firms are only interested in the skills of the specific language which the company uses. As long as the level of knowledge of this particular language is sufficient, the communication between employer and employee should be satisfactory. The GDP level (p=0.011), displays a positive effect on the number of foreign enterprises in a country, in line with the previous results from the binary logistic regression. In Model 1, two social factors are rendered significant in the OLS model, which were previously insignificant in the logistic regression. The Availability of Skilled Labour (p=0.020) is found to have a positive effect on the number of FATs present. The skill level should not be interpreted as synonymous with the level of education. A skilled labour force may be due to the gain in experience rather than the education achieved. It seems that firms are attracted to a skilled labour force. Perhaps firms who locate in Europe are headquarters of the company and would require highly skilled workers to make decisions concerning the entire company. Also, these firms may be involved in the service sector, which requires highly skilled workers, unlike in the manufacturing sector for example. The Persons with Tertiary Education % (p=0.010) factor has a significantly negative effect on the number of 26 FATs in a country. However, firms may hire people with a lower educational achievement, such as the upper or lower secondary. The factors which are insignificant are Compensation Level US$(p=0.762), Productivity of Labour US$(p=0.979), Language Skills are Meeting the Needs of Enterprises (p=0.897) and University Education Importance (p=0.897). It seems the wages paid, how much a worker produces and whether the language skills of the labour force are sufficient, are not important for FATs when they decide on where to locate to. Also, whether tertiary education is considered important or not in a country, and whether or not policies make it accessible to all, is unimportant for the FATs when they choose where to locate. This may be due to the fact that firms hire workers who are not university graduates, but rather those who graduated from an upper secondary education. In the fourth model specified for the OLS regression, the three variables with the highest p-values, the Compensation Level US$, Productivity of Labour US$ and Language Skills are Meeting the Needs of Enterprises, have been removed. All the variables which were significant in the first OLS model are significant once again, with the same signs of the coefficients affecting the number of FATs per region. Once these variables are excluded the variable University Education Importance (p-value=0.001) becomes significant. Its effect on the number of FATs present is positive. It seems that the variables removed in Model 4 suppressed the effects of this variable on the MNE location decision. This may be the reason why this variable was insignificant in the first model. In order to make any generalizations beyond this data, a number of assumptions have to be checked for the data. Firstly the normality assumption is tested, the results of which can be found in Table 10a. The Kolmogorov-Smirnov test statistic has been used to do this, where a normal distribution exists if the null hypothesis of normality is not rejected, and the significance level is greater than 0.05. According to this test, this assumption is violated for the dependent number of FAT (p=0.004). Nearly none of the explanatory variables comply with the normal distribution. Except for the Availability of Skilled Labour (p-value=0.200), University Education Importance (p-value=0.088) and the variable Language Skills are Meeting the Needs of Enterprises (p-value=0.200), all other variables are not normally distributed. To try and correct for this, the logarithms of the explanatory variables are computed. The results can be found in Table 10b. This specification only seems to correct for the non-normal distribution of the number of FATs (p-value=0.200). The other two variables which were previously normal still appear normal except the Number of Foreign Languages 27 Known %.. It is excluded from this analysis as it is a dummy variable, and taking the logarithm of it would create a constant variable. The Durbin-Watson statistic in Table 11 test checks whether the data display independent errors. A statistic smaller than 1 is considered to be troublesome, and proves that this assumption is violated. However, with the statistic of 1.081 displayed in Table 11, evidence in support of this assumption is provided. Three different methods have been used to check whether the dataset suffers from heteroskedasticity. In Figure 1 in the Appendix, a scatter-plot of the standardized residuals versus the standardized predicted variables has been made. This graph seems to display no problem of heteroskedasticity. Next, the assumption of homoskedasticity is explored with the Levene’s test Statistic. For this assumption to hold the p-values obtained should be greater than the critical value of 0.05. Except for the dependent variable FAT (p-value=0.000) and the two variables on the language factors, Language Skills are Meeting the Needs of Enterprises (p-value=0.030) and Number of Foreign Languages Known (p-value=0.000), all factors seem to comply with the assumption of homoskedasticity. However, this method is an ad hoc, proxy method which actually tests for homogeneity of the variances. If it is violated, it is likely that a problem of heteroskedasticity may exist. Due to this, the more formal White test is also specified, which tests the null hypothesis of homoskedasticity and can be found in Table 12. With the probability of 0.008 the null hypothesis is rejected. The different methods seem to display contrasting results on whether homoskedasticity is a problem for the dataset used. Hence this implies that the conclusions made beyond this dataset could possibly be weaker, and therefore general conclusions should be drawn with caution. As tested for in the binary logistic regression, it is found that multi-collinearity is also a problem in the model, but only for the variable on labour productivity. Hence, the results estimated for the linear regression as well as for the binary regression need to be interpreted with caution. 5. Conclusion In line with findings from previous literature by Hartman (1984) and Slemrod (1990), it seems that the corporate tax rates affect the number of FATs in a country negatively. Therefore, MNEs do consider this factor when choosing where to locate subsidiaries. Furthermore, the higher the GDP level the higher the chance that many FATs locate to a 28 certain country, as is found in the study by Hajkova et al. (2006). The effects on wages are similar to the findings from previous literature, such as that by Faggio (2001). Low wages seem to attract MNEs to locate to certain countries, as they will have lower costs, and therefore higher overall profit levels. As is found by Siedschlag et al (2009), a skilled labour force also attracts MNEs. As the study is on a European level, perhaps the firms who choose to situate in this continent are involved in the provision of services. Hence they may decide between European countries, after already having chosen to locate in Europe. The result on the university education importance is also similar to that of Siedschlag et al (2009), where it has a positive effect in attracting FATs. With regards to the finding that a higher number of foreign languages spoken leads to fewer FATs, more research is required to make any policy implications. This may be because MNEs only require the workers to speak the language which the firm uses in its daily activities. This result may also be due to the fact that this data is available only for tertiary education graduates. Perhaps firms also hire graduates from the lower and higher levels of education. Furthermore, although the intuitive result obtained that more productive labour attracts more FATs is rather intuitive, further research is required to make any general assumptions, as this variable suffers from collinearity to the other variables. The remarkable finding that a higher educated workforce leads to a lower number of FATs also requires further research. Although theoretically predicted, no evidence is found in favour of the statement that a nation with a high tertiary education level would attract more MNEs. Instead, a highly educated population seems to have a repulsive effect on the location choice of MNEs. As shown in Table 11, the independent variables used in this study help explain about 60% of the number of FATs. This means that there are many unobserved and possibly spurious factors which are not accounted for. Future research should focus on not only economic but social factors, as this study has shown that both may have some explanatory power for the MNE and its location decision. 29 6. References Barrios S., H. Huizinga, L. Laeven, G. Nicodeme, 2009, International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 7047 Basile R., D. Castellani , A. Zanfei, 2008, Location Choices of Multinational Firms in Europe: The Role of EU Cohesion Policy, Journal of International Economics, vol. 74 (2008) pg 328–340 Basile R., D. Castellani , A. Zanfei, 2003, Location Choices of Firms in Europe: The Roel of National Boundaries and EU Policy, Centro Studi Luca D’Agliano Development Studies Working Papers, No. 183, ISAE Rome & University of Urbino Bruinsma F., P. Rietveld, 1993, Urban Agglomerations in European Infrastructure Networks, Urban Studies, vol. 30, no. 6, pg 919-934 Brülhart, M., M. Jametti, K. Schmidheiny, 2012, Do Agglomeration Economics Reduce the Sensitivity of Firm Location to Tax Differentials? The Economic Journal, Blackwell Publishing Crozet M., T. Mayer, J.L. Mucchielli, 2003, How do firms agglomerate? A study of FDI in France, Regional Science and Urban Economics,vol.34, pg27–54 Davis J., J.V., Henderson, (2003), Headquarters’ Location Decisions, Working Paper, Brown University Devereux M., R. Griffith, H. Simpson, 2007, Firm location decisions, regional grants and agglomeration externalities, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 91, Issues 3–4, pg 413-435 Directive 2004/38/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council, Official Journal of the European Union, vol.158: pg 77-123 Faggio G., 2001, Foreign Direct Investment and Wages in Central and Eastern Europe,CEP Field, A. 2009, Discovering Statistics Using SPSS, Third Edition, Sage Publications Ltd, Los Angeles, London, New Delhi, Singapore, Washington DC. Fortune global 500, 2007, “Top Cities”, July 23, http://money.cnn.com/magazines/fortune/global500/2007/cities/ (downloaded 11th July 2012) 30 Guimarães P., O. Figueiredo, D. Woodward, 2000, Agglomeration and the Location of Foreign Direct Investment in Portugal, Journal of Urban Economics, vol.47, pg 115-135. Grubert, H. and J. Mutti (1991), “Taxes, Tariffs and Transfer Pricing in Multinational Corporate Decision-Making”, Review of Economics and Statistics 73, pg 285-293. Hajkova, D., G. Nicoletti, L. Vartia, K. Yoo, 2006, Taxation, Business Environment and FDI Location in OECD Countries, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, no. 502 Hartman, D.G. (1984), Tax Policy and Foreign Direct Investment in the United States, National Tax Journal, vol.37, pg 475-488. Hines, J.R. (1996), Altered States: Taxes and the Location of Foreign Direct Investment in America, American Economic Review, vol. 86, and pg. 1076-1094. Konings, J., A. P. Murphy, 2006, Do Multinational Enterprises Relocate Employment to Low Wage Regions? REVIEW OF WORLD ECONOMICS, vol. 142, no. 2, pg 267-286 Laamanen T., T. Simula, S. Torstila, 2012, Cross-border Relocations of Headquarters in Europe, Journal of International Business Studies, vol. 43, pg187–210 Mariotti s., L. Piscitello, 1995, Information Costs and Location of FDIs within the Host Country: Empirical Evidence from Italy, Journal of International Business Studies , Vol. 26, No.4,pg 815-841 Mejer L., S. Boateng, P. Turchetti, 2010, Population and Social Conditions, Eurostat Statistics in Focus, vol.42, pg 1-11 OECD, 2007, Tax Effects on Foreign Direct Investment: Recent Evidence and Policy Analysis, OECD, Paris Pain, N. and G. Young (1996), Tax Competition and the Pattern of European Foreign Direct Investment, mimeo, National Institute of Economic and Social Research Scholes M.S., M.A. Wolfson (1990), The effects of changes in tax law on corporate reorganisation activity, Journal of Business, vol. 63, pg. 141-164. 31 Siedschlag I., S. Donal, C. Turcu, X. Zhang, 2009, What Determines the Attractiveness of the European Union to the Location of R&D Multinational Firms? Working Paper, Economic and Social Research Institute, Dublin & Faculty of Economics, France Slemrod, J. (1990), “Tax Effects on Foreign Direct Investments in the United States: Evidence from a Cross-Country Comparison”, in Razin and Slemrod (eds.), Taxation in the Global Economy, pg 79-117, Chicago University Press Swenson, D.L. (1994), The Impact of US Tax Reform on Foreign Direct Investment in the United States, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 54, pg243-266. Swenson, D.L. (2001a), Transaction Type and the Effect of Taxes on the Distribution of Foreign Direct Investment in the United States, in Hines (ed.), International Taxation and Multinational Activity, 89-109, Chicago University Press Stöwhase, S. (2003b), Profit Shifting Opportunities, Multinationals, and the Determinants of FDI, Working Paper, Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität, Munich Van Dijk, J., P. Pellenbarg, 2000, Firm Relocation Decisions in the Netherlands: An Ordered Logit Approach, 39th European Congress of the Regional Science Association, Papers in Regional Science, vol.79, pg.191-219 Voget, J., 2011, Relocation of headquarters and international taxation, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 95, pg. 1067–1081 Welch D., L. Welch, and R. Piekkari, 2005, Speaking in Tongues: The Importance of Language in International Management Process, International Studies of Management. & Organization, vol. 35, no. 1, pg. 10–27 32 7. Appendix Table 1: Country FAT Statistics Year Country Austria Belgium Bulgaria Czech Republic Denmark Estonia Finland France Ireland Italy Lithuania Netherlands Poland Romania Slovakia Slovenia Spain Sweden United Kingdom 2006 5,433 17,017 3,292 753 2,360 19,726 13,310 2,291 4,535 2,625 1,868 5,212 9,674 17,140 2007 8,510 1,459 11,648 16,191 3,166 826 2,536 19,223 13,429 5,320 5,352 5,418 3,004 2,032 10,311 19,330 2008 8,653 1,500 13,297 16,777 3,503 863 2,722 17,260 3,205 13,413 2,619 5,810 5,980 11,396 3,624 2,174 7,497 11,194 22,407 2009 8,773 13,915 22,871 3,296 800 2,805 16,715 3,451 13,136 5,989 6,058 25,835 3,483 2,171 8,712 11,772 21,516 Table 2:Model fit for data beginning from 2006 and 2007 Omnibus Cox & Hosmer and ChiSnell R Lemeshow square Square Test Data from 2006 Data from 2007 34.621 .338 6.582 23.183 .308 12.178 33 Table 3: Descriptive Statistics Mean 8,800 24.76 760.08 16.12 35.77 Median 5,895 25.75 311.27 18.29 40.82 Std. Deviation 6,959 7.05 981.57 11.17 11.84 Minimum 753 10.00 16.81 1.15 11.99 Maximum 25,835 39.63 3623.69 49.53 53.39 FAT Corporate tax rate GDP Compensation level (hourly) Labour productivity N 73 73 73 73 73 Skilled labour is readily available 73 5.37 5.31 1.16 2.25 7.92 University education importance 73 5.52 5.38 1.40 2.50 8.13 Persons with tertiary education 73 21.18 21.85 6.73 9.60 31.60 Number of foreign languages known (self-reported) 73 0.67 1.00 0.47 0.00 1.00 Language skills are meeting the needs of enterprises 5.96 1.79 2.45 8.72 73 5.84 34 Table 4: Results of Binary Logistic Regression 95% C.I.for EXP(B) Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Corporate tax rate on profit B .454 S.E. .196 Wald 5.389 df 1 Sig. .020 Exp(B) 1.575 Lower 1.073 Upper 2.310 GDP US$ (Billions) -.002 .001 4.393 1 .036 .998 .996 1.000 Compensation Level US$ .133 .104 1.620 1 .203 1.142 .931 1.401 Productivity of Labour US$ -.202 .137 2.192 1 .139 .817 .625 1.068 Availability of Skilled Labour University Education Importance Persons with Tertiary Education % Number of Foreign Languages Known % -.374 .581 .413 1 .520 .688 .220 2.150 -1.018 .636 2.562 1 .109 .361 .104 1.257 .112 .097 1.338 1 .247 1.118 .925 1.352 2.543 1.057 5.790 1 .016 12.723 1.603 100.9 Language Skills are Meeting the Needs of Enterprises Constant .169 .522 .105 1 .746 1.184 .426 3.291 -2.399 2.594 .855 1 .355 .091 Corporate tax rate on profit .458 .191 5.726 1 .017 1.580 1.086 2.299 GDP US$ (Billions) -.002 .001 6.825 1 .009 .998 .996 .999 Compensation Level US$ .126 .101 1.566 1 .211 1.134 .931 1.381 Productivity of Labour US$ -.201 .135 2.215 1 .137 .818 .628 1.066 Availability of Skilled Labour University Education Importance Persons with Tertiary Education % Number of Foreign Languages Known % -.329 .566 .339 1 .560 .719 .237 2.180 -.870 .421 4.281 1 .039 .419 .184 .955 .111 .096 1.324 1 .250 1.117 .925 1.349 2.501 1.054 5.634 1 .018 12.192 1.546 96.139 Constant -2.324 2.603 .797 1 .372 .098 Corporate tax rate on profit .493 .187 6.949 1 .008 1.637 1.135 2.362 GDP US$ (Billions) -.002 .001 6.816 1 .009 .998 .996 .999 Compensation Level US$ .132 .099 1.782 1 .182 1.142 .940 1.387 Productivity of Labour US$ -.243 .118 4.259 1 .039 .784 .623 .988 University Education Importance Persons with Tertiary Education % Number of Foreign Languages Known % -.927 .417 4.949 1 .026 .396 .175 .896 .113 .095 1.400 1 .237 1.119 .929 1.349 2.350 .995 5.580 1 .018 10.487 1.492 73.711 Constant -3.107 2.222 1.956 1 .162 .045 Corporate tax rate on profit .533 .181 8.637 1 .003 1.704 1.194 2.431 GDP US$ (Billions) -.002 .001 6.533 1 .011 .998 .996 .999 Compensation Level US$ .194 .114 2.911 1 .088 1.214 .972 1.516 Productivity of Labour US$ -.258 .117 4.862 1 .027 .772 .614 .972 University Education Importance Number of Foreign Languages Known % -.901 .402 5.022 1 .025 .406 .185 .893 2.133 .978 4.754 1 .029 8.440 1.241 57.408 Constant -2.181 2.184 .997 1 .318 .113 35 Table 5 :Goodness of Fit Tests Omnibus Tests of Model Coefficients -2 Log likelihood Cox & Snell R Square Nagelkerke R Square Hosmer and Lemeshow Test Model 1 Model 4 32.435 30.547 42.300 44.239 0.452 0.432 0.603 0.576 5.158 (0.741) 8.631 (0.576) Note: The figures in brackets represent significance values Table 6 : Linearity Test B -2.129 Sig. .129 .006 .149 1.243 .285 Productivity of Labour US$ by Log .717 .525 Availability of Skilled Labour by Log .534 .931 University Education Importance by Log -5.624 .389 Persons with Tertiary Education % by Log 2.699 .038 -17.855 .006 -46.612 .073 Corporate tax rate on profit % by Log GDP US$ (Billions) by Log Compensation Level US$ by Log Language Skills are Meeting the Needs of Enterprises by Log Constant 36 Table 7 :Correlation Matrix Compensation Level US$ Productivity of Labour US$ Availability of Skilled Labour University Education Importance Persons with Tertiary Education % Number of Foreign Languages Known % Language Skills are Meeting the Needs of Enterprises Constant -.379 .193 .219 .170 -.458 .168 -.333 -.227 -.114 -.379 1.000 -.584 .431 -.740 .259 -.424 -.024 .237 -.024 Compensation Level US$ .193 -.584 1.000 -.012 .172 -.095 .050 -.155 -.286 .490 Productivity of Labour US$ .219 .431 -.012 1.000 -.681 .024 -.264 -.364 .055 .207 Availability of Skilled Labour .170 -.740 .172 -.681 1.000 -.461 .268 -.044 .006 -.059 University Education Importance -.458 .259 -.095 .024 -.461 1.000 .048 .005 -.305 -.237 Persons with Tertiary Education % .168 -.424 .050 -.264 .268 .048 1.000 -.164 -.389 -.742 Number of Foreign Languages Known % -.333 -.024 -.155 -.364 -.044 .005 -.164 1.000 .257 .070 Language Skills are Meeting the Needs of Enterprises Constant -.227 .237 -.286 .055 .006 -.305 -.389 .257 1.000 .162 -.114 -.024 .490 .207 -.059 -.237 -.742 .070 .162 1.000 Corporate tax rate on profit % GDP US$ (Billions) Corporate tax rate on profit % 1.000 GDP US$ (Billions) 37 Table 8: Collinearity Diagnostics Variance Proportions Model1 Model2 Model3 Model4 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Eigenvalue Condition Index Corporate tax rate on profit Maximum tax rate, calculated on profit before tax 8.578 0.705 0.341 0.213 0.056 0.05 0.023 0.016 0.013 0.005 7.61 0.695 0.335 0.213 0.055 0.047 0.018 0.015 0.012 6.711 0.649 0.334 0.187 0.05 0.039 0.018 0.012 5.971 0.643 0.251 0.052 0.041 0.026 0.015 1 3.487 5.017 6.342 12.379 13.112 19.516 23.14 25.549 42.326 1 3.309 4.768 5.984 11.717 12.742 20.511 22.41 24.717 1 3.216 4.482 5.994 11.639 13.05 19.276 23.202 1 3.047 4.876 10.678 12.095 15.221 19.718 0 0 0 0 0 0.01 0.29 0.05 0 0.65 0 0 0 0 0 0.02 0.8 0.03 0.14 0 0 0 0 0.01 0.03 0.81 0.14 0 0 0 0 0.07 0.18 0.75 Gross Domestic Product (GDP) US$ billions 0 0.19 0.11 0 0.04 0.01 0.6 0.01 0.02 0.02 0 0.21 0.1 0 0.06 0 0.37 0.12 0.14 0 0.27 0.11 0.03 0.03 0 0.4 0.15 0 0.29 0.12 0.02 0.01 0.06 0.5 University education meets the needs of a competitive economy Persons with tertiary education attainment and sex (%) 1565yr olds Number of foreign languages known (selfreported) by the highest level of education attained (%) 0 0 0 0 0.06 0.04 0 0.7 0.09 0.1 0 0 0 0 0.08 0.02 0.12 0.77 0 0 0 0 0.01 0.05 0.59 0.32 0.02 0 0 0 0.1 0.44 0.25 0.21 0 0 0 0 0.43 0.1 0.06 0.08 0.24 0.08 0 0 0.01 0 0.36 0.18 0.31 0.01 0.12 0 0 0.01 0.01 0.54 0.02 0.29 0.13 0 0 0.03 0.82 0 0.1 0.04 0 0.06 0.19 0.54 0.05 0 0.06 0 0.01 0.09 0 0.06 0.21 0.55 0.05 0.01 0.1 0.02 0 0 0.09 0.24 0.48 0.06 0.04 0.09 0 0.01 0.08 0.66 0.13 0.04 0.03 0.05 Language skills are meeting the needs of enterprises 0 0 0 0.01 0.06 0.06 0.08 0.44 0.08 0.27 0 0 0 0.01 0.09 0.03 0.01 0.85 0 38 Table 9: OLS Coefficients Model 1 Coefficients Collinearity Statistics B 11559.178 Std. Error 4720.322 T 2.449 Sig. .019 Tolerance VIF -464.674 236.958 -1.961 .057 .176 5.689 3.218 1.206 2.668 .011 .309 3.235 -40.612 133.138 -.305 .762 .193 5.181 Productivity of Labour US$ 5.198 199.986 .026 .979 .084 11.873 Availability of Skilled Labour 2408.170 997.373 2.415 .020 .360 2.780 University Education Importance 1344.606 825.898 1.628 .111 .340 2.943 Persons with Tertiary Education % -428.226 158.242 -2.706 .010 .454 2.203 Number of Foreign Languages Known % -7155.293 1674.016 -4.274 .000 .737 1.358 93.487 719.964 .130 .897 .310 3.229 11558.976 4663.821 2.478 .017 .015 .294 3.406 -460.772 181.148 -2.544 3.222 1.180 2.730 .009 .315 3.173 .687 .376 2.663 .004 .558 1.793 .093 .366 2.733 .007 .477 2.098 .000 .767 1.303 .897 .354 2.829 (Constant) Corporate tax rate on profit % GDP US$ (Billions) Compensation Level US$ Language Skills are Meeting the Needs of Enterprises 2 (Constant) Corporate tax rate on profit % GDP US$ (Billions) Compensation Level US$ -38.200 94.306 -.405 Availability of Skilled Labour 2423.616 791.439 3.062 University Education Importance 1350.341 786.346 1.717 Persons with Tertiary Education % -429.123 152.579 -2.812 Number of Foreign Languages Known % -7164.018 1620.389 -4.421 86.899 665.798 .131 Language Skills are Meeting the Needs of Enterprises 39 Table 9 Continued: OLS Coefficients Model 3 Coefficients Collinearity Statistics B 11619.740 Std. Error 4587.179 t 2.533 Sig. .015 Tolerance VIF -454.918 173.490 -2.622 .012 .313 3.197 3.156 1.053 2.996 .005 .387 2.587 -41.497 89.815 -.462 .646 .405 2.472 Availability of Skilled Labour 2432.928 779.154 3.123 .003 .562 1.779 University Education Importance 1417.467 588.002 2.411 .020 .639 1.564 Persons with Tertiary Education % -429.259 150.821 -2.846 .007 .477 2.098 Number of Foreign Languages Known % -7172.924 1600.341 -4.482 .000 .769 1.301 (Constant) 12696.763 3915.258 3.243 .002 Corporate tax rate on profit % GDP US$ (Billions) -448.717 171.417 -2.618 .012 .315 3.178 3.143 1.044 3.012 .004 .387 2.585 Availability of Skilled Labour 2233.675 643.093 3.473 .001 .811 1.234 University Education Importance 1404.554 582.065 2.413 .020 .641 1.560 Persons with Tertiary Education % -467.862 124.436 -3.760 .000 .688 1.454 Number of Foreign Languages Known % -7191.432 1585.476 -4.536 .000 .769 1.300 (Constant) Corporate tax rate on profit % GDP US$ (Billions) Compensation Level US$ 4 40 Table 10a: OLS Assumption Tests Levene Statistic df1 Sig. KolmogorovSmirnov df Sig. FATs 24.753 1 .000* .154 51 .004* Corporate tax rate on profit % GDP US$ (Billions) Compensation Level US$ Productivity of Labour US$ Availability of Skilled Labour 2.697 1 .107 .124 51 .048* 3.778 1 .058 .350 51 .000* 2.928 1 .093 .170 51 .001* 2.590 1 .114 .195 51 .000* 1.117 1 .296 .066 51 .200* University Education Importance 3.261 1 .077 .115 51 .088 1 .337 .136 51 .020* 1 .000* .425 51 .000* 1 .030* Language Skills are Meeting the 4.967 Needs of Enterprises Note: * represents significance at a critical value of 5% .105 51 .200* Persons with Tertiary Education .939 % Number of Foreign Languages Known % 32.394 Table 10b:Normality Test on Logarithmically Transformed Data Kolmogorov-Smirnov logFAT Statistic .102 df 43 Sig. .200* logTAx .167 43 .004* logGDP .135 43 .049* logCompensationLevel .165 43 .005* logLaborProductivity .222 43 .000* logSkilledLabourAvailability .127 43 .081 logUniImportance .119 43 .135 logEducationLevel .166 43 .004* logLanguageSkills .134 43 .050 Table 11: Model Summary Adjusted R Square .510 Change Statistics F R Square Change Change .598 6.780 Model 1 R .773 R Square .598 2 .773 .598 .522 .000 .001 3 .773 .598 .533 .000 .017 4 .772 .596 .541 -.002 .213 DurbinWatson 1.081 41 Table 12: Heteroskedasticity Test White's test for heteroskedasticity P-value 36.59825 0.008904 Figure 1 : Scatterplot 42