Feldstein Chapter 1: Rising Health $ in US Two questions: 1. How much? 2. Why? Background: 1. What are some of the reasons for the increased demand for medical services since 1965? A. More government insurance: Pre 1965, most healthcare paid privately (80%) and out of pocket (53%). Government paid just 20% (see slides) . Average spending = $210 @ 5.5% of GDP. % w/o health insurance is stuck around 17% today. Post 1965 comes Medicare and Medicaid programs enacted in 1965. These programs reduced out-of-pocket expenses for the aged and the poor; as a result, demand for hospital and physician services dramatically increased. Hospitals had to spend more to meet the growing demand for services, which led to rapid rises in expenditures. By 2014 Federal & State spending = 48.3% of total health care. Spending now = $8700 per person at 17% of GDP. Obamacare will increase spending further, with $ expected to double by 2020. Insured not concerned with total cost of care, just out of pocket cost. The growth in health care spending has consistently been much higher than general inflation (see 2.2), so health care takes a bigger and bigger share of total GDP. B. Advances in medical technology also increased the demand for medical treatment. New methods of diagnosis and treatment were developed, so those with previously untreatable diseases could now have access to technology that offered hope of recovery. C. Aging of population, e.g. elderly just 13% of population but fill 40% of hospital beds. D. Rising incomes lead to increased demand (normal good) for health care and health insurance E. Private employer-paid health insurance has excess demand because: Buying in group better than individual Employer-paid insurance not subject to federal income tax. When employees receive additional income in the form of wages, they pay federal, state, and Social Security taxes and are left with less disposable income. Instead of having their employer pay wage increases in after-tax cash, employees prefer to have their employer spend those same dollars, before tax, to buy additional health insurance. Thus employees can have their out-of-pocket medical expenses paid with before-tax dollars rather than after-tax dollars. This tax subsidy for employer-paid health insurance has stimulated the demand for medical services in the private sector and further increased medical prices. Rising incomes, high marginal tax rates (up to 70%) and inflation increase demand for health insurance as compensation vs. wages Insured not concerned with total cost of care, just out of pocket. 2. How did insurance rules promote inefficiency? In the 1960s and 1970s hospitals were paid their costs plus 2 percent for serving Medicare patients. Private insurers paid in a similar manner. Because hospital costs were reimbursed, there was no incentive to be efficient and reduce expenditures. On the contrary, hospitals actually had an incentive to increase costs. They expanded their capacity, invested in the latest technology, and duplicated facilities and services available in nearby hospitals. Hospital prices rose faster than any other medical service during this period. HMOs & managed care insurers faced barriers in the 1960s and 1970s? o When Medicare and Medicaid were enacted, federal law prohibited Medicare and Medicaid from contracting with HMOs. o Providers could only be paid fee-for-service. HMOs, such as Kaiser, also were paid fee-for-service, not an annual capitated amount per Medicare and Medicaid enrollee. o The government, under Medicare and Medicaid, was not permitted to enroll Medicare or Medicaid beneficiaries in HMOs; enrollees in these two programs had to have free access to any provider. o The AMA had lobbied for these provisions and others limiting HMOS (prepaid group practices): HMOs could not advertise, they had to be nonprofit, and a majority of the Board of Directors of an HMO had to be physicians. The purpose of these restrictions were to prevent HMOs from competing with fee-for-service physicians. 3. Federal efforts to reduce Medicare spending Medicare Part A was funded by a special payroll tax, and the amount collected was insufficient to pay for Medicare hospital expenditures, which rose faster than expected. Feds faced with the following options: increase the payroll tax and the wage base to which it applied, pay hospitals less for treating Medicare patients, or increase fees to Medicare patients. Tried first two options were politically less costly than increasing the burden on the aged. Additional regulatory approaches were also used by federal and state governments to control these rapidly rising expenditures. Medicare utilization review programs were instituted, and controls were placed on hospital investment in new facilities and equipment. However, these government controls proved ineffective; hospital expenditures continued their rapid rise throughout the 1970s. 4. 1980s medical services becomes much more price competitive Reagan efforts to achieve savings in Medicaid o In 1981 removed the “free choice of provider” requirement for Medicaid enrollees; states were able to require their Medicaid population to participate in closed provider panels, enabling them to contract with HMOs and accept bids from hospitals for care of their Medicaid patients. o The “free choice” requirements remained in place for Medicare until the mid-1980s, at which time enrollees were permitted to voluntarily join HMOs. o In 1983, a new Medicare hospital payment system was phased in. Hospitals were no longer paid according to their costs; fixed prices were established for each diagnosticrelated-group (DRG) admission, and each year Congress set an annual limit on the increase in these fixed prices per admission. Since hospitals could keep the difference between their costs and the fixed DRG price, they now had an incentive to reduce their costs for caring for Medicare patients and discharge them earlier. The length of stay per admission fell, and occupancy rates declined. o In 1992 Medicare went to prospective payment for MDs. In the private sector, businesses struggling to survive the recession of the early 1980s focused on reducing labor costs. Because health insurance was the fastest-growing labor expense, businesses put pressure on health insurers to better control both the use and cost of medical services. This led to more outpatient surgery, increases in deductibles and copayments, priorauthorization restrictions, and utilization reviews to reduce costs. These actions greatly reduced hospital admission rates. Between 1970 and 1998, hospital admissions per 1,000 in Blue Cross plans declined from 127 to 71. Physician supply, which increased as a result of the 1960s federal support to medical schools, resulted in physicians having excess capacity and a willingness to join closed provider panels. With excess capacity among suppliers, and demanders determined to reduce employees’ medical expenses, the preconditions for price competition were in place. The applicability of the antitrust laws to healthcare, upheld by the US Supreme Court in 1982, removed any anticompetitive barriers to price competition. Consequences of 1980s changes: o Traditional physician-patient relationship disrupted o Utilization review, limited panels, case management, mandatory use of cheaper substitutes (providers, outpatient, generics) o Big drop in hospitalization & big discounts from providers to insurers o Big increase in competition between insurers. Compete for employer business via price & reputation of networks. o Managed care insurance became dominant (20% of Medicare today, most Medicaid and nearly all private employer plans) 5. 1990s and on starts a new escalations Backlash: public wanted greater access to care, and politicians respond with restrictions on managed care organizations—mandating minimum lengths of stay in the hospital for normal deliveries, for example. The population is aging, technological advances are improving early diagnosis, and new methods of treatment are becoming available, all of which result in higher demand for costly medical services. Costs are also driven up by government regulations at the state and federal levels that mandate minimum care requirements and freer access to specialists. New technology is believed to be the most important force behind rising expenditures. More highly trained medical personnel are needed to handle this technology, and wages must be raised to attract more nurses and technicians to the medical sector. In response to consumer demands for easier access to providers and specialists, health plans have broadened their provider networks, thereby decreasing their ability to negotiate large provider discounts. Hospital mergers that have lessened competition have also enabled these hospitals to increase their prices to health plans. 6. The Affordable Care Act (ACA) briefly Decreased the number of uninsured by expanding Medicaid, offering individual subsidies, and mandates for companies and individuals. Before (2013) ACA, 40-45 million (15%) Americans uninsured. ACA expanded Medicaid eligibility from 100 to 133 percent of the federal poverty level (FPL). Subsidies for people who bought on state & federal exchanges (from 133 to 400 % of FPL). Larger companies must also provide full-time employees coverage. Today 30 million uninsured and uninsured % decreased to 9.2%. Note: most “Red” states did not expand Medicaid.