ECON 100 Tutorial: Week 6 www.lancaster.ac.uk/postgrad/alia10/ a.ali11@lancaster.ac.uk office hours: 3:45PM to 4:45PM tuesday LUMS C85 Past exam questions If an indifference curve is smooth and convex to the origin, then: a) The two goods are said to be convex combinations of each other b) There is a diminishing marginal rate of substitution c) The indifference curve is said to be normal d) None of the above Q5 From Tutorial 4 worksheet: Question 1 Assuming an indifference curve which is convex to the origin, what can this tell us about a consumer’s marginal rate of substitution between coffee and muffins? A profit maximizing firm would like to produce at least the number of units which minimises short run: a) b) c) d) Average total cost Average fixed cost Average variable cost Marginal cost Note: A profit-maximizing firm produces at the efficient scale: the quantity of output that minimizes ATC. We can find this quantity where MC = ATC. Q18 Long Run Exit Condition • In the long run, firms will continue if there is a profit, so the exit condition is: Profit < 0 TR – TC < 0 TR < TC AR < ATC P < ATC Short Run Exit Condition • In the short run, fixed costs are sunk costs and firms will run if there is greater profit from continuing than from exiting. The firm pays the fixed cost whether it continues or exits the market, so the exit condition is: TR – (VC+FC) < -FC TR-VC-FC < -FC TR – VC < 0 TR < VC AR < AVC P < AVC • So a firm’s short run exit condition is P < AVC P, C • Since a firms supply curve is equal to its Marginal Cost Curve, and since MC = AVC at the minimum of AVC, if 0 Q is less than the quantity that minimizes AVC, P will be less than AVC for that Q. MC=S AVC q Suppose demand curve written D=120-2P, and the supply curve is S=20+2P. What is the equilibrium price and quantity? a) b) c) d) P*=70 and Q*=25 P*=25 and Q*=70 P*=50 and Q*=35 P*=35 and Q*=50 Note: Set the two equations equal to each other and solve for P. Plug that value back in to either equation to solve for Q. Q22 Suppose a product has a demand curve written D = 120 – 2P, and the supply curve is S = 20 + 2P. What is the equilibrium price and quantity. Equilibrium occurs where D = S, i.e. 120 – 2P = 20 + 2P 100 = 4P P = 25 Then, substitute P = 25 into either the D or S equation: D = 120 – 2 * 25 = 70 or S = 20 + 2*25 = 70 a. b. c. d. P* = 70 and Q* = 25 P* = 25 and Q* = 70 P* = 50 and Q* = 35 Q* = 35 and P* = 50 Suppose demand is given by D=120-2P and supply is originally S=20+2P but the government imposes a tax of 10 on this good. What happens to the equilibrium price? a) b) c) d) Rises by 10 Rises by 8 Rises by 5 Rises, but it’s not possible to say by how much Q23 We have D=120-2P and S=20+2P Then a tax of 10 is imposed on this good. What happens to the equilibrium price? There are two ways we can solve this. 1. By assuming that the tax is placed on consumers, thus affecting the Demand curve (shifting it to the left) 2. By assuming that the tax is placed on suppliers/sellers, thus affecting the Supply curve (shifting it to the left). I’ll work through both methods in the following slides. We have D=120-2P and S=20+2P Then a tax of 10 is imposed on this good. By assuming that the tax is placed on consumers, thus affecting the Demand curve (shifting it to the left) The new demand curve can be written as: D = 120 – 2(P+T), where T = 10. D = 120 – 2P -20 D = 100 – 2P We then need to find where this new demand curve crosses the supply curve. D=S 100 – 2P = 20 + 2P 80 = 4P P = 20 This gives us the new market equilibrium price. It is the price that the consumers will give to the suppliers for each good purchased. On top of this, the consumers must pay the tax of 10, so the total cost to the consumers will be: P + T = 30. So the actual price consumers pay will rise by $5 because of this tax. We have D=120-2P and S=20+2P Then a tax of 10 is imposed on this good. By assuming that the tax is placed on suppliers, thus affecting the Supply curve (shifting it to the left) The new Supply curve can be written as: S = 20 + 2(P-T), where T = 10. S = 200 + 2P -20 S = 2P We then need to find where this new supply curve intersects with our original demand curve. D=S 120 – 2P = 2P 120 = 4P P = 30 This gives us the new market equilibrium price. It is the price that the consumers will give to the suppliers for each good purchased. From this, the sellers have to pay the government a tax of 10, so the total cost to the consumers will be: P = 30 and the total amount that sellers receive will be 20. So the actual price consumers pay will rise by $5 because of this tax. Suppose D=10/P, work out the price elasticity at P=10 and P = 20 and P=30. a) Not possible to say without knowing what the corresponding level of demand is. b) -1, -2, -3 c) -3, -2, -1 d) -1, -1, -1 Q25 Suppose D=10/P, work out the price elasticity at P=10 and P = 20 and P=30. Because we are asked to find the price elasticity at a specific point, we will use the point elasticity method. The equation for 𝑑𝐷 𝑃 𝐷 point elasticity is: 𝜀 = ∗ Step 1: we can solve 𝑑𝑝 𝑄 𝑑𝐷 for : 𝑑𝑝 D = 10/P = 10𝑃−1 𝑑𝐷 = −1 10 𝑃 −1−1 𝑑𝑝 𝑑𝐷 = − 10 𝑃 −2 𝑑𝑝 𝑑𝐷 10 =− 2 𝑑𝑝 𝑃 Now that we have dD/dp, we can plug it into our point elasticity equation for any value of P and the corresponding Q. Q25 We have solved for 𝑑𝐷 𝑑𝑝 = 10 − 2. 𝑃 Step 2: we need to solve for Q when P = 10 by plugging into the demand equation that was given. D = 10/P D = 10/10 (remember, in equilibrium D = S= Q, so when P = 10, Q = 1)) D=1 Step 3: we can plug all of these parts into the elasticity 𝑑𝐷 𝑃 𝐷 equation : 𝜀 = ∗ 𝑑𝑝 𝑄 10 10 𝜀 𝐷 =− 2 ∗ 𝑃 1 10 10 𝐷 𝜀 =− ∗ 2 (10) 1 10 10 𝐷 𝜀 =− ∗ = 100 1 100 − 100 = -1 To find elasticity when P = 20 and P = 30, repeat steps 2&3. Q25 Suppose supply is perfectly elastic at a price of £10 and the government imposes a tax of £2 on a good whose demand curve is given by D=100-5P. Compute the amount of tax revenue raised, the deadweight loss of the tax, and the change in consumer surplus. a) b) c) d) 10, 80, 90 80, 10, 90 10, 90, 100 10, 75, 85 Q26 Suppose supply is perfectly elastic at a price of £10 (i.e. the S curve is horizontal) and the government imposes a tax of £2 (so the S curve shifts upward by 5) on a good whose demand curve is given by D = 100 – 5P. Compute the amount of tax revenue raised, the deadweight loss of the tax, and the change in consumer surplus. P = 20 – 1/5 D 20 P To find horizontal intercept: 0 = 20 – 1/5 D 1/5 D = 20 D = 100 D 12 10 S’ S 0 D 40 50 100 If P = 10, 10 = 20 – 1/5 D D = 50 If P = 12, 12 = 60 – ½ D D = 40 Continued: Compute the amount of tax revenue raised, the deadweight loss of the tax, and the change in consumer surplus. Tax Revenue: £2 * 40 = 80 20 DWL: ½ * 10 * 2 = 10 P D 12 10 S’ S Tax 0 40 50 D 100 CS = ½ * 50 * 10 = 250 CS’ = ½ * 40 * 8 = 160 CS – CS’ = 90 a) b) c) d) 10, 80, 90 80, 10, 90 10, 90, 100 10, 75, 85 Suppose the TC curve for a firm where TC=12+4Q+Q2 and MR=8. What level of output will the firm produce in order to maximise profit (ie where MC=MR)? a) b) c) d) 0 2 4 8 Q30 Suppose the TC curve for a firm where TC = 12 + 4Q + Q^2 and MR = 8. What level of output will the firm produce in order to maximise profit (i.e. where MC = MR)? Remember the rule slope of Y = b.Xc is c.b.Xc-1 a. b. c. d. 0 2 4 8 TC 12 4Q 2Q 2 MC 4 2Q MR 8 MC MR : 2Q 4 8 2Q 4 Q2 Exam this Friday • 50 minutes: – 30 questions; 20 Caroline, 10 Ian • Check your timetable for exam time and location. • Don’t forget to bring the following items: – Library Card Number – Pencil and Eraser – Basic calculator (no programmable calculators or cell phones will be allowed.) Good Luck! (For next week, check Moodle for a worksheet) This Thursday: Martin Ravallion Edmond D. Villani Chair in Economics, Georgetown University; Research Associate NBER; Non-Resident Fellow CGD; Formerly Director of the World Bank’s Research Department will deliver the Esmée Fairbairn Lecture Entitled The Idea of Anti-Poverty Policy Lecture Theatre 1, Leadership Centre, Management School, 6.00pm Thursday 14th November 2013 Question 1 If the industry under perfect competition faces a downward-sloping demand curve, why does an individual firm face a horizontal demand curve? In a perfectly competitive market, each firm is quite small and unable to affect price on it’s own. We say that firms are price takers. This means that in a perfectly competitive market, P = MR = MC. Question 2 If supernormal profits are competed away under perfect competition, why will firms have an incentive to become more efficient? Improving efficiency can lower costs and lead to positive short run profits, based on the time it takes for competing firms to adopt the more efficient methods. In the long run, profits will go back to zero, however. Question 3 Why is the marginal cost curve of a competitive firm its supply curve? Question 4(a) The following table contains information about the revenues and costs for Ernst’s Golf Ball Manufacturing. All data are per hour. Complete the first group of columns which correspond to Ernst’s production if P = £3. Quantity 0 1 2 3 4 5 TR (P=£3) TC Profit MR (P=£3) (P=£3) MC 1 2 4 7 11 16 Total Revenue = Price X Quantity; Profit = Total Revenue – Total Cost; Marginal Revenue = Change in Revenue/Change in Quantity; Marginal Cost = Change in Cost/Change in Quantity; TR = (P)(Q) Profit = TR – TC MR = (TR2-TR1)/(Q2-Q1) MC = (TC2-TC1)/(Q2-Q1) Question 4(a) The following table contains information about the revenues and costs for Ernst’s Golf Ball Manufacturing. All data are per hour. Complete the first group of columns which correspond to Ernst’s production if P = £3. (TR = total revenue, TC = total cost, MR = marginal revenue, MC = marginal cost) Quantity TR (P=£3) TC Profit MR (P=£3) (P=£3) MC 0 0 1 -1 3 1 1 3 2 1 3 2 2 6 4 2 3 3 3 9 7 2 3 4 4 12 11 1 3 5 5 15 16 -1 Question 4(b) If the price is £3 per golf ball, what is Ernst’s optimal level of production? What criteria did you use to determine the optimal level of production? Quantity TR (P=£3) TC Profit MR (P=£3) (P=£3) MC 0 0 1 -1 3 1 1 3 2 1 3 2 2 6 4 2 3 3 3 9 7 2 3 4 4 12 11 1 3 5 5 15 16 -1 To find the optimal level of production, we find where MR = MC. Optimal production is either two or three golf balls per hour. This level of production maximizes profit (at £2) and it is the level of output where MC = MR (at £3). Question 4(c) Is £3 per golf ball a long-run equilibrium price in the market for golf balls? Explain. What adjustment will take place in the market for golf balls and what will happen to the price in the long run? Answer: No, because Ernst is earning positive economic profits of £2. These profits will attract new firms to enter the market for golf balls, the market supply will increase, and the price will fall until economic profits are zero. Quantity TR (P=£3) TC Profit MR (P=£3) (P=£3) MC 0 0 1 -1 3 1 1 3 2 1 3 2 2 6 4 2 3 3 3 9 7 2 3 4 4 12 11 1 3 5 5 15 16 -1 Question 4(d) Suppose the price of golf balls falls to £2. Fill out the remaining three columns of the table above. Quantity 0 1 2 3 4 5 TR (P=£3) 0 3 6 9 12 15 TC 1 2 4 7 11 16 Profit MR (P=£3) (P=£3) -1 3 1 3 2 3 2 3 1 3 -1 MC 1 2 3 4 5 TR Profit MR (P=£2) (P=£2) (P=£2) 0 -1 2 2 0 2 4 0 2 6 -1 2 8 -3 2 10 -6 Question 4(d) What is the profit-maximizing level of output when the price is £2 per golf ball? How much profit does Ernst’s Golf Ball Manufacturing earn when the price of golf balls is £2? Answer: Optimal production is either one or two golf balls per hour. Zero economic profit is earned by Ernst. Quantity 0 1 2 3 4 5 TR (P=£3) 0 3 6 9 12 15 TC 1 2 4 7 11 16 Profit MR (P=£3) (P=£3) -1 3 1 3 2 3 2 3 1 3 -1 MC 1 2 3 4 5 TR Profit MR (P=£2) (P=£2) (P=£2) 0 -1 2 2 0 2 4 0 2 6 -1 2 8 -3 2 10 -6 Question 4(e) Is £2 per golf ball a long-run equilibrium price in the market for golf balls? Explain. Why would Ernst continue to produce at this level of profit? Answer: Yes. Economic profits are zero, therefore firms will neither enter nor exit the industry. Zero economic profits means that Ernst doesn’t earn anything beyond his opportunity costs of production but his revenues do cover the cost of his inputs and the value of his time and money. Question 4(f) Describe the slope of the short-run supply curve for the market for golf balls. Describe the slope of the long-run supply curve in the market for golf balls. The slope of the short-run supply curve is positive because when P = £2, quantity supplied is one or two units per firm and when P = £3, quantity supplied is two or three units per firm. In the long run, supply is horizontal (perfectly elastic) at P = £2 because any price above £2 causes firms to enter and drives the price back to £2. Question 5(a) Draw the isoquant corresponding to the following table, which shows the alternative combinations of labour and capital required to produce 100 units of output per day of good X. Capital 16 Labour 200 20 160 26.67 120 40 80 60 53.33 80 40 100 32 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 0 50 100 150 200 250 Question 5(b) Assuming that capital costs are £ 20 per day and the wage rate is £10 per day, what is the least-cost methods of producing 100 units? What will the daily total cost be? Given: Solve for: Capital Labour cost of capital cost of labour total cost 16 200 320 2000 2320 20 160 400 1600 2000 26.67 120 533.4 1200 1733.4 40 80 800 800 1600 60 53.33 1200 533.3 1733.3 80 40 1600 400 2000 100 32 2000 320 2320 Price of Capital: £20/day Price of Labor: £10/day The least-cost method of production uses 40 units of Capital and 80 units of Labor. This method costs £1600 per day. Question 5(b) Use Excel to graph, or graph by hand, the isoquant curve and the Isocost lines: 120 100 80 Isoquant Series2 60 Series3 Series4 40 20 0 0 50 100 150 200 250 Question 5(c) Now assume that the wage rate rises to £20 per day. Draw a new series of isocosts. What will be the least-cost method of producing 100 units now? How much labour and capital will be used? Given: Solve for: cost of capital cost of labour total cost Capital Labour 16 200 320 4000 4320 20 160 400 3200 3600 26.67 120 533.4 2400 2933.4 40 80 800 1600 2400 60 53.33 1200 1066.6 2266.6 80 40 1600 800 2400 100 32 2000 640 2640 Price of Capital: £20/day Price of Labor: £20/day The least-cost method of production uses 60 units of Capital and 53.33 units of Labor. This method costs approximately £2,267 per day. Question 6 In a downturn firms want to layoff some workers. This has an effect on productivity (output per employee). On the one hand, it frees up some machinery that the remaining workers can use more flexibly – you don’t have to hang around so much waiting for a machine to become free. On the other hand, workers have to do a wider ranges of tasks because there are fewer workers – so the firm loses some of the advantages of specialisation. Suppose the output of the firm, Q, depends on the number of workers, L, and the number of machines, K, in such a way that Q=LaKb Suppose a=0.4 and b=0.6. Question 6(a) Suppose the output of the firm, Q, depends on the number of workers, L, and the number of machines, K, in such a way that Q=LaKb Suppose a=0.4 and b=0.6. Write down an expression for the average product of labour, APL. HINT: APL=Q/L. We’ll start with: And plug in Q=LaKb for Q: APL=Q/L APL= LaKb /L This can be simplified to: APL = La-1Kb Now we can plug in a=0.4 and b=0.6: APL = L-0.6K0.6 APL = (K/L)0.6 Question 6(b) Now Suppose L=10 and K=10. What is the firm’s output? And its APL? To find the firm’s output, we plug in L=10 and K=10 into our Output function from part (a): Q = LaKb From part (a), we know that a=0.4 and b=0.6, so: Q = L0.4K0.6 Plugging in L=10 and K=10: Q = 100.4100.6 Q = 101 Q = 10 So the firm’s output is 10 units. We solved for APL in part (a): APL = (K/L)0.6 So, we can plug in L=10 and K=10 APL = (10/10)0.6 APL = 1. So the firm’s average product of labor is 1. Question 6(c) If the number of workers is reduced by 1 (i.e 10%) what happens to output? And the APL? So, now L = 9 and K = 10. We will go through the same steps in part (b). From part (a), we know that Q = LaKb and that a=0.4 and b=0.6, so: Q = L0.4K0.6 Plugging in L=9 and K=10: Q = 90.4100.6 Q = 9.6 So the firm’s output has fallen from 10 to 9.6, or it has fallen by 4%. We solved for APL in part (a): APL = (K/L)0.6 So, we can plug in L=9 and K=10 APL = (10/9)0.6 APL = 1.065 So the firm’s average product of labor has gone from 1 to 1.065, or it has risen by 6.5%. Question 7 Cost functions depend on the nature of the firm’s technology (i.e. its production function) and input prices. Suppose beer is produced according to the production function: Q=1.5 L0.4 K0.6 Assume that K is fixed at 100 units in the short run. The price of a unit of K is £8. So fixed cost is £800. Question 7(a) Suppose beer is produced according to the production function: Q=1.5 L0.4 K0.6 Assume that K is fixed at 100 units in the short run. The price of a unit of K is £8. So fixed cost is £800. If K is fixed then, in the short run, show how Q depends on L, and L depends on Q. Q=1.5 L0.4 1000.6 Q = 1.5L0.4(15.8) Q = 24L0.4 To show how L depends on Q, we can solve the above equation for L: Q = 24L0.4 𝑄 24 = L0.4 𝑄 1/0.4 =L 24 𝑄 1/0.4 L= 24 ≈ 0.00035Q2.5 Question 7(b) Suppose beer is produced according to the production function: Q=1.5 L0.4 K0.6 Assume that K is fixed at 100 units in the short run. The price of a unit of K is £8. So fixed cost is £800. The only variable factor is L in the short run. Suppose the wage rate is £25 per unit of L. What is the relationship between VC and output? VC = wL = w L(Q) From part (a) we solved for L and can plug that in: VC = 25 𝑄 1/0.4 24 VC = 0.0089 Q2.5 Question 7(c) Suppose beer is produced according to the production function: Q=1.5 L0.4 K0.6 Assume that K is fixed at 100 units in the short run. The price of a unit of K is £8. So fixed cost is £800. The only variable factor is L in the short run. Derive AVC We know that: AVC=VC/Q We solved for VC in part (b) and can plug that in here: AVC = 0.0089 Q2.5/Q AVC = 0.0089 Q1.5 Question 7(d) Suppose beer is produced according to the production function: Q=1.5 L0.4 K0.6 Assume that K is fixed at 100 units in the short run. The price of a unit of K is £8. So fixed cost is £800. Derive MC. HINT: You will need to find the slope of the VC function. Marginal cost is the slope of variable cost curve, or the derivative of VC: From (b) we know: VC = 0.0089 Q2.5 MC = slope of VC = dVC/dQ dVC/dQ = 2.5*0.0089 Q(2.5-1) =0.022 Q1.5 Question 7(e) Suppose beer is produced according to the production function: Q=1.5 L0.4 K0.6 Assume that K is fixed at 100 units in the short run. The price of a unit of K is £8. So fixed cost is £800. Use Excel to graph MC, AFC, AVC and AC against Q (from a range of Q from 0 to, say 300)