External Adjustment in Small and Large Economies Roberto Chang Econ 336 April 2013 • The last decade witnessed increased global imbalances, especially prior to the global financial crisis. • Also, a fall in world interest rates USA: Current Account (% of GDP) 0.01 0 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 -0.01 -0.02 -0.03 -0.04 -0.05 -0.06 -0.07 Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) 2001 2003 2005 2007 Real Interest Rates, 1999-2006 5.00 4.50 4.00 3.50 3.00 2.50 2.00 1.50 1.00 0.50 Ja n99 Ju l-9 9 Ja n00 Ju l-0 0 Ja n01 Ju l-0 1 Ja n02 Ju l-0 2 Ja n03 Ju l-0 3 Ja n04 Ju l-0 4 Ja n05 Ju l-0 5 Ja n06 Ju l-0 6 0.00 10-Year 3-7/8% Treasury Inflation-Indexed Note. Source: FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Source: Lane and Milesi Ferreti 2006 Source: Lane and Milesi Ferreti 2006 • We can use the theory discussed in class to interpret these developments. • We end up with a theory of world equilibrium. • Main reference: SU, ch. 4 • The starting point is the investment schedule and the savings schedule, which we derived already. The Savings Function Interest Rate S r* S S* Savings Interest Rate An increase in savings. This may be due to higher Y(1). S S S’ S’ Savings The Investment Function Interest Rate I r* I I* Investment An increase in investment, May be due to an increase in the future MPK Interest Rate I’ I r* I’ I I* I** Investment • Recall that the current account is equal to savings minus investment. This suggests putting the two schedules together will give us the current account. Interest Rate Savings and Investment I S S I S, I Interest Rate Savings and Investment I S If the world interest rate is r*, savings are S* and investment I* r* S I S* I* S, I Interest Rate Savings and Investment I S The current account is CA* = S* - I* (a deficit) r* S I S* I* CA Deficit S, I Interest Rate Savings and Investment I S r** If the world interest rate increases to r**, savings increase to S** and investment falls to I** r* S I S* I** S** I* S, I Interest Rate Savings and Investment I S r** The current account is now in surplus, Since CA** = S** - I** r* S I S* I** S** I* CA Surplus S, I Interest Rate I S S I S, I Interest Rate The Current Account Diagram Interest Rate CA I S S I S, I 0 CA = S-I If the world interest rate is rA, the CA is zero CA I S rA S I S, I 0 CA If the world interest rate is r*, the CA is in deficit CA I S rA r* S I S, I 0 CA If the world interest rate is r*, the CA is in deficit CA I S rA r* S I S, I 0 CA If the world interest rate is r**, the CA is in surplus CA I S r** rA S I S, I 0 CA • Now we can ask the question: what can cause a CA deficit? An increase in savings? An increase in investment? An Increase in Savings Interest Rate Interest Rate CA I S S I S, I 0 CA = S-I An Increase in Savings Interest Rate Interest Rate CA I S’ S S S’ I S, I 0 CA = S-I An Increase in Savings Interest Rate Interest Rate CA I S’ S S S’ CA’ I S, I 0 CA = S-I The CA improves, given r* Interest Rate Interest Rate CA I S’ S CA’ r* S S’ I S, I 0 CA = S-I An Increase in Investment Interest Rate Interest Rate CA I S S I S, I 0 CA = S-I An Increase in Investment Interest Rate Interest Rate CA I S S I S, I 0 CA = S-I The CA deteriorates Interest Rate Interest Rate CA I S S I S, I 0 CA = S-I • Note that some changes may cause both the savings schedule and the investment schedule to shift • For example, an increase in the future marginal productivity of capital causes investment to increase and savings to fall. (Savings fall because consumption today must increase, in anticipation of future income). Interest Rate An increase in the future MPK (investment surge) Interest Rate CA I S CA’’ S I S, I 0 CA = S-I Interest Rate If the world interest rate Is r*, the deficit in current account is CA’’, not CA’ CA I S r* S I S, I CA’’ CA’ 0 CA = S-I World Equilibrium • Assume two countries, US and rest of the world (ROW). • It will be useful to graph their CA schedules in the same diagram. The US CA schedule CAUS US Current Account The ROW CA schedule CAROW ROW Current Account • It is convenient, however, to measure the ROW CA in the opposite direction (i.e. positive to the left, negative to the right). • We just “flip the axis.” Interest rate CAROW - + The ROW CA schedule Interest Rate CAROW + - The ROW CA schedule Interest Rate CAROW r* - + CA Surplus in ROW The ROW CA schedule Interest Rate CAROW r* - + CA Deficit in ROW • The world is in equilibrium if CAUS + CAROW = 0 i.e. the US CA surplus or deficit is exactly matched by a ROW deficit or surplus. • The world interest rate adjusts to ensure this equality The US CA schedule CAUS US Current Account Add the ROW CA schedule CAROW ROW CA CAUS US Current Account The world interest rate Is r* CAUS CAROW r* ROW CA US Current Account The world interest rate Is r* CAUS CAROW r* ROW CA US CA deficit = ROW CA surplus US Current Account Application: The US CA Problem • We can use this apparatus to examine two possible explanations of the current US CA situation: low savings in the US, and a “savings glut” in the world (i.e. an increase in savings in the ROW) CAUS CAROW r* ROW CA US CA deficit = ROW CA surplus US Current Account A fall in the US savings rate causes the CA schedule to move to the left. CAUS CAROW r* ROW CA US CA deficit = ROW CA surplus US Current Account The US CA deficit increases, and the world interest rate goes up CAUS CAROW r** r* New US CA deficit US Current Account CAUS CAROW r* ROW CA US CA deficit = ROW CA surplus US Current Account Increased savings in ROW move the CAROW schedule to the left CAUS CAROW CAROW’ r* ROW CA US CA deficit = ROW CA surplus US Current Account The US CA deficit widens, and the interest rate falls. CAUS CAROW CAROW’ r* r** ROW CA The US CA deficit increases US Current Account The Role of Fiscal Policy • Suppose that the government must spend an amount G(1) in period 1 • Assume, for now, that this is financed via lump sum taxes T(1) = G(1) in period 1. • Hence there is no fiscal deficit in period 1. • Under these assumptions, the analysis is exactly the same as if the household’s income in period 1 had fallen by T(1) = G(1). Interest Rate A Tax financed increase in G(1): Effects at Home Interest Rate CAUS I S S I S, I 0 CA = S-I Interest Rate A Tax financed increase in G(1): Effects at Home Interest Rate CAUS I S S I S, I 0 CA = S-I Effect on World Equilibrium New CAUS CAROW CAUS r** r* New US CA deficit US Current Account • One may ask the question: what would happen if G(1) were financed by increased government borrowing (i.e. a fiscal deficit) rather than taxes in period 1? • By definition, this would reduce national savings, if other things were kept equal. • However, other things are not equal. • In particular, future taxes will have to increase to service the national debt. • Households will recognize this fact and adjust (in this case, increase) their savings correspondingly. • In fact, in theory households will increase savings so as to perfectly compensate for the anticipated increase in taxes due to the fiscal deficit. • Hence private savings will increase exactly by the amount of the fiscal deficit • But then national savings do not change!! Ricardian Equivalence • Recap: a deficit financed increase in government expenditure has the same effects as a tax financed increase in G(1). • In this sense, fiscal deficits are irrelevant (once government expenditure is accounted for). • This is known as Ricardian Equivalence. • Chapter 5 of Schmitt Grohe and Uribe’s text discusses Ricardian Equivalence in some detail. (Please read.) Why Ricardian Equivalence May Fail • Households may face borrowing constraints. • The households that benefit from current tax cuts may not be the ones that pay the necessary future tax increases. • Taxes may be not be lump sum. The Economic Report of the President, 2006 “In 2004 the United States ran a current account deficit of $668 billion. This deficit meant the United States imported more goods and services than it exported. The counterpart to the U.S. current account deficit was a U.S. capital account surplus. This surplus meant that foreign investors purchased more U.S. assets than U.S. investors purchased in foreign assets, investing more in the United States than the United States invested abroad. “ Is this statement justified? “The size and persistence of U.S. net capital inflows reflects a number of U.S. economic strengths (such as its high growth rate and globally competitive economy) as well as some shortcomings (such as its low rate of domestic saving).” “The recent rise in U.S. net capital inflows between 2002 and 2004 in part reflects global economic conditions (such as a large increase in crude oil prices) as well as policies (such as China’s exchange rate policy) and weak growth in several other large economies (such as Germany) that led to greater net capital outflows from these countries.” Lessons for policy? “Encouraging greater global balance of capital flows would be helped by steps in several countries. The United States should raise its domestic saving rate. Europe and Japan should improve their growth performance and become more attractive investment destinations. Greater exchange rate flexibility in Asia, including China, and financial sector reforms could increase the role of domestic demand in promoting that region’s future growth.” “In addition, the chapter makes two broader points. First, global capital flows—the flow of saving and investment among countries—should be analyzed from a global perspective and not by considering U.S. economic policies alone. Global capital flows are jointly determined by the behavior of many countries. To understand why the United States receives large net capital inflows requires understanding why countries like Japan, Germany, China, and Russia experience large net capital outflows. A second point is the need to distinguish between marketdriven and policy-driven capital flows. “ An answer (Roubini) “Having the Chutzpah to title this deficit as a capital account surplus and then go on for the entire chapter to interpret all of the global current account imbalances as a matter of capital exporting countries (i.e. countries who run current account surpluses) and capital importing countries (i.e. the few countries who run current account deficits) is to confuse cause and effect. ” “…most of this "inflow" (call it more properly borrowing binge) is coming on net not from willing private foreign investors wanting to invest in U.S. assets but rather from political agents, i.e. foreign central banks that are oblivious to the low returns on U.S. Treasury bills and bonds (and capital losses once the dollar falls) and are lending cheaply to the U.S. Treasury. So much for the rest of the world wanting to buy U.S. assets and we thus generously running a current account deficit to accommodate this portfolio demand for U.S. assets.”