Getting smart about subsidies Markus Goldstein The World Bank Subsidies are all around us Obvious ones such as agriculture, urban transport, fuel But think about the air we breathe (e.g. subsidies for pollution control), the water we drink (subsidies for water utilities) Not all subsidies are bad, but in order to tell the good from the bad we need to think smart. How do we think smart about subsidies? Think systematically What are subsidies and why are they important? Why do we subsidize? Who gets the subsidies? How do we implement subsidies? Why are subsidies important? Subsidies are political Why are subsidies important? A lot of money is spent on subsidies In 2005, the EU was spending 2 euros per cow, per day (puts them above the poverty line) Egypt spent an estimated 6.9% of GDP on fuel subsidies and 1.6% on food subsidies in 2005/6 Subsidies can have big policy effects Malawi removed all primary school fees, enrollment went up by 1 million children over 6 years, and the enrollment gap between rich and poor closed We often view subsidies too narrowly The tendency is to think in terms of producer subsidies (e.g. agriculture) but they apply to both supply & demand A subsidy is when the price is lower than the cost, where the government provides the funds And a tax is a negative subsidy Why subsidize? Do we know why we subsidize? Take the case for subsidizing primary health care: Some would argue it’s a right, so we do it for equity reasons Others would argue market failure, e.g. incomplete information Still others would argue that it is an externality – healthier people are better able to participate in society So the answer is both yes and no – we can see a set of justifications, maybe even more than one for a given subsidy To understand whether a subsidy is working or not, we need to know why -- the main reason why -- we did it in the first place Understanding why a subsidy is in place, also provides grounds for taking the debate into the political realm and dealing with fiscal constraints So why do we actually subsidize? Markets aren’t working right – efficiency We care about the poor – equity There may (or may not) be tradeoffs across these These are tempered by the hard facts of real constraints, in particular: Fiscal constraints Politics Making markets work right Externalities e.g. government subsidies to identify and treat tuberculosis Special case of externalities is public goods e.g. government funds (100% subsidy) national defense Market failures due to information issues e.g. the rationale for subsidizing microcredit Promoting equity Best option: give the poor the cash. But: Administration costs are too high Possible political constraints So we subsidize… But we need to consider what we mean by equity An equity/efficiency tradeoff? Often, but not always Reasons there might not be an equity/efficiency tradeoff: When correcting market failure is not possible or too costly, some redistribution can improve efficiency e.g. think about subsidizing education, Psacharopoulos (1994) estimates returns to primary education of 24 percent in Africa and 20 percent in Asia…we could try to create a credit market to pay for primary education but this is really not feasible. Not always a tradeoff -2 Getting rid of some kind of subsidies can improve both equity and efficiency e.g. In Japan, the average farm hh income is 110% of average hh income, yet over 2000-2 producers received $47.5 bn in subsidies Between 1996-2000, the US government mailed farm subsidy checks to 31 addresses in Beverly Hills and 803 in Washington D.C. For better or worse, equity and efficiency run into politics and real budget constraints… 3 questions to assess the political constraints Who are the winners/losers and who will they vote for (if they vote)? Who are the interest groups around this issue and how much power do they have? What is the time horizon of policy makers? Outcome need not be fair nor efficient Politics in action: food subsidies in Sri Lanka Food subsidy, almost universal from independence Maintained by gov’ts of different ideology in the name of political stability and equity Broad based political support, particularly from organized labor Subsidies to producers as well to keep them happy And making things better could make them worse… 1978-9 large devaluation, new gov’t Implemented means test ½ the pop. Change from rations to food stamps and froze new issues and nominal budget allocation Removed price subsidies Protected wage earners who were no longer getting subsidies through inc. wages (interest groups) But then, benefits erode with inflation…political constituency? (time horizon of policy makers, beneficiaries did not have enough voting power) Three ways to pay the bill 1. Tax and redistribute e.g. Health in Finland taxes from the state (progressive income and indirect) and municipalities Patients pay only 24%, the remainder is financed by local (43%) and national gov’t (18%) and national health insurance (15%) Over 80% of Finns are satisfied with their health care, against EU average of 41% Paying the Bill (2 ) 2. Cross-subsidize Can be within or across sector Gabon: urban electricity subsidizes water and electricity in rural areas and small towns. Ecuador: surcharge on telecom subsidizes water 3. Grants e.g. Tajikistan Pamir Power Project Poor people, low capacity, irregular supply Concession put in place, but move to market prices for power immediately not feasible (500% increase required) Mix of IDA, Swiss and IFC funding for 10 year gradual phase out of subsidized prices Some things you need to know to pay the bill: 1. Tax and redistribute 2. Cross subsidize 3. Grants Tax incidence, tax costs Incidence of benefits, now and post change Elasticity of demand – both for suppliers of funds and beneficiaries Size of financing gap Funding source Exit strategy, since not sustainable Do we know who we subsidize? Primary education is progressive, but higher education is not Country Early Childhood, Preschool Primary Secondary Tertiary Bolivia (2002) Progressive Regressive Regressive Cambodia (1997) Neutral Regressive Regressive Cambodia (2002) Progressive Regressive Regressive Ecuador (1999) Progressive Bell Curve Regressive Progressive Bell Curve Regressive Neutral Regressive Regressive Jamaica (2000) Progressive Madagascar (2001) Overall Neutral Mexico (2002) Progressive Progressive Regressive Regressive Neutral El Salvador (2002) Progressive Progressive Regressive Regressive Progressive Vietnam (1998) Progressive Regressive Vietnam (2002) Progressive Regressive Health varies… Country Type Distribution Bolivia (1999) Social Insurance Regressive Public Expenditure Progressive Health Care IESS Regressive Health Care MSP Relatively Neutral Health Care SSC Progressive Mexico (2002) All Public Health Expenditure Regressive* El Salvador (2002) Hospital Care Relatively Neutral Primary Health Care Progressive Ecuador (1999) Jamaica (19912002) Average Ratio of Poorest to Richest Quintile for Public Hospital Use (Q1/Q5) 1.83 Jamaica (19912002) Average Ratio of Poorest to Richest Quintile for Primary Care Use (Q1/Q5) 0.82 Jamaica (19912002) Average Ratio of Poorest to Richest Quintile for Outpatient Care (Q1/Q5) 1.76 Infrastructure subsidies are clearly regressive… progressive regressive So who do we subsidize? First step is to look at incidence data – what share of the benefits go to an income group? But both the benefits and the costs (taxes) to the individual matter At the national level, adding them up is key… Mexico: Benefits and Taxes 20 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Percent -10 -20 -30 Benefits Taxes -40 -50 -60 Decile 7 8 9 10 To estimate the net effect of public subsidies - tax Mexico: Net Effect 100 80 % of hh income 60 40 20 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 -20 -40 decile 7 8 9 10 How do we implement subsidies? The rationale for the subsidy tells us where to start… If we are doing subsidies for equity reasons we need to target both: Access Affordability If subsidies are justified for efficiency concerns, we need to target: Overcoming/reducing a market distortion Changing behavior And what we need to know Know your poor in order to achieve access and affordability Know your markets (including public goods) when trying to remove distortions Know your elasticity when trying to change behavior We have some (potentially) powerful tools Know your poor (access and affordability) Know your markets (remove distortions) Market assessments, CEM, PSIA, WTP studies Know your elasticities (change behavior) poverty assessments, poverty maps Market assessments, ESW, WTP studies Data is key – household, investment climate, market SURVEYS But what about the constraints? (1) Political economy Know your polity PSIA Keep in mind the political economy can be an opportunity, not only a constraint Use politics to put subsidies on the table and in perspective: e.g. Andhra Pradesh: introduced metering so that subsidy was visible, transparent e.g. Punjab: free power, but part of a fixed agricultural budget What about the constraints (2) Fiscal Know your budget, know your incidence (don’t forget the taxes) CEM, PER For equity: think about real tradeoffs, balance inclusion/exclusion What can make subsidies go wrong (or right)? We need to avoid bad design Badly designed – Information was inadequate/wrong Within the relevant market: Lack of attention to other markets e.g. Cote d’Ivoire water e.g electricity/irrigation in India Question of provider Keep in mind subsidies are about gov’t finance, not provision And the environment matters too Constraints change (good design initially) Budget Political economy e.g. Sri Lanka food Budget constraints tighten Possible opportunity to narrow targeting Or political economy binds and benefits erode In the end good design can have a powerful impact The Bangladesh secondary school stipend Tuition and stipend subsidy for girls for educational costs, supplies, uniforms and transport. Good design: priced well (~1/2 of costs), tied to attendance. The subsidy was put very close to the good it was aimed at. Covered 1.9 million girls in 2004, for around $25 million Resulted in enrollment increases of 8-12 percentage points. To take stock: Not all subsidies are bad… Bad subsidies are bad. To separate the good and the bad, think systematically Understand why we have this subsidy Who is the subsidy for, who is getting it? How is this subsidy improving access, affordability, reducing distortions, or changing behavior. Is this the best feasible way? Benchmark on the counterfactual of no intervention make an informed decision Now how do we decide what to do? Why? Equity Efficiency Equity Will a lump sum transfer work? yes No subsidy no Subsidy for whom? Access Affordability Identify targeting mechanism Identify political constraints and opportunities Identify fiscal constraints & tradeoffs Identify target poor Efficiency Behavior • know elasticities • identify closest and least distortionary policy handle Reduce market distortions Externalities & other MF Public Goods • know markets • gov’t funds these • identify closest and least distortionary policy handle • assess optimal level of provision • identify funding mechanism, fiscal constraints and tradeoffs This is a PREM task Subsidies are everywhere PREM economists have a central role in thinking about them systematically Understanding within sector Adding up across sectors and taxes Helping identify tradeoffs for the gov’t We have an existing set of tools that allow us to tackle these issues