Competition policy, industrial policy and corporate conduct Simon Roberts 3 July 2012 Paper written in personal capacity, does not reflect the views of the Competition Commission Introduction • Expansion of competition laws, vigorously promoted by IFIs, USA o ‘one size fits all’ form aimed at minimal intervention to correct market failures (‘cartels’) • Industrial policy and competition policy conflict or complement? o Competition means removing constraints, industrial policy is about imposing distortions and constraints to meet government’s objectives Or: o Competition requires effective rivalry, this means need a number of firms which might require industrial policy to support entrants and smaller firms • In practice there is great diversity in competition regimes • Are competition institutions only appropriate at a stage of development where they will not be undermined by powerful business interests? o North, Acemoglu & Robinson – competitive markets as part of ‘open access’ (note: antitrust in US promoted by farmers) • I argue that competition policy needs to be viewed in context of policies to address orientation and conduct of big business o Competitive rivalry is important source of discipline o The approach and conditions vary by country Competitive rivalry and industrial development • Orientation of big business is central to countries’ industrial development – Investments to adopt and adapt new technologies, realise economies of scale and scope, build production capabilities, skills – Nature of relations with smaller firms is important for their development also • Rapid industrialisation to ‘catch-up’? – ‘Unbalanced’ growth through interventionist industrial & trade policy; this context is explicit in mandate of Korea FTC – Discipline needed to ensure firms build new capabilities rather than entrench positions to extract rents – the evolution of ‘business enterprise systems’ – Different sources of discipline – using export performance; contests for state support etc, as part of wider framework. – Dynamic rivalry and ‘optimal’ competition – competition relates to behaviour not structure Practice of competition law in developing countries • Competition law, under wider competition policy framework, embodies particular choices • Competition law and tests should depend on country conditions – especially tests for abuse of dominance – Entrenched incumbents? May be created by state, now may be TNC owned. • Competition policy and law in practice reflects local factors, in terms of influences and needs – SA law reflects fear of ‘business confidence’, need for ‘certainty’; and fear of the state – independence and checks – KFTC – took USA law, and adapted it to ‘free and fair competition’, promote ‘balanced development’, meaning a very active set of instruments addressed at large firms, chaebols – New law in 1981, 1987 – addressing ‘unreasonable’ practices and ‘unjustifiable’ restrictions on competition, including subcontracting arrangements – KFTC promoted ‘shared growth’ of large firms and SMEs, synchronised with industrial policy – Other countries with laws not implemented but notionally independent institutions South Africa case study • Two different motivations: – addressing apartheid legacy of concentration of control – as part of making liberalisation work Reflected in tension between broad objectives of law, and specific, narrow provisions relating to particular conduct • Act following international best practice (Australia, Canada, EU) • Independent institutions, with strong legal checks on their action – – – – separate Commission, Tribunal, Appeal Court Mergers – substantial lessening of competition test; public interest test Cartels Abuse of dominance – separately specified contraventions; procompetitive defences • Very concentrated economy: 1994 – Anglo-controlled companies accounting for 43% of JSE; top six conglomerates 84% • Mergers Outcomes? – Pre-merger notification above thresholds meant around 400 merger to evaluate per year main area of work for first 7 years • Cartel prohibition: agreement or concerted practice which is: – direct or indirect price fixing, market division, bid rigging; or – has SLC effect (no penalty for first offence) – Dependent on pro-active enforcement to identify, together with Corporate Leniency Policy 125 leniency applications over three years – cartels coupled with exclusionary strategies • Abuse of dominance: – Exploitative (excessive pricing) – Exclusionary abuses – Over 12 years, only 18 cases referred to the Tribunal, plus 2 settled prior to referral = 20 – long and drawn out cases, extensive legal proceedings, often 3-5 years from referral to hearing. Of the 20 abuse cases: • To date 9 decided and 5 settled • Tribunal found abuse in 6 of 9 cases on which it ruled • 2 over-turned on appeal (Sasol-Nationwide Poles, HarmonyMittal) 4 cases where finding stands: South African Airways (2); Patensie (agric co-op); Senwes (former agric co-op) • 3 of 5 settlements with substantive undertakings (Sasol Nitro, GSK&BI for ARVs, Foskor) • Former state-owned, regulated and/or supported in most cases, protecting existing monopoly margins: – SAA(2); Telkom (2); Sasol (3), Foskor; Mittal Steel (formerly Iscor) – Cigarettes and beer (SAB, BATSA) – Forestry and agriculture (Safcol, Patensie, Senwes, Rooibos, Astral) Example of fuels, chemicals, fertilizer • Initial development related to: – requirements of mines and agriculture – Apartheid state concern to reduce dependence on imported oil • Sasol, as infant industry (now grown up), and Anglo subsidiary • State providing capital; infrastructure • Source of discipline? Interests of constituencies – agriculture, mining. – regulation (of fertilizer, fuel) • Firm strategies - adapting to liberalisation? – control inputs – access to alternative feedstock (natural gas) – raise entry barriers – downstream firms with outside options, include them in coordinated arrangements – consolidation – attempted two mergers • Fertilizer and polymers – by-products from coal to liquid operations • Liberalisation ≠ competition • Other levers? – Infrastructure; fuel regulation; mining rights? – Or: competition law?? Competition law and corporate conduct in Southern and East Africa • Arrangements by and between large companies operate across region, examples: – Beer ‘This agreement enabled us to develop opportunities’, justified, Najil Fairbass, SABMiller Communications Director. Before adding: ‘There may be antitrust laws at the national level, but none covering the continent. I don’t see what the problem is.’ (Philippe Perdrix Le marché de la bière africaine monte en pression Jeune Afrique 10/09/2008, cited in Jenny, 2009) – Cement: cartel across SACU – Construction: bid-rigging across continent – Fertilizer: overland market, including ‘Export Club’ • Entry also easier from adjacent markets (in the region), for example, poultry (from Zimbabwe/Botswana); steel rolling (from Kenya). – potential entrants can also be undermined such as ArcelorMittal acquisition in Mozambique. • Rivalry more likely across the region rather than in individual countries, if are substantial scale economies • Regional Comesa authority Conclusions • Competition law is part of framework for regulating conduct of large corporations; as is industrial policy • Competition does not result from liberalisation, nor simply in the absence of explicit cartels – is about effective rivalry • Choice of model for competition regime matters – diversity of options: free competition, prosecutorial model; or fair competition standard in administrative model (Germany, Korea) • Depends on institutional capabilities • Will regimes simply be undermined by elite interests? – depend on mediation of interests, – provides information/insight into business practices even in absence of effective sanctions • Examples from e.g. Kenya, Tanzania, Zambia point to building of popular support, pressure for greater powers, autonomy leading to laws strengthening authorities (e.g. Tanzania ruling on Breweries)