Bridging the gap between scientific necessity and political realism Sivan Kartha, Stockholm Environment Institute contributed background paper for report by Watson et al. to the Chair of AOSIS Abstract In the words of the authors of the Blue Planet Report, “In the face of an absolutely unprecedented emergency, society has no choice but to take dramatic action to avert a collapse of civilization. Either we will change our ways and build an entirely new kind of global society, or they will be changed for us.” (Brundtland et al, 2012) With the recent release of the Fifth IPCC assessment report, the science community has further underscored the need for dramatic action if society is to successfully face the climate challenge. Yet, as is all too clear from the lack of concerted action so far to reduce emissions, what is politically realistic remains far short of what is scientifically necessary. This report synthesizes (from the recent IPCC Fifth Assessment Report, notably) some core elements of what is scientifically necessary to address the climate challenge. It highlights some key dimensions of the political realism that has prevented a commensurate global response. It finally outlines two issues that are critical to bridging the gap: equity in the distribution of global efforts, and the political-economic impediments to earnest climate action. Scientific Necessity: Gt CO2-equivalent/yr Since well before the release of the IPCC’s First Assessment Report in 1990, climate scientists have been providing the input needed for society to assess the risks posed by dangerous climate change, and the steps that would be needed to avoid those risks. Most recently, with its Fifth Assessment, the IPCC clearly providedi the “carbon budgets” corresponding to various levels of risk of exceeding 2°c global warming. For a 1-in-3 chance (i.e., a 33% chance) that warming will stay below 2°c, the available budget is about 1,410 GtCO2. For a 70 less risky 1-in-2 chance that warming will stay IPCC-66% below 2°c, (i.e., a 50% chance), the budget is IPCC-50% about 1,120 GtCO2. And for still less risky 260 IPCC-33% in-3 chance (i.e., 66% chance), the budget is Business-as-usual Historical emissions around 1,1010 GtCO2. (See Table 1.) (Note, 50 however, that the analysis presented by IPCC WG3 (IPCC, 2014) suggests that even the most stringent of these budgets is “more 40 unlikely than likely” to hold warming below 1.5°c.) 30 20 10 0 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060 2070 2080 2090 2100 Figure 1. Three global emission reductions pathways, corresponding to the IPCC carbon budgets that provide a 33% chance (red pathway) that warming stays below 2°c, a 50% chance (blue pathway), and a 66% chance (green pathway). To make the implications of these budget figures more clear, Figure 1 presents three emissions pathways with cumulative carbon emissions that keep within these three budgets. (All of them use the same non-CO2 emissions pathway, consistent with IPCC concentration pathway “RCP2.6”). The red pathway uses up the budget that gives a 1-in3 (33%) chance of staying below 2°c, the blue pathway uses the budget with the 1-in-2 chance (50%), and the green pathway uses the budget with a 2-in-3 chance (66%). (See Baer et al, 2013 for further details.) Table 1. The IPCC’s three carbon budgets as presented in the WG1 AR5 Summary for Policy Makers Chance of keeping warming below 2°c >66% chance >50% chance >33% chance Total CO2 budget (assuming no non-CO2 forcing) (1880 forward) (GtCO2) 3,670 4,440 5,760 Adjusted CO2 budget (accounting for non-CO2 forcing as per RCP2.6) (1880 forward) (Gt CO2) 2,900 3,010 3,300 Already used CO2 budget (up to 2011) (Gt CO2) 1,890 1,890 1,890 Remaining CO2 budget (2012 forward) (Gt CO2) 1,010 1,120 1,410 As Figure 1 makes immediately clear, in order for each of these three pathways to keep within its respective budget (as given in Table 1), emissions must peak very soon, and decline rapidly thereafter. All three pathways shown in Figure 1 have global carbon emissions peaking in the next five years (before 2020), and then soon declining precipitously at rates that reach 4-5.5% per year, even while economies and access to energy services continue to grow. It is striking how close together these three curves are to each other, despite the rapidly rising level of risk they span. Indeed, by opting for the more lenient 33% pathway instead of the 66% pathway, one accepts twice the risk of exceeding 2°c, but gains disappointingly remarkably little additional emissions space in return. There are two ways to defy the strict constraints of the IPCC’s 2°c budgets. One way is to accept considerably greater risk (or virtual certainty) of exceeding 2°c. This, of course, implies also accepting rising risks of exceeding even higher temperatures -- 3°c, 4°c, even more. Without additional mitigation, global temperature rise of roughly 3°c to 8°c (IPCC AR5 WG3, SPM table 1) can be expected. While this amount of warming might not seem terribly large when compared to our everyday experience in our own locales (after all, don’t we often see the outdoor temperature rise by even 15°c on many days as the sun rises and warms the air?), it would in fact be a tremendous amount of warming when imposed at the scale of the entire planet. Indeed, the earth has warmed only 3°c to 8°c (IPCC AR5, WGI Ch 5) since the frigid depths of the last ice age, yet this was sufficient to utterly transform the surface of the planet, in the process making it hospitable to the development of human civilization. To impose a further warming of this magnitude is to invite a future in which the earth’s surface is again profoundly transformed. It’s hospitability to human civilization can by no means be taken for granted. A second way to defy the IPCC’s budget constraints is to assume that at some point in the future, society will have the ability and willingness to deploy “negative emissions” technologies at large scale. This strategy allows us to exceed the budget in the near term and make up for it in the long term. However, this strategy also has its risks. We might learn, much too late, that the needed technologies are not feasible at the necessary scale. Or, if they are deployable at the necessary scales, it may be only with adverse affects of their own, such as the appropriation of land to grow biomass energy feedstocks, competing with scarce land to provide natural habitat and to secure food for a growing global population. And, by exceeding the budget in the near term, we elevate the risk of overshooting temperature thresholds that trigger tipping elements or irreversible climate impacts. These budget constraints are clearly a severe challenge to our current business as usual development, and there are no alternatives to radical changes to our ways of doing business. As articulated in the Blue Planet Report, “In the face of an absolutely unprecedented emergency, society has no choice but to take dramatic action to avert a collapse of civilization. Either we will change our ways and build an entirely new kind of global society, or they will be changed for us.” (Brundtland et al, 2012) Yet, all the same, the emergency still seems distant and secondary to the policy maker with other pressing priorities. What is politically realistic is far short of what is scientifically necessary. Politic Realism Chief among those other pressing priorities facing societies is the challenge of poverty eradication and development for the majority of the world’s population that is still impoverished. In both the developed and developing world, it is understood that unmitigated climate change is a severe challenge to further development. In developing countries, however, action against climate change is also felt to jeopardize development. In many ways, it is this latter danger that is the more keenly feared. Consider the Figure 2, which highlights the predicament facing the developing world. The figure shows a global emission pathway (green, from Figure 1) consistent with the IPCC budget with a likely (i.e., 66%) chance of keeping warming below 2°C. 60 IPCC-66% developing country pathway Annual emissions (GtCO2e/yr) developed country pathway 50 40 30 20 10 0 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 Figure 2. The global pathway (red) with a 66% chance of keeping warming below 2°c, divided between developed (blue) countries and developing (red)) countries. The developed country shows emissions reduction of 8%/yr starting immediately. Developing country emissions peak one year after global emissions peak. Figure 2 also shows the developed (i.e., Annex 1) emission pathway (red), assuming dramatic mitigation efforts were undertaken, sufficient to drive emissions down nearly 50% by 2020 and 95% by 2050 relative to current emission levels (which is similar to that assumed by Anderson and Calverley in this volume). While this would be very challenging and is well beyond the mitigation pledges put forward in Cancun, developed countries do have the technological and financial wherewithal to undertake such ambitious reductions if they mustered the political will to do so. Having stipulated a global 2°c pathway, and made a heroic assumption about the future developed country pathway, simple subtraction reveals the pathway that would be available to support the South’s development (shown in blue, which is simply the green path minus the red path). Despite the apparent aggressiveness of the developed country mitigation efforts, the developing countries are still left with a severely limited budget that forces upon them the need for similarly aggressive mitigation. Developing country emissions would have to peak only a few years later than those in the North – still well before 2020 – and then decline rapidly through 2050. Figure 3 gives a sense of the level of development in several countriesii at the time at which their emissions need to peak. For the developed countries, the figure shows incomes in the year 2010 (blue bars), roughly when aggregate developed countries emissions started a decline. The range in incomes is substantial (consider Norway and Ukraine), reflecting a substantial range in material welfare. Figure 3 also shows a set of developing countries, and their $$10,000 $20,000 $30,000 $40,000 $50,000 projected annual per capita United States Canada incomes during the 2015 to Australia 2025 time period. (This time Japan period is generously wide, since EU28 Income in Russia in order for developing 2010 Ukraine countries in aggregate to peak in the next few years, as Figure 2 implies, most developing China countries individually would also Mexico need to peak within the next Brazil South Africa few years.) The darker red Projected income Iran portion of the bars in Figure 3 range 2015 - 2025 Indonesia shows the projected income India LDCs range, with the left end showing the 2015 income projection, and Figure 3. Annual per capita incomes (PPP – purchase power parity) of the right end showing the 2020 several developed and developing countries at the time of peaking of income projection. The range in emissions. incomes across countries is substantial, but most developing countries will still be considerably less wealthy when their emissions would need to peak than most developed countries were in 2010. China, for example, is projected to have an income one-sixth to one-half the US income in 2010. Indonesia and India are projected to have per capita incomes in the $5,000 range, which happens to be the income level the United States was at in the 1890siii. At that point in time, the US had recently found industrialization fuelled by fossil carbon to be its route out of poverty, and its emissions were soaring. At this same level of development, countries such as Indonesia and India would need to be eliminating carbon emissions – and forgoing development fuelled by fossil fuels – at similar annual percentage rate that the United States had been increasing its carbon emissions. This peaking of emissions would thus need to take place while most of the developing world’s citizens were still struggling to maintain or improve their livelihoods and raise their material living standards. Yet the only proven routes to development – to water and food security, improved health and education, secure livelihoods – involve expanding access to energy services, and, consequently, a seemingly inevitable increase in fossil fuel use and thus carbon emissions. As clearly reflected in the companion piece by Strivastava et al in this volume, and the numerous studies and reports that underlie it, access to energy services is fundamental to the fulfilment of development goals. Indeed, in the absence of climate constraints, developing countries would continue to increase the use of conventional energy resources to fuel the expansion of their infrastructure and the improvement of the material well-being of their citizens, as was done in the developed world. This perceived tension between development and decarbonisation motivates a powerful form of political realism. It underlies the developing world’s reluctance to earnestly engage in the lowcarbon transition that is scientifically necessary if warming is to be limited to 2°C or less. Yet, this gap between scientific necessity and political realism is not necessarily insurmountable. One of the key findings of the IPCC’s AR5 is that technological and policy options are available that would allow warming to be held below 2°C, without preventing poverty eradication or impeding development, in the North or the South (IPCC WG3 AR5). This portfolio of technological and policy options has been broadly overviewed in several of the other companion papers in this volume. While further delay will make this endeavour much more challenging – and will soon render it impossible – it still within reach now, but not without its costs. A fundamental challenge, therefore, is agreeing how those costs will be shared. Who will provide the financial and technological resources required to realize these technological options and implement the necessary policies, while advancing development sustainably. Who will bear the costs of the globally essential low-carbon transition? Thus arises a conflict between two seemingly irreconcilable political realisms. On one hand are the decision-makers in developing countries who cannot imagine dramatically curbing emissions, certainly not so severely as indicated in Figure 2 and not without substantial international support. On the other hand are the decision-makers in developed countries for whom the prospects of providing substantial financial and technological resources to the South itself seriously strains their political realism. In principle, such support is already accepted in the climate context. The UNFCCC obliges the developed countries to “take the lead in combating climate change and the adverse impacts thereof”, and commits them to provide financial and technological resources to enable and support mitigation actions in developing countries. But the details remain unresolved and highly contentious. Bridging the gap An approach based on equity may be the only viable way forward. Even though discussions of equity on the international stage have been extremely divisive and shown little progress so far, there may be no alternative. An equitable approach is morally preferable, of course, but also a legal commitment for all Parties to the UNFCCC, who have agreed to “protect the climate system … on the basis of equity and in accordance with their common but differentiated responsibilities and respective capabilities.” But more importantly, an equitable approach is more likely to succeed in solving the climate crisis. This is so because climate change is a classic case of a commons problem. As with any commons problem, the solution lies in collective action (Ostrom, 1990). No single country is able to protect “its own” climate by reducing its own emissions, and thus no country can solve its own climate problem by itself. For this reason, countries concerned about protecting their climate must persuade other countries to help it. Thus, countries reduce their own emissions – and cooperates in other ways – not in order to directly protect their climate, but for the sake of inducing reciprocal effort, i.e., getting other countries to do likewise. A country is only likely to succeed in inducing reciprocal effort among its negotiating partners if it is perceived to be doing its fair share of the effort. Thus, a cooperative agreement among countries is more likely to be agreed and successfully implemented if based on equitable effort-sharing. Young (2013) has identified three general conditions—all of which apply to the climate context— under which the successful formation and eventual effectiveness of a collective action regime may hinge on equitable burden sharing: the absence of actors who are powerful enough to coercively impose their preferred burden sharing arrangements; the inapplicability of standard utilitarian methods of calculating costs and benefits; and the fact that regime effectiveness depends on a longterm commitment of members to implement its terms. This, in the terse words of the WG3 Summary for Policy Makers, “The evidence suggests that outcomes seen as equitable can lead to more effective cooperation.” Much scholarship and analysis has been carried out examining the nature of an international agreement that would distribute costs of a low-carbon transition equitably. Even absent any specific universally accepted definition of equitable effort-sharing, one salient and robust finding stands out. That is that wealthy countries have the greatest share of the responsibility for causing climate change and the greatest financial and technological capabilities for solving it, while the developing countries have the greatest share of the mitigation opportunities that must be captured if warming is to be held below 2°C. The implication of this is that a global cooperative agreement will depend, to an important degree, on institutions, mechanisms and frameworks whereby countries generally perceived to have the moral obligation to bear the costs can provide the resources to those countries where emissions must be driven down. Again, as articulated by the IPCC WG3, “Effort-sharing frameworks can help to clarify discrepancies between the distribution of costs based on mitigation potential and the distribution of responsibilities based on ethical principles, and they can help reconcile those discrepancies through international financial transfers.” [AR5 WG3 TS]. Government decision-makers cannot, unfortunately, simply and straightforwardly respond to the scientific necessity, acting objectively and benevolently to secure the long-term interests of society. Political realism, inevitably, intrudes here as well. Rather, governments respond to constituents, which are sometimes their citizens articulating their interests through legitimate means, but all too often are powerful vested interests imposing their interests through undemocratic means. There is a long and ignominious history of corporate interests resisting and effectively impeding initiatives to protect the environment and public health. Tobacco is the most notorious example, but similar campaigns have delayed and weakened efforts to regulate lead additives in gasoline and paint, seat belts in automobiles, sulphur from power plants, leachate from landfills, and countless other environment and health issues. The tactics consistently rely on undermining science to sow doubt, fabricating economics to overestimate regulatory costs and underestimate benefits, and, perhaps most importantly, subverting democratic processes by unduly influencing elected representatives through campaign finance and interfering with government regulatory agencies and judicial processes. (See, for example, Union of Concerned Scientists, 2012a, 2012b; Mann, 2012. Oreskes and Conway, 2011; Pew Environment Group, 2010.) That these tactics have been applied in the climate change context as well is no surprise, given the financial stakes for corporations currently engaged as major actors in our fossil fuel economy (Grantham Institute, 2013). With the evident interest of such actors in impeding climate action, even the European Parliament has passed a resolution acknowledging “growing recognition of the need to be vigilant concerning efforts by economic actors that emit significant amounts of greenhouse gases or benefit from burning fossil fuels, to undermine or subvert climate protection efforts;” (European Parliament, 2013). Political economy determines whether we act to address climate change, and if so how we do so. Though curbing corporate influence and restoring government accountability are only part of what is needed to bridge scientific necessity and political realism, an effective climate response is implausible otherwise. References Bear, Paul, Tom Athanasiou, and Sivan Kartha, 2014. Three Salient Global Mitigation Pathways Assessed in Light of the IPCC Carbon Budgets. Revised February 2014. Stockholm Environment Institute. Blue Planet Prize Laureates, (Gro Harlem Brundtland, Paul Ehrlich, José Goldemberg, James Hansen, Amory Lovins, Gene Likens, Suki Manabe, Bob May, Hal Mooney, Karl-Henrik Robèrt, Emil Salim, Gordon Sato, Susan Solomon, Nicholas Stern, M.S. Swaminathan Research Foundation, Robert Watson, Barefoot College, Conservation International, International institute for Environment and Development, and International Union for the Conservation of Nature ) 2012. Environment and Development Challenges: The Imperative to Act. The Asahi Glass Foundation. European Parliament, 2013. European Parliament resolution of 23 October 2013 on the climate change conference in Warsaw, Poland (COP 19) www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/getDoc.do?type=TA&language=EN&reference=P7-TA-2013-443 Grantham Institute , 2012. Unburnable Carbon 2013: Wasted capital and stranded assets. (Carbon Tracker & The Grantham Research Institute, LSE. IPCC, 2013: Summary for Policymakers. In: Climate Change 2013: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Stocker, T.F., D. Qin, G.-K. Plattner, M. Tignor, S.K. Allen, J. Boschung, A. Nauels, Y. Xia, V. Bex and P.M. Midgley (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA. IPCC, 2014: Summary for Policymakers, In: Climate Change 2014, Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Edenhofer, O., R. Pichs-Madruga, Y. Sokona, E. Farahani, S. Kadner, K. Seyboth, A. Adler, I. Baum, S. Brunner, P. Eickemeier, B. Kriemann, J. Savolainen, S. Schlömer, C. von Stechow, T. Zwickel and J.C. Minx (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA. Mann, Michael, 2012. The Hockey Stick and the Climate Wars: Dispatches from the Front Lines. Columbia University Press: New York. Oreskes and Conway, 2011. Merchants of Doubt. Bloomsbury Press. Union of Concerned Scientists, 2012. Heads They Win, Tails We Lose – How Corporations Corrupt Science at the Public’s Expense. i The figures given in Table 1 are taken from the IPCC’s Working Group 1 Summary for Policymakers (IPCC, 2013, Sec. E.8). It gives budgets of 3670, 4440, and 5760 GtCO2 for keeping warming below 2°c with probability of 66%, 50%, and 33% respectively. If emissions of non-CO2 climate forces are strictly limited through ambitious reductions (consistent with IPCC’s stringent “RCP2.6” pathway), the IPCC states the remaining budgets are 2900, 3010, and 3300 GtCO2, respectively. Subtracting off the emissions already released up through 2011 (amounting to 1980 GtCO2) – leaves 1010, 1120, and 1410, respectively, for the period 2012 and forward. (Note, roughly 75 GtCo2 of this budget was consumed by 2012-2013 carbon emissions.) The scenario analysis presented by WG3 (IPCC, 2014, SPM Table 1) suggests that all of budgets are, at best, “more unlikely than likely” to hold warming below 1.5°c. ii The developed countries show here amount to about nine-tenths of total Annex 1 population. The developing countries shown here amount to about three-quarters of total non-Annex 1 population. iii See Maddison’s historical database covering population by country, GDP and GDP per capita back to 1820., http://www.worldeconomics.com/Data/MadisonHistoricalGDP/Madison%20Historical%20GDP%20Data.efp)