Tax Evasion and the Firm Frank Cowell Encuentros de Economía Pública Almeria, February 2006 Purpose • • • • This talk is about modelling in public economics I want to focus on a puzzle Then a suggestion for answering the puzzle But first: a history lesson an English history lesson William the Conqueror • 1066: a date known to British schoolchildren • But 1086 should be better known to tax researchers • The Domesday Book a detailed audit of the kingdom what is the place that I have conquered worth? who owns what? where are the resources? • A thorough operation extensive teams of investigators multiple information sources penalties for wrong information Lessons from the Conqueror • Not just a system of national accounts • Clearly concerned with revenue raising Note questions on valuation • An early example of a tax audit problem But questions are about assets rather than income A forerunner of the Allingham-Sandmo problem? Tax Compliance: Background • Typically focus on the personal taxpayer exogenous income isolated economic agent • Simplified information structure • Since Allingham and Sandmo lots of specifications But broadly two categories • TAG models Taxpayer As Gambler • Cat-and-mouse models The main economic actors play games with each other TAG • • • • • • The individual taxpayer behaves just as a gambler: Taxpayer has fixed income Conceals a part of this income Knows the penalty and probability of audit Audit probability is fixed Taxpayer takes a risk on whether he is audited Cat-and-mouse • • • • Audit probability depends on report Generates strategic interaction Known distribution of income and types Condition audit on report Get a “cut-off” rule • Alternatively models use other forms of information Reinganum and Wilde (1985,1986) A modelling strategy • Is the analysis well suited to analysing taxpayer behaviour… …when the taxpayers are producers? …when the taxpayers are grouped in an industry? • Let’s see how well the models work • Do they capture the essential features of tax compliance with firms? • Start with TAG TAG: competitive firms • Assume expected profit maximisation Only source of randomness is due to audit.. • Behaviour driven by two things Nature of concealment costs Structure of audit probabilities • Tax evasion incurs resource costs Firm declares proportion of output a. Incurs total concealment cost C(1 – a). Average cost c(1 – a) := C(1 – a) / [1 – a]. TAG model structure • Can treat this as modified Allingham-Sandmo • Tax-enforcement parameters: Proportional tax rate t. Probability of audit b. Penalty rate for concealed output f. • Compute expected effective tax rate te te = [1 – b]at + b [t + [1 – a ]ft ] = [a + [1 – a ] b [1+f]]t • Expected profits are [p – m – c – te ] · q p: price m: marginal production cost Competitive model: results • Only c and te depend on concealment increasing marginal cost of concealment reduced effective expected tax rate Firm always conceals if te < t • Optimal concealment satisfies [1 – a ]g'(1– a) = t – te “MC concealment equals reduction in expected tax” • Optimal output satisfies p = m + g + te “Price = (adjusted) marginal cost” • Essentially a “separation” result Makes it easy to get comparative statics But does it survive more generalised modelling? Generalisations • Monopoly / imperfect competition Determinate demand curve Replace q with q(p) Little changes: replace "price" with "MR" in FOC Separation result persists. (Marrelli 1984, Marelli and Martina 1988) • Risk aversion max Eu([p – m – g – t ] · q) Separation result is preserved • Change the tax/penalty regime. b not only a function of over-reported cost? b or penalty not constant? No longer get the separation result – Lee (1998) TAG and firms – a puzzle • The puzzle is that the firm seems to have disappeared write out FOC solve for output and profits back into an “Allingham-Sandmo” world • Tax-neutrality argument is central but it appears artificial not robust to different tax base seems to run counter to experience zealous enforcement has no effect on output? • Perhaps the answer is in the audit rule? Audit rule is naïve Does not make full use of industry information Consider cat-and-mouse Cat-and-mouse: firms • The cat-and-mouse model is a reporting game tax-payer and tax authority (TA) With or without precommitment • Is cat-and-mouse a suitable for firms? • Simple reporting models may be inappropriate There is no fixed income to uncover Don’t have independent estimate of distribution • May omit some of the key strategic aspects of the game Do we have the right players? What do the players know? William the Conqueror again • How does the modern tax-audit differ from the Domesday book? production nature of report nature of reporting process • We need to address a key practical question how would we expect the TA to act? clearly depends on the type of tax… …corporation tax? VAT? • Recognise the contrast with the situation of personal taxpayers who knows what the taxable profit is? how handle of heterogeneity of firms? how handle inter-relations amongst firms? • Design an audit strategy that uses the available information recognises its own ignorance Learning from the tax authority • What will the TA do? sort firms by industry grouping sort firms by size monitor over time adapt audit procedure accordingly • Can we adapt the standard approaches…? • Neglect some important features and information Production Creation / disappearance of taxable units Structure of industry This provides an answer to our puzzle of the vanishing firm Taking the firm seriously • What makes the firm “special”? Internal organisation Interrelation with other firms The role of information • Internal organisation Not a single decision-making entity Role of Chief Financial Officer? Effective separation of functions within the firm? • Interrelations Several models that deal with this – for example Benjamini-Maital But why should firms care about each other? Not “stigma” but “profits” • Information… …needs closer examination Information • What does the firm know about itself? incomplete information may lead to agency problems Crocker and Slemrod (2005) • What does the tax authority know about the firm? • What do firms know about each other? A way forward • How to capture the essence of the tax-compliance problem with firms? • We will focus on two main features: • 1. “Industry-group typing” incorporates interrelations among taxpaying firms arises naturally from informational structure of the problem results in a well-behaved equilibrium in a minimalist model • 2. “Production and industry” incorporates industrial organisation considerations again uses naturally arising information introduces an output-security tradeoff modifies standard IO equilibria in an interesting way Approach 1: Industry-group typing • Consider the cat-and-mouse model simple versions use a “cut-off” rule Reinganum and Wilde (1985) ignore income declarations greater than d* • But this based on a particular strategic interaction… …TA “versus” representative taxpayer • Can the model be made richer? In some cases yes see tax-payers as a group allow natural group interaction (Sánchez 2006) particularly important for firms • Role of the industry classify according to broad observable characteristics enough information to condition audit policy Cut-off rule • Well-known to be wasteful: the cut-off rule wastes ammunition: auditing “genuine” taxpayers but what if firms in an industry are subject to common shocks… …unobserved from the outside? problem gets worse • Negative shock: more firms than expected by the TA have profits below the cut-off level more firms declare low • Positive shock: more than expected by the TA have profits above the cut-off level d* but each successful firm will declare only d*, thus increasing the number of evaders that go undetected. • Result: more resources wasted find systematic mis-targeting by the TA under-auditing in good years over-auditing in bad years Policy with shocks • Can the TA do better than a cut-off rule? Suppose TA is concerned about “wasted ammunition” resources spent on audits of compliant taxpayers TA better off if policy is contingent on the industry information • Use the industry typing form fairly homogeneous audit class let D be average declaration for the class di be declaration for firm i within the class condition on D di • Changes nature of the compliance game the D component induces interaction among firms (Alm and McKee 2004) improves TA’s ability to estimate probability of firm i being an evader. • Firms who declare relatively low are more likely to be evaders homogeneity within a given industry category since firms share characteristics expect to have similar profits consequently expect similar income declarations. declaration significantly below the class average seen as “suspect” How interaction works • Consequences for TA policy : knows relationship between D di and probability that i is an evader so make auditing intensity for low declarers increase with D. • Introduces an externality among taxpayers fundamental nature of the tax compliance problem each firm has to interact strategically with other firms not just with TA as in conventional cat-and-mouse • Firms forced to participate in a coordination game if the average declaration is high (most firms comply)… …probability of detection is also high too if the average declaration is low (so most people evade) … the probability of detection is low • Each firm always has incentive to join the majority. A paradox? • Auditing intensity increases with the average declaration? A waste of resources…? …most firms would have declared truthfully. • Will this policy harm the goal of discouraging evasion? Low auditing intensity when D is low… …means TA lets evaders get away undetected.? • But auditing intensity applies only to low di those who declare high are never audited the greater is D the greater is the TA's belief that the class faces a favourable shock the greater is its belief that a low di means i is an evader. So – no paradox The contingent rule… • Contingent policy slightly resembles the cut-off rule non-increasing in true income • But there is a big difference: probability of detection for those who declare low… …an increasing function of the class-wide average declaration. • Why the contingent rule? not a consequence of new elements added to the model simply an application of common sense making efficient use of all the available information. • Implications for TA take advantage of strategic uncertainty it generates manipulate this by imposing severe penalties in the case of a coordination failure Fundamental uncertainty • But how do firms view the government? • A second element of uncertainty the type of the government value it puts on resources wasted on auditing compliant taxpayers this information is private to the government • Firms do not know this type faced with a the probability distribution need to estimate it results in a system of beliefs The role of firms’ beliefs • Beliefs generate heterogeneity expectations over type of the government differ among taxpayers eliminates all but one equilibrium the presence of different signals… …leads to different taxpayers to make different decisions • Simplifies the model each firm has a unique optimal strategy unlike a coordination game without heterogeneity... …get multiple solutions (one for each possible equilibrium) • Sánchez (2006) model yields unique, interior equilibrium The industry-typing model • Presence of two kinds of uncertainty strategic: generated by the coordination game fundamental: firms’ imperfect information about government type …makes the tax evasion problem well suited to be modelled as a global game. • Global game captures the interaction among its actors firms in an industry a bit like subjects in the kingdom of William I leaves open scope for manipulating beliefs • Capture stylized facts missing in other models Unique interior equilibrium where some comply, some evade TA's comprehensive and efficient use of all available information • But incomes (profits) are still exogenous consider the second approach Approach 2: production and industry • Explicitly model the industry Make the multi-firm setting essential Model differential information of insiders and outsiders Bayer and Cowell (2005) • Make better use of information by the TA On part of firms On part of tax authority • Compare with Naïve audit rules Simple models of compliance Model motivation • How much does the tax authority know about firms? May be reasonably well informed about a specific industry or sector. But firms probably have better information about their own industry This information may concern both production and financial performance • Yields a natural way to model output and evasion linkage Firms • Production Identical cost structures Details of these subsumed within profit function • Evasion Opportunities to evade are common knowledge • Specify cost-of-evasion function C() Argument is concealed output Increasing, convex C(0) = 0 • Objectives Firms are risk-neutral Objective function is expected profits Industry • Fixed number of firms n. • Firms compete Cournot style Bertrand style • Firms make profit declarations d := (d1, d2, ..., dn ) • New possibilities for tax authority independent audits use information from all declarations in audit rule Taxation, audit and enforcement • Conventional tax/penalty regime linear profits tax simple fine structure for non-compliance both could be generalised • But a variety of audit regime • Instead of considering a policy of independent audit… …given a fixed audit probability β* for all firms • Consider the use of a relative audit rule… …Audit probability for firm i is given as β(i, d) depends on firm i's declaration relative to the rest. Again we could use the D di rule • Under the relative rule each firm knows that: ...own declaration may reduce the probability ...others' declaration may increase the probability Tax, profits and penalties • Firm i’s profits gross of tax and depend on q output vector of industry • Profits form base of tax assume linear tax function • The tax it actually pays depends on evasion decision assume a fixed proportional fine f. • Risk-neutrality: firm i maximises expected net profit: probability of audit gross profit if audited gross profit if not audited cost of concealment How the model works • Timing in the model is intuitive: The TA announces taxes and an audit regime Firms choose quantities Firms observe gross profits of the others Firms choose profit declarations TA audits and punishes where appropriate • The solution is found as usual… by working backwards start with the declaration stage Declaration decision • At this stage, outputs have been determined profits are determined… …and known within the industry • Declaration problem for each firm is simple driven by the known audit rule • To get an interior solution need two conditions 1 If marginal concealment costs are high for extensive tax evasion… then, near di = 0, expected payoff increases with di 2 If C'(0) = 0 and detection probability is low… … then, near full declaration, expected profits decrease with di. Latter condition corresponds to usual TAG case. Output decision • Changes in quantity are known to affect optimal declarations of others there is the usual Cournot interdependence and the audit rule is common knowledge • Changes in others' declarations affect i's audit probability the audit rule is common knowledge • Decisions on output will reflect this interdependence • Condition for i’s optimal output reflects the induced change in j’s declarations the indirect impact on i’s probability of audit Role of information • Announcement of audit regime is crucial If tax authority uses relative rule… …interdependence of firms’ declarations is common knowledge • Each firm’s declaration creates an externality • Tax authority can use this in selecting the type of audit rule can influence the “climate” of the industry • Imagine starting with simple independent audits. • Would there be a “dividend” in refining and announcing the refinement? A double dividend • Bayer and Cowell show that there are two “dividends” from refining the audit policy • First: audit efficiency Under the relative audit rule with mean equilibrium detection probability β* firms declare more profits than under independent audits with the fixed detection probability β(i) = β*. • Second: production efficiency A relative audit rule leads to outputs higher than in under the independent audit rule Audit rules and output • Independent audit rule fixed audit probability output is independent of the evasion decision and equals the Cournot quantities. rather like the simple competitive model • Relative audit rule audit probability depends on D di outputs are higher than in Cournot competition without taxes. Changing the audit rule shifts the output reaction function Another paradox? • What is gained from increasing output beyond the Cournot level? Surely a firm reduces its own profit… …as well as its competitors’ profits? A loss rather than a gain? • Informational externality As qi increases, profits of other firms fall Optimal declarations of the other firms fall Given the relative audit rule… …probability of audit of firm i decreases This gives firm i more scope for evasion • So it is rational for the Cournot firm to operate in this way The non-paradox again • A tradeoff by increasing output beyond the Cournot quantity… …a firm loses some gross profit but gets a better environment for evasion. • A malicious incentive? other firms decrease their declaration if their profits fall but this decreases firm i's audit probability firm i has an incentive to sabotage other firms' profits …by producing more than under the usual Cournot Changing the industry rules • The result is not special to quantity competition • Similar results for Bertrand price-competition model you need differentiated products… …and a regularity condition on demand curves • The intuition is the same forgo some gross profits for a better evasion environment Changing the audit rule shifts the price reaction function Conclusions • We can suggest an answer to our puzzle can we find an approach to the topic… …where the firm does not vanish? two main components to the answer • Who’s in the game? firms versus the TA firms versus firms perhaps a little like William I’s Domesday investigation • How is the tax-base determined? profits created by firms firms in the context of an industry where TA’s could learn something that king William’s investigators did not know References • • • • • • • • • • Allingham, M. and A. Sandmo (1972). Income tax evasion: a theoretical analysis. Journal of Public Economics 1, 323-338. Alm, J. and M. Mckee (2004). Tax compliance as a coordination game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 54, 297-312. Bayer, R.-C. and F. A. Cowell (2005). Tax compliance and firms’ strategic interdependence. Distributional Analysis Discussion Paper 81, STICERD, London School of Economics, London WC2A 2AE. Crocker, K. J. and J. Slemrod (2005). Corporate tax evasion with agency costs. Journal of Public Economics 89, 1593.1610. Lee, K. (1998). Tax evasion, monopoly and nonneutral profit taxes. National Tax Journal 51, 333-338. Marrelli, M. (1984). On indirect tax evasion. Journal of Public Economics 25, 181.196. Marrelli, M. and R. Martina (1988). Tax evasion and strategic behaviour of firms. Journal of Public Economics 37, 55.69. Reinganum, J. F. and L. L. Wilde (1985). Income tax compliance in a principal-agent framework. Journal of Public Economics 26, 1.18. Reinganum, J. F. and L. L. Wilde (1986). Equilibrium verification and reporting policies in a model of tax compliance. International Economic Review 27, 739.760. Sánchez, M. (2006). Divide and conquer: Tax evasion as a global game. Distributional Analysis Discussion Paper 80, STICERD, London School of Economics, London WC2A 2AE.