Chapter 10 Summary: Interest Groups The Role of Interest Groups While the United States consistently has lower voter turnout than other democracies, it has much higher participation in civic groups and associations. Such civic participation has been a central characteristic of the United States since Alexis de Tocqueville first praised it in the 1830s when he visited from France. The name for voluntary civic associations that participate in the policymaking process is interest groups. One view of interest groups is that they are examples of the factions that James Madison warned against in Federalist 10, but another view is that interest groups are crucial linkage institutions that operate in a constructive, pluralistic manner to reflect the people’s preferences within the political system. Organizing to promote political interests is an essential part of democratic selfgovernment. The right to organize groups is protected by the Constitution, which guarantees people the right “peaceably to assemble, and to petition the Government for a redress of grievances.” The freedom to organize is as fundamental to democratic selfgovernment as freedom of speech and freedom of the press. Interest refers to a policy goal; a group is a combination of people. An interest group is an organization of people with similar policy goals who enter the political process to try to achieve those goals. Interest groups seek to influence all branches of government. A policy battle lost in Congress may be pursued within bureaucratic implementation (executive branch) or the judicial process. Interest groups differ from political parties in that they do not nominate and run candidates for public office. They support candidates sympathetic to their policy views, but they do not seek to influence the policymaking process by winning elections. Another difference between interest groups and political parties is that interest groups are usually policy specialists, whereas parties are policy generalists. There are currently over 25,000 interest groups in the United States and they use both technology and money to effectively promote their views and influence elected officials. The debate over whether lobbying and interest groups in general create problems for government requires an examination of three important theories. Pluralism argues that interest group activity brings representation to all; groups compete and counterbalance one another in the political marketplace. In contrast, elitism argues that a few groups (primarily the wealthy) have most of the power. Finally, hyperpluralism asserts that too many groups are getting too much of what they want, resulting in government policy that is often contradictory and lacking in direction. In using these theories to evaluate the Madisonian system, a pluralist interpretation would suggest that Madison’s system has worked as intended. An elitist interpretation, however, would argue that the wealthy have captured the system and can subvert the public interest in favor of their private interest. A hyperpluralist interpretation would argue that the system has too many competing groups with too much power. The Success of Interest Groups Among the factors that affect the success of an interest group are the size of the group, its intensity, and its financial resources. While greater intensity and more financial resources work to a group’s advantage, surprisingly, smaller groups are more likely to achieve their goals than larger groups. The size of a group is determined by its potential members in relation to its actual members. An environmental protection group’s potential members include all of society, while an oil industry group’s potential members include individuals who work in that industry. According to potential members, the oil industry group is smaller and will most likely be able to get a much higher percentage of potential members to become actual members, increasing the group’s organization and effectiveness. While the environmental protection group’s actual members work to provide a collective good, something of value (clean air) that cannot be withheld from anyone, including the potential members who do not join the group, they will most likely be less successful than the oil industry group. The reason is the free-rider problem. Again, everyone will benefit from the collective good if they are an actual member or potential member, and many potential members will rationally decide to allow other people to achieve the goal for them. The bigger the potential group, the more serious the free-rider problem. The organizing advantage of small groups helps explain why consumer groups have a harder time organizing for political action than do businesses. Consumer groups may seek to achieve public interest goals, but the policy benefits will be spread out over the entire society. In contrast, the lobbying costs and benefits for business are concentrated. If the policy benefit is small for each individual (benefits everyone) then the incentive to participate will be smaller, whereas the incentive to participate in securing benefits that will go largely to those participating in the lobbying effort is much higher. Thus, the power of business in the American political system is due to more than just money, as proponents of elite theory would have us believe. In addition to their considerable financial strength, multinational corporations have an easier time organizing themselves for political action than larger potential groups, such as consumer advocates. One way that a large potential group may be mobilized is through an issue that people feel intensely about. Intensity is a psychological advantage that can be enjoyed by small and large groups. Intensity is usually directed at opposition to a policy change rather than support for change, in practice this serves to preserve the status quo. An interest group characterized by high levels of intensity is often a single-issue group, a group that has a narrow interest, dislikes compromise, and single-mindedly pursues its goal. One of the major indictments of the American interest group system is that it is biased toward the wealthy. However, it is important to emphasize that on some of the most important issues, the wealthiest interest groups do not always win. Studies have shown a relatively weak correlation between big money and lobbying success. One reason is that lobbying is very competitive; with all sides on an issue mobilized to lobby for their position. A proponent of hyperpluralism would point to this as evidence that too many interest groups have too much influence to be very effective as an individual group. A proponent of pluralist theory would point out that the competitiveness of lobbying often leads to coalitions that include less powerful interest groups, as well. The Tactics of Interest Groups Interest groups use four basic strategies to achieve their policy goals: lobbying, electioneering, litigation, and appealing to the public. Lobbyists are political persuaders who represent organized groups. Lobbyists are often former legislators themselves. There are two basic types of lobbyists. The first type is a regular, paid employee of a corporation, union, or association. The second type is available for hire on a temporary basis. The Lobbying Disclosure Act of 1995 established criteria for determining whether an organization should register its employees as lobbyists. Thus, the number of lobbyists and how much they were paid is public information. Although lobbyists are primarily out to influence members of Congress, it is important to remember that they can be of help to them as well. Lobbyists are an important source of specialized expertise and information, they can help politicians with political strategy for getting legislation passed, and they can help formulate campaign strategy for reelection. A lobbyist’s success depends on their ability to deploy information strategically on behalf of their clients. In other words, a lobbyist is often not changing anyone’s mind but rather simply helping political allies. Lobbying works best on people already committed to the lobbyist’s policy position. Thus, like campaigning, lobbying is directed toward primarily activating and reinforcing supporters. Getting the right people into office and keeping them there is also a key strategy of interest groups. Electioneering, aiding candidates financially and getting group members to support them, is an important strategy in achieving policy goals. A means for interest groups to participate in electioneering is provided by political action committees (PACs). The number of PACs has increased dramatically since 1974 when they were created as a result of campaign finance reform. PACs raise money from individuals and then distribute it in the form of contributions to candidates. PACs must register with the Federal Election Commission (FEC) and report both their donations and contributions. During a primary election, a PAC can donate up to $5,000 per candidate, and then donate the same amount in the general election. Candidates need PACs because high-tech campaigning is expensive. A symbiotic relationship emerges between the PACs and the candidates: Candidates need money, which they insist can be used without comprising their independence and integrity; PACs want access to officeholders, which they insist can be gained without buying votes. Many incumbents enjoy significant fundraising advantages by taking contributions from PACs. Critics of the PAC system worry that all this money leads to PAC control over the agenda once the incumbents are reelected. Defenders of the PAC system point out that it further increases participation in the political process. If James Madison was right in thinking that the key to controlling the power of interest groups (factions) is to expand their sphere of participation, then PACs certainly do this. If lobbying and electioneering fail to achieve policy goals through Congress, then interest groups may try to use the courts to advance their cause. One tactic to make the views of interest groups heard by the judiciary is the filing of amicus curiae briefs (“friend of the court” briefs), written arguments submitted to the courts in support of one side of a case. A more direct judicial strategy employed by interest groups is the filing of class action lawsuits, which enable a group of people in a similar situation to combine their common grievances into a single suit. Because public opinion ultimately makes its way to policymakers, interest groups carefully cultivate their public image and use public opinion to their advantage when they can. Interest groups often use the mass media to influence the public’s views on an important policy debate. The Variety of Interest Groups Interest groups are omnipresent in the American political system and political scientists loosely categorize interest groups into four distinct types: economic issues, environmental concerns, equality issues, and consumer/public interest. Economic interest groups are concerned about quotas and tariffs (fees imposed on imports), the soundness of the dollar, taxing and spending, and labor relations. Unions are the main interest groups representing labor. The aim of American union organizations is to press for policies to ensure better working conditions and higher wages. In response to the free-rider problem, unions have fought to establish and maintain the union shop, which requires employees of a business that has a union contract to join the union and pay dues. In contrast, business groups have supported right-to-work laws, which outlaw union membership as a condition of employment. In 1947, the American labor movement suffered a big defeat when Congress passed the Taft-Hartley Act, permitting states to adopt right-to-work laws. The American labor movement, led by the AFL-CIO, reached its peak in 1956 when 33 percent of the workforce belonged to a union. Currently, only 12 percent of the workforce belongs to unions. As labor union membership has declined in traditional blue-collar industries, the labor union movement has expanded in the public sector. As unions have declined in the private sector, business PACs have increased more dramatically than any other category of PACs over the last three decades. Many people assume that business PAC contributions are always tilted in favor of the Republican Party and its tax-cutting and deregulatory agenda. While it is true that business PACs such as the Chamber of Commerce are more likely to favor the Republicans, Democrats receive more business PAC contributions when they are in the majority. In other words, a business PAC tends to give money to those in power in order to gain access to the policymakers. Some environmental groups such as the Sierra Club and Audubon Society have been around since the 19th century, but many others trace their origins to the first Earth Day in 1970. Environmental groups have promoted policies to control pollution and to combat global warming, wilderness protection, and species preservation. The United States has a high percentage of membership to environmental interest groups, including the World Wildlife Fund, the Nature Conservancy, the National Wildlife Federation, and Greenpeace. Two sets of interest groups, representing minorities and women, have made equal rights their main policy goal. The oldest and largest of these groups is the National Association for the Advancement of Colored People (NAACP). It argued and won the monumental Brown v. Board of Education case that declared segregated schools unconstitutional. Civil rights groups continue to push for equality today through affirmative action programs to ensure that minority groups are guaranteed equal educational and employment opportunities. The National Organization for Women (NOW) lobbies to end discrimination against women in a variety of social spheres. Public interest and consumer advocacy groups seek a collective good that will benefit society as a whole rather than the members of the group. The benefit that public interest lobbies seek may be for the public as consumers, for the public more broadly defined, or for some sector of the public. In 1973, Congress responded to consumer advocacy groups by creating the Consumer Product Safety Commission, which is authorized to regulate all consumer products and to ban products that are dangerous. Interest Groups and Democracy James Madison argued that a free society must allow for the representation of all groups that seek to influence political decision making, yet groups are usually more concerned with their own self-interest than with the needs of society as a whole; for democracy to work well, it is important that specific groups not be allowed to assume a dominant position. Madison’s solution was to create a wide-open system in which many groups would be able to participate. In a wide-open system groups with opposing interests would counterbalance one another. Proponents of pluralist theory assume that a rough approximation of the public interest emerges from this competition. However, if business PACs and multinational corporations effectively compete with consumer advocacy and public interest lobbies, how can the result be in the public interest? Some scholars conclude that the general increase in lobbying activity has actually resulted in less clout overall for individual interest groups – and better democracy. In other words, business PACs may attempt to undermine the public interest, but will not entirely succeed. Elitist theory argues that the ability of any powerful group to subvert what is in the public interest is itself corruption, while hyperpluralist theory would blame our inability to solve problems or promote the public interest on the proliferation of too many interest groups.