Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion Saturday, 12 March 2016 5:38 AM 12.11 Traps A heffalump is a type of fictional elephant in the Winnie the Pooh stories by A. A. Milne. In the fifth chapter of Winnie-the-Pooh, Pooh and Piglet attempt bravely to capture a heffalump in a trap. The term “heffalump trap” has been used in political journalism for a trap that is set up to catch an opponent but ends up trapping the person who set the trap (as happens to Winnie the Pooh in The House at Pooh Corner). 12.22 Behavioural Traps “Thank you for calling. All of our operators are temporarily busy. Please stay on the line and your call will be answered in the order received.” A minute passes. Two minutes. You begin to wonder whether you should hang up and redial. Maybe you got transferred to an empty line – a telephone twilight zone of some kind. If a call rings in the forest and no one is there to answer it! 12.33 Behavioural Traps On the other hand, hanging up probably means starting over. Other people will advance in the queue and you will lose whatever priority you had. Better to keep waiting. Who knows you may even be next in line. You wait a while longer. Three minutes. Four minutes. What is taking so long, you wonder? Finally you make a decision. If an operator doesn’t pick up the phone in the next sixty seconds, you will hang up. Thirty seconds goes by, Forty seconds. Fifty seconds and still no answer. As the deadline passes you hesitate a few hopeful moments, then slam the receiver down in frustration. 12.44 Behavioural Traps Sound familiar? This situation has all the features of a “behavioural trap”. A behavioural trap is a situation in which individuals or groups embark on a promising course of action that later becomes undesirable and difficult to escape from. This definition is similar to one developed by Platt (1973) in his pioneering work on social traps, and explored by Cross and Guyer (1980). Because traps can be non-social as well as social, however, the general term “behavioural trap” will be used rather than the more traditional “social trap”. 12.55 1.66 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.77 Behavioural Traps - A Taxonomy Of Traps In 1980, Cross and Guyer published a taxonomy of traps and counter-traps. In the words of Cross and Guyer (1980 p. 18) “Counter-traps (sins of omission) arise when we avoid potentially beneficial behaviour while traps (sins of commission) occur when we take potentially harmful courses of action.” As mentioned above, one common trap involves waiting for a telephone operator. 12.88 Behavioural Traps - A Taxonomy Of Traps Ordinary counter-traps include aversive cleaning chores (in which messes worsen with time) and overdue correspondence (in which embarrassment increases with the length of delay). There are several distinct types of traps, each with a corresponding counter-trap. 12.99 Behavioural Traps - A Taxonomy Of Traps Using the Cross-Guyer taxonomy as a starting point, we can divide traps into five general categories: 1. Time delay traps 2. Ignorance traps 3. Investment traps 4. Deterioration traps 5. Collective traps Although the elements of these five traps often combine to form hybrid traps, each trap works on somewhat different principles. The following sections therefore discuss each type 12.10 10 of trap separately. 1.11 11 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.12 12 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps If you find it hard to diet or exercise regularly, you know the power of time delay traps, momentary gratification clashes with long-term consequences. What begins innocently enough with a favourite dessert or a few cigarettes ends up many years later in obesity or lung cancer. Or, in the counter-trap version, the avoidance of what is momentarily unpleasant – aerobic exercise for some people, dental examinations for others – eventually leads to a heart attack or periodontal disease. 12.13 13 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps In fact tooth decay and heart disease are related? Sounds weird, but it is true. Many studies have found out that there is indeed a connection. Periodontal (gum) disease is an infection caused by bacteria that gets under the gum tissue and begins to destroy the gums and bone. Teeth become loose, chewing becomes difficult, and teeth may have to be extracted. Gum disease also may be connected to damage elsewhere in the body; recent studies link oral infections with diabetes, heart disease, stroke, and premature, low-weight births. CDC - Chronic Disease - Oral Health - At A Glance 12.14 14 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps What is striking about these traps and counter-traps is that relatively small pains and pleasures in the short run are sufficient to produce behaviour that is devastating or even lethal in the long run. Any situation in which short-term consequences run counter to long-term consequences has the potential for becoming a time delay trap. 12.15 15 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps Prototypic conflicts include the euphoria of drinking versus the next day’s hangover; the momentary pleasure of unprotected sex versus the deferred prospect of AIDS or unwanted pregnancy; the convenience of disposable products versus the long range environmental consequences the “buy now, pay later” option afforded by credit cards and higher purchase schemes; the quick but ultimately counter productive results 12.16 16 brought by corporal punishment. Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps the euphoria of drinking versus the next day’s hangover; David Nutt (Director of the Neuropsychopharmacology Unit, Imperial College London) reported: “Science now allows us to develop a safer way to get drunk. But before we can sober up in minutes, the drinks industry needs to embrace this healthier approach.” … “All that is needed now is funding to test and put them on the market.” Alcohol without the hangover? It's closer than you think - The Guardian - 11 November 2013 But was this new!! Alcohol substitute that avoids drunkenness and hangovers in development - Telegraph - 26 Dec 2009 12.17 17 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps Even the apple in the Garden of Eden can be regarded as bait in a time delay way – the ultimate symbol of temptation and its potentially entrapping consequences. 12.18 18 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps People in time delay traps often realise the long-term consequences of their behaviour. Over-eaters are usually very aware of putting on weight. Smokers some times even refer to cigarettes as “cancer sticks” or “coffin (coughing) nails”. Warnings about weight gain or cancer are rarely effective against time delay traps. 12.19 19 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps Doyle (2013) surveys over twenty models of delay discounting (also known as temporal discounting, time preference, time discounting), that psychologists and economists have put forward to explain the way people actually trade off time and money, see Reed et al. (2012) for a simple Excel model. 12.20 20 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps Aggregate indifference curves (indifference between the immediate and delayed consequences) for participants in the gambling and non-gambling contexts for delay discounting. Data points represent medians of the individual indifference points. Error bars represent the interquartile range of the individual indifference points at each delay. The solid line shows the best fit in the gambling context, and the dashed line shows the best fit in the non-gambling context (Dixon et al. 2006). 12.21 21 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps Error bars represent the interquartile range of the individual indifference points at each delay. The solid line shows the best fit in the gambling context, and the dashed line shows the best fit in the nongambling context (Dixon et al. 2006). The evidence suggests that empirically derived sensitivity to change in delay values (k, see below) from delay-discounting tasks are context sensitive and are not constant across various settings for the individual. The research findings illustrate that most pathological gamblers 12.22 22 discounted delayed rewards to a greater degree in a gambling context. Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps People are constantly making decisions that involve whether they take gains (also losses) now or at some later time(s). Individuals ‘discount the future’ when they value imminent goods over future goods. Discounting is typically assessed by offering real or hypothetical choices between different monetary sums after different delays. 12.23 23 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps For example if we offer a person who likes apples a choice between receiving one apple today or receiving two apples in a month, that person may choose the apple today because (a) the future apples are discounted such that they are worth subjectively less as a result of the delay, (b) the person does not trust us to deliver the apples in a month, (c) arranging to obtain the two apples in a month might be costly or inconvenient, thereby offsetting the value of the additional apple. 12.24 24 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps Indifference between a smaller, earlier reward (£tomorrow) and a larger, later reward (£future) indicates the following hyperbolic discount parameter k (Kirby and Santiesteban 2003 also Reed et al. 2012): £future - £tomorrow k= delay(in days) × £tomorrow - £future How do people choose between a smaller reward available sooner and a larger reward available later? The predictive accuracy of intertemporal-choice models Arfer, K.B. and Luhmann, C.C. British Journal Of Mathematical & Statistical Psychology 2015 68(2) 326-341 DOI: 10.1111/bmsp.12049 12.25 25 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps Wilson and Daly (2004) found that seeing pictures of the faces of attractive women induced men to discount money more steeply than if the faces were unattractive. Van den Bergh et al. (2008) reached similar conclusions for men who were asked to handle bikinis. After looking at sexually arousing images, men, but not women, become more impatient for financial rewards and more willing to take financial risks. A current stimulus for future behaviour. 12.26 26 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps Now a study has shown that women too show these changes to their decision making if they touch “sexually laden stimuli” - in this case men's boxer shorts (Festjens et al. 2014)! 12.27 27 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps What explains these effects on behaviour? Festjens and her colleagues believe that the touch of men's boxer shorts have sexual connotations that trigger the general reward circuitry in the women's brains hence their subsequent risk-taking and willingness to pay more for other rewards. For men, a similar, yet broader, process is triggered by the sight or touch of stimuli with sexual connotations. They said, “We call upon further research to investigate the genderspecific sensitivity to sexual cues and their effects”. 12.28 28 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps Skakoon-Sparling et al. (2015) report that sexual arousal has emerged as an important contextual feature in sexual encounters that can impact safer-sex decision-making. They conducted two experiments (decribed below) that investigated the effects of sexual arousal among male and female participants. 12.29 29 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps Skakoon-Sparling et al. (2015) experiment 1 (N = 144) examined the impact of sexual arousal on sexual health decision-making. Sexually explicit and neutral video clips as well as hypothetical romantic scenarios were used to evaluate the effects of sexual arousal on sexual risk-taking intentions. Men and women who reported higher levels of sexual arousal also displayed greater intentions to participate in risky sexual behaviour (e.g., unprotected sex with a new sex partner). 12.30 30 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps Skakoon-Sparling et al. (2015) experiment 2 (N = 122) examined the impact of sexual arousal on general risk-taking, using the same videos clips as in Experiment 1 and a modified version of a computerized Blackjack card game. Participants were offered a chance to make either a risky play or a safe play during ambiguous conditions. Increased sexual arousal in Experiment 2 was associated with impulsivity and a greater willingness to make risky plays in the Blackjack game. These findings suggest that, in situations where there are strong sexually visceral cues, both men and women experiencing strong sexual arousal may have lower inhibitions and may experience impaired decision-making. This phenomenon may have an impact during sexual encounters and may contribute to a failure to use 12.31 31 appropriate prophylactic protection. Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps It is reported that young men who have sex with men and have detectable levels of the human immunodeficiency virus (HIV) were more likely to report condomless anal sex, including with a partner not infected with HIV, than virologically suppressed young men who have sex with men, according to Wilson et al. (2015). 12.32 32 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps A willingness to take risks enhances men's sex appeal. This much we know from past research. What's not clear, is whether this is because of cultural beliefs about traditional gender roles, or if it's an evolutionary hang-over (or perhaps both). John Petraitis and his colleagues (2014) have put these two explanations to the test by drawing a distinction between risk-taking behaviours that reflect the challenges faced by our ancestors, and contemporary risks based around modern technology. 12.33 33 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps The young male and female participants agreed that the sex appeal of both sexes was boosted by engaging in risky behaviours relevant to our hunter gatherer ancestors. However, this attractiveness enhancement was far more pronounced for men, than for women. In contrast, men and women agreed that the sex appeal of both sexes was actually diminished by engaging in risky behaviour based on modern technology or contexts. Petraitis, J., Lampman, C., Boeckmann, R., and Falconer, E. (2014). Sex differences in the attractiveness of hunter-gatherer and modern risks Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 44 (6), 442-453. 12.34 34 Behavioural Traps - Time Delay Traps So losses stink! Loss aversion was larger when prospects were displayed in the presence of methylmercaptan (an unpleasant odour) compared to jasmine or clean air. Moreover, individual differences in changes in loss aversion to the unpleasant as compared to pleasant odour correlated with odour pleasantness but not with odour intensity. Skin conductance responses to losses during the outcome period were larger when gambles were associated with methylmercaptan compared to jasmine (Stancak et al. 2015). 12.35 35 1.36 36 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.37 37 Behavioural Traps - Delay Traps - Procrastination Students procrastinate instead of doing their schoolwork. In one study (Day et al. 2000), 32% of surveyed university students were found to be severe procrastinators — meaning that their procrastination had gone from being an annoyance to an actual problem — while only 1% claimed that they never procrastinated at all. Getting Over Procrastination - New Yorker - 22 July 2014 12.38 38 Behavioural Traps - Delay Traps - Procrastination Employees procrastinate instead of taking care of their office tasks. D'Abate and Eddy (2007) in a survey found the average employee spends about an hour and twenty minutes each day putting off work. That time, in turn, translates to a loss of about nine thousand dollars per worker per year. In the study, about a quarter of surveyed adults reported that procrastination was one of their defining personality traits. In addition to Americans, the sample included Europeans, South Americans, and Australians. 12.39 39 Behavioural Traps - Delay Traps - Procrastination About 95% of people who procrastinate wish they could reduce that tendency (O'Brien 2002); and, as Steel (2012) writes in his book, “The Procrastination Equation,” procrastination leads to lower over-all wellbeing, worse health, and lower salaries. To test the notion of procrastination directly, a study of three hundred and forty-seven pairs of same-sex identical (monozygotic) and fraternal (dizygotic) twins from the Colorado Longitudinal Twin Study was conducted (Gustavson et al. 2014). The Procrastination Equation - Steel - Psychology Today 2014 12.40 40 Behavioural Traps - Delay Traps - Procrastination The study had been ongoing since the twins’ birth, in the nineteen eighties, and had already yielded vast amounts of data on impulsivity, such as whether or not subjects had trouble initiating difficult tasks. They looked at the relationship between procrastination and impulsiveness more closely. They asked each twin to complete questionnaires measuring procrastination, impulsivity, and goal management, so that they could evaluate the extent to which those characteristics and behaviours are genetically, as opposed to environmentally, determined. The researchers found that each trait was moderately heritable: about 46% of the tendency to procrastinate, and 49% of the tendency 12.41 41 toward impulsiveness, was attributable to genes. 1.42 42 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.43 43 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps Ignorance traps operate differently. In these traps, the negative consequences of behaviour are not understood or forseen at the outset. 12.44 44 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps For example, smokers in the nineteenth century did not realise that smoking was related to lung cancer, and if this information had been available, many people would never have begun to smoke (of course smoking still has the properties of a time delay trap, and millions of people continue to be trapped even though the link with lung cancer is now well known). 12.45 45 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps Sir Richard Doll (Doll and Hill 1954) made history in the 1950’s as the scientist who established beyond doubt that smoking caused lung cancer. He is revered in the medical and scientific establishment not only for what he achieved but the way he achieved it: through painstaking analysis of the evidence. More recently Sir Richard Doll and colleagues from Oxford presented findings from the 50 years of follow-up of British doctors in relation to cancer risk (Doll et al. 2005). There are many important aspects surrounding this article, some of which deserve wider and deep reflection. 12.46 46 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps Ignorance traps are common when new life paths are taken. For example, college students some times end up specialising in a field that is not as exciting as initially imagined; workers some times find themselves trapped in a job that does not live up to expectations; lovers some times get involved with partners who are less appealing than they first seemed to be. Such traps are an inevitable part of life, though there are ways to minimise the chances of being trapped (techniques to reduce or avoid entrapment are discussed later in the chapter). 12.47 47 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps One particular tragic example of an ignorance trap is the story of insecticide dependence in American agriculture. When synthetic organic insecticides such as DDT were introduced in the 1940’s, they appeared to be an effective way to protect crops against insect damage. Soon after these products became available, American farmers adopted them as the method of choice for insect control. 12.48 48 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps Then two unforeseen events occurred: Birds and other insect predators began to die. Insects developed a resistance to the chemicals that were used. Insect damage began to increase. New insecticides were invented, but resistant strains of insects emerged once again. After 400 hundred million years of evolution, the insects were not giving up without a fight. 12.49 49 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps For decades this battle has been fought on the farmlands, yet each new round of chemical weapons serves only to provoke further pestilence. The percentage of American crops lost to insects doubled between the years 1950 and 1974 (Robbins 1987), and according to entomologists at the University of California, 24 of the 25 most serious agricultural pests in California are now insecticide induced or insecticide aggravated (Luck et al. 1977). Each year, more than 100 million pounds of insecticides are used in the United States, much to the detriment of wildlife, vegetation, waterways, and 12.50 50 human safety. 1.51 51 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.52 52 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps - PayDay Payday loans (examples of Investment Traps) in the United Kingdom are a rapidly growing industry, with four times as many people using such loans in 2009 compared to 2006. In 2009, 1.2 million people took out 4.1 million loans, with total lending amounting to £1.2 billion. The average loan size is around £300, and two-thirds of borrowers have annual incomes below £25,000. There are no restrictions on the interest rates payday loan companies can charge, although they are required by law to state the effective annual percentage rate (APR). 12.53 53 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps - PayDay According to Consumer Focus, “the cost of obtaining a loan online (often £25-£30 [per month] per £100) exceeds the costs of obtaining a loan on the High Street (often £13-£18 per £100)” because the lenders reject fewer applicants and face higher rates of fraud and default. Marie Burton, Consumer Focus, Keeping the plates spinning: Perceptions of payday loans in Great Britain 12.54 54 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps - PayDay In 2009, the payday loan industry generated around £242m in revenue - around 20% of the total lending. The largest lender is Dollar Financial Group (which includes The Money Shop and Express Finance), which provided around a quarter of all payday loans in 2009. In February 2011 Dollar Financial additionally acquired the largest British internet payday lender, PayDay UK, and suggested The Money Shop's network could grow from around 350 shops to around 1200. If you have financial problems contact our own Student Financial Support Fund. US payday loan firms plan rapid expansion in cash-strapped Britain | 11 February 2011 | The Guardian 12.55 55 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps - PayDay As the BBC (25-11-2013) report Payday lenders are facing a cap on the cost of their loans, under new government plans. An official study in 2010 said they provided a legitimate, useful, service that helped to cover a gap in the market. But in early 2013, the Office of Fair Trading said that there was widespread irresponsible lending in the industry. 12.56 56 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps - PayDay And by the end of the year, the government said there was “growing evidence” in support of a cap on the cost of a loan, including the fees and interest rates. Why borrowing £400 can cost from £3 to £130 - Telegraph 30 Jan 2014 12.57 57 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps - PayDay New rules being brought in to clean up the payday lending industry may result in the eradication of specialist high street lenders altogether, the head of the Financial Conduct Authority has admitted as he outlined a radical shake up of the controversial industry. Payday lenders will be forced to limit charges on loans under tough new rules set by the UK’s financial regulator on Tuesday. A cap will apply from January next year (2015) to ensure daily charges for interest and fees do not exceed 0.8% of the loan amount. New rules could wipe out payday lenders - FT - 11 Nov 2014 Use the up-to-date list to compare different loans. 12.58 58 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps - PayDay Using the BBC (3-12-2013) monthly PayDay interest rate calculator with an APR of 4670% on a loan of £250. 12.59 59 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps - PayDay Under-fire FCA spells out its targets for the year ahead | The Guardian | 31-3-2014 A review of how firms can prevent traders manipulating key benchmarks in a bid to stop a new Libor scandal and an investigation into how lenders treat borrowers who have fallen behind on repayments are among the City regulator's plans for the year ahead. The FCA takes over regulation of the consumer credit sector on Tuesday, and it also outlined plans for a review of how struggling borrowers are treated by the industry, and how loans are advertised. It has already signalled that it plans to get tough on the payday lenders that offer short-term loans at high interest rates, with new restrictions set to come into force in July, and it said it planned to visit the top five firms to check they are following the rules. Wheatley said: “Taking on the regulation of consumer credit is an enormous task which effectively doubles the number of firms we regulate.” “Using our new power we want to tackle harm to consumers who are most at risk and our work will focus on protecting vulnerable consumers.” 12.60 60 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps - PayDay Britain’s crackdown on payday lending is forcing a mass exodus from the quick credit market, with up to half the lenders pulling out in the past 18 months. A Financial Times analysis of data from the Financial Conduct Authority found that at least a third of the UK’s 210 payday lenders had failed to apply for permission to operate under the new regulatory regime introduced last month. That was on top of about 30 lenders that had surrendered licences or had them revoked by the Office of Fair Trading (OFT) since the end of 2012. The OFT said in 2012 that about 240 lenders were operating in the market. Tougher UK rules drive payday lenders away - FT - 22/5/2014 12.61 61 Behavioural Traps Ignorance Traps - PayDay A cap on charges that payday loan companies levy on customers came into effect on Friday, putting new constraints on the industry’s profitability. Regulations imposed by the Financial Conduct Authority mean customers taking out a loan will now never need to pay back more than twice the amount they borrowed. Interest and fees charged must not exceed 0.8% a day on the sum lent. If borrowers default, charges must not be greater than £15. Companies can continue to charge interest on the loan after default, but not above the initial rate. Some lenders such as Wonga have already restructured their rates and fees ahead of the introduction of the new rules. Others have closed down. Crackdown on payday loans charges - FT - 2 Jan 2015 Wonga rolls out revamped payday loans - FT - 19 May 2015 12.62 62 Behavioural Traps Investment Traps Cross and Guyer (1980) did not explicitly include investment traps in their taxonomy, but this type of trap has recently become the topic of a great deal of research. Investment traps occur when prior expenditures of time, money, or other resources lead people to make choices they would not otherwise make. In the parlance of decision research, these traps result in “sunk cost effects”. 12.63 63 Behavioural Traps Investment Traps This discussion closely follows that of Kahneman (2011). An ironic example that Thaler (1999) related in an early article remains one of the best illustrations of how mental accounting affects behaviour: Two avid sports fans plan to travel 40 miles to see a basketball game. One of them paid for his ticket; the other was on his way to purchase a ticket when he got one free from a friend. A blizzard is announced for the night of the game. Which of the two ticket holders is more likely to brave the blizzard to see the game? What do you think? 12.64 64 Behavioural Traps Investment Traps The answer is immediate: we know that the fan who paid for his ticket is more likely to drive. A rational decision maker is interested only in the future consequences of current investments. Justifying earlier mistakes is not among an economist’s concerns. The decision to invest additional resources in a losing account, when better investments are available, is known as the sunk-cost fallacy, a costly mistake that is observed in decisions large and small. Driving into the blizzard because one paid for tickets is a sunk-cost error. 12.65 65 Behavioural Traps Investment Traps Arkes and Blumer (1985) illustrated the effects of sunk costs in ten different mini-experiments. In one of these experiments, a group of subjects were given the following problem: As the president of an airline company, you have invested 10 million dollars of the company’s money into a research project. The purpose was to build a plane that would not be detected by conventional radar, in other words, a radar-blank plane. 12.66 66 Behavioural Traps Investment Traps When the project is 90% completed, another firm begins marketing a plane that cannot be detected by radar. Also, it is apparent that their plane is much faster and far more economical than the plane your company is building. The question is: should you invest the last 10% of the research funds to finish your radar-blank plane, yes or no? What would you do? 12.67 67 Behavioural Traps Investment Traps Arkes and Blumer found that 85% of their subjects recommended completing the project, even though the finished aircraft would be inferior to another plane already on the market. Then a second group were given the following problem. As president of an airline company, you have received a suggestion from one of your employees. 12.68 68 Behavioural Traps Investment Traps The suggestion is to use the last 1 million dollars of your research funds to develop a plane that would not be detected by conventional radar, in other words, a radar-blank plane. However, another firm has just begun marketing a plane that cannot be detected by radar. Also, it is apparent that their plane is much faster and far more economical than the plane your company could build. 12.69 69 Behavioural Traps Investment Traps The question is: should you invest the last million dollars of your research funds to build the radarblank plane proposed by your employee? What would you do? Only 17% opted to spend money on the project. (This version of the problem did not mention prior investments.) A sunk cost of $10 million made the difference. 12.70 70 Behavioural Traps Investment Traps In another experiment, Arkes and Blumer (1985) showed that sunk costs could have long lasting effects. The subjects in this study were 60 theatre patrons who approached the ticket window to buy season tickets for the Ohio University Theatre. 12.71 71 Behavioural Traps Investment Traps Unbeknownst to these people, they were randomly sold one of three tickets a normal ticket for $15 a ticket discounted by $2 a ticket discounted by $7 Subjects lucky enough to receive discounted tickets were told that the discounts were part of a promotion by the theatre. 12.72 72 Behavioural Traps Investment Traps Each type of ticket was a different colour, so Arkes and Blumer (1985) were able to collect the stubs after each performance and determine how many subjects attended each play. For purposes of analysis the theatre season was divided into two halves, each with five plays that ran over the course of six months. Although Arkes and Blumer did not find significant differences in the second half of the season, they found that, for the first six months, subjects who had paid the full ticket price attended more plays than those who had received a discount (regardless 12.73 73 of the size of the discount). Behavioural Traps Investment Traps Thus, even a paltry $2 difference in investment continued to influence behaviour for up to six months. This study is important for two reasons. First, it shows that sunk cost effects are not limited to paper and pencil measures. Second, it shows that differences in investment can have relatively enduring effects on behaviour. 12.74 74 Behavioural Traps Investment Traps As Fischhoff et al. (1981 p. 13) wrote, “The fact that no major dam in the United States has been left unfinished once begun shows how far a little concrete can go in defining a problem.” Not the case with Mount Rushmore. The initial concept called for each president to be depicted from head to waist. Lack of funding forced construction to end in late October 1941 with only the heads completed. 12.75 75 Behavioural Traps - Investment Traps Pseudo-Certainty Effect Investors will limit their risk exposure if they think their portfolio/investing returns will be positive – essentially protecting the lead – but they will seek more and more risk if it looks like they are heading for a loss. Basically, investors avoid risk when their portfolios are performing well and could bear more. They seek risk when their portfolios are floundering and don't need more exposure to possible losses. This is largely due to the mentality of winning it all back. Investors are willing to raise the stakes to “reclaim” capital, but not to create more capital. How long would a race car driver survive if he only used his brakes when he had the lead? (4 Psychological Traps That Are Killing Your Portfolio - Investopedia) 12.76 76 1.77 77 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.78 78 Investment Traps - Avoidance Hammond et al., 2006 1. Seek out and listen carefully to the views of people who were uninvolved with the earlier decisions and who are hence unlikely to be committed to them. 12.79 79 Investment Traps - Avoidance 2. Examine why admitting to an earlier mistake distresses you. If the problem lies in your own wounded self-esteem, deal with it head-on. Remind yourself that even smart choices can have bad consequences, through no fault of the original decision maker, and that even the best and most experienced managers are not immune to errors in judgment. Remember the wise words of Warren Buffett: “When you find yourself in a hole, the best thing you can do is stop digging.” (Warren Buffett 1930- is an American investor, industrialist and philanthropist. He is widely regarded as one of the most successful investors in the world.) 12.80 80 Investment Traps - Avoidance 3. Be on the lookout for the influence of investment cost biases in the decisions and recommendations made by your subordinates. Reassign responsibilities when necessary. 4. Don't cultivate a failure-fearing culture that leads employees to perpetuate their mistakes. In rewarding people, look at the quality of their decision making (taking into account what was known at the time their decisions were made), not just the quality of the outcomes. 12.81 81 1.82 82 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.83 83 Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps Deterioration traps are similar to investment traps, except that the costs and benefits of behaviour change over time. These traps – which Cross and Guyer (1980) called “sliding reinforcement traps” – occur when initially rewarding courses of action gradually become less reinforcing and/or more punishing. 12.84 84 Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps The emblematic example of a deterioration trap is heroin addiction (though heroin addiction can also be considered a time delay trap and an ignorance trap). At first, heroin users find the drug enjoyable. In time, however, they build up a tolerance. Larger doses are needed to achieve the same feeling and eventually, heroin users end up taking the drug to avoid with-drawl symptoms rather than to experience euphoria. What begins as a pleasant experience turns into a nightmare of dependence. 12.85 85 Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps Much the same process operates with “insecticide addiction.” Although the use of insecticides may have begun as an ignorance trap, it continues in part as a deterioration trap. According to a report in BioScience, insecticide dependence works like this: There is first a period of variable duration, in which crop losses to insects are greatly reduced. . . . Eventually, however, resistance develops in one of the primary, occasional, or insecticide induced pests. 12.86 86 Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps This problem is met by adding (diversifying) and changing insecticides, but the substituted materials . . . are generally more ephemeral and thus must be applied more frequently to effect the same degree of control. At this point, it also becomes difficult if not impossible for growers to extricate themselves from the strategy. As they continue to apply insecticides, their problems magnify (Luck et al. 1977 p. 607). 12.87 87 Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps Its still on-going! Insecticide regulators ignoring risk to bees, say MPs Damian Carrington The Guardian 12-12-2012 A parliamentary inquiry has uncovered evidence that links widespread use of neonicotinoid pesticides to decline in bees. 12.88 88 Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps A growing body of scientific evidence has linked the widespread use of neonicotinoid pesticides on crops to a serious decline in the bees and other pollinators, which are vital in producing a third of all food. The inquiry has uncovered evidence, apparently ignored by regulators, that the toxic insecticide can build up in soil to levels likely to be lethal to most insects, including the bees that overwinter in soil. 12.89 89 Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps Studies strengthen insecticide link to bee population decline - FT - 22 April 2015 Two studies have added powerful scientific evidence to the view that agricultural pesticides are contributing to a decline in bee populations across Europe and North America. One research team in Sweden found that neonicotinoid insecticides (neonics) reduced wild bee numbers. The other in the UK (Newcastle) discovered that bees preferred nectar containing neonics to uncontaminated nectar. Both studies appear in Nature, the scientific journal. Neonics have become a cause célèbre for the environmental movement in its battle against the agrochemical industry. Their worldwide sales are about $2bn a year, with Bayer of Germany and 12.90 90 Syngenta of Switzerland the largest producers. Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps Deterioration traps and counter-traps often produce behaviour that seems absurd or self destructive to bystanders who have not watched the situation evolve. 12.91 91 1.92 92 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck skip Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.93 93 Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps In his memoir Skinner (1980 pp. 150-1) described one example of such behaviour involving Bill and his truck: 12.94 94 Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps Bill’s truck is his only means of support – like a fisherman’s boat or a small farmer’s cow and plough horse. The island salt air, badly maintained roads, and the abuse of a drunken driver have nearly finished it. The windshield is full of small holes with radiating cracks. The fenders are rusted to thin sheets, bent and torn. Only fragments of padding remain on the springs of the seat. 12.95 95 Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps I asked Bill to help bring our boat down the hill. The truck was parked on a downgrade in front of the village store. I got in and sat on what was left of the right side of the seat. Bill gave the truck a push, jumped in, set the gear, and, as we picked up a little speed, let in the clutch. A violent jerk, and the motor began to cough. Bill . . . pumped the accelerator wildly, keeping his hand on the choke. Satisfied that the motor was started, he reversed and backed rapidly to the store to turn around. The truck stalled across the road. 12.96 96 Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps Three or four of us pushed, including two young men from a car whose way was blocked. . . . We went downgrade again, starting and stalling. From time to time Bill would jump out, open the hood and adjust something with a wrench. We worked our way a tenth of a mile in the wrong direction, the engine coughing and exploding and refusing to race as Bill pumped gas. Eventually he explained that his starter was in for repairs. It might come back on the excursion boat. How would it be if he came up for the boat in a couple of hours? He did not come. Forty-eight hours later he was still parking his truck on downgrades. No 12.97 97 one would tow him anymore. Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps Why does he go on? For one thing there is no alternative. He drinks away his income . . . [But his] lack of alternatives is not the whole story. His zealous preoccupation with the truck is the result of a [shrinking ratio of reinforcement to effort] . . . Bill will not take no from the truck. If it were a horse, he would have beaten it to death long ago, for it is also the lot of an aging horse to reinforce the behaviour of its owner on a lengthening ratio of work per task. Bill’s truck is being beaten to death too. 12.98 98 Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps To an outside observer who does not know Bill’s history, his actions may seem ludicrous and bizarre. Yet the same dynamic operates routinely in deteriorating social or romantic relationships. When interpersonal relationships erode gradually over time, they create a counter-trap in which exiting becomes extremely difficult. 12.99 99 1.100 100 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.101 101 Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps - Facit Consider the Facit case, for a real world example. A Swedish firm, Facit AB, formed in 1920 to make mechanical calculators and it then operated with great success for almost 50 years. Besides mechanical calculators, it made typewriters and office equipment like desks and chairs. A few of its personnel had dreamed of someday making electronic equipment. Facit’s mechanical calculators contained approximately 2,300 components that required specialized machinery to be produced. 12.102 102 Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps - Facit The Facit calculator was arguably one of the most profitable products in Sweden. Even though Facit’s performance declined from the mid-1960s, minutes from board and top management meetings in 1965 and 1966 do not reveal any concerns. Rather, management seems to have been occupied with expansion plans. In 1966, a company forecast was presented to management projecting that sales of mechanical calculators would continue to increase 12% annually over the coming years, which implied that the number of employees in the calculator business in Atvidaberg would 12.103 103 increase from 1,060 to 1,830. Behavioural Traps Deterioration Traps - Facit Facit made its first entry into electronics in the 1950s when it created the subsidiary Facit Electronics. Calculators based on individual transistors started to emerge in the early 1960s. Did it not see the writing on the wall? It used electronic calculators to perform quality control on its manual calculator production lines! For more details see Sandstrom (2013) or Starbuck and Nystrom (1997). 12.104 104 1.105 105 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.106 106 Behavioural Traps Collective Traps Unlike the previous traps, collective traps involve more than one party. In collective traps, the pursuit of individual selfinterest results in adverse consequences for the collective. A simple example is rush hour traffic. Hundreds of people prefer to drive at the same time, but if each person operates according to selfinterest, everyone suffers. 12.107 107 Behavioural Traps Collective Traps Collective traps – a close cousin of the “social dilemma” in mathematical and game theory (Dawes 1980) – have received more research attention than all the other traps combined. 12.108 108 Behavioural Traps Collective Traps The most celebrated example of a collective trap is the Prisoner’s Dilemma in which two prisoners are confined in separate jail cells and offered a deal such as the following. 12.109 109 1.110 110 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma skip Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.111 111 Behavioural Traps Collective Traps District Attorney: Listen Billy Boy. We’ve got enough evidence to send you and your partner up the river for a year if neither of you confesses. What we’d really like, though, is to get at least one confession. If you confess and your partner doesn’t, we’ll hit your partner with 10 years and let you go free. On the other hand if you play it quiet and your partner comes clean, you’ll be the one who gets 10 years. 12.112 112 Behavioural Traps Collective Traps Wild Bill: What if we both confess – will we both get 10 years. District Attorney: No. In that case, we’ll reward your honesty with a reduced sentence of 5 years. 12.113 113 Behavioural Traps Collective Traps In a standard Prisoner’s Dilemma, both prisoners face the same choice – a choice in which they are better off confessing regardless of what their partner chooses. If their partner refuses to confess, they are set free; if not, they are at least protected against a 10year sentence. The dilemma is that if both prisoners follow their self-interest and confess, they will each receive a sentence five times longer than if both keep quiet. 12.114 114 Behavioural Traps Collective Traps For a recent paper on the prisoner’s dilemma see Pothos et al. (2011). 12.115 115 1.116 116 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.117 117 Behavioural Traps Collective Traps Another famous collective trap is what biologist Hardin (1968) dubbed “the tragedy of the commons.” In the classic version of this trap, a herding community uses common pastureland to graze cattle. 12.118 118 Behavioural Traps Collective Traps At first there is no problem, but in time the number of cattle reaches the carrying capacity of the land. At that point, the utility of adding another animal to the herd has two components – one positive and one negative. The positive utility consists of whatever profit can be made from raising one more animal. This profit belongs solely to the herder who adds the animal; the negative utility is a function of the additional over grazing caused by a new animal. This cost is borne by all members of the community and is negligible to any 12.119 119 one herder. Behavioural Traps Collective Traps The result is a dilemma in which one person benefits from adding another animal to the herd, but the pursuit of individual self-interest leads to an outcome that is less than ideal. Hardin likened the tragedy of the commons to problems such as over population, pollution, global resource depletion, and the proliferation of nuclear weapons. 12.120 120 Behavioural Traps Collective Traps The tragedy of the commons is similar in many ways to the infamous “mattress problem,” a collective counter-trap first described by Schelling (1971). In the mattress problem thousands of cars on a twolane highway are returning from a weekend on Cape Cod when a mattress falls into the northbound lane, unnoticed, from the top of a station wagon. The question is: Who stops to move the mattress? 12.121 121 Behavioural Traps Collective Traps Often times, the answer is that no one does. People far back in the stream of traffic don’t know what the problem is and can’t help. People who are passing the mattress have waited so long in line that all they can think of is how to get around it. After such a long wait, the last thing they want to do is spend another few minutes pulling a mattress out of the lane. And those who have already passed the mattress no 12.122 122 longer have a direct stake in moving it. Behavioural Traps Collective Traps The mattress problem resembles the type of collective counter-trap found in emergency situations (in which responsibility is diffused and bystanders are slow to intervene or simply film the outcome). Leytonstone Tube station stabbing a 'terrorist incident' - BBC News - 6 Dec 2015 “video of the aftermath of the attack has been posted online” It may also provide a partial explanation for the political “apathy” so prevalent in the United States. Unfortunately, as Hofstadter (1985 p. 757) has succinctly observed “Apathy at the individual level translates into insanity at the mass level”. 12.123 123 1.124 124 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.125 125 Behavioural Traps – Bystander Behaviour Darley and Latané (1968) ran a series of experiments in the late 1960s. The most famous exercise took place in a room into which smoke could be piped. Research participants were taken inside, where they might be left alone; with two other participants; or with two researchers masquerading as participants oblivious to the incoming smoke. The majority of participants (75%) who were alone in the room reported the smoke; by contrast, only 10% of those in a room with two seemingly unobservant researchers reported it. 12.126 126 Behavioural Traps – Bystander Behaviour Darley and Latané attributed this to two factors: one was the “diffusion of responsibility effect”, where the presence of others leads individuals to assume that someone else will help or already has. The other factor was “the power of social norms”; in which people observe others’ reactions to evaluate the severity of a situation. 12.127 127 Behavioural Traps – Bystander Behaviour Darley et al. (1973) note that previous studies of bystander intervention in emergencies have found that an individual is more likely to intervene if he witness the emergency alone than as a member of a group. In a study with 50 male undergraduates, pairs of students working on a task overheard a loud crash in an adjoining room. Some pairs of students were seated in a pattern that facilitated the visual communication exchanges that naturally occur when a noisy event takes place and others were seated so as to block these communications. 12.128 128 Behavioural Traps – Bystander Behaviour When the emergency occurred, groups which could exchange reactions were not reliably less likely to respond than were a third group of students who faced the emergency alone. The blocked communications groups tended not to respond and responded significantly less than the other 2 conditions. Results support the hypothesis that a group of people who witness an ambiguous event interact to arrive at a definition or interpretation of it, which then guides each member's reactions to the event. 12.129 129 Behavioural Traps – Bystander Behaviour Levine et al. (1994) evaluated “helping behaviours” in cities all over the world. In each city, Levine and his team have run a series of experiments in which bystanders have the opportunity to help or not help a stranger. In one experiment, for example, researchers feigned a leg injury and dropped a large pile of magazines, in view of a passing pedestrian, and visibly struggled to bend over and pick them up. Rankings were obtained on a number of criteria for 36 US cities, the most helpful was Rochester (NY) and the least Patterson (NJ). 12.130 130 Behavioural Traps – Bystander Behaviour Two experiments (Levine et al. 2005) exploring the effects of social category membership on real-life helping behaviour were reported. In Study 1, inter-group rivalries between soccer fans are used to examine the role of identity in emergency helping. An injured stranger wearing an in-group team shirt is more likely to be helped than when wearing a rival team shirt or an unbranded sports shirt. In Study 2, a more inclusive social categorisation is made salient for potential helpers. Helping is extended to those who were previously identified as out-group members but not to those who do not display signs of group membership. Taken together, the studies show the importance of both shared identity between bystander and victim and the inclusiveness of salient identity for increasing the likelihood of emergency 12.131 131 intervention. 1.132 132 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.133 133 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Modern psychological and economic research has identified herd behaviour in humans to explain the phenomena of large numbers of people acting in the same way at the same time. For example, stock market bubbles, large stock market trends often begin and end with periods of frenzied buying (bubbles) or selling (crashes) (Lee and Ahn 2015). 12.134 134 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour What is a bubble? It cannot exist in rational markets because bubbles imply deviations of prices from intrinsic values. A positive bubble in a security exists when its price is higher than its intrinsic value. Whereas a negative bubble exists when its price is lower than its intrinsic value. Bubbles can persist in unbeatable markets if investors are unable to exploit them for excess returns because, for example, digging for information about intrinsic values is difficult. Trading on such information is costly, and risk which is embedded in necessarily imprecise estimations of intrinsic values can bring losses (Shefrin and Statman 2012). 12.135 135 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Many observers cite these episodes as clear examples of herding behaviour that is irrational and driven by emotion – greed in the bubbles, fear in the crashes. Individual investors join the crowd of others in a rush to get in or out of the market (Brunnermeier 2001). One of the distinctive features of the start of this century was the formation and collapse of two financial market bubbles – one in internet stocks and a second in the housing and mortgage finance system. The Bank of England has said it is poised to take fresh steps to slow down Britain's housing market if the pickup in prices and mortgage demand threatens a new property bubble. Bank of England poised to act over house price momentum | The Guardian | 27/3/2014. 12.136 136 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour London house prices rose 18% in a year (2013/4) fuelling fears of a bubble. Nationwide's figures put London house prices above pre-crisis peak at an average £362,699, as gap widens with rest of UK. House prices in London have increased by almost a fifth over the past 12 months, and are now 20% above their pre-crisis peak, according to the latest data from the country's biggest building society. In news that will fuel concerns of a price bubble in the capital, Nationwide Building Society said the average price of a London home had increased by 18% over the year and by 5.3% in the past three months alone, and at £362,699 was now more than twice the figure for the rest of the UK. London house prices rise 18% in year fuelling fears of bubble | The Guardian | 1/5/2014 also see Later Slide (Bank of Mum and Dad). 12.137 137 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Bank of England deputy (Cunliffe) argues it would be “dangerous to ignore the momentum that has built up in the UK housing market”. Surging house prices pose the single biggest threat to UK financial stability. Cunliffe, who is in charge of financial stability at the Bank, suggested that it might have to take radical steps to curb the recent housing boom, which could include introducing a cap on how much Britons can borrow. Surging house prices pose the single biggest threat to UK financial stability, the deputy Governor of the Bank of England has warned. Cunliffe said that policymakers must decide quickly whether to take action to cool the market and, in the starkest warning yet that rapid price rises could derail Britain’s recovery, argued that it would be “dangerous to ignore the momentum that has built up in the UK housing market”. 12.138 138 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Price rises have not been limited to London and “pent-up demand” could “add significantly to pressure on the market for the next few years.” “All of this paints a picture of further pressure on transactions that could take us quickly to pre-crisis rates,” he said. Dangerous to ignore house price boom warns BoE deputy | Telegraph | 1/5/2014 Jon Cunliffe, Threadneedle Street's deputy governor for financial stability, said it would be dangerous to ignore the momentum apparent across the country and dropped strong hints of new measures to slow down the market in the months ahead. Bank of England warns housing market boom may turn to crash | The Guardian | 1/5/2014 12.139 139 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour The behavioural finance literature is full of examples of measurable stock price distortions. It would seem easy to build superior performing portfolios, but doing so would mean taking positions that are opposite to the crowd. The powerful need for social validation acts as a strong deterrent for many investors, discouraging them from pursuing such an approach. It is tough to leave the emotional crowd and become behavioural-data investors. Though we find price distortions to be measurable and persistent, building a portfolio benefiting from them is emotionally challenging (Howard 2013). 12.140 140 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Hey and Morone (2004) analysed a model of herd behaviour in a market context. Their work is related to at least two important strands of literature. The first of these strands is that on herd behaviour in a non-market context. Private information that is not publicly shared. The second of the strands is that of information aggregation in market contexts. Uninformed traders in a market context can become informed through the price in such a way that private information is aggregated correctly and efficiently. 12.141 141 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour For strand 1, the seminal references are Banerjee (1992) and Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer and Welch (1992), both of which showed that herd behaviour might result from private information not publicly shared. More specifically, both of these papers showed that individuals, acting sequentially on the basis of private information and public knowledge about the behaviour of others, might end up choosing the socially undesirable option. 12.142 142 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour The second of the strands of literature motivating this chapter is that of information aggregation in market contexts. A very early reference is the classic paper by Grossman and Stiglitz (1976) that showed that uninformed traders in a market context could become informed through the price in such a way that private information is aggregated correctly and efficiently. A summary of the progress of this strand of literature can be found in the paper by Plott (2000). 12.143 143 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Hey and Morone (2004) showed that it is possible to observe herd-type behaviour in a market context. Their result is even more interesting since it refers to a market with a well-defined fundamental value (they designed a simplified share market). Even if herd behaviour might only be observed rarely, this has important consequences for a whole range of real markets – most particularly foreign exchange markets. 12.144 144 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Empirical results are consistent with the notion that concern about reputation causes herding. Thus, younger portfolio managers deviate less from consensus than their older colleagues. Possibly because they have more at stake in terms of reputation, as they face a longer working life ahead (Hong, Kubik, and Solomon, 2000). 12.145 145 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Experiments with professional stock analysts have also demonstrated reputational herding. In one study (Cote and Sanders, 1997), the participants’ task was to predict future returns. After each prediction, the average prediction was shown to the participants, giving them an opportunity to adjust their own predictions. The results showed that presenting the average prediction had a significant influence and that the degree of influence was related to the participants’ perceptions of their own ability and motivation to create or maintain a good reputation. 12.146 146 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Motivated by extant theories of herding behaviour, Wei et al. (2015) empirically identify contrarian mutual funds, those trading most frequently against the crowd. They find that “contrarian funds generate superior performance both when they trade against and with the herd”, indicating that they possess superior private information. Uncommon Value: The Characteristics and Investment Performance of Contrarian Funds (Wei et al. 2015) 12.147 147 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Furthermore, contrarians do not trade in a particularly correlated fashion with each other. Consistent with these funds having disparate information. The fund-level contrarian measure is largely unrelated to existing measures of fund strategy uniqueness, as both contrarian and herding funds score highly on such measures. 12.148 148 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Contrarian investment funds far outperform their herd-fund rivals in several performance measurements. Research suggests, that their managers have found ways to gather information that other managers have not figured out. Wei et al. 2015 also Zig while others zag for more successful investments - ScienceDaily - 13 Nov 2015 12.149 149 1.150 150 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.151 151 Emotional Crowds Or Behavioural-Data Investors Behavioural portfolio management, a concept within the broader paradigm of behavioural finance. Assumes most investors make decisions based on emotions and shortcut heuristics (see lecture 1). Behavioural portfolio management posits that there are two categories of financial market participants: emotional crowds and behavioural-data investors. 12.152 152 Emotional Crowds Or Behavioural-Data Investors Emotional crowds are made up of investors who base decisions on anecdotal evidence and emotional reactions to unfolding events. Human evolution hardwires us for short-term loss aversion and social validation, which are the underlying drivers of today’s emotional crowds (Howard 2013). Emotional investors make their decisions based on what Kahneman (2012) refers to as System 1 thinking: automatic, loss-avoiding and quick, with little or no effort and no sense of voluntary control. 12.153 153 Emotional Crowds Or Behavioural-Data Investors On the other hand, behavioural-data investors make their decisions using thorough and extensive analysis of available data. Behavioural-data investors use what Kahneman (2012) refers to as System 2 thinking: effortful, high-concentration and complex. Behavioural portfolio management is built on the dynamic interplay between these two investor groups (Howard 2013). 12.154 154 1.155 155 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.156 156 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Peer-to-peer lending (also known as person-to-person lending, peer-to-peer investing, and social lending; abbreviated frequently as P2P lending) is the practice of lending money to unrelated individuals, or “peers”, without going through a traditional financial intermediary such as a bank or other traditional financial institution. This lending takes place online on peer-to-peer lending companies' websites using various different lending platforms and credit checking tools. Peer-to-peer lending - Wikipedia 12.157 157 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour The results of an empirical study (Dholakia and Soltysinski, 2001) provide evidence of strategic herding behaviour by lenders such that they have a greater likelihood of bidding on an auction with more bids (a 1% increase in the number of bids increases the likelihood of an additional bid by 15%), but only to the point at which it has received full funding. After this point, herding diminishes (a 1% increase in bids increases the likelihood of an additional bid by only 5%). 12.158 158 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour They also found a positive association between herding in the loan auction and its subsequent performance. That is, whether borrowers pay the money back on time. Unlike eBay auctions where herding impacts bidders adversely, their findings reveal that strategic herding behaviour in P2P loan auctions benefits bidders, individually and collectively (Dholakia and Soltysinski, 2001). 12.159 159 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Michal Herzenstein et al. (2011) studied herding behaviour in peer-to-peer loan auctions. Online Peer-toPeer (P2P) loan auctions enable individual consumers to borrow and lend money directly to one another. They studied herding behaviour, defined as a greater likelihood of bidding in auctions with more existing bids, in P2P loan auctions on Prosper.com. Unlike eBay auctions where herding impacts bidders adversely, their findings reveal that strategic herding behaviour in P2P loan auctions benefits bidders, individually and collectively. 12.160 160 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Equity income and multi-asset fund managers are adding peerto-peer debt to their portfolios after the launches of two investment trusts opened up access to the fast-growing sector through listed shares. Managers of F&C and Axa Investment have been attracted to peer-to-peer by annual target yields of six to eight per cent, combined with a perceived low correlation with other asset classes. They see potential for long-term growth in the sector, in which consumers and institutions lend directly to individuals or businesses through online platforms. Fund managers turn to P2P - FT - 6 May 2015 12.161 161 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour It must be succeeding, if its being copied. Six months ago Goldman Sachs was a lead underwriter on the initial public offering of Lending Club, the biggest and brashest of a new breed of online lenders. Now the Wall Street titan is looking to disrupt the disrupters, launching its own web-based business offering loans to consumers and small businesses. Rather than using a peer-to-peer model — matching borrowers and investors through the online platform — Goldman will look to fund loans directly via its New York State-chartered banking subsidiary, which was set up after Goldman became a bankholding company in the wake of the 2008 financial crisis. To date, the unit — with $128bn in assets at the end of March — has mostly provided loans to private clients and institutions. Goldman joins online lenders’ club - FT - 16 June 2015 12.162 162 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Growth in peer-to-peer lending passed a new milestone this week. Data revealed that platforms such as Zopa, RateSetter and Funding Circle lent out more than £500m in the first half of the year. The latest figures from the Peer-to-Peer Finance Association show the nascent industry’s expansion is picking up speed, with lending on track to hit a record £1bn in 2014. More than 66,000 individuals have lent money through these platforms to entrepreneurs and businesses such as start-up airlines or wind turbine projects, in return for high rates of interest at around 6%. Peer-to-peer lending: the risks and rewards - FT - 4 Aug 2014 Lending services revolution piles pressure on banks as fintech sector grows - FT - 8 Dec 2015 12.163 163 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Consumers from lower income groups look set to be the big beneficiaries of the peer-to-peer rental market generated through the sharing economy, according to the latest research from professors at New York University (NYU). Peer-to-peer rental — of houses or cars, for example — has grown in popularity in recent years as an alternative to outright purchase. One of the things the research set out to determine was how these developments changed people’s modes of consumption, says Arun Sundararajan, professor of information, operations and management sciences at NYU Stern, and one of the two researchers on the preprint. The research focused on peer-to-peer rental in the car market in San Francisco, where 10% of the population rent cars through the sharing economy. Some of the findings were to be expected, says Prof. Sundararajan — only a fraction of the population stopped buying and started renting instead, for example. Sharing economy benefits lower income groups - FT - 27 April 2015 12.164 164 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Crowd funding (alternately: crowdfunding, crowd financing, equity crowdfunding) (Prpića et al. 2015) is a process in which web sites provide Internet platforms which support the collective cooperation, attention and trust by people who network and pool their money and other resources for projects initiated by other people or organizations. Comparison of crowd funding services – Wikipedia One in five UK crowdfunding investments fail - FT 19 Nov 2015 12.165 165 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour While crowdfunding is usually aimed at start-ups and asks backers to invest to get an idea off the ground, P2P is usually directed at businesses that have been around for at least a few years. Crowdfunding and peer-to-peer lending: How start-ups learnt to work a crowd, Independent, 6 April 2013 includes two interesting case studies. Of course there is a cost P2P providers urged to come clean on fees - FT - 7 Sept 2015. Popular capitalism or the madness of crowds - FT - 6 March 2015 A beer or a milkshake? Crowdfunding can bring delicious dividends - The Guardian - 10 March 2015 12.166 166 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour However the following comments from the Financial Services Authority should be noted. “We believe most crowdfunding should be targeted at sophisticated investors who know how to value a startup business, understand the risks involved and that investors could lose all of their money.” “We want it to be clear that investors in a crowdfund have little or no protection if the business or project fails, and that they will probably lose all their investment if it does.” 12.167 167 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour We are also concerned that some firms involved in crowdfunding may be handling client money without our permission or authorisation, and therefore may not have adequate protection in place for investors. 12.168 168 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Savers warned of dangers of investing in start-ups through crowdfunding websites as investors in Bubble & Balm face losing their shirts - Daily Mail - 11 September 2013 Savers who lent money to start-up firm Bubble & Balm on a crowdfunding website recently learned they could lose all their cash. THE MINOR INVESTOR: The wisdom of the crowd or herd mentality? Crowdfunding looks tempting but it pays to tread carefully - Daily Mail - 5 Feb 2015 12.169 169 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Alternative financing draws in almost £1bn - FT - 13-12-2013 Almost £1bn in loans and equity funding has been generated through crowdfunding, peer-to-peer lending and invoice trading, according to a comprehensive study of the market. Data compiled by the think-tank Nesta with the Universities of Cambridge and Berkeley (California), put the total value of this type of activity – which relies on online marketplaces bringing together those who have cash and those who want it to bypass the banks – at £939m. The Rise of Future Finance - Nesta - 13/12/2013 12.170 170 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Linked to P2P is the so called “Bank Of Mum And Dad”. However the Council of Mortgage Lenders (CML 5 June 2013) have published a worrying report. Millions of parents are “unable or unwilling” to help their children. “Deposit constraints loom large in framing people’s perceptions about their ability to buy a home”. Deposit demand is major worry for parents and many can't help children. In 2006, 67% of first-time buyers got on the housing ladder without financial help from parents - but by last year (2012) this figure had collapsed to just 36%. Bank Of Mum And Dad - Council of Mortgage Lenders - News & Views Issue no. 10 - 5 June 2013 Youngsters who need to inherit to buy a house: Half of parents fear their children will never be able to own their own property - Daily Mail - 21 April 2015 Now it's the 'bank of son and daughter': Parents increasingly turning to children for mortgage help after 'ageist' lenders turn them down - Daily Mail - 19 May 2015 12.171 171 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour On the other hand, according to the Office For National Statistics (2013), there has been a large increase in 20 to 34-year-olds living with parents since 1996. In 2013, over 3.3 million adults in the UK aged between 20 and 34 were living with a parent or parents. That is 26% of this age group. 12.172 172 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour However Nikolaev (2015) found Living at the parental home past adolescence is associated with lower life satisfaction. The negative effect of living at the parental home is non-linear with age. The difference in life satisfaction is stronger for individuals around the ages of 35-45. 12.173 173 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Nearly two million working young adults aged between 20 and 34 years old in England are still living with their parents according to Shelter, which is urging stronger action to help the “clipped wing generation” fly the nest. The charity said data it has taken from the Census shows that there are 1.97 million people in this age group in England who are still living with their parents, accounting for one quarter of all young adults in employment. A survey commissioned by the charity also found that nearly half (48%) of 250 young adults who live with their parents said they do so because they cannot afford to rent or buy their own home. 'Clipped wing generation' still live with mum and dad - Telegraph - 29/7/2014 12.174 174 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour More children in the Western world are staying at home longer, but their parents often pay the price as tensions flare and conflict damages relationships, an international literature review shows. The study, conducted by researchers at the University of Melbourne, concluded that the changing nature of family living situations often led to avoidable conflict. Boomerang families and failure-to-launch: commentary on adult children living at home. Katherine Burn, Cassandra Szoeke. Maturitas, 2016; DOI: 10.1016/j.maturitas.2015.09.004 More young adults are failing to launch or 'boomerang' home, study shows - ScienceDaily - 12 Nov 2015 12.175 175 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Average house price in England could double in next decade, report says. Research by Shelter and KPMG shows a radical new housebuilding programme is needed to provide nearly 250,000 new homes a year. The average price of a house in England could double in the next decade and hit more than £900,000 by 2034, unless there is a radical new house building programme to provide nearly a quarter of a million new homes a year, a report claims today. Research by the housing charity Shelter and consultancy firm KPMG suggests that more than half of those aged 20-34 could be living with their parents by 2040 as rising housing costs lock them out of the property market. Average house price in England could double in next decade, report says - The Guardian - 1/5/2014 12.176 176 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Parents with adult children still living at home are typically spending £1,200 a year more on items such as groceries and bills than those whose offspring have flown the nest, according to a new report. It claimed some “full nesters” were putting their own financial futures at risk as a result of having to provide room and board for grown-up children at a time when they would prefer to be focusing on preparing for their old age. The findings are contained in a report called Meet the Full Nesters, published by the Centre for the Modern Family, a think tank set up three years ago by the insurer Scottish Widows. Parents with adult children at home putting financial future at risk – Guardian - 22/Oct/2014 12.177 177 Behavioural Traps – Other Sources Owners of young businesses often have an abundance of ideas and enthusiasm, but a shortage of cash. A loan seems like the most logical answer, right? That would be the case if loans were given out like candy, but unfortunately, small business loans are still a challenge to come by. Alternative lending options exist, but those come with downsides too. So, many default to borrowing money from more financially stable friends and family. But does a friends and family loan always make sense? Is there any situation that it actually works out for every one involved? Why It’s So Hard to Succeed With Friend or Family Loans Business.com - 11 June 2015 12.178 178 Behavioural Traps – Other Sources New research shows what many people can guess intuitively: Lending money can cause negative effects on the relationships between people who borrow and people who lend. According to an article in the Boston Globe (26 July 2012), Dezső and Loewenstein (2012) say that their investigation into the impact of personal loans on people’s feelings “is the first to academically study the consequences of personal loans between friends, coworkers, siblings, and cousins.” They found “that borrowers have a blind spot when it comes to recognising the negative feelings and perceptions evoked in lenders by delinquent loan repayment”. With Personal Loans, Lenders Have "Blind Trust" and Borrowers Have "Blind Spots" - MIT Sloan Review - 26 July 2012 12.179 179 Behavioural Traps – Other Sources Dezső and Loewenstein (2012) surveyed 971 individuals about their experiences with personal loans. Beyond the objective characteristics of the loans (e.g., whether interest was charged), and the purpose of the loan, they tested – and found support for – two main predictions: (1) that recall and evaluation of loans would be subject to a selfserving bias such that borrowers would, for example, recall having paid back a larger proportion of the loan (2) that loans, and particularly those not paid off by the agreed upon date, would have pernicious effects on the personal relationship between lender and borrower. 12.180 180 1.181 181 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.182 182 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour An example of a P2P auction Funding Circle 12.183 183 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour An example of a P2P auction Funding Circle 12.184 184 1.185 185 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.186 186 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour Some Examples Of Bubbles Tulip mania (1637) Mississippi Company (1720) Encilhamento (“Mounting”) (1886–1892) Roaring Twenties stock-market bubble (19221929) Japanese asset price bubble (1980s) The Dot-com bubble (1995–2000) Australian first home buyer (FHB) property bubble (2009) British property bubble (2006) United States housing bubble (2007) Spanish property bubble (2006) Romanian property bubble (2008) South Sea Company (1720) Railway Mania (1840s) Florida speculative building bubble (1926) Poseidon bubble (1970) Asian Financial Crisis (1997) Real estate bubble (2000s) Indian property bubble (2005) Irish property bubble (2006) The former Florida swampland real estate bubble (2007) China stock and property bubble (2007) Uranium bubble (2007) source and links 12.187 187 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour – Bubble Examples For instance The Rhodium bubble of 2008 (increase from $500/oz to $9000/oz in July 2008, then down to $1000/oz in January 2009) Exotic Livestock production in North America (i.e. llamas, ostriches, white tail deer, elk, wild boar, and to a lesser extent bison) and the U.K. (i.e. ostrich eggs, ostriches, llamas, wild boar and emu eggs). 12.188 188 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour – Bubble Examples Higher education bubble (1980–Present) the steep increase of tuition and other costs at colleges and universities, and a possible future collapse. The expansion of higher education raises the risk environment for school-leavers, as more occupations become partially graduate with the result that occupational signals are fuzzy. It is shown that a rising proportion of graduates receive only average pay, thus raising the risks associated with educational investments even further. Malcolm Brynin, “Individual Choice and Risk: The Case of Higher Education” 12.189 189 Sociology April 2013 47(2) 284-300. Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour – Bubble Examples The earnings of recent English graduates have deteriorated so rapidly since the financial crisis that the latest class is earning 12% less than their pre-crash counterparts at the same stage in their careers. They also owe about 60% more in student debt. Graduate data reveal England’s lost and indebted generation - FT - 18 November 2013 12.190 190 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour – Bubble Examples As Britain starts to emerge from the downturn, a Financial Times analysis of student loan data exposes the damage done to a generation of graduates, for whom a degree has all but ceased to be a golden ticket to a decent job. Tuition fees in England almost tripled last year to a maximum £9,000 a year. Graduate data reveal England’s lost and indebted generation - Financial Times - 18 Nov 2013 12.191 191 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour – Bubble Examples Nearly three-quarters of UK students will fail to clear their student loans before they are written off after 30 years, and the large majority will still be paying off their loans well into their forties and early fifties, according to new research for the Sutton Trust by the Institute for Fiscal Studies (IFS) published today. The research by Crawford and Jin of IFS sets out in detail, for the first time, the full implications for graduates of the new student loan system which accompanied the higher tuition fees introduced in 2012. Payback Time? Student debt and loan repayments: what will the 2012 reforms mean for graduates? - Sutton Trust - 10 April 2014 12.192 192 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour – Bubble Examples The trebling of UK university tuition fees has resulted in a highly uncertain future for higher education funding and produces just a 5% saving for the taxpayer, research shows. A report, published on Thursday by the Institute for Fiscal Studies think-tank, calculated that for every £1 loaned by the government to students to cover fees and maintenance, 43p will not be recouped. The study calculates that each student will be lent an average of just over £40,000, meaning the amount not recovered will be about £17,000 a student. Trebling university tuition fees cuts taxpayer costs just 5% Helen Warrell, Financial Times, 23 April 2014 12.193 193 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour – Bubble Examples When LaTisha Styles graduated from Kennesaw State University in Georgia in 2006 she had $35,000 of student debt. This obligation would have been easy to discharge if her Spanish degree had helped her land a well-paid job. Ms. Styles found herself working in a clothes shop and a fast-food restaurant for no more than $11 an hour. Frustrated, she took the gutsy decision to go back to the same college and study something more pragmatic. She majored in finance, and now has a good job at an investment consulting firm. Her debt has swollen to $65,000, but she will have little trouble paying it off! 194 Higher education: Is college worth it? | The Economist | 5 Apr12.194 2014 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour – Bubble Examples On the plus side, new figures from the UK Office for National Statistics suggest. One in five graduates now go on to become millionaires. Only 3% of millionaires have no formal qualifications. 20% of all adults who hold at least one university degree — more than two million people — now have wealth totalling at least £1 million. Almost a tenth of all British adults now own assets — property, pensions, savings and physical objects — worth £1 million or more. 12.195 195 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour – Bubble Examples More recently, there were two bubbles, the first emerged in technology, media and telecommunications stocks – the so-called internet or Nasdaq craze of the late 1990s. 12.196 196 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour – Bubble Examples The second occurred in 2008 when the mortgage financing system (Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are government sponsored enterprises that purchase mortgages, buy and sell mortgage-backed securities, and guaranteed nearly half of the mortgages in the U.S.) and was characterised by a rapid rise in housing prices, surging household and financial system debt levels and a subsequent retrenchment in prices and housing finance. The collapse of the mortgage bubble was associated with the worst economic downturn since the 1930s. Federal takeover of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac - Wikipedia 12.197 197 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour – Bubble Examples For a little more on Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac (2000’s) and the Libor scandal (2010’s), refer back to chapter 5. Housing bubble brewing – prices are now unaffordable for middle earners, says Business Secretary Vince Cable - The Independent - 4 Apr 2014 Despite Fannie Mae’s Bulk Sales Of NPLs, Number Of Delinquent Loans Remains High - ValueWalk - 7 Dec 2015 (NPL – NonPerforming Loan!) Other goods which have produced bubbles include postage stamps (1970’s) and coin collecting (2010’s – linked to the bullion bubble), obviously any collecting craze can cause a bubble, even in the playground. Stamps: China’s next bubble? - FT - 2 March 2011 10 Collectible Crazes That Were A Waste Of Money - Business Insider - 31 May 2012 12.198 198 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour – Bubble Examples The first large-scale empirical analysis of online news-seeking behaviour, has found that people who seek out news and information from social media are at higher risk of becoming trapped in a 'collective social bubble' compared to using search engines (Nikolov et al. 2015). 12.199 199 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour – Bubble Examples Each circle represents a unique website, and its area is proportional to the number of pages accessed on that website. (A)Links clicked by a single search engine user. (B) Links shared by a single Twitter user. (C) Search traffic generated by a collection of users. (D) Social media traffic generated by a collection of users. 12.200 200 Behavioural Traps – Herd Behaviour – Bubble Examples In each case, a random sample of 50 links was taken for a period of one week. These examples illustrate typical behaviours gleaned from our data. On the left we see more heterogeneous patterns with search traffic distributed more evenly among several sources. The patterns on the right are more homogeneous, with fewer sources dominating most social traffic (Nikolov et al. 2015). 12.201 201 1.202 202 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.203 203 Bubble Model Following Utkus (2011) the difference between a bubble and crash scenario versus the more common bull and bear phases of a market may be only a question of degree. In bubbles and crashes, the psychological biases discussed in the model may simply reach more extreme levels. 12.204 204 Bubble Model (Utkus 2011) Stage 1. 2. Behavioural heuristics Characteristics The initial Representativeness Forecasts of future asset values are developed with forecast heuristic embedded errors in statistical inference Overconfidence Overconfidence, Future forecasts become excessively rosy and are excessive extrapolation skewed to the positive, especially based on recent experience 3. Group Groupthink, group Overly optimistic forecasts are widely transmission/ polarisation disseminated and lead the group as a whole to amplification 4. Recalibration higher risk-taking levels Group polarisation Forecasts are deflated by actual experience and revised downward rapidly and beyond realistic values Explored below 12.205 205 Bubble Model Stage 1. Behavioural heuristics Characteristics The initial Representativeness Forecasts of future asset values are developed with forecast heuristic embedded errors in statistical inference In Stage 1, investors develop initial forecasts of asset prices based on errors in statistical inference, broadly captured under the idea of the representativeness heuristic (where ‘heuristic’ means a decision shortcut). 12.206 206 Bubble Model Stage 2. Overconfidence Behavioural heuristics Characteristics Overconfidence, Future forecasts become excessively rosy and are excessive extrapolation skewed to the positive, especially based on recent experience In Stage 2, these forecasts of future price appreciation become exaggerated. Overconfidence and excessive extrapolation of recent positive experience come into play. 12.207 207 Bubble Model Stage 3. Behavioural heuristics Characteristics Group Groupthink, group Overly optimistic forecasts are widely transmission/ polarisation disseminated and lead the group as a whole to amplification higher risk-taking levels In Stage 3, individual forecasts influence the behaviour of the group (in this case, the market or financial system as a whole). Through a process known as group polarisation, the financial system takes on higher risk exposures than individual members would separately agree is prudent. 12.208 208 Bubble Model Stage 3. Behavioural heuristics Characteristics Group Groupthink, group Overly optimistic forecasts are widely transmission/ polarisation disseminated and lead the group as a whole to amplification higher risk-taking levels With Groupthink a particular group begins to feel invulnerable; it rationalises its behaviour; and it systematically ignores external and contradictory sources of information. There is a failure to examine alternatives, poor information search, and a failure to work out contingency plans. Group polarisation is the tendency for a group to make riskier decisions than individuals alone would make. 12.209 209 Bubble Model Survation conducted a careful telephone poll for the 2015 UK election “the results seemed so out of line with all the polling conducted by ourselves and our peers that I chickened out of publishing the figures.” The same thing happened in the days before the 1992 election, another so-called “surprise” Conservative victory. Classic examples of the influence of groupthink. This is exactly the same phenomenon which led to the financial crisis. The influence of the network of peers becomes so strong that individual judgement is overridden. “Everyone” knew that mortgage-backed securities were a licence to print money, “everyone” knew that debt was no longer a problem in the new economic paradigm. Even the strong willed leaders of major institutions capitulated in the face of such pressure, no matter what their private doubts. Polling errors and the financial crisis: Why groupthink is to blame for both - City A.M. - 13 May 2015 12.210 210 Bubble Model Stage 4. Recalibration Behavioural heuristics Group polarisation Characteristics Forecasts are deflated by actual experience and revised downward rapidly and beyond realistic values Finally, in Stage 4, as actual market data begins to undermine the group’s overconfident forecast of the future, the group polarisation process plays in reverse, and the collective market outlook shifts sharply to the negative. This is the point at which actual data from the field causes market participants to begin to question their too-rosy forecasts and the consensus group opinion. In particular, it consists of a recalibration of the overly optimistic group forecasts based on the actual observed data in the economy and financial markets.12.211 211 1.212 212 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.213 213 Behavioural Traps - How Much Would You Pay For A Dollar? One of the best-known behavioural traps in psychological research is the dollar auction game – a game that combines the features of a collective trap, and an ignorance trap. In this game, invented by Shubik (1971), a dollar bill is auctioned to the highest bidder. As outlined by Platt (1973), the dollar auction game has four simple rules: 12.214 214 Behavioural Traps - How Much Would You Pay For A Dollar? 1. No communication is allowed among bidders while the auction is taking place. 2. Bids can be made only in multiples of 5 cents, beginning with a nickel. 3. Bids must not exceed $50 (to protect bidders from wild enthusiasm). 4. The two highest bidders both have to pay what they bid, even though the dollar goes only to the highest bidder (after all, the auctioneer has to recover expenses some how). Lets play! 12.215 215 Behavioural Traps - How Much Would You Pay For A Dollar? Although the game sounds innocent enough, there are two “points of no return” worth noting. The first one comes when the two highest bids cumulatively exceed $1, thereby assuring the auctioneer of a profit (e.g. when one person bids 50 cents and another bids 55 cents). At this point, the auction still seems attractive from a bidders point of view (a dollar bill in return for 55 cents), but the pursuit of individual self-interest has already ensnared a collective loss to the bidders. 12.216 216 Behavioural Traps - How Much Would You Pay For A Dollar? The second slippery slope appears with the first bid above $1. Why might people bid more than $1 for a dollar bill, consider the predicament of someone who has just bid 95 cents, only to have someone else bid $1. What would you do in such a situation? If you quit at that point, you are sure to lose 95 cents. On the other hand, if you bid $1.05 and win the dollar, you lose only a nickel. The problem is that the person you are bidding against faces the same situation. And as a result, the bidding often reaches a few dollars. 12.217 217 Behavioural Traps - How Much Would You Pay For A Dollar? One reason the dollar auction game has received so much attention is that it resembles the nuclear arms race and other international conflicts (Costanza 1984). In 1980 Teger published an entire book (Too Much Invested To Quit) devoted to research on the dollar auction game, and many of his conclusions are directly applicable to military conflict. 12.218 218 Behavioural Traps - How Much Would You Pay For A Dollar? According to Teger subjects are usually motivated initially by personal gain, but in time their motivation changes. As the bidding continues, subjects become concerned with winning the competition, saving face, minimizing losses, and punishing their opponent for getting them into such a mess (typically, only two bidders remain active in late stages of the trap). 12.219 219 Behavioural Traps - How Much Would You Pay For A Dollar? Teger found that when the bidding approached $1, both sides felt they were being forced by the other bidder to continue, and many subjects thought the other person was crazy to continue – without seeing that identical forces were operating on both participants. This “mirror image” is strikingly reminiscent of the nuclear arms race. 12.220 220 1.221 221 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! skip Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.222 222 Behavioural Traps - Knee Deep In The Big Muddy Once bidders in the dollar auction game are caught – “knee deep in the big muddy,” as Staw (1976) puts it – they usually continue clobbering each other before someone finally gives up. Brockner and Rubin (1985 p. 5) refer to this dynamic, as “entrapment” defined as “a decision making process whereby individuals escalate their commitment to a previously chosen, though failing, course of action in order to justify or ‘make good on’ prior investments.” 12.223 223 Behavioural Traps - Knee Deep In The Big Muddy One of the first studies of entrapment was conducted by Staw (1976). Staw presented business students with a hypothetical but richly detailed scenario concerning a high-tech company that had begun to lose money, and he asked them to assume the role of Financial Vice President. According to the scenario, the company’s directors have decided to pump $10 million of additional research and development funds into one of the two largest divisions – Consumer Products or Industrial Products. 12.224 224 Behavioural Traps - Knee Deep In The Big Muddy In Part 1 of the study, half the students were asked to choose which division should receive the additional funding. Roughly half the students were then told that the chosen division outperformed the unchosen division over the next five years (i.e., that the choice had yielded positive consequences), and roughly half were told the reverse (i.e., that the choice had yielded negative consequences). 12.225 225 Behavioural Traps - Knee Deep In The Big Muddy In Part 2 of the experiment, students learned that a re-evaluation by company managers had led to the allocation of an additional $20 million for research and development, and they were asked to split this amount between the consumer and industrial divisions in any way they saw fit. What Staw (1976) found was entrapment – the escalation of commitment to a failing course of action. 12.226 226 Behavioural Traps - Knee Deep In The Big Muddy Students who were personally responsible for an initially unsuccessful choice allocated an average of approximately $13 million to the previously chosen division – about $4 million more than the allocation made by other students. When responsibility was high, failure produced greater investment, not lesser investment. 12.227 227 Behavioural Traps - Knee Deep In The Big Muddy Is this a good plot? Note the false origin! The following plot is clearer. 12.228 228 Behavioural Traps - Knee Deep In The Big Muddy 14 Millions of dollars allocated 12 10 8 Positive consequences Negative consequences 6 4 2 0 Low responsibility High Responsibility 12.229 229 Behavioural Traps - Knee Deep In The Big Muddy Staw’s (1976) experiment stimulated a great deal of subsequent research, and since the time of his study, several theoretical analyses of entrapment have appeared (two of the best are Brockner and Rubin 1985 and Staw and Ross 1987). Although research on entrapment is still relatively new, experimental evidence suggests that: Situations in which passivity maintains the status quo, such as automatic investment plans, are more entrapping than situations in which decisions to continue must be made actively (Brockner et al. 1979). 12.230 230 Behavioural Traps - Knee Deep In The Big Muddy Entrapment is greater in competitive social situations than in non-social situations, at least for men (Rubin et al. 1980). Entrapment occurs as readily with groups as with individuals (Bazerman et al. 1984), though this may be true only for women (Brockner and Rubin 1985). 12.231 231 Behavioural Traps - Knee Deep In The Big Muddy There is also some data on entrapment in romantic relationships. Rusbult (1980) found that college students in a role playing experiment were more committed to a romantic partner – and less likely to date other people – when the relationship had lasted a year rather than a month. Thus, all things being equal, the amount of time students had already invested in the relationship was directly related to their degree of future commitment. 12.232 232 Behavioural Traps – Antiherding Rülke et al. (2016) use a large international data set, to analyse whether business cycle forecasters herd or anti-herd. In general, they find evidence for antiherding, i.e. forecasters appear to scatter their forecasts deliberately away from the forecasts of others. Anti-herding tends to be more prevalent for the longer (next year) horizon. There is some evidence for a reduced level of anti-herding at times of increased forecast uncertainty and when the forecasts are being revised more substantially. 12.233 233 1.234 234 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.235 235 Why Do Lie-Catchers Fail? How do you tell if senior management are lying? Their lips are moving! (possibly Mark Twain 1835– 1910 or Will Rogers 1879–1935) Hartwig and Bond (2011) provide valuable insight into the behaviour of lying. They employ a meta-analysis to combine more than one hundred studies which were conducted over 50 years into lying and lie detection. 12.236 236 Why Do Lie-Catchers Fail? People are generally very bad at detecting lies. In fact the analysis shows that people are only able to detect lies about 54% of the time. Only slightly better than chance. The authors note that “contrary to common expectations, presumed lie experts who routinely assess credibility in their professional life do not perform better than lay judges do.” Why is this? Two main theories try to explain the poor ability of people to detect lies: 1. People have a false stereotype about what constitutes lying behaviour. That is, they are using the wrong cues to detect lies. 2. There is only a minute behavioural difference 12.237 237 between truth-tellers and liars. Why Do Lie-Catchers Fail? Hartwig and Bond (2011) found that the first hypothesis (false stereotype ) did not hold. In general people are using behavioural cues to identify lying. However, the behavioural cues that subjects reported using are not the cues they actually utilized to detect lies. The subjects were, able to detect lies at an intuitive level, but they didn’t consciously know how they were doing it. As for the second hypothesis (only a minute behavioural difference), the researchers did find strong evidence that there are only small behavioural differences between truth-tellers and liars. 12.238 238 Why Do Lie-Catchers Fail? What about the overall accuracy of truth detectors? Hartwig and Bond (2011) measured the ability of truth detectors as a Pearson product-moment correlation coefficient — that is, the correlation between actual lying (RDec), perceptions of lying (RPer), and the accuracy of the detection methods (G). Put mathematically, the accuracy of truth detection is calculated as follows (Tucker, 1964): racc = RDec × RPer × G = 0.36 × 0.63 × 0.93 = 0.21 The accuracy of lie detection is hurt most by the lack of valid behavioural cues (r = 0.36). The behavioural difference between truth-tellers and liars is small. Lie detectors’ perceptions of lying behaviour are strong (r = 0.63). Lie detectors appear to be using the correct 12.239 239 cues to detect lying (r = 0.93). Why Do Lie-Catchers Fail? In different assessments of human judgment of behaviours other than lying, the average accuracy coefficient is much higher. One study of peoples’ ability to perceive other qualities in human behaviour had an accuracy coefficient of 0.56 (Karelaia and Hogarth 2008). This compares to the accuracy coefficient of 0.21 (previous slide) for lie detectors. 12.240 240 Why Do Lie-Catchers Fail? Though many people believe they can recognize when someone is lying, detecting deception is difficult. Accuracy rates in experiments have proven to be only slightly greater than chance, even among trained professionals. But a new study published recently in Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences finds that groups are consistently more accurate in distinguishing truths from lies than one individual is. Nadav Klein and Nicholas Epley 2015 Group discussion improves lie detection. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 112(24) 7460–7465 DOI: 10.1073/pnas.1504048112 12.241 241 In More Depth Researchers have been increasingly focusing on the science behind interrogation techniques and confessions — and emerging criminal justice system data patterns — with the hope of better understanding how false confessions are produced and how to limit the chances innocent persons are imprisoned. False confessions, new data and law enforcement interrogations: Research findings - Journalists Resources 12.242 242 1.243 243 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.244 244 What Cues Can I Rely On? The best indications of a lie are not single behaviours but the overall impression the liar makes on the truth detector. Research has continually demonstrated that overall impressions of lying dominate individual cues. The top five behavioural cues to deception, each of which is positively correlated with lying, but the correlations are low. Just because you witness the following behaviours does not necessarily mean that the speaker is lying. 12.245 245 What Cues Can I Rely On? Cue to Deception Indifferent (speaker seems unconcerned) Thinking hard N Actual Correlation to Lying P 100 0.45 1.00 8 0.29 0.76 243 0.19 0.90 46 0.19 0.99 144 0.19 1.00 Ambivalent (communication seems internally inconsistent or discrepant) Not spontaneous (statement seems planned or rehearsed) Not fluent (miscellaneous speech disturbances) The strongest indication that someone is lying is indifference. The impression that a speaker is thinking hard is also a relatively strong indication that the speaker is lying (r = 0.29). Ambivalence and lack of spontaneity and fluency are signs of lying, but weak signs. 12.246 246 What Cues Are Less Reliable? Cue to Deception Competent Arm movements Object fidgeting Involved Pleasant face Plausibility N 536 232 130 622 370 1103 Actual Correlation to Lying 0.59 0.37 0.49 -0.42 -0.44 -0.47 N Perceived Correlation to Lying Difference 90 52 420 214 635 395 -0.02 -0.19 -0.02 0.05 -0.05 -0.11 0.61 0.56 0.51 0.47 0.39 0.36 People tend to think that someone they perceive as incompetent (negative correlation to competence) is lying; yet the actual correlation between perceived incompetence and lying is almost zero. 12.247 247 What Cues Are Less Reliable? Cue to Deception Competent Arm movements Object fidgeting Involved Pleasant face Plausibility N 536 232 130 622 370 1103 Actual Correlation to Lying 0.59 0.37 0.49 -0.42 -0.44 -0.47 N Perceived Correlation to Lying Difference 90 52 420 214 635 395 -0.02 -0.19 -0.02 0.05 -0.05 -0.11 0.61 0.56 0.51 0.47 0.39 0.36 If communicators use lots of arm movements or fidget, people tend to think it is a sign of lying (positive correlations of 0.37 and 0.49). A person who move their arms/fidget slightly less (negative correlation of -0.19 and -0.02) are more likely to be lying. 12.248 248 What Cues Are Less Reliable? Cue to Deception Competent Arm movements Object fidgeting Involved Pleasant face Plausibility N 536 232 130 622 370 1103 Actual Correlation to Lying 0.59 0.37 0.49 -0.42 -0.44 -0.47 N Perceived Correlation to Lying Difference 90 52 420 214 635 395 -0.02 -0.19 -0.02 0.05 -0.05 -0.11 0.61 0.56 0.51 0.47 0.39 0.36 Lie detectors tend to think that a lack of involvement is a sign of lying, but in fact, to a slight degree (0.05) the more involvement, the greater the chance that a lie has been told. 12.249 249 What Cues Are Less Reliable? Cue to Deception Competent Arm movements Object fidgeting Involved Pleasant face Plausibility N 536 232 130 622 370 1103 Actual Correlation to Lying 0.59 0.37 0.49 -0.42 -0.44 -0.47 N Perceived Correlation to Lying Difference 90 52 420 214 635 395 -0.02 -0.19 -0.02 0.05 -0.05 -0.11 0.61 0.56 0.51 0.47 0.39 0.36 Perhaps most surprisingly, implausibility is actually not a strong indication that a lie is being perpetrated. 12.250 250 What Cues Are Less Reliable? Cue to Deception Ambivalent (communication seems internally inconsistent or discrepant) Vocal uncertainty (impressions of uncertainty and insecurity, lack of assertiveness) Not spontaneous (statement seems planned or rehearsed) Unfilled pauses (periods of silence) Gaze aversion N Actual Correlation to Lying N Perceived Correlation to Lying Difference 502 0.49 243 0.19 0.3 826 0.43 329 0.14 0.29 175 0.48 46 0.19 0.29 718 0.27 655 0.01 0.26 202 0.28 411 0.05 0.23 Sometimes truth detectors err by using the proper criteria to detect a lie but placing too much significance on a particular cue. Kraut (1980) was the first to suggest that behaviours are more strongly related to perceived deception than actual deception. 12.251 251 1.252 252 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.253 253 How Can I Improve My Ability to Detect a Lie? Interestingly the authors suggest a holistic approach to lie detection. That is, do not rely upon individual behavioural cues, as a preponderance of lying behaviours is more indicative than any single cue. Another method for improving your ability to detect a lie is to trust your intuition rather than what you perceive are good behavioural cues. Studies continually demonstrate that when lies are successfully detected the methods of detection ascribed by detectors are not the ones they actually use. This suggests a disconnect between the potency of unconscious detection and impotency of conscious method. 12.254 254 How Can I Improve My Ability to Detect a Lie? The typical prescription of truth-detection trainers is to give prospective truth detectors a list of behavioural cues to look for and then give feedback on performance to improve the results. But these methods have statistically been demonstrated to be ineffective, or only marginally effective. 12.255 255 How Can I Improve My Ability to Detect a Lie? Hartwig and Bond (2011) feel that the best way to improve one’s ability to assess a lie is to increase the difference in the behaviours of liars and truth-tellers. One way to do this is to engage in interactional interviews. Because lying requires greater cognitive energy than telling the truth, you can increase the cognitive demand of your questions. For example, ask someone a question that challenges them to place a detail of their complex story back in its proper chronological context, to see if they can remember where the detail fits in the timeline. 12.256 256 1.257 257 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.258 258 Why Do Lie-Catchers Fail? Finally, the business of investing requires an ability to discern the truth and veracity of the information you are using in your analytical process. Yet, most of us are in fact very poor at catching lies when they are told. Statistically, more than 50 years of research has shown this is because there is not that much difference between liars and truth tellers in how they communicate, and because, in all likelihood, you are ignoring your intuitive faculties. A liar CAN look you in the eye...but watch out for a twitching nose: World's leading human lie detector divulges how to sniff out deceit (and it's not how you might think) - Daily Mail - 1 May 2015 12.259 259 Deception Detection using Real-life Trial Data? Sample screenshots showing facial displays and hand gestures from real-life trial clips. deceptive trial withdeceptive trial with one head hand forward with both hands movement (Move movement (Both (Single hand) forward) hands) truthful trial with deceptive trial with scowl face with aneyebrows up gaze raised (Gaze up) raising) (Scowl) (Eyebrows Which are truthful and which deceptive? Pérez-Rosas et al. 2015 12.260 260 Deception Detection using Real-life Trial Data? The experiment started with an analysis of the nonverbal behaviours occurring in deceptive and truthful videos. Comparing the percentage of each behaviour as observed in each class. For instance, there is a total of 61 videos in the dataset that include the Eyebrows raising feature, out of which 24 are part of the deceptive set of 61 videos, and 37 are part of the truthful set (60 videos). See next slide. Pérez-Rosas et al. 2015 12.261 261 Deception Detection using Real-life Trial Data? 12.262 262 Distribution for nine facial displays and hand gestures Pérez-Rosas et al. 2015 Deception Detection using Real-life Trial Data? These ratios (24/61 = .39 and 37/60 = .62) are shown in the following figure. Hence, the percentages of existence of this feature are 39% in the deceptive class and 62% in the truthful class. The figure shows the percentages of all the non-verbal features for which we observe noticeable differences for the deceptive and truthful groups. As the figure suggests, eyebrow and eye gestures help differentiate between the deceptive and truthful conditions. For instance, we can observe that truth-tellers appear to raise their eyebrows (Eyebrows raising), shake their head (Head repeated shake), and blink (Eyes closing repeated) more frequently than deceivers. Interestingly, deceivers seem to blink and shake their head less frequently than truth-tellers. 12.263 263 See next slide. Pérez-Rosas et al. 2015 Deception Detection using Real-life Trial Data? Distribution of non-verbal features for deceptive and truthful groups Rather sketchy error bars! Pérez-Rosas et al. 2015 12.264 264 Deception Detection using Real-life Trial Data? In summary How to REALLY spot a liar: Scowling, eye contact and exaggerated hand movements are all signs someone is hiding the truth - Daily Mail - 11 Dec 2015 •Researchers studied video clips from media coverage of criminal trials •They trained software to recognise so-called 'tells' of people who had lied •This combined gestures, such as hand movements, with vocal clues •Experts conclude that liars tend to give confident answers, use 'um' and 'er' more regularly, scowl or grimace while talking and make eye contact 12.265 265 1.266 266 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.267 267 Behavioural Traps - The Great Escape As sticky as traps can be, they rarely last forever. Eventually, people waiting on hold, hang up. Corporate officers stop throwing good money after bad. Romantic partners who are unhappy break up. Usually the problem is not that behavioural traps capture victims permanently, but that in retrospect, people wish they had exited the trap sooner than 12.268 268 they did. Behavioural Traps - The Great Escape Luckily, there are several ways that entrapment can be reduced or avoided (for reviews, see Brockner and Rubin 1985; Cross and Guyer 1980; Staw and Ross 1987). One technique proposed by Staw and Ross (1987) is to “bring phase-out costs forward” before a commitment is made – that is, to explicitly consider the costs of withdrawal before embarking on a long-term venture. Experimental evidence suggests that entrapment is reduced or eliminated when the costs of participation are made salient up front (Brockner et al. 1981; Nathanson et al. 1982). 12.269 269 Behavioural Traps - The Great Escape In their book on entrapment, Brockner and Rubin (Entrapment in escalating conflicts: A social psychological analysis 1985 p. 203) advise decision makers to set limits in advance whenever possible, and to use these limits in the following way: Rather than to quit automatically upon investing the amount specified by their limits, decision makers should use their limit point as a time to reassess whether persistence or withdrawal is wiser; independent of the fact that prior investments have been made. That is, if individuals decide to invest beyond their earlier set limit, this must be the result of a prospective, future 12.270 270 (rather than past-oriented) cost benefit analysis. Behavioural Traps - The Great Escape In a business context, Staw and Ross (1987a) recommend asking the question: “If I took over this job for the first time today and found this project going on, would I support it or get rid of it?” This question can easily be adapted for use in contexts other than business (e.g. “If I were meeting this person for the first time today, would I be attracted?”). 12.271 271 Behavioural Traps - The Great Escape One other technique is to have different people make initial and subsequent decisions (Bazerman et al. 1984; Staw and Ross 1987). For example, a financial loan might be made by one bank officer and reviewed for renewal by another. The advantage of this technique is that later decisions are made by people who are not responsible for earlier blunders (and who therefore have little reason to escalate commitment). The disadvantage however, is a disruption in continuity and a potential loss in “institutional memory.” 12.272 272 Behavioural Traps - The Great Escape How to improve group decision making? When it operates efficiently, a group's decision making will nearly always outperform the ability of any one of its members working on their own. This is especially the case if the group is formed of diverse members. One problem: groups rarely work efficiently. How to improve group decision making BPS Research Digest Blog Mesmer-Magnus, J., & DeChurch, L. (2009). Information sharing and team performance: A meta-analysis. Journal of Applied Psychology, 94 (2), 535-546 DOI: 10.1037/a0013773 12.273 273 1.274 274 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.275 275 Behavioural Traps Conclusion Behavioural traps are a ubiquitous part of life, and if unchecked, they can lead to serious consequences. Staw (1981) has argued that many of the most damaging personal decisions and public policies arise from sequential and escalating commitments (such as those found in the Vietnam War). Platt (1973 p. 651) went even further, claiming “traps represent all of our most intractable and large scale urban, national, and international problems today.” 12.276 276 Behavioural Traps Conclusion Yet traps are not always bad. As Brockner and Rubin (1985) observed, there are many cases in which people deliberately attempt to trap themselves. For example, recovering alcoholics, ex-smokers, and dieters often “screw their courage to the sticking place” (From Shakespeare's Macbeth (1605) - Lady Macbeth) by intentionally trapping themselves in healthful patterns of living. 12.277 277 Behavioural Traps Conclusion When entrapment is desired, decision makers should: Avoid information about the costs of entrapment Refrain from setting limits or evaluating the costs of continuing Make a public declaration of commitment (Alcoholics Anonymous meeting, Weight Watchers…) Compete with other people who are striving towards the same goal (Weight Watchers…). 12.278 278 Behavioural Traps Conclusion As with many of the biases discussed above, behavioural traps are neither inherently good nor inherently bad, and it is not the purpose of psychology research to adjudge this issue. Rather, the purpose of entrapment research – and decision research in general – is more circumscribed. It is to further our understanding of how decision processes operate, and in so doing, contribute to the quality of the decisions that are made. 12.279 279 1.280 280 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.281 281 Next Week Also worth an easy read is Michael Bond 2009 “Risk School” Nature 461 1189-1192 | DOI: 10.1038/4611189a Can the general public learn to evaluate risks accurately, or do authorities need to steer it towards correct decisions? Michael Bond talks to the two opposing camps. References – also worth a look 1. Gigerenzer, G., Gaissmaer, W., Kurz-Milcke, E., Schwartz, L. M. & Woloshin, S. “Helping Doctors and Patients Make Sense of Health Statistics” Psychol. Sci. Publ. Int. 8, 53-96 (2007). | Article | OpenURL 2. Frederick, S. J. “Cognitive Reflection and Decision Making” Econ. Persp. 19, 2542 (2005). | Article | OpenURL 3. Fong, G. T., Krantz, D. H. & Nisbett, R. E. “The effects of statistical training on thinking about everyday problems” Cogn. Psychol. 18, 253-292 (1986). | Article | OpenURL 4. Milkman, K. L., Chugh, D. & Bazerman, M. H. “How Can Decision Making Be Improved?” Persp. Psychol. Sci. 4, 379-383 (2009). | Article | OpenURL 5. Dieckmann, N. F., Slovic, P. & Peters, E. M. “The Use of Narrative Evidence and Explicit Likelihood by Decisionmakers Varying in Numeracy” Risk Anal. 29, 14731488 (2009). | Article | PubMed | OpenURL 6. Peters, E. et al. “Bringing meaning to numbers: The impact of evaluative categories on decisions”J. Exp. Psychol. Appl. 15, 213-227 12.282 282 (2009). | Article | PubMed | OpenURL Next Week While not intended as a review Soufian et al. (2014) does contain numerous useful links and interesting ideas. 12.283 283 1.284 284 Traps Introduction Herd Behaviour Next Week Taxonomy Investors Where Next? Time Delay Traps Peer To Peer Procrastination Funding Circle Ignorance Traps Examples of Bubbles Investment Trap Bubble Model Avoidance Buy a Dollar? Deterioration Traps Knee Deep! Bill's Truck Lie Catchers Fail? Facit Can I Rely On? Collective Traps Can I Improve? Prisoner's Dilemma Why Fail? Tragedy of the Common's Great Escape Bystander Behaviour Conclusion 12.285 285 Where Next? For those considering a career in banking/financial risk they might explore “A Flight Simulator for Financial Risk”. Described here. Freely available here (there is no registration charge). Explanatory video. Take it for a flight, did you loose money? 12.286 286 Where Next? The internship: Generation i - The Economist – 6 Sept 2014 “Don’t talk to the press. Have a good attitude. Always say yes. You are not here to change the world.” And ladies, please, “Do not put us in a position to remind or suggest what qualifies as proper attire.” These are among the instructions given to interns in the office of John Boehner, the Speaker of the United States House of Representatives. 12.287 287 Where Next? Daily chart: CV fillers - The Economist - 8 Sept 2014 During the summer months waves of young, temporary workers flood the private and public sectors. They hope that fetching coffee and photocopying will bulk up their CVs — and help secure a permanent job. But in which industries is it easiest to get work experience? And which are most likely to retain their interns? 12.288 288 Where Next? 12.289 289 But It Might Be Too Late! Work experience: an essential socialising influence - FT - 20 Oct 2014 The phrase “work experience” is one parents dread. Even if you have friends that you can beg favours from, it is a very uncomfortable process. But for a child at any stage from 14 to University graduation, it is an important part of becoming "career-ready". Work experience is important for two reasons. The first is to learn what is expected in a work environment – to turn up on time, shake people’s hands firmly, look them in the eye, wear appropriate clothing, don’t be too chatty, and so on. The second is to understand what people in various jobs actually do. How do you know what you want to do in life if you haven’t seen others do it? How to turn an internship into a job offer - FT - 29 June 2015 12.290 290 And Finally! How to negotiate a job offer and salary - FT - 17 July 2015 When you receive an offer, you should first and foremost thank the employer and genuinely express your interest in the position. This will lay the groundwork for a positive discussion if you pursue the position and decide to negotiate. Even if you know that you will accept the position, ask for time to consider the offer to make an informed decision. This request is customary, it gives you bargaining room and allows you time to think clearly. Career Builder reveals how to avoid classic CV mistakes - Daily Mail - 15 Aug 2015 The end! 12.291 291