Monetary policy and financial imbalances David Vestin, 2015-11-30 Purpouse Discuss the ”nexus” of monetary policy and financial stability/imbalances Main reference: Smets (2013) ”Financial stability and Monetary Policy: How Closely Interlinked?” ”Monetary Policy and Financial Stability” (IMF) Why does the monetary policy mandate focus on price stability? High and volatile inflation 1960-80 Back then, belief in long-run trade-off : pi = … - u Revolution: Insight that Conclusion: unemployment can be permanetly reduced if inflation is kept high Monetary policy lacks long-run real effects Political business-cycles creates short-run losses Conclusion: delegate monetary policy to independent central bank Nominal anchor Sticky prices and wages -> monetary policy can influence real interest rates and thereby economic activity and prices Pre-crisis monetary policy framework Flexible inflation targeting (Svensson 2007, EER) 𝐿 = (𝜋 − 𝜋 ∗ )2 +(𝑥 − 𝑥 ∗ )2 𝜋 inflation, x resource utilisation, e.g. unemployment 𝑥 = −𝑎(𝑖 − 𝐸(𝜋)) 𝜋 = 𝑥 Conclusion: MP balances inflation and Resource Utilisation Financial stability problems Throughout history (Reinhart-Rogoff, ”This time is different”) Recent reminder: financial crisis 2008-2009 Definition of financial stability Narrow: ”Banking system reasonably robust” Broad: ”Financial system reasonably robust” Financial crisis: US background Long-standing policy to promote home ownership ”Underwriting”: banks originates loans to households, then transfers the loans to state-owned enterprises Banks also packaged loans and sold them to investors Loans without interest and amortization Assumption: house prices would continue to rise House-prices turned down Phases of crisis Bear-Stearns, AIG, Lehman Brothers No confidence in banking sector – important fundingmarkets closed Massive intervention of FED Contagion to rest of world, also to Sweden, Swedish banks had exposures to Estonia and Latvia. Large macroeconomic downturn, trade collapsed, uncertainty increased Banking crisis transformed into government debt crisis for countries that needed to inject capital into banks Lessons from the crisis ”The great moderation” did not prevent build-up of financial imbalances Imbalances can be hard to ”clean” Ensuring sustainable economic development needs further policy intervention Strong credit growth to households in Sweden MFI lending, annual change Note: Last observation october 2013. Source: Statistics Sweden Big questions after the financial crisis 1. Rethinking the monetary policy framework Goals for monetary policy 2. Introduction of a new policy area Macroprudential policy (BIS) 3. Challenges (finacial trilemma*) with achieving financial stability in a world with cross-border banking Banking union BIS The financial trilemma states that (1) financial stability, (2) financial integration and (3) national financial policies are incompatible. Monetary policy effects on imbalances Low interest rates might stimulate (unsustainable?) debt growth Induce ”search-for-yield” behavior Possible first-best: other tools added to deal with unwarranted side-effects of monetary policy Why should MP be concerned with financial imbalances? Imbalances can lead to low inflation, high unemployment Macro-pru not in place – MP provides temporary bridge Macro-pru instruments too weak, can be circumvented… Possible narrow aim of macro-pru: only ”systemic” risk Similar transmission channels, co-ordination needed? Rethinking the monetary policy framework - Smets (2013) Modified Jackson Hole consensus Leaning agains the wind vindicated Financial stability is price stability Smets (2013) Smets three questions 1. How effective is macropru to ensure financial stability? 2. How significant is the effects of monetary policy on financial stability? 3. What is the risk of ”financial dominance” - risk of losing the nominal anchor… Schematic outline: concern for imbalances • Inflation • Resource utilisation Monetary policy deliberations Repo-rate path Macro-pru Target attainment during the forecast period Probability of the scenario Debt Consequences of the scenario: • inflation • resource utilisation Expected target attainment beyond the forecast horizon Risk-taking Source: The Riksbank Schematic outline: concern for imbalances • Inflation • Resource utilisation Monetary policy deliberations Repo-rate path Macro-pru Target attainment during the forecast period Probability of the scenario Debt Consequences of the scenario: • inflation • resource utilisation Expected target attainment beyond the forecast horizon Risk-taking Source: The Riksbank Smets: Leaning against the wind • Inflation • Resource utilisation Monetary policy deliberations Repo-rate path Macro-pru Target attainment during the forecast period Probability of the scenario Debt Consequences of the scenario: • inflation • resource utilisation Expected target attainment beyond the forecast horizon Risk-taking Source: The Riksbank Smets: financial stability is price stability Brunnemeier and Sannikov: I-theory of money Focus on financial intermediation Financial intermediation can be impeded Monetary policy works through banks Bank capital losses Lower interest rates raises bond prices, recapitalizes banks In this setting, monetary policy works by stabilizing banks IMF 2015: Monetar Policy and Financial Stability Monetary policy should deviate from its traditional response only if costs are smaller than benefits … Costs arise in the short term, from lower output and inflation. Benefits materialize mainly in the medium term, as financial risks are mitigated, though uncertain effects Current knowledge – limited case for leaning, as in most circumstances costs outweigh benefits. Decision-tree IMF: Three questions 1. Are financial risks excessive? 2. Are macro-pru instruments effective? 3. Whether tighter monetary policy warranted by pricestability is also sufficient for financial stability? Strategy Identify channels from monetary policy to financial stability Establish trade-offs between price stability and financial stability Do empirical cost-benefit analysis IMF: comparable calculations Example: Trying to quantify the trade-off k Policy problem How to weigh risks to households balance sheet with ”normal” monetary policy considerations We illustrate a simple example: Extend policy horizon Model ”bad scenario” Model how monetary policy affect p(bad scenario) Foundation Svensson (1997) 𝑳 = 𝝅 − 𝝅∗ 𝟐 + 𝝀 𝒖 − 𝒖∗ 𝟐 Schularick and Taylor (2012): p(crisis) = f(real credit growth) BVAR: real credit groth = f(interest rate) Alternative interest rate paths: through MP shocks Schematic outline: concern for imbalances • Inflation • Resource utilisation Target attainment during the forecast period Monetary policy deliberations Repo-rate path Probability of the scenario Debt Consequences of the scenario: • inflation • resource utilisation Expected target attainment beyond the forecast horizon Source: The Riksbank Effects of policy on likelihood of bad scenario Monetary policy Real debt accumulation Quantified via VAR model Likelihood of crisis Quantified via Schularick and Taylor, AER 2012 Pragmatic inflation targeting Forecasting period of 3 years Loss = 𝟑 𝟏 𝝅 − 𝝅∗ 𝟐 + 𝝀 𝒖 − 𝒖∗ 𝟐 Construct a main forecast, based on models, judgement Policy options: consider higher/lower rate path Use unanticipated monetary policy shocks Reasonable if temporary deviation Lengthen forecast horison Risks can build, even if inflation forecast on ”target” Risks ”beyond the forecasting horison” Loss = 𝟏𝟎 𝟏 𝝅 − 𝝅∗ 𝟐 + 𝝀 𝒖 − 𝒖∗ 𝟐 I.e. same targets for monetary policy, but now T=10 Two alternative interest rate paths, High and Low Lenghten forecast horison Unemployment 12 12 10 L 10 H 8 8 6 6 4 4 2 2 0 0 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 33 Model ”Bad scenario”. Based on IMF (2012) Unemployment 12 12 10 L 10 Crisis, with prob p H 8 8 6 6 4 4 2 2 0 0 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 34 Short-run vs. longer-run risks E(Loss) = 𝑬 𝑬 𝟑 𝟏 𝝅 − 𝝅∗ 𝟐 𝟏𝟎 𝟏 + 𝝀 𝒖 − 𝒖∗ 𝟐 𝝅 − 𝝅∗ + shortrun(x) x: path for interest rate 𝟐 + 𝝀 𝒖 − 𝒖∗ 𝟐 𝒑 ∗ 𝑪𝒓𝒊𝒔𝒊𝒔 + 𝟏 − 𝒑 ∗ 𝟎 + p(x) Crisis Crisis: loss during crisis Comparing two alternatives, High and Low: Diff = shortrun(H) – shortrun(L) + (P(H)-P(L)) Crisis Quantifying the probability of a crisis: Schularick and Taylor: p(crisis) linked to growth in real debt, 𝑆𝑡 𝑝𝑡 = exp(𝑋𝑡 ) 1+exp(𝑋𝑡 ) 𝑋𝑡 = −3.89 − 0.40𝑆𝑡−1 + 7.14𝑆𝑡−2 + 0.89𝑆𝑡−3 + 0.20𝑆𝑡−4 + 1.87𝑆𝑡−5 Average value of S is 4.4% -> average p is 3% BVAR-model: real debt for alternative interest rate paths Another way to illustrate… Crisis = (x) = 𝐄 𝟑 𝟏 𝟏𝟎 𝟒 𝝅 − 𝝅∗ 𝝅 − 𝝅∗ 𝟐 𝟐 + 𝝀 𝒖 − 𝒖∗ + 𝒑(𝒙) 𝟏𝟎 𝟒 U(x) similarly… _diff = (H) - (L) 𝟐 𝝅 − 𝝅∗ 𝟐 Difference between High and Low Negative value = good for low-interest rate alt Skillnad i kvadrerade förluster för arbetslöshet 1,4 Bad for lower path 1,2 Huvudscenario Main scenario 1,0 P constant utan risk 0,8 P depends on MP med risk 0,6 Unemployment 0,4 0,2 0,0 -0,2 högre utväxling -> skuld Higher impact repo rate->debt Higher impact skuld debt -> ->risk risk högre utväxling Higher impact on both högre utväxling på både skuld och risk -0,4 -0,6 Good for lower path -0,4 -0,2 0,0 0,2 Skillnad i kvadrerade förluster för KPIF Difference in squared losses, CPIF 0,4 0,6 Conclusions Room for concern for imbalances within standard flexible inflation targeting Concern for imbalances aims at achieving sustainable economic developments Benchmark calibration and example of an economy in recession: short run cost of leaning higher than longterm benefit Pescatori, Laséen and Vestin (2015): Crisis in near term A crisis can be triggered every period, Markov chain If crisis hits, inflation = non-crisis inflation – delta (like in Svensson, 2015) New dimension: Presense of risk LOWERS the main inflation forecast Current state interacts with crisis size to determine Loss If p does not depend on MP, leaning WITH the wind If p depends on MP, less leaning than when crisis can only occur from steady state Example Example calibration: IRFS for inflation and unemployment from Ramses, credit from BVAR If we start from a case where E(pi)=2 and E(u)=u*, then about 6 bps leaning is ”optimal” What matters is RELATIVE effect of i on pi,u and p Doubling the ST-coefficients leads to more leaning Interest rate 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 -0.1 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 Inflation an unemployment Expected inflation 0.4 0.2 0 -0.2 -0.4 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 30 35 40 Expected unemployment 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 -0.1 0 5 10 15 20 25 Real credit growth 1.15 1.1 1.05 1 0.95 0.9 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 Probability of crisis 0.11 0.109 0.108 0.107 0.106 0.105 0.104 0.103 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 Alternative versions Crisis state as in Ajello et. al; if crisis occurs, inflation = constant Crisis-profile: An n-state Markov chain where the different crisis stages have different delta Prel. result: Slightly stronger case for leaning, as interaction of short-run cost and crisis decreases Estimate BVAR-models for large number of countries Effects from interest rates to debt can be larger if misperceptions… Debt/disposable income, Walentin (2013) Skuld/disponibel inkomst 240 220 200 180 160 140 2,25% resp. 145% 120 100 0 1 2 3 realränta 4 5 Issues Systematic leaning -> expectational effects Financial crisis can lead to permanent LEVEL effects? Need dynamic DSGE version, extend Woodford (2011)? Work in Gerali et.al. model, effects of macro pru? Allows analysis of steady-state issues like Barro-Gordon etc. GDP, unemployment Much more costly than fluctuations (Lucas…) Non-linearities in MP->Credit, Credit->p Disaggregated credit analysis focusing on ”bad” credit growth Leeper suggest analog to fiscal-limit: house-hold limit… Conclusion Small effects of policy on real debt accumulation and probability of bad scenario in mean estimates But uncertainty; if willing to ”tails”, effects are larger In the latter case, concern for debt contributes to explain why rate is not lowered Discussion Non-linearities Expectation formation: if households perception of normal rate is affected by low rates for a long period, effects can be larger Small effects stand in contrast to studies of procyclicality of banks balance sheets Analog to Leepers ”fiscal-limit” for households Distributional effects Assets The Swedish policy-debate Some leaning 2010, 2013, but how much? Recent experience, inflation gradually lower, no room for concerns for debt growth Important that the FSA deals with the potential imbalances Alternative take: adding financial stability as a separate objective The authorities have three objectives: E(𝜋𝑡 − 𝜋 ∗ )2 E(𝑦𝑡 − 𝑦 ∗ )2 E 𝑓𝑡 − 𝑓 ∗ 2 The authorities have two instruments: Price stability: Real stability: Financial stability: Monetary policy: Macroprudential: r c (interest rate) (capital requirement) Two alternative strategies: A: coordination (centralization) B: no coordination (decentralization) 52 Two alternative strategies A: set r and c to minimize E ∞ 𝑡 𝑡 𝛽 [(𝜋𝑡 − 𝜋 ∗ )2 + 𝜆1 (𝑦𝑡 − 𝑦 ∗ )2 + 𝜆2 𝑓𝑡 − 𝑓 ∗ 2 ] B: set r to minimize E and set c to minimize E ∞ 𝑡 𝑡 𝛽 [(𝜋𝑡 − 𝜋 ∗ )2 + 𝜆1 (𝑦𝑡 − 𝑦 ∗ )2 ] ∞ 𝑡 𝑡 𝛽 [ 𝜆2 𝑓𝑡 − 𝑓 ∗ 2 ] 53 Two alternative strategies A: CB uses both MP and macro-pru to stabilize inflation, economic activity and financial development B: The central bank uses different instruments for different purposes, or central bank has responsibility for monetary policy financial stability is delegated to another authority (e.g. an FSA) 54 Suggested answers: In this setting, coordination is at least as good But perhaps easier to evaluate cb if fewver objectives? Decentralisation offers higher transparency, credibility and legitimacy, and allows independence The disadvantages of the second strategy are small if r has large effects on 𝜋 and y, but small effects on f c has large effects on f, but small effects on 𝜋 and y there are strong correlations between 𝜋 and y, but not between f and y or f and 𝜋 55 Suggested answers, cont. There is a ”risk-taking channel” which implies that r can have large effects on f there is a strong correlation between f and y r and c can be close substitutes (have similar effects) 56