International Economics University of Helsinki September 22nd – October 17th, 2008 Practicalities Lecturer: Matti Sarvimäki matti.sarvimaki@vatt.fi / (09) 703 2953 Lectures: Mondays 14-16, Wednesdays 14-16 Fridays 10-12 at Economicum Exam: Retake: 27.10.2008 at 8 - 10 ECO, lecture room 24.11.2008 at 8 - 10 ECO, lecture room Requirements • Lectures • Krugman (1993): What Do Undergrads Need to Know About Trade? The American Economic Review 83(2): 23– 26 (available from JSTOR) • There are two textbooks that are likely to be helpful (one by Krugman & Obstfeld another by Appleyard & Field). Both are called International Economics. The course covers most of the first half of the books (trade theory and policy) and the books cover most of the material I will present during the lectures Outline The course • • • Basic Trade Models Introduction to Trade Policy Further Topics This lecture: Introduction • Stylised facts • What models do • Mercantilism and Adam Smith • (introduction to comparative advantage) World Trade 1820-1992 World Exports/GDP (in 1990 constant dollars, percent) Source: Rodrik (2000), original data from Maddison (1995) Real GDP per capita (population weighted averages, 1950-2000) Real GDP per capita (1996 international dollars) Index: 1950=100 30.000 4.50 4.00 25.000 3.50 3.00 20.000 2.50 15.000 2.00 1.50 10.000 1.00 5.000 0.50 0.00 0.000 1950 1960 1970 1980 bottom 25% 1990 2000 25-50% 1950 1960 50-75% 1970 1980 top 25% Source: Calculations from Penn World Table, data available at http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/ 1990 2000 World Inequality 1820-1992 (mean logarithmic deviation) 0.90 0.80 0.70 Inequality within countries 0.60 0.40 Inequality between countries 0.30 Total Inequality 0.50 0.20 0.10 0.00 1820 1850 1870 1890 1910 1929 1950 1960 1970 1980 1992 Source: Bourguignon & Morrisson (2002). See also Human Developments Trends in http://www.gapminder.org/, in particular slides 1/15 and 2/11. Change in the U.S. Real Wages Change in real wages 1970–2002 (per percentile between 1970 and 2002 ) Percentile Source: Smith (2006) 0 100 200 300 Openness to Trade, GDP per capita and population (2000) 0 10 20 Real GDP per capita ($'000) 30 Source: Calculations from Penn World Table, data available at http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/ 40 300 Openness to Trade, GDP per capita and population (2000) HKG LUX 200 MYS EST SYC ATG SVK CZE KNA MUS HUN SVN TTO BRB TJK 100 GNQ NGA IDN RUS GRC BRA ARG NZL ESP MAC NLD AUT SWE FIN GER GBR FRA ITA CHE CAN DNK NOR AUS USA JPN 0 CHN PAK BGD IND KOR ISR PRT IRL BEL 0 10 20 Real GDP per capita ($'000) 30 Source: Calculations from Penn World Table, data available at http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/ 40 Openness to Trade and GDP per capita over time (Finland, 1950-2000) 80 Finland 70 2000 60 1980 50 1970 1990 40 1960 30 1950 5 10 15 Real GDP per capita ($'000), constant prices 20 Source: Calculations from Penn World Table, data available at http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/ 25 Openness to Trade and GDP per capita over time (Selected countries, 1950-2000) Mexico 10 1980 1960 2000 40 1990 1950 1980 1960 20 20 1990 (imports+exports)/GDP 30 40 2000 60 50 China 1970 0 0 1970 0 1 2 3 Real GDP per capita ($'000), constant prices 4 2 4 12 Argentina 40 (imports+exports)/GDP 40 60 50 India 6 8 10 Real GDP per capita ($'000), constant prices 1980 10 19501960 1990 2000 20 20 30 2000 1950 1960 1990 1970 1980 0 0 1970 0 1 2 3 Real GDP per capita ($'000), constant prices 4 2 4 6 8 10 Real GDP per capita ($'000), constant prices 12 0 2 4 6 Changes in Openness to Trade and changes in GDP per capita (1950/60 - 1990/00) 0 2 6 4 Change in real GDP per capita between 50/60 and 90/00 8 Source: Calculations from Penn World Table, data available at http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/ 10 6 Changes in Openness to Trade and GDP per capita (1950/60 - 1990/00) CHN TUR 4 KOR ESP ISR TWN 0 2 PHL AGO NGA NPL BEN MRT LSO NER ETH USA PRY CHL GUY SYC ROM GRC MYS IDN ITA IRL AUT PNG JOR INDPRI BEL SEN PRT MDG NIC GINHND CAN JAM MEX MUS BGD FRA CRI ECU GNB GTM MLI FIN ARG URYFJI SWE TCD NAM CYP PAK MOZRWA GMB DOM LUX SYR CHE COL ZAR CIV BDI GBR IRN SLV BOL COG NLD ISL MWI GNQVEN TGO GAB BRA MAR EGY TZA DNK GHANZL AUS COM BRB ZWE PAN NOR BFA KEN LKA CPV HTI ZAF CMR CAF ZMB TTO PER UGA DZA 0 2 THA BWA HKG JPN 6 4 Real GDP per capita ($'000) SGP 8 Source: Calculations from Penn World Table, data available at http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/ 10 Leading Merchandise Traders (2004, excluding intra-EU trade) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Exporters EU (extra-25) United States China + HK Japan Canada South Korea Mexico Russia Taiwan Value 1203.8 818.8 838.9 565.8 316.5 253.8 189.1 183.5 182.4 Share 18.1 12.3 12.6 8.5 4.8 3.8 2.8 2.8 2.7 68.5 Importers United States EU (extra-25) China + HK Japan Canada South Korea Mexico Taiwan Singapore Value Share 1525.5 21.8 1280.6 18.3 588.6 8.4 454.5 6.5 279.8 4.0 224.5 3.2 206.4 3.0 168.4 2.4 163.9 2.3 70.0 Billions of dollars, Source: WTO http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/its2005_e/section1_e/i06.xls Structure of Trade (Finland, 2000) Food etc. Materials etc. Manufacturing Machinery and transport Other Exp. 0.8 7.9 17.3 20.3 0.8 47.1 Imp. 1.7 9.7 7.2 14.2 0.8 33.7 -1.0 -1.8 10.1 6.1 0.0 13.5 Billons of dollars, Source: Calculations from the NBER-United Nations Trade Data. Data available at http://cid.econ.ucdavis.edu/. Stata code available by request (from me). In 2000, Finland’s GDP was about 130 billion dollars. Finland’s Top 6 Trading Partners, 2000 Exports Germany UK USA Sweden France China* value 4.9 3.6 3.0 3.0 2.2 2.3 Surplus UK France USA Italy Spain Philippines value 1.5 0.9 0.9 0.6 0.5 0.4 Imports Germany Sweden Russian Fed USA UK China* value 4.8 3.5 3.2 2.4 2.2 2.1 Deficit Russia Japan Sweden Norway Denmark Korea Rep. value -2.4 -1.4 -0.5 -0.4 -0.3 -0.3 * China, Hong Kong, Macao, Areas NES Billons of dollars, NBER-United Nations Trade Data Structure of Bilateral Trade (Finland, 2000) China Food etc. Materials etc. Manufacturing Machinery and transport Other Exp. Imp. 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 -0.1 0.1 0.5 -0.3 1.9 0.7 1.2 0.2 0.8 -0.6 2.3 2.1 0.2 Sweden Food etc. Materials etc. Manufacturing Machinery and transport Other Exp. Imp. 0.1 0.3 -0.2 0.7 0.8 -0.1 1.2 1.2 -0.1 1.0 1.2 -0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 3.0 3.5 -0.5 Billons of dollars, NBER-United Nations Trade Data Structure of Trade (Finland 1962, 1989, 2000) Exp. Food etc. 0.0 Materials etc. 0.5 Manufacturing 0.4 Machinery and 0.0 transport Other 0.0 0.9 1962 1989 2000 Imp. Exp. Imp. Exp. Imp. 0.1 -0.1 0.5 1.2 -0.7 0.8 1.7 -1.0 0.1 0.3 5.3 6.1 -0.8 7.9 9.7 -1.8 0.3 0.1 12.3 6.9 5.5 17.3 7.2 10.1 0.4 -0.3 0.0 0.9 0.0 0.1 6.4 9.4 -3.1 0.2 0.2 -0.1 24.7 23.8 0.8 20.3 14.2 6.1 0.8 0.8 0.0 47.1 33.7 13.5 Economic Theory / Models “. . . just talking plausibly about economics is not the same as having a real understanding; for that you need crisp, tightly argued models.” Paul Krugman (1996) “[Models] reduce a complex problem to a few essentials and illustrate the relationships between them. A good model is one which is wide in scope and unexpected in implications.” John Kay (2003) “…The ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed, the world is ruled by little else.” John Maynard Keynes (1936) Economic Models as Simplifications • The point of economic models is to simplify the complex reality in order to understand it. A good model is such that a. it is easy to understand (simple) b. it increases the understanding of reality • Mathematics is the language of economics. The point is to be consistent and to make assumptions transparent. In this course we use geometry to make the math more intuitive Gibbard & Varian (1978) describe models as “caricatures”, “approximations”, “stories with a specific structure” etc. Models typically ask “what would happen if this and this was the case?” and exaggerate to make a point • Example: London A model of London Another model of London Economic Models as Imitations “[…] a "theory" is not a collection of assertions about the behavior of the actual economy but rather an explicit set of instructions for building a parallel or analogue system […] A "good" model, from this point of view, will not be exactly more "real" than a poor one, but will provide better imitations. Of course, what one means by a "better imitation" will depend on the particular questions to which one wishes answers.” Lucas (1980) • For an example of this kind of model in trade contest, visit www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu • However, in this course we will concentrate on models that are best described as caricatures. International Economics • What is different in comparison to “ordinary” economics? The institutional setting (national policies, currencies etc) nothing else, really. • International economics typically divided: o o international trade and international money. In this course we will concentrate on the former. HSE provides a similar course that concentrates on the latter. • The study of international trade can be extended to study international capital, labour flows and diffusion of technology Evolution of Trade Theory • Mercantilism (1500–) • Classical Political Economy o o o Price-Specie-Flow Mechanism (Hume, 1752) Absolute Advantage (Smith, 1776) Comparative Advantage (Ricardo, 1817) • Neo-Classical Economics o Heckscher-Ohlin Model (1919, 1933) and extensions • Modern Economics o Economies of scale, imperfect competition… Mercantilism • Diffuse collection of economic thought • Mostly written by merchants and businessmen • Appears in economics virtually always as a target of critique. However, the mercantilist mindset has not vanished among many non-economists • The word mercantilist is still used for a person opposing free trade based on “traditional arguments” For short discussion, see Appleyard & Field (chapter 2). If you’re more interested, see Landreth & Colander (2002) Mercantilist View of the Economy • • • Nations wealth = holdings of precious metals Zero-sum economy “Favourable balance of trade” o • i.e. exports good, imports bad Implicit assumption that the economy was operating at less than full employment Conclusion: Economic activity should be regulated Mercantilist Policy Recommendations International o o o o Tariffs & Quotas on imports Subsidies on exports Exclusive trading rights Government control on exchange of precious metals Domestic o o Regulating production (exclusive product charters, tax exemptions, subsidies, special privileges…) Regulating labour (crafts guilds, low wages, subsidies for children, financial incentives for marriage…) Adam Smith “... He generally, indeed, neither intends to promote the public interest, nor knows how much he is promoting it [...] he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention.” Smith (1776) “Somehow all of the activities seem to get coordinated. There’s a taxi to get you to the airport. There’s butter and cheese for lunch on the airplane. There are refineries to make the airplane fuel and trucks to transport it, cement for the runways, electricity for the escalators, and most important of all, passengers who want to fly where the airplanes are going. […] if you are in a mood to be amazed, it can amaze you that the system works at all.” Schelling (1978) Smith’s View of the Economic System • Nations wealth = Production capacity • Positive-sum economy • Self-interest combined with competition serves public interest • Division of labour increases productivity Conclusion: Policy of laissez faire promotes economic growth Labour theory of value • The amount of labour required to produce a good determines its’ value o Let’s assume that it takes two hours to produce A and an hour to produce B → A is two times more valuable than B • The prevailing value theory until 1870s o o Main problem: Does not consider utility Other problems: measurement, differing skills, how to deal with capital, land and profits Smith on Trade: Absolute Advantage Cloth Wine England 1 hr. / yd. 4 hrs. / bbl. Portugal 2 hr. / yd. 3 hrs. / bbl. Absolute Advantage: Relative Prices in Autarky • Autarky price of wine in terms of cloth o England: 1 bbl. wine = 4 yd. cloth o Portugal: 1 bbl. wine = 1,5 yd. cloth • Autarky price of cloth in terms of wine o England: 1 yd. cloth = 0,25 bbl. wine o Portugal: 1 yd. cloth = 0,67 bbl. wine → England has absolute advantage in cloth, Portugal in wine Absolute Advantage: Rationale for Trade • If international trade is allowed o o → England wants to buy wine if it costs less than 4 yard of cloth per barrel of wine Portugal wants to sell wine if it gets more than 1,5 yard of cloth per barrel of wine Both are willing to trade for any price between 1,5 - 4 yard per barrel References • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • Gibbard & Varian (1978): Economic models. Journal of Philosophy 75:664–677 Bourguignon & Morrisson (2002): Inequality Among World Citizens: 1820-1992. American Economic Review. Vol. 92, No. 4 Heckscher (1919): The Effect of Foreign Trade on the Distribution of Income, Ekonomisk Tidskrift. Hume (1752): Of the Balance of Trade. Availabe at www.utilitarian.net/hume/ Kay (2003): The Truth about Markets. Allan Lane. Published in the U.S. as “Culture and Prosperity“ by HarperBusiness. Keynes (1936): The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. Krugman (1993): What Do Undergrads Need to Know About Trade? The American Economic Review. Vol. 83(2): 23–26 Krugman (1996): Pop Internationalism. MIT Press. Landreth & Colander (2002): History of Economic Thought. Houghton Mifflin Company. Lucas (1980): Methods and Problems in Business Cycle Theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 12: 696-715 Ohlin (1933): Interregional and International Trade. Ricardo (1817): On the Priciples of Political Economy. Schelling (1978): Micromotives and macrobehavior. W. W. Norton Smith, A. (1776): An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Smith, J. (2006): Immigrants and the Labor Market. Journal of Labor Economics 24(2)