A/T SHORT OUTLINE WHAT CONDUCT IS ILLEGAL I. II. III. IV. V. VI. VII. VIII. IX. Central Role for Economic Analysis a. Economic effects: collusion or exclusion – focus on inc. prices, dec. output, loss of innovation b. Substitution/Switching: demand elasticity c. Entry d. Surplus – consumer or producer (most juris favor consumers) Collusive Effects – directly impairs mkts by coordinated activity btwn firms w/ mkt power to reduce own output Exclusionary Effects – indirectly impair mkts by raising rival costs; single firm or collusive (cause others to reduce their output) What factors effect if corporation will comply w/ rules: Legal Standards a. Per se i. Evidence of a/c effect not req’d; presumed w/ no excuses allowed. ii. Used when have experience w/ the sort of conduct under consid iii. Makes most econ sense when: prohib conduct would likely harm competition severely, D will frequently claim conduct is reasonable; little pro-competitve conduct will be deterred b. Rule of Reason, Quick Look – burden shifting, efficiencies. c. Arg for more lenient rule – false positives more costly b/c deters precompetitive conduct and mkt power likely to be temporary d. Arg for less lenient rule – mkt power results in immed harm and is often long-lasting ANTITRUST INJURY REQUIREMENT – Brunswick Corp v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat (1977) a. Arose at time of signif econ change – mid-70s see rise of foreign competition b. Injury must be the sort that A/T laws sought to regulate – protect competition, not competitors JTC Petroleum v. Piasa Motor Fuels (7th Cir 1999) – exclusionary group boycott a. 2 level cartel – producers and applicators –A gets P to enforce and to exclude JTC b. Justification a pretext b/c were paying in cash Bell Atlantic v. Twombley (2007) – elevated pleading requirement a. Complaint must rise above speculative level – req’s some facts suggesting agreement. ANALYSIS STEPS a. Step 1 – concerted or exclusionary action b. Step 2 – type of restraint/theory of anticompetitive harm c. Step 3 – determine the mkt and mkt share allocation. HORIZONTAL AGREEMENTS I. II. Sherman Act S.1 – 2 elements: “contract, combination, conspiracy” & “restraint of trade” Per Se Ban on Price-Fixing a. Trenton Potteries (1927) i. Aim and result of every price fixing is the elimination of 1 form of competition – can have no benefit to competition; thus no further analysis is necessary ii. “Reasonable” price today may be unreasonable tomorrow 1 A/T SHORT OUTLINE b. Appalachian Coal – no monop menace b/c no mkt power – “honest effort to remove abuses” c. US v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co (1940) i. Per se rule clearly established for ALL price-fixing ii. Need only to have intent (FN59) – not having mkt power is not a defense d. Horizontal Agreements Subject to Per Se Condemnation i. Price-Fixing – entire price or one term (incl. credit terms) ii. Output Restriction iii. Market Allocation iv. Customer Allocation III. CHARACTERIZATION a. Broadcast Music Inc v. Columbia Broadcasting System (1979) i. Before condemning conduct as per se illegal, need to “characterize” the conduct – implicit in the framework. ii. To use per se, need to establish that the conduct is “plainly a/c” and “without redeeming value” iii. Here, this is not price-fixing in the literal sense 1. Would not expect any mkt arrangement reasonably necessary to effectuate [IP] rights to be deemed per se illegal 2. Blanket licenses accompany the integration, sale, monitoring, & enforcement 3. Clearing companies add value to the process b. Catalano Inc. v. Target Sales - collective refusal to compete on credit terms indisting from price fixing (refused to deal with beer suppliers on credit; cash only) c. Texaco v. Dagher (2006) – single firms cannot price fix. When firms pool capital and share risks, regarded as a single firm. IV. MARKET DIVISION – Per Se Illegal a. Timken – div of mkts by competitors per se violation – group viewed as a cartel and action is an alternative means of price-fixing. b. US v. Topco (1972) i. Classic per se violation is agreement btwn competitors at the same level. ii. Justification - need mkt division to compete w/ larger chains. iii. Good intention is not a defense. 1. No authority to determine respective value of competition in a sector 2. Should have made the BMI new product argument (came 9yr later) c. Palmer v. BRG of Georgia (1990) – straight forward geog allocation per se illegal d. HYPO – how would Topco have come out under BMI or Sylvania? V. OUTPUT RESTRICTION – Collusive Boycott (effort to bet higher price from rival) a. FTC v. Superior Court Trial Lawyers Ass’n (1990) i. Constriction of supply to raise price the essence of price-fixing – per se illegal ii. Social justifications do not make restraint any less lawful 1. Disting from Noerr b/c restraint was consequence of seeking new law 2. O’Brien only held that Court should apply A/T law w/ sensitivity to 1st Am concerns iii. “No mkt power” is not a cognizable defense b. National Society of Professional Engineers v. US (1978) – Professional Services. i. Sherman Act does not require competitive bidding, but does prohibit unreasonable restraints of trade. 2 A/T SHORT OUTLINE ii. Preventing competitive bidding illegal under RoR iii. Defense (quality would decrease) is not cognizable – impedes ordinary give and take of mkt place by not allowing price negotiations. Not NSPE’s job to determine whether competition is good or bad. c. Impact of NPSE on burdens production/proof i. Per se – only have to prove action is in per se category ii. RoR – multi-faceted analysis where P gets to intro more evidence iii. Reframed A/T law around core economic issues. VI. DEVELOPMENT OF QUICK LOOK FOR HORIZONTAL AGREEMENTS a. Evolution of Unreasonableness i. US v. Trans-Missouri Freight Ass’n (1897) – Every means Every, but did recognize that common law supported some exceptions ii. Standard Oil (1911) – reasonableness is intended in S.1 iii. Addyston Pipe – separated naked and ancillary restraints (per se v. RoR) b. Board of Trade of City of Chicago v. US (1918) – Origins of Rule of Reason i. Must consider facts peculiar to business: 1. Condition before and after restraint – could still send bids after close, just temporary restriction on price 2. Nature of Restraint – restrained to small amount of daily business 3. Effect (actual or probable) – no effect generally on mkt price/volume c. The Quick Look Analysis i. NCAA v Board of Regents FN39 – “RoR can sometimes be applied in the twinkling of an eye” ii. Goal is to cut from RoR Analysis where conduct has obvious a/c consequences iii. Common Quick Look Test – burden shifting (Law v. NCAA) 1. P has initial burden of showing adverse effect – quick review shows harm to competition. 2. D then gets to show pro-competitive effects, must be cognizable and supported by evidence. 3. P can show that rule not reasonably necessary or can be implemented using less restrictive means 4. If met, then balance – generally based on weight of the evidence. d. Board of Regents of University of Oklahoma (1984) i. TV restriction illegal under quick look ii. Per se rule not applied b/c of characterization – need some agreement for product to exist iii. However, restrictions not linked to the product – removes price competition and decreases quantity. iv. Cannot protect weaker product by harming more attractive product – good motives will not validate an otherwise a/c restraint v. Mkt power not essential to proof of illegality – absence of mkt power does not justify restraint e. Cal Dental Ass’n v. FTC (1999) i. Quick Look Analysis not sufficient – need more extensive inquiry. ii. Looking at circum, details, logic of restraint, the object is to see whether experience of mkt has been so clear that confident conclusion about principal tendency will follow from the quick look. 3 A/T SHORT OUTLINE f. Polygram Holding Inc v. FTC (DC Cir 2005) i. Use Quick Look, not per se b/c might be certain way to limit own venture to benefit common undertaking, but still see as dangerous. ii. In determ whether competition restrained, inquiry must be met for the case iii. JV inherently suspect, due to close resemblance to suspect practices. iv. Case seems to expand QL to where there may not be actual evidence of a/c effects, but only a high likelihood. v. TEST 1. Commision determ whether it is obvious that consumers will likely be harmed (“inherently suspect” – consid earlier cases and econ theory 2. If “inherently suspect” D must come forward w/ justifications 3. Submit fuller evidence of harm a. Commission must then address in 1 of 2 ways: i. Confidently conclude that consumers likely harmed ii. Provide suffic evidence to show a/c effects likely. b. D must show actual pro-competitive effects or that benefits outweigh harms. g. Non-Cognizable Defenses for Horizontal Restrictions i. Competition reasonable/destructive (NSPE) ii. Prices set were reasonable (SCTLA) iii. No market power (NCAA & SCTLA) iv. Restraint protected weaker product from stronger product (NCAA) VII. DETERMINING WHAT IS CONCERTED ACTION a. Economics of Modern Cartels – what they have to do to succeed i. Reach consensus ii. Deter and punish cheating iii. Cope w/ new or external threats – mavericks/hold-outs; new entry/subs; suppliers; buyer resistance. b. Certain factors make collusion more or les likely i. # of firms ii. Product heterogeneity iii. Excess capacity (yours or others) iv. Predictable Demand v. Lumpy Sales/Large Buyers c. Info Sharing i. Mere sharing NOT ILLEGAL, nor is agreement to share ii. Considered a plus factor iii. Eval’d through rule of reason: common themes: 1. Legitimacy of sharing and decreased risk if smaller mkt share 2. Better off if info is aggregated 3. More likely to be acceptable if data is past info 4. If “benchmark” info, have 3d party do it w/ a template iv. American Column & Lumber (1921) 1. 90% of members, extensive and detailed data, incl. name of buyer, seller and price; also suggested prices and production levels; not made available to buyers 4 A/T SHORT OUTLINE 2. HELD as a conspiracy to fix prices – could be understood as helping firms to reach consensus and deter cheating. v. Maple Flooring (1925) 1. 22 members, 70% of US production. 2. HELD to have competitively legitimate purposes 3. Disting from AC&L b/c didn’t ID buyer/seller, didn’t share current prices or make recommendations. d. Parent & Sub – Copperweld Corp v. Independence Tube Corp (1984) i. Parent and wholly-owned sub considered one entity, thus no S.1 scrutiny ii. Decision w/in a corporation to implement single firm’s policy – common purpose and should be able to choose own corp org structure iii. Holding been expanded to: parents and less than wholly owned subs; sister corps; other intra-enterprise conduct e. Incomplete Coordination – In re Brand Name Prescrip Drug Litigation (7th Cir 1997) i. Denied pharmacies discounts, but retained discounts for “preferred buyers” ii. Cartel may not be tight enough to prevent large, bulk buyers from shifting demand 1. Single price may not always be profit maxizing 2. Thin profits don’t disprove cartel – could have been thinner iii. Matsushita’s “no economic sense” test unavailing. f. Oligopolistic Interdependence – is it concerted action? i. Posner – YES, in some circum: equiv to negotiation, eventually get a pegged $ ii. Turner – NO, it’s a natural thing for firms to do. VIII. INFERRING CONSPIRACY a. Interstate Circuit v. US (1939) i. Distrib knew others also being approached and plan would only work w/ concerted action. ii. This constituted an AGREEMENT. iii. Unanimity of Action – enough that concerted action was invited and contemplated and that they participated. iv. Failed to provide contrary testimony – seen as estab the weakness of any counter-testimony. b. American Tobacco v. US (1946) i. Similar, subsequent actions of competitors can support finding of conspiracy ii. No formal agreement is necessary – can be found in course of dealing iii. Important Factors: concentrated oligopoly (community of interest), parallel conduct, falling cost and declining demand (yet $ increasing) – combo’d show firms knew what they were doing c. Parallelism Plus Doctrine – Theater Enterprises Inc v. Paramount (1954) i. Circumstantial evidence of consciously parallel behavior may have made strong inroads, BUT ii. It has not read “conspiracy” out of the Sherman Act entirely. d. Current Doctrine i. Circum proof can estab conspiracy, but… ii. Proof of parallel conduct alone not suffic to estab concerted action. Thus, iii. Proof of agreement req’s parallel conduct plus other proof. 5 A/T SHORT OUTLINE e. Plus Factors (p310-311) i. Industry conditions – structure, product characteristics ii. Firm Conduct – irrational behavior, info sharing, other communications iii. Past behavior indicating collusion. f. Approaches to plus factors: Check the box; Link to Conspiracy/what cartel has to do to succeed; weigh according to past cartel experience. IX. X. PROVING CONCERTED ACTION a. Invitation to Collude – US v. American Airlines (5th Cir 1984) i. Mere suggestion of collusion can trigger S.2 violation (attempted monop) ii. 2 req’d elements – Specific Intent & Dangerous Probability – at time act occur 1. Dangerous Probability – call btwn CEOs and high mkt share 2. Might have been okay if firms were smaller (threshold: 50%) iii. It is not a defense that plan proved impossible to execute. b. Pre-Matsushita – Poller v. CBS (1962) – summary procedures should be used sparingly. c. Monsanto (1984) – build up to Matsushita i. Where illegal action appears same as legal action, P must show more likely than not due to concerted action. d. Matsushita v. Zenith Corp. (1986) – standard for Summary Judgment i. Evidence must “TEND TO EXCLUDE THE POSSIBILITY” that the action was for competitive benefits – “plausibility” ii. If evidence ambiguous, P must show more at trial. iii. Conduct as consistent w/ permissible competition as w/ illegal conspiracy does not support inference of A/T conspiracy. – circum evid + plausibility. 1. Pred Pricing is by its very nature speculative a. To be rational, must have reasonable expectation of recouping b. Also uncertain b/c req’s maintaining mkt power 2. Even more difficult when firms have to coordinate 3. Makes no “economic sense” e. Three factors helf confer coordinated equilibrium i. Behavior more complex than would be plausible w/o agreement ii. Justifications given are weak iii. Opportunity for firms to communicate. f. Two Situations where Matsushita “no economic sense” test should shield firms i. Industry structure not conducive to coordination (thus would be irrational) ii. Could have been achieved by leader-follower behavior, w/o agreement Expanded Emphasis on Procedural Screens a. Matsushita’s “plausibility” screen has been extended backward to the pleading stage b. Twombley (2007)–complaints must rise above speculative level (motion to dismiss) i. “Plausible” is greater than possible – parallel behavior is not enough; req’s some facts suggesting agreement ii. Arg – AT&T break-up firms should have been expanding to other mkts; defended by saying it was too risky – no req to compete, but can’t not compete 6 A/T SHORT OUTLINE c. In re Text Messaging Antitrust Litigation (7th Cir 2010) i. P must meet “plausibility” standard to survive dismissal of suit ii. Used economically grounded approach – looked at what factors make conspiracy more or less probable iii. Plus factors supplement communication, hard-to-understand conduct counts iv. Direct evidence not essential d. In re Publication Paper Antitrust Litigation (2d Cir 2012) i. P put forth suffic evidence to permit reasonable jury to find that higher prices resulted from agreement rather than independent action ii. Range of permissible inference depends on plausibility – broader inferences allowed when theory is more economically sensible. iii. Factors 1. Structural conditions – commodity prod, few subs, lmt’d #sellers, high barriers to entry 2. Counter-intuitive pricing 3. Excess capacity (closing mills) 4. Parallel pricing 5. Direct evidence – “we’re a follower” DISTRIBUTIVE ARRANGEMENTS I. II. III. IV. Distinction btwn substitutes and complements Relevant legal framework a. Antitrust law (below) b. State law (eg: dealer location restrictions) c. Sector specific (eg: petroleum market) History/Early Cases a. Dr. Miles (1911) – vertical price restraints unlawful – once sold, cannot control price b. Albrecht – extended Dr. Miles to maximum RPM c. Colgate (1919) – weakened Dr. Miles; only applies where there is agreement d. US v. GE (1926) – may set RPM when there is a genuine principal-agent relationship e. Schwinn – per se rule for vertical, intrabrand non-price restraints (territorial) f. Miller Tydings Act (1937) and McGuire Act (1952) – states may auth RPM laws g. Consumer Goods Pricing Act (1975) – repealed Miller-Tydings and McGuire Acts – Dr. Miles now back in full force (has to do w/ econ conditions at the time). h. Monsanto – rasied burden for proving RPM (Cong refused to fund arg for repeal of Dr. Miles) i. Business Electronics Corp (1988) – raises Monsanto standard, harder to prove agreement, on price or price level j. State Oil v. Khan – abandoned per se rule for max RPM Vertical Non-Price Restraints – Continental TV Inc v. GTE Sylvania (1977) a. Restriction per se violation under Schwinn, BUT Schwinn should be overturned. b. RoR is the standard, and departure is only justified by demonstrable a/c effect (Northern Pacific) c. These sorts of agreements are not manifestly a/c (“transaction cost literature” – Turner) d. Schwinn did not distinguish actions based on the indiv potential for intrabrand harm or interbrand benefit 7 A/T SHORT OUTLINE V. Recognized Justifications for Non-Price Intrabrand Restraints a. Induce competent retailers to carry new products b. Promote existing products c. Defeat mkt imperfections d. Insulate mnfctr from product liability exposure e. Protect mnfctr reputation by ensuring quality. VI. Post-Sylvania – P has been successful only when D has interbrand mkt power or there is not evidence of pro-competitive purposes. VII. VIII. IX. X. XI. Vertical Price Restraints – Leegin Creative Leather Products v. PSKS Inc (2007) a. Recent (econ) jurisprudence has rejected rationales justifying Dr. Miles’ per se rule b. Cannot be stated w/ confidence RPM always or most always tends to restrict completion and decrease output – per se rule would inc. total cost to system. c. Potential Harms – mnfct cartel; retail cartel; forestall innovation in distribution d. Justifications i. Can stimulate interbrand competition by suppressing intrabrand competitioin. ii. Encourage retailers to invest in tangible/intangible services/promos iii. Facilitate new mkt entry by inducing competent and aggressive retailers to invest in necessary capital/labor. e. Also allows other pricing programs to be eval’d on their merits Vertical v. Horizontal – Characterizing the Challenge – Nynex Corp v. Discon (1988) a. Distribution chain choices are not per se illegal – freedom to switch from one retailer to another b. Distinguish case here from Klor’s b/c this is a vertical chain c. On remand – could still use RoR to estab a/c harm; kickback not an A/T issue. Post Leegin Process a. Apply BMI to RPM cases b. Rule of Reason Standard c. Screens – mkt power, cartels (producer or retailer) Legal Issues from the Apple e-Book Decision a. Parallelism Plus Doctrine b. Entered same agreement w/ all publishers – resulting in uniform price increases c. Evid of conspiracy can be found through direct evid (Job’s statements) and circum evid (goals, shift in model, simultaneous and sudden price increases) – suffic to infer collective action. d. Apple’s Args: i. Does not “tend to exclude”; however, evid here leaves ambiguity (go to jury) ii. Never intended to conspire; however, good motives don’t allow a/c injury Distrib relationships in the EU – distinctions from US System a. More particular categories of agreement articulated b. EC can exempt indiv agreements/categories c. Interpreted more broadly than S.1 8 A/T SHORT OUTLINE HORIZONTAL MERGERS I. II. III. IV. V. VI. VII. VIII. “May be substantially to lessen competition” – no substantive guidelines, left to agencies/courts to elaborate standards – predictive enforcement mechanism. S.7 of Clayton only req’s an “appreciable danger” so can satisfy w/ conduct that would not necessarily satisfy S.1 – eg: “conscious parallelism” Can harm competition through coordinated, unilateral, or exclusionary effects Pre-Merger Notification (HSR) a. Steps: i. Filing – mandatory notification if past threshold ii. Initial Waiting Period (30d started at filing) 1. Who gets to look at deal – historical allocation, statutory carve-outs 2. Decide if want more info – 90% of cases end here. iii. Second Request (30 add’l days after all docs turned over) iv. Enforcement Choices – fed court for injunction, do nothing, settlement b. Use other firms and customers for info c. Generally not resolved through litigation – withdraw and refile, lmt’d divestiture, or consent decree/settlement 2010 HMG a. Analysis of competitive effects over mkt structure–can still create rebut presump b. Recognized multiple methods by which merger can harm competition. c. Coordinated Effects – relevant evid: behavioral feat, industry char. EU v. US Merger Enforcement a. Similarities i. Mandatory notification of large transactions ii. Rely mainly on info provided by merging parties – US 2d request more taxing iii. Similar analytical framework – high evidentiary standard b. Differences i. 3d parties can appeal EU decisions to not challenge merger ii. US agencies not liable for damages if decisions overruled iii. US has higher evidentiary standard Enforcement Trends a. SCT Jurisprudence (1962-1975) – structural view i. Horiz merger – 4.49% (Pabst) ii. Vert Merger – 2% foreclosure iii. Conglomerate – more lenient, but still skeptical (P&G/Clorox) iv. Efficiencies disregarded b. Lower Courts Today – Modern View i. Horiz – strong structural presumption for 3-2, and scrutiny at 5-4 and 4-3 ii. Vert – “subst degree of foreclosure” – usually about 30% iii. Conglomerate – largely ignored iv. Strong role for efficiencies v. HMG – non-binding, but influential – not binding, but quoted back by courts STRUCTURAL ERA CASES – assoc btwn mkt conc and competitive concerns a. Brown Shoe v. US (1962) i. Fear of rising tide of econ concentration – Congressional intent ii. Control of substantial share of trade in a city may have effect on competition in such fragmented industry even if only control of a small share. 9 A/T SHORT OUTLINE iii. National chain can insulate mkt from competition in certain areas iv. Dichotomy in holding – not entirely indifferent to inc. in output/efficiency b. US v. Philadelphia National Bank (1963) i. Enjoin merger b/c produces firm with controlling share of the market ii. Only allowed justification is direct evid that merger does not actually harm competition. iii. Bank’s arguments: 1. Necessary to follow customers to suburbs – could expand internally 2. Inc. lending limit allows compet. w/ out of state banks – a/c effects in one market cannot be justified by pro-compet benefits in another. 3. Will bring business to area – value judgment best left to Congress c. Van’s Grocery – would result in firm w/ 7.5% of mkt and stong trend toward conc d. Pabst – 4.49% and strong trend to conc over past 30yr e. Start seeing shift – rapid conc a key feature, but so is tech dev and lower transport and commun. Costs – leading to higher output and lower price. IX. X. DECLINE OF THE STRUCTURAL PRESUMPTION a. US v. General Dynamics (1974) i. Not enjoin b/c mkt share was improperly calculated – mkt share should be based on uncommitted reserves (determ firm’s future ability to compete) 1. Was initially based on current sales – coal producers ii. Not contesting validity of presumption, but need for proper calculation iii. Case has been read broadly by lower courts to permit wide ranging analysis of ability to compete. b. Boeing-McDonnel Douglas Merger (1997) i. FTC clears w/o conditions b/ MD no longer able to compete for future sales – customer interviews, biggest purchaser didn’t consider them for new order ii. EC clears w/ conditions (give up exclusive contracts) – political decision. c. Structural Presumption in 1982 HMG i. Mkt Conc is highly influential but NOT outcome determinative ii. Precedence from SCT – mkt structure can create virtually conclusive presump of illegality, rebutted by showing improper calculation. iii. Focus on lower court decisions – raised mkt share thresholds and gave D more ability to rebut presumption. ECONOMICS OF MODERN MERGERS a. Substitution – proper market is defined by reasonable interchageability of use i. Step 1 of analysis is to ID mkt participants and then assign mkt shares b. Entry (can be used to rebut prima facie case of illegality) i. Early Case – Rome Cable – SCT forecloses use of efficiency arguments ii. GD – ease of entry could be used to rebut a/c effect derived from mkt stats iii. WMI – 2d Cir treats mkt entry as a trump card iv. Entry Analysis 1. Timely – rapid enough to make a/c acts unprofitable 2. Likely – will it really happen? 3. Sufficient – if single firm, must replicate at least scale and strength of one merging firm; mult firms operating at smaller scale may be suffic v. US v. Waste Management Inc (2d Cir 1984) 1. Ease of entry can rebut prima facie illegality by showing no a/c effect 10 A/T SHORT OUTLINE XI. 2. The mkt def was artificially restricted to current firms even though subst competition would react quickly. 3. Case signaled that courts willing to embrace modern econ thinking w/o SCT guidance. c. Efficiencies. i. Must be “cognizable” 1. Substantiated and verified 2. Merger specific (could not e achieved otherwise) 3. Cannot arise from an a/c reduction in output or service ii. Limited usefulness w/ high concentration iii. HMG seems to focus on consumer welfare (over aggregate welfare) d. Mavericks – don’t have to lower their price, but only refuse to raise price i. ID’ing mavericks 1. Past conduct 2. “Natural Experiments” that ID firms restraining movement 3. Features of mkt that tend to suggest firm would prefer lower price. ii. Signif of Maverick 1. If involves maverick, will lose party constraining price 2. Non-maverick – show affects mavericks’ incentive (eg: excl boycott) e. Failing Firm Defense i. HMG allows acquisition regardless of potential harm, if: 1. Unable to meet financial oblig and unable to reorganize efficiently 2. Unsuccessful, good-faith effort to sell assets to buyer who would keep them in mkt and would be a less severe threat 3. Assets would exit the mkt absent the merger ii. These req’s are strictly construed – “weak firm” will not satisfy them iii. Courts have allowed analogous “failing division” defense f. Measuring Market Concentration – concentration and increase i. Not measure capacity if committed or profitably employed outside mkt, such that they wouldn’t shift in response to price increase ii. HHI Safeharbors – unlikely to challenge if: 1. 2. 3. DEFINING THE MARKET a. Mkt Def needed to be able to measure price effects. b. Measured by reasonable interchangeability of use. c. Submarkets – exam practical, industry, and public recognition – related to buyer substitution patters d. Price Discrimination, often by use or location e. Cluster Market – indiv services commonly recog as relevant product mkt; deviates from demand substitution approach. f. US v. H&R Block (DDC 2011) – collusive conduct. i. Holding – proper mkt is “online tax prep” submarket ii. Outer bounds of product mkt defined by reasonable interchangeability iii. Broad overall mkt may contain smaller relevant mkts 1. Ask hypothetically whether it would be profitable to have monopolist over given set of substitutable products. 11 A/T SHORT OUTLINE 2. Just b/c firms compete does not mean they should be in the same mkt iv. Here, DDIY the relevant mkt – looking at ordinary corporate acts 1. Assisted tax prep – exclude b/c of price disparity, usually held as separate business from DDY, hybrid products not mature enough yet 2. Manual tax prep – exclude b/c function experience diff, such that subst. # of customers would not switch. v. Coordinated Effects – presumption: HHI inc. by 400 to 4691; history of collusion (lobbying); would decrease incentive to compete vi. Burden shifts to D to produce evidence of barriers to collusion – transparent pricing; historical acts; w/o merger would have race to zero g. FTC v. Cardinal Health (DDC 1998) – collusive conduct i. Relevant market should be wholesalers only (submarket) ii. Although all forms of delivery compete at some level, mere fact firms compete does not mean they should be included in the same, relevant mkt iii. Services provided make wholesalers unique – services not currently suffic provided by others to serve as real sub – based on firms’ internal records iv. Anticompetitive b/c 1. Excess capacity pushes down prices – merger wanted to elim that excess capacity 2. Continuing competition in industry after prev merger rejected, which led to decreased in prices (shows mkt likely for collusion) v. Indicative that courts can consider a large range of factors. XII. COLLUSIVE EFFECTS a. Consider what behavior and mkt structure facilitates collusion – 3 elements i. Mkt conc is high and increasing ii. Mkt shows signs of vulnerability to coord conduct iii. Merger may enhance that vulnerability. b. US v. Baker Hughes (DC Cir 1990) i. HHUDR mkt naturally high conc w/ few sales of large machinery and mkt % changes notable from year to year – DOJ argued coord effects by mkt structur ii. However, structure/volatility show that coord not taking place – mkt share and conc are just a starting point, need other factors (struc presump weak) iii. “Clear showing” is NOT necessary for rebuttal of structural presump – relies on totality of circumstances approach – GD is a mandate to use many factors iv. Entry not req’d to be “quick and effective” – timely, likely, sufficient v. Here, barriers not so high as to impede entry – have recent entry and threats of new entry (eg: from Canada); low barrier, threat of entry can be enough vi. The more evidence gov’t submits, the more evidence req’d by D for rebuttal c. FTC v. HJ Heinz (DC Cir 2001) i. Sort of a qualification of Baker Hughes ii. 3 to 2 merger should be enjoined. 3 steps to analysis of issue on merits 1. Merger would produce firm controlling undue % of mkt and have signif concentration 2. To rebut, D must produce evid showing mkt stats inaccurate pic – fails a. Little competitive loss b/c firms don’t really compete b. Effects offset by efficiencies c. Enable H to innovate 12 A/T SHORT OUTLINE 3. Burden shifts to gov’t to produce add’l evidence of a/c effects iii. Structural presumption still strong at 3 to 2 – barriers and conc are recipe for price coordination, so need strong rebuttal evidence. d. Hospital Corp of America v. FTC (7th Cir 1986) i. Holding – FTC correctly balanced factors; enjoin merger ii. Ultimate question is whether merger is likely to facilitate collusion. 1. Structural – 11 to 7 merger, with increase from 14% to 26% 2. HCA would still set prices for them all (even though indiv entities) 3. TN Cert of Need estab high barriers to entry, and others can object 4. Demand for hospitals/services highly inelastic – high value on health, docs make decisions, insurers pay. 5. Trad of cooperation btwn hospitals (insurer reimbursement issues) iii. Defenses – all rebutted 1. Each participant heterogeneous, b/c diff specialties – makes collusion more difficult, but NOT impossible 2. Econ and tech changes – may actually make collusion more imperative XIII. UNILATERAL/EXCLUSIONARY EFFECTS a. Need enough mkt power to raise price by themselves – next sub is relatively distant b. Main application is differentiated products (can also be homogenous though) c. Relevant Economics – Williamson Diagram. i. Recapture/Repositioning – upward price pressure (closeness of subs) ii. Reduction in MC/efficiencies – downward pressure d. Early Case – Kraft Foods i. Rejected unilateral effects claim b/c of compet w/ many other products – lost sales likely diverted among many other products. 5 types of evidence 1. Physical characteristics/image 2. Customer testimony about buyer substitution 3. Survey data about customer base/demographics 4. Extent to which firms monitor and respond to movements of others 5. Econometric study of demand – low elasticity in mkt e. FTC v. Staples (DDC 1997) i. FTC sufficiently showed theory of likely harm by unilateral effects ii. Mkt defined as “consumable office supplies through office superstores” 1. Sensitivity to price change – higher prices in mkts where firms don’t compete (other sellers don’t effect pricing_ 2. Uniqueness of office superstores – diff appearance, size, format, variety, customer base 3. Industry/public recognition – eval’d own competition as that w/ other superstores iii. Probable effects on completion – 3 to 2 merger would recapture much of the diversion iv. Efficiences – not persuasive here 1. Must show FTC’s evid gives inaccurate picture of probable effects – evidence overstated cost savings and pass throughs v. Relied on econometric models and internal docs 13 A/T SHORT OUTLINE f. Oracle i. 3 firms dominate mkt for “enterprise software” (Oracle, PeopleSoft, SAP) – excludes 3 toher firms due to customer testimony (Lawson, AMS, Microsoft) ii. To prevail on differentiated products unilateral effects claim P must prove relevant mkt in which merging parties would have dom position iii. Court insisted on narrow mkt, but expressed skepticism it could be defined in a principaled way – avoid “localized competition analysis” g. Whole Foods i. Principal Issue – mkt definition “premium, natural, and organic supermarkets” refined to supermarkets more generally. 1. Other supermkts seeking to offer natural/organic products 2. Pricing didn’t differ based on presence of each other ii. Unilateral Effects 1. WF and WO close subs 2. Evidence of 20% price increase 3. Project Goldmine – WF would recapture most WO diversion 4. Evidence: a. Qual Evid – CEO statements b. Quan Evid – “best econ data” ever seen iii. Ct App found that Dist Ct wrongly focused on marginal customers, and overlooked committed customers – should have relied more on FTC’s evid h. CCC (2009) – suggests that mkt def may not be req’d to prove unilateral effects VERTICAL MERGERS I. II. III. Primarily an exclusionary conduct issue – forecloses competition from mnfct/retail mkt Early Foundation Cases – opposed merger even when only small foreclosure (2%) a. Autolite (1972) – SCT refused to consider enefits of merger b. Brown Shoe (1962) i. Every vert merger forecloses, but Clayton only forbids those whose effect may be to subst lessen competition 1. Thus size of the mkt foreclosed is important 2. But if neither to de minimis or monop, mkt share cannot be determ 3. Examine various econ and hist factors, incl. nature and purpose 4. Type of restraint matters – exclusive dealing for lmt’d term less harmful than tying b/c “at behest of customer” ii. Here, no merger btwn mnfctr and retailer could involve larger potential foreclosure (would be about 1-2%) iii. Remaining competitive vigor cannot immunize merger where industry trend is towards oligopoly. Vertical Analysis Since 1980 a. Would transaction harm horiz competition in either upstream or downstream mkt b. Theories by which competition may be harmed i. Raising “two-level entry barriers” – Modern Theory 1. Incentive to foreclose? 2. Ability to forecolose? 3. Countermeasures? ii. Could facilitate horiz collusion iii. Evading rate regulation 14 A/T SHORT OUTLINE MONOPOLY – SINGLE FIRM EXCLUSIONARY CONDUCT I. II. III. IV. V. VI. VII. VIII. IX. X. S.2 has 3 offenses – monopolization, attempt, conspiracy Diff btwnn bringing case under Sherman Act (“dangerous prob of actual monop”) and Robinson-Patman (“reasonable probability”) Monopoly Leveraging – use monop power in 1 mkt to gain advantage in 2d adjacent mkt Monopolization Elements a. Possession of monopoly power in relevant mkt (70%) – 90% stronger threshold b. Willful acquisition or maintenance of power (“excessive pricing” not enough) Attempted Monopolization Elements a. Substantial Market Power (~50%) b. Specific Intent (inferred from conduct) – Spectrum Sports c. Dangerous Probability of Success (mkt structure – eg: high barriers) Traditional Approach – measure foreclosure and compare to threshold (quantitative) Modern Approach – Raising Rivals Costs (qualitative analysis) a. Raises MC or makes it more difficult for competitor to sell product b. Incl. practices beyond complete foreclosure, excluded firm need not be incumbent c. Mere foreclosure not enough – need to show remaining firms could and would take advantage – need to inc prices and dec. output b/c exclusion may not work i. Alternate ways for firm to attain supply/distrib ii. Other firms may not go along with it – cheating iii. Exclusion may be unprofitable. d. Need to also show foreclosure not outweighed by pro-competitive benefits. Modern Analysis a. Has firm been excluded i. Common focus on whether excluded firm has practical alternatives ii. Is there incentive to foreclose? – action iii. Countermeasures rival can take? b. Can firm obtain/keep mkt power? – ability to foreclose and make it profitable c. Any legit business justifications? Lorain Journal (1951) – raising rivals costs a. Surrounding circum of restraint are important – most subst is the monop on newspapers that made it indispensible for advertising. i. If papers colluded, not illegal – no reason should be diff here b. Framework Applied i. Limited radio station access to key inputs – excluded firm ii. Elim of radio station would leave journal w/ monopoly iii. Desire to maintain mkt power is not a legitimate justification. c. Advertising restriction an improper use of monopoly power Origins of Power + Conduct Framework a. US v. US Steel Corp (1920) – suggests permissive view of dom. firm behavior b. US Machine Corp (1953) – establishes thresholds for Power Prong i. Law does not allow entity to maintain mkt control through non-econ justifiable/inevitable practices ii. Judge Hand’s Benchmarks: 1. >90% YES (Standard Oil) 2. 60-64% - MAYBE 15 A/T SHORT OUTLINE XI. XII. 3. 33% - PROB NOT (US Steel – by time of trial, shrunk from 85-90% to 40%) c. US v. Aluminum Co of America (2d Cir 1945 – sitting as SCT) i. Alcoa possessed mkt power 1. Internal Consumption Included – most ingot used to produce product, so any ingot used to produce own product is not put into mkt – could and would switch easilty if price changed 2. Secondary Ingot is considered in making production decisions, so in a way producer controls – exclude from mkt 3. Within limites of tarrit and import costs, Alcoa free to raise price so imports not included ii. Power alone not suffice – need to have acted to monopolize (reject No Fault) 1. Alcoa not a passive recipient of monopoly 2. Not inev would always anticipate inc. in demand & be prep’d to supply iii. Remedy – by time of remedy, already have structural shift – gov’t built plants create 2 new rivals (Kaiser and Reynolds) – structural relief rejected d. Effects of Alcoa i. Broad definition of exclusionary behavior ii. Such broad definition not used today. MODERN THEORY a. Increased concern w/ efficiency b. Improper conduct requirement bolstered substantially c. Analysis is a malleable standard that can expand/shrink: i. Presence of mkt power ii. Improper conduct to retain mkt power – broad discretion for product development, pricing, and distribution decisions iii. Appropriate remedy d. United Shoe Machinery (D.Mass 1953) – efficiency rationale good: quality control, service product improvement feedback e. US v. EI DuPont de Nemours & Co (1956) i. Most cited def: “monop power is the power to control prices or exclude competition” ii. Other wrapping materials pose sufficient competition to find “flexible packing materials” as the relevant mkt iii. Focus on interchangeability of demand – what is an acceptable sub 1. Depends on cross-elasticity of demand – largely gauged by similar uses – considering price, characteristics, adaptability iv. Cellophane Fallacy – may have already been charging monop pricing ATTEMPTED MONOPOLIZATION a. Swift Co v. US (1905) – if there is specific intent and dangerous prob, if unchecked such conduct will ripen into monopoly b. Can adjust inference drawn from mkt share depending on height of entry barriers c. Monopoly Broth Theory (Continental Ore) – look at whole pic and indiv acts together may be enough when indiv acts wouldn’t on their own – “critical mass” d. Spectrum Sports v. McQuillan (1993) i. Dangerous Probability hinges on Proximity and Degree – intent cannot establish “dangerous probability:” 16 A/T SHORT OUTLINE XIII. Durable Goods Monopoly and Market Definition Issues – aircraft hypo a. Used/Recycled Products – are they considered close subs in the mkt? i. Secondary producer can constrain prices, but is anticipated at initial prod ii. Aircrafts have long usefule lives (~30yr) b. Can Monopolist commit to high future prices – need to price discrim by time (need to ensure consumers won’t shift buying patterns i. Considerable inventory of used aircrafts c. Excess Capacity as Barrier to Entry – “strategic entry deterrence” – great risk but great reward. i. Importance of having 2 (or more) rivals. XIV. PREDATORY PRICING a. Early Cases: 1950s and ‘60s – could use deep pockets to finance below cost sales b. Utah Pie v. Continental Baking (1967) – condemned behavior; charging well below what it did other geographic areas. i. UP showed enough to sustain jury verdict – charged less than direct cost plus overhead allocation; created declining price structure; did so w/ a/c intent c. Schools of Thought i. Cost-Based School – based on AVC ii. Recoupment – only if mkt structure would permit supracompetitive prices to recoup, then consider rel. btwn cost and price. iii. Per Se Lawful iv. Game Theory School – full, fact-specific analysis d. From mid-70s to early-90s, courts generally accepted that price-cost tests apply e. Brooke Group v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp (1993) – Reformulated Theory i. Insuffic evid to prove B&Ws volume rebates furthered pred pricing scheme ii. Establishes a 2-step test (mkt power issue considered in prong2): 1. Below appropriate level of pricing a. Above cost but below industry norm is not sufficient b. SCT didn’t specify what cost to use, most courts use AVC 2. Recoupment (which incl. mkt power analysis) a. Must be able of producing intended effect on rival (raise price or exit mkt) – req’s understanding extent/duration of conduct, rival’s financial strength, and firm’s incentives b. Must obtain high enough mkt share to set high price for long enough (req’s an output restriction – here, output inc, so price inc. could be due to increase in demand) c. Harder to prove w/ conscious parallelism (esp. in mkt w/ changing conditions) iii. Could prove restraint in sense output didn’t inc. as quickly as it should have f. Weyerhaeuser v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber (2007) – predatory bidding i. Must prove that bidding led to below cost pricing of output and that recoupment was likely – Brooke Group prongs XV. NON-PRICE EXCLUSIONARY CONDUCT a. Aspen-Kodak Rule for Non-Price Dominant Firm Conduct i. Substantial market power ii. Conduct that injures consumers/rivals (esp. if change in past practice) 17 A/T SHORT OUTLINE iii. Burden shifts to D for justifications. b. Refusal to deal often arises in 3 patterns i. Dom firm threaten to cease cooperation if firm estab a rel w/ competitor (LJ) ii. Challenge to dom firm’s attempt to w/draw from existing rel. (Aspen Skiing) iii. Essential Facilities (Trinko) 1. Control of EF by Monopolist 2. Inability of competitor to reasonably duplicate EF 3. Denial of use of EF to competitor 4. Feasibility of providing access to EF c. Refusal to Deal – Verizon Communications v. Trinko (2004) –no general duty to deal i. Firms should not be forced to cooperate b/c it could lead to collusion ii. Doesn’t mean right not to cooperate is unlimited iii. Unilateral termination of agreement that is a willingness to forsake profit for anticompetitive goal (Aspen) is the extreme iv. A general refusal to deal does not fit into that framework v. Essential Facilities Doctrine does not apply – not recognized and where access to exist serves no purpose. d. PacBell v. Linkline – absent duty to deal and absent satisfying BG prongs, price squeeze is not cognizable. e. Aspen Skiing v. Aspen Highlands i. Dominant firm has no duty to cooperate w. smaller rivals so long as there exists a legit business justification for refusal (improper conduct) ii. Right to refusal to deal not unqualified – need to consider effects on: 1. Rival – tried to protect self but couldn’t compete 2. Own firm – was willing to forego ticket sales to hurt competitor 3. Consumers – preferred all mountains pass iii. Usually seent at or near bounds of S.2 and confined to facts – 7th Cir: “where cooperation is indispensible to effective competition” f. Kodak – Aftermarkets i. Profitability depends on lost sales in both mkts – will lose sales if ppl consider lifetime costs ii. Improper conduct – change in business practice iii. Justifications – quality control: good argument, but no supporting evidence iv. Seems to foreshadow use of post-Chicago School – efficiency, broader use of anticompetitive conduct, facts more important than efficiency. g. US v. Microsoft (DC Cir 2001) i. Analytical Framework 1. P has to show – monopoly power and theory of a/c harm (less reliance on trad. categories) 2. D’s rebuttal/justifications 3. Balancing ii. Direct proof of mkt power rarely avail – more typically rely on mkt structure (95% - 80% if Mac included) iii. Mkt Definition 1. No competing products now or in the likely future 2. Non-Intel O/S (Mac) – won’t switch b/c of costs and less apps 3. Non-PC based (handhelds) – don’t perform same functions 4. Middleware – not enough interconnection t foreseeably replace O/S 18 A/T SHORT OUTLINE 5. Signif barriers mean that mkt share is an approp stat – consumers prefer O/S with lots of apps, and developers prefer O/S with existing customer base iv. Dominance is being unlawfully maintained – thwarted distrib of rival browser by incorporating it into hardware preventing mod/removal v. Justification of valid copyright fails b/c changes to browser would not alter stability or consistency of program – not a tech necessity here. vi. Outcome of Case 1. No liability for alleged invitation to collude 2. Liability for exclusive dealing with OEMs/ISPs and for creation of incompatibility 3. Note – no balancing takes place 4. Remanded on Tying and for the Remedy h. Bundling i. LePage’s Inc v. 3M (3d Cir 2003) – no Brooke Group analysis 1. Mere fact pricing is core of issue doesn’t make it a predatory pricing claim ii. Cascade Health Solutions v. PeaceHealth (9th Cir 2008) 1. Bundling can provide benefits for both a. Buyers – get more for less, better match consumer pref b. Sellers – lower production costs 2. Thus, needs a case-by-case evaluation of bundle for legality. 3. Bundling considered a/c when below “an approp measure of D’s costs” a. Low prices benefit consumers so long as above predatory levels (BG) b. Given widespread use of bundling, above cost pricing is a necessary prong. 4. Measured by “discount attribution standard” (need to prove) a. Full amount of discount allocated to competitive product b. If resulting price below incremental cost, may not be found exclusionary c. Legal unless has potential to exclude hypothetically equally efficient producer. 5. Incremental Cost measured by MC or AVC iii. Loyalty Programs 1. 2 methods – bonus paid per sale OR bonus paid when pass threshold 2. British Airways a. A/C Conduct – rebate system diverted sales away from competing airlines by inducing agents to commit all or most efforts to BA tix b. Requisite harm can take the form of either injury to consumers or injury to competitors and the competitive process c. Can infer consumer injury from injury to competitive process d. ECJ on Proof – can be actual or likely harm; provided adequate factual basis to satisfy both; rivals cannot replicate bonus system 19 A/T SHORT OUTLINE e. BA lacked cognizable justifications i. Incentive to achieve occupancy to make profits ii. Agents not “forced” to go along with plan 1. No need for agreement to specify exclusivity 2. Can infer exclusivity from agreement structure iii. No proof of adverse effects on consumers/competitors 1. Injury inferred from damage to competitive process f. In the US (2d Cir) – BA hs right to expand sales, other airlines cont. to grow, o evidence of consumer harm i. Cannot prove abuse of dominance or recoupment REFUSAL TO LICENSE IP RIGHTS I. II. Up to 1970s – suspicion of IPR – seen as creating a monopoly Modern Approach – policy complements (preserve incentive to innovate) a. Mkt power depends on avail of subs, not on holding a patent b. Image Tech Services v. Eastman Kodak (9th Cir 1997) i. Assertion of IPR presumptively legit justification for refusal to deal ii. However, here it is only a pretext 1. Refusal involved thousands of unpatented parts 2. Subjective intent – justification came about afterwards c. CSU v. Xerox (Fed. Cir. 2000) – push back against 9th Cir i. Only examine subjective intent of firm if IPR obtained by unlawful means or refusal used to gain monopoly power beyond patent’s scope d. IPR in EU – only deemed abuse of dominance under exceptional circum, defined by: i. Properly characterized as refusal to deal ii. Refusing party is dominant iii. Input is indispensible to particular activity iv. Refusal likely to have negative effect on competition v. Refusal not objectively justified vi. Must use license to innovate e. FTC v. Actavis (2013) i. FTC Alleges 1. Agreeing to share in monopoly profits (conspiracy to monopolize?) 2. Agree to abandon patent challenge 3. Refrain from launching low-cost generic competition (no req. to compete but cannot collude not to compete). ii. 11th Cir dismissed complaint under “scope of the patent” test iii. 5 considerations why FTC suit should be allowed to continue 1. Specific restraint has potential for genuine a/c effects – inflated prices 2. A/c effects may sometimes prove unjustified – but such defenses are best put forth at trial, rather than dismissed per se 3. Where reverse payment threatens unjustified harm, likely has mkt power 4. More feasible than 11th Cir believes – size of unexplained reverse payment can provide workable surrogate for patent’s weakness 20 A/T SHORT OUTLINE 5. Fact large payment risks A/T liability doesn’t prevent settlement – may settle in other ways like other industries do. iv. These consid trump the one contrary consid of a policy promoting settlement v. Should thus analyze under RoR b/c effect is not entirely obvious to justify a per se or quick look approach 1. Likelihood of a/c effects depends on nominal mount, amount in relation to antic future litigation, independence from other services 2. Up to lower courts to structure the analysis vi. Dissent – correct test is scope of the patent 1. A/T case will come down to having to litigate validity of the patent anyway 2. Large settlement not a good proxy for validity b/c may result in riskadverse party 3. Patent law is about long-term innovation - rule of reason analysis is not designed for such judgments EXCLUSIONARY GROUP BOYCOTTS I. II. Early cases a. Eastern State Retail Lumber Dealer’s Ass’n (1914) i. Generally have right to deal with who you want, BUT ii. When begin conspiring to obstruct free course of commerce and suppress competition, firms exceed that lawful right b. Fashion Originator’s Guild of America v. FTC (1941) i. Condemned regardless of direct relation to price fixing (dec. output) c. Klor’s v. Broadway Hale Stores (1959) i. “Long held in the forbidden category” ii. Justification: numerous retailers remain – NOT adequate (should have offered free-riding rationale) d. Cased do not provide a coherent framework for differentiating collusive boycotts that are plainly a/c form those with some legit justification Contemporary Analysis a. Northwest Wholesale Stationers Inc. v. Pacific Stationary Printing (1985) i. Older Case Law – per se rule applies only with a showing of mkt power or control over essential element ii. Per se rule applies only when practice facially appears to be one that would always tend to restrict competition – depends on familiarity w/ restraint. 1. Coop arrangements seem generally designed to increase efficiency a. Economies of scale for purchasing and warehousing b. Assured supply 2. Exclusion from coop does not always show an a/c animus iii. Exclusionary boycott illegal only if 1. D “possess mkt power or unique access to a business element necessary for effective coop” 2. Absence of valid justifications b. Toys R Us v. FTC (7th Cir 2000) i. Exclusive sales made it more difficult for consumers to coparison shop and insulated TRU from price competition – hub and spoke theory 21 A/T SHORT OUTLINE c. JTC Petroleum v. Piasa Motor Fuels (7th Cir 1999) – exclusionary group boycott i. 2 level cartel – producers and applicators –A gets P to enforce and exclude ii. Justification a pretext b/c were paying in cash d. US v. Visa USA Inc (2d Cir 2003) i. Exclusion by JV of other network competitors from members is illegal ii. New Framework 1. Conspirators have mkt power 2. Conduct has substantial adverse effect on competition 3. Burden to D to provide justifications 4. P must show restraint not reasonable necessary OR may be a less restrictive alternative iii. Relevant Mkt and Mkt Power 1. Network services – other forms of paymnt not considered reliable sub 2. Visa & MC jointly and separately have mkt power iv. Anticompetitive Harms 1. Exclusionary rule leaves there to be only 2 competitors – denies access to ~70% of banks, shrinking # of avail cards 2. Stunts product development v. Justifications – promotion of cohesion, but undercut by actual practice 1. No harm overseas where no exclusionary program 2. Already diluted b/c V can use MC, and vice-versa 3. Citibank offers Visa and Diners vi. Case had no mention of group boycotts or per se rule. TYING I. II. Early cases – per se illegality a. IBM – justifications not rejected outright, but rejected b/c unsupported b. Int’l Salt – explicitly estab per se treatment i. May impose reasonable restrictions designed in good faith to minimize burdens and assure satisfactory operation ii. BUT, restrictions here broader than necessary c. Lower courts did recognize some exceptions – US v. Jerrold Electronics (EDPa 1960) – new products Modern Theory Economics a. Anticompetitive Effects i. Equivalent of paying a higher price ii. Foregoing choice/consumer preference iii. Evading rate regulation b. Pro-competitive uses i. Quality control (aftermarket servicing, new products) ii. Reduce production/distribution costs iii. Prevent excessive markups of complementary goods iv. Consumer convenience/simplicity v. Undermines Cartels – discount on 2d product equates to cheating c. Ambiguous Competitive Effects – price discrimination (Xerox – metering) i. Positive – increase output ii. Negative – transfer consumer surplus 22 A/T SHORT OUTLINE d. Raising Rivals Costs Theory – force 2 stage entry; denies potential rivals needed experience to enter III. Modern Test for per se violation– Jefferson Parrsih a. 2 distinct products/services b. Conditional sale c. Seller must have “appreciable economic power” in tying product, such that Forcing is likely d. Arrangement must affect “subst volume of commerce in tied mkt” – proxy for adverse a/c effects IV. Jefferson Parish Hospital District No. 2 v. Hyde (1984) a. Not a per se violation b/c there is no forcing; also unreasonable under RoR b. Whether one or two products exists depends on the character of demand (not their functional relationship_ - is there suffic demand for purchase of anestehesiological services separate from other hospital services? – YES c. Essential char of invalid tying is exploitation of control over tying product, enabling forcing the purchase of tied product i. Pref for closest hospital doesn’t estab forcing – 70% residents go elsewhere ii. Lack of price/quality competition does not create forcing iii. Lack of price consciousness (3d party payors will not force consumers to take services they don’t want. V. US v. Microsoft Corp (DC Cir 2001) – software platform tying should be eval’d under RoR a. Not enough experience to classify these restraints as per se illegal b. Separate Products Inquiry i. Answer turns on whether there is suffic demand for tied product separate from tying product – efficient to offer products separately? ii. Eval based on direct evidence (what do consumers do when faced w/ a choice) and indirect (how do firms w/o mkt power behave) iii. If competitive firms always bundle, then single product – if there were no efficiencies then firms wouldn’t do it iv. All major O/S producers bundle browsers – also sell non-tied versions c. If a per se analysis were used, first to merge 2 prev distinct functions or elim the need for the second risks being condemned PRODUCT DESIGN AND DEVELOPMENT I. II. III. Liability for deliberate efforts to alter design/interface when there is no valid tech justification Berkey Photo v. Eastman Kodak (2d Cir 1979) – generally firms have broad freedom to design and intro products as they wish IBM – rejected case where design choice made to improve quality of machines, even though one aim was to frustrate culpability (design was okay) a. No duty to reveal new interface designs. 23 A/T SHORT OUTLINE REMEDIES I. II. III. Conduct remedies freq. imposes, but not favored b/c don’t do anything to unravel dominant firm behavior a. United Shoe Machine Corp (1954) i. Failed to implement divestiture ii. SCT treats mkt share as sole index of remedial effectiveness iii. Ignores entry, profitability, innovation Divestiture orders most common a. Esp in mergers and monopoly where power attained through merger b. Drastic when done outside these narrow circumstances – destroys efficiencies c. Difficult to administer – attract suffic buyer at reasonable price US v. Microsoft Corp (DC Cir 2001) a. When deciding remedy, must hold evidentiary hearing for disputed facts and provide adequate reason for remedy b. Prediction about future events is not a prediction any less than nay other prediction about a factual dispute c. Generally only use divestiture where heart of violation is inter-corp combo/control d. Mere exclusionary act does not itself justify full feasible relief. 24