Bridget Reidy, Dan Sherman, Travis Beal Economics 272 Professor Cottrell November 18, 2010 Greenspan’s Fed and the Financial Crisis As Chairman of the Federal Reserve and overlord of the Great Moderation, Alan Greenspan was hailed as “the greatest central banker who ever lived” (AP 2008). The entire economy, and everyone directly involved with it, seemed to hang on his every word. I once heard that several companies even hired consultants whose job it was to analyze his appearance, right down to the color, length, and style of his tie, in order to determine his mood and predict the actions the Fed might take. In short, he was the maestro (Krugman 13) and nobody could undermine his power. Then came the 2008 subprime crisis, and Greenspan’s reputation went down almost as fast as the Dow Jones in September. Now, a man once virtually above criticism has had to go on the defensive. He has faced scrutiny by everyone from Henry Waxman, chairman of the House Committee on Oversight and Government Reform, to Tim Iacono, editor of the blog entitled “The Mess That Greenspan Made.” While Greenspan now has many detractors, there are still some who believe in him and the decisions he made as Fed chair. Current Chairman of the Fed Ben Bernanke is perhaps Greenspan’s most powerful ally; and while many would argue Bernanke could not realistically attack Greenspan’s policies, an investigation of his recent speech (Bernanke 2010) leads us to conclude that Bernanke genuinely supports his predecessor. Yet, the question remains, as Waxman bluntly asked on Capitol Hill, was Greenspan wrong (Cassidy 5)? Like many others, Greenspan undoubtedly played a role in the financial crisis of 2008. However, through a comparison of aspects of the crisis that were a direct result of Greenspan’s ideology and those that he has been unfairly blamed for, it is clear that in many ways he has become a scapegoat. While all recessions are multi-faceted in nature, this crisis in particular is more complex than any the country has faced. This is mostly due to the intricate relationships among the financial institutions that played a central role. When the crisis began, politicians, along with the public, immediately looked to identify someone who could be held accountable; and that person was Alan Greenspan. When Alan Greenspan entered into his position as Federal Reserve chairman in 1987, President Reagan looked for Greenspan to provide such monetary policy actions that would undo the high Federal Funds rate put in place by Greenspan’s predecessor, Paul Volcker. Up until this point, the economy had experienced extreme volatility. It was the conservative ideal that a lower Federal Funds rate would promote private sector spending, thus increasing economic stability. The Greenspan Fed looked forward to make their decisions, making predictions of the economy. Their main focus was on core inflation and how to counteract it, and they had a goal to smooth interest rates. Originally, it was believed that the Greenspan Federal Reserve followed the Taylor rule. The Taylor rule compares the Federal Funds rate target against two economic variables: lagged inflation and the output gap. Then the actual Federal Funds rate is adjusted to the target in each period (Taylor 1993). This adjustment to the target rate during each implies that the Taylor rule is “non-inertial,” or the Federal Reserve does not work to smooth interest rates. Inflation, as quantified in the Taylor rule, is measured by the behavior of the GDP deflator and the output gap and is the deviation of the log of real output from a linear trend. Taylor (1993) shows that from 1987 to 1992, policy actions did not differ significantly from the prescriptions of this simple rule. Hence, according to the Taylor rule, the Federal Reserve, at least during the early part of the Greenspan era, was backward looking, focused on headline inflation, and followed a non-inertial policy rule. Figure 1 However, recent research argues that the Greenspan Fed modified its thinking to become more forward looking in its inflation counterbalance, thus deviating slightly from the Taylor rule. Greenspan’s policy actions after straying away from the basic Taylor rule are better explained by an “inertial” Taylor rule reflecting the presence of interest rate smoothing. The Greenspan Fed focused on a “core” measure of inflation in adjusting its federal funds rate target. The “inertial” Taylor rule relates the current funds rate target to “expected” inflation and output developments (Economic Quarterly). In choosing a federal funds target rate, Greenspan’s thinking in his early days as Fed chairman acknowledged the significance of having a rate that was just right. In a WSJ article, he stated that it was his opinion that the Federal Funds rate needs to be low to increase the money flow in the private sector (WSJ.com, Financial Crisis). Figure 2 Taylor may have been right about the Federal Funds rate in 2000. Following the dotcom bubble, the Fed reduced the federal funds rate to spur investment and consumption. In 2003, the federal funds rate was a mere 1%, far less what it had been 2 years previously (Figure 1). Figure 3 While reducing the federal funds rate is a typical response to a recession or decreased consumption, reducing the rate by such a large amount is unusual. Lowering the interest rate to1% and keeping it there for so long can be considered “deviation from a policy rule, such as the Taylor rule, and in that sense it is a deviation from a more rules-based policy” (Taylor 2). Not for decades had the interest rate been so low, and this negatively affected the housing market. Such a low federal funds rate made borrowing easier, and encouraged the housing boom. With lower rates, the banks could more cheaply borrow money from each other which allowed them to make more loans. The increase in consumer loans seemed to increase around the same time that the federal funds rate dropped (Figures 2 and 3). Figure 4 Figure 5 This easy monetary policy encouraged and helped to stimulate the housing bubble which was the stimulus for the recent financial crisis. Federal funds rates do have an impact on such consumer behavior. According to an article in the Wall Street Journal, “Researchers at the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development have provided corroborating evidence from other countries: The greater the degree of monetary excess in a country, the larger was the housing boom” (Taylor 1). In this sense, the Fed did aid in the housing boom and bust. As can be expected, Alan Greenspan and Ben Bernanke defend their actions. Bernanke states that the Taylor Rule, which is a guideline for the federal funds rate based on output and inflation, is subject to limitations. The main limitation is its “implication that monetary policy should depend on currently observed values of inflation and output” (Bernanke 2). Bernanke believes that it is necessary to take into account future expectations when making policy decisions. While this is true and seems reasonable, there is one issue with how the “future” is defined. The future is completely unpredictable. To take into account future inflation values requires that these values be predicted using past values. As we have seen recently, the past is not necessarily a good indicator of the future. Once again, we are falling victim to what John Cassidy calls “utopian economics.” Had the Federal Reserve followed the Taylor Rule more closely, perhaps things would have been different. However, Greenspan’s actions were clearly affected by the financial environment at the time. An interest rate so low in “normal” times (not during a housing bubble) may not have had such an effect. Greenspan’s actions on their own are not what caused the problem. It was the combination of his choices and the freedom of the financial markets at the time. It is easy to say in retrospect, but it is clear that Greenspan’s major flaw was a classic case of disaster myopia, inspired by his faith in the advancement of the financial industry. This can be seen in the now infamous “‘Greenspan Doctrine,’ which warmly welcomed the development of new financial products, such as securitized loans and credit default swaps” (Cassidy 22). While these terms are now synonymous with chaos, at the time they represented innovation and lead to increased prosperity. The problem with disaster myopia is that it is extremely difficult to recognize at the time of occurrence. Since the Great Moderation was in full force for most of Greenspan’s tenure, it made no logical sense to question his philosophy. To be fair, this does not completely absolve the Fed of their responsibility, since they are often thought of as extremely rational and impartial. Nonetheless, “As long as the music is playing, you’ve got to get up and dance” (Cassidy 296) and the Fed was definitely dancing. Deregulation also played a part in the crisis, and from early on in his intellectual career Greenspan was a staunch opponent of regulation. Going back to the 1950’s, Greenspan was involved with Ayn Rand’s “Collective,” and one can see that his “libertarian, antigovernment instincts stayed with him throughout his long career” (Cassidy 229). He believed that because of their motivation for profit, companies would effectively manage risk without the intervention of the government. This may be so to some extent, but as we now know many of the risk management tools that became widely used were founded on either inaccurate assumptions or were not utilized in the correct way. Once again, while Greenspan cannot be held personally responsible for the mistakes made by others, he was an advocate of the principles that led to deregulation. These faults are minor when compared to the amount of blame that has been hurled at Greenspan since 2008. In Time Magazine’s list of the “Top 10 Collapses of 2008,” Greenspan’s reputation was number nine, and the only entry on the list that referred to an individual (Iacono 2008). At the time the public did not think highly of the newly retired Fed chair, but much of the criticism he faced, and continues to face, are vast generalizations that have little validity. In an article titled “Alan Greenspan, Meet Reality (Part II),” Michael Hurd condemns Greenspan for not being an advocate of the free market since his early years with Ayn Rand (Hurd 2009). As previously discussed, Greenspan was without a doubt an advocate of the free market while at the Fed, and others have found great fault with him because of it. Hurd also fails to realize that in many ways Greenspan has been forced to change, or at least adjust, his opinions on free market ideals to defend the little respect he has left. Attempting to point out inconsistencies with Greenspan’s ideology that do not exist seems to be a popular way of attacking him. In a piece that classifies Greenspan as a “Party Boy,” Fred Sheehan tries to make the point that Greenspan should no longer appear on television because he is always wrong, and cites that he once said, “I don’t think [home prices will] decline from here. In other words, they seem to be bottoming out” and “The recession is over” (Sheehan 2010) on the same day in February 2010 as proof that Greenspan is somehow crazy. Perhaps Sheehan believes that if we are not in a recession we should be having double-digit growth in GDP, or some other strange definition but realistically house prices bottoming out was a good sign that the end of the recession was near. Greenspan’s argument is further supported by that fact that in September of 2010, seven months after Greenspan’s comments, the Center for Business and Economic Research announced that the recession officially ended in mid-2009 (NBER 2010), just about a year before his comments. Sheehan was wrong in his accusations of Greenspan, and Greenspan was in fact correct in making these statements. In a blatantly standoffish manner, Greenspan was called to testify before the Committee of Government Oversight and Reform on October 23, 2008 to justify the actions he took as Chairman of the Fed. He was essentially cornered into admitting that he was wrong, becoming the scapegoat for the recession. Analysis of his testimony allows reveals that Greenspan truly did not see the crisis coming. He said, “those of us who have looked to the self-interest of lending institutions to protect shareholder’s equity (myself especially) are in a state of shocked disbelief” (Greenspan 2). Next, he went on to claim, rightfully so, that what precipitated the crisis was risk management models that relied only on data from the past two decades (Greenspan 3). While he may have promoted the legalization of such models, he was not the person designing them, nor the person incorrectly using them and their predictions. Therefore, he should have no sense of obligation in regards to their place in causing the crisis. Interest rates played an important role in the subprime mortgage aspect of the recession, and because everyone knows of the connection between interest rates and the Fed, fingers were quickly pointed at Greenspan. The flaw here is that while the Fed controls the federal funds rate, they cannot fix the rates offered to consumers, or more specifically homeowners. The rate of long-term mortgages is obviously extremely relevant to the 2008 subprime crisis, but because he was removed from that portion of interest rate determination, Greenspan could not have drastically changed the situation. In his personal rebuttal of this issue, he stated, “No one, to my knowledge, employs overnight interest rates such as the fed-funds rate to determine the capitalization rate of real estate” (Greenspan WSJ). Yet again it becomes clear how unfair it is to claim that the actions of the Fed and Greenspan caused the crisis. While Chairman of the Federal Reserve, Alan Greenspan was praised as an economic genius and congratulated for instituting policies that helped ensure an extended period of economic growth for the United States. His fall from grace has not been pleasant, and in the eyes of many he quickly went from being an icon to a villain. With the length and scope of the 2008 subprime crisis, there is plenty of blame to be placed. Politicians, businessmen/women, and economists are all at fault on some level. Greenspan is no different, and he can be faulted for his disaster myopia. However, as we have seen, much of the criticism he has faced is unfounded and nonsensical. He may not be the prophet-like ruler of the US economy we once thought he was, but he is still a great economist and should be respected as such. Works Cited "FRED Graph." St. Louis Fed. N.p., n.d. Web. 17 Nov. 2010. <research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/graph/?chart_type=line&s[1][id]=FEDFUNDS&s[ 1][range]=5yrs>. "Federal Reserve." FRED Data. N.p., n.d. Web. 17 Nov. 2010. <www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/data/Monthly/H15_FF_O.txt>. "Inflation vs. FFR Graph." ICMARC. N.p., n.d. Web. 17 Nov. 2010. <www.icmarc.org/ImageCache/rc/content/marketview/chart/2005/20051104infla tioninterestrates_2ectt/v2/image_5b_40id_3d_22chart_22_5d/1/20051104inflatio ninterestra.gif>. Mehra, Yash, and Brian Minton. "A Taylor Rule and the Greenspan Era." Economic Quarterly 93.3 (2007): 229–250. Print. "Taylor Rule FFR." Federal Reserve.Gov. N.p., n.d. Web. 17 Nov. 2010. <www.federalreserve.gov/PUBS/FEDS/2009/200949/figure_2.gif>. Taylor, John B.. "Government Intervention, Not the Lehman Collapse, Caused the Financial Crisis - WSJ.com." Business News & Financial News - The Wall Street Journal - WSJ.com. N.p., n.d. Web. 17 Nov. 2010. <http://online.wsj.com/article/SB123414310280561945.html>. Taylor, John B. "Macroeconomic Lessons from the Great Deviation." Speech. 25th NBER Macro Annual Meeting. Taylor, John B. "How Government Created Financial Crisis." Wall Street Journal [New 2010. York] 9 Feb. 2009. Wall Street Journal. Web. 8 Nov. <http://online.wsj.com/article/SB123414310280561945.html> Associated Press. “As Greenspan’s Reputation Sinks, Volcker’s Rises.” MSNBC.com. MSNBC. 13 April 2008. Web. Krugman, Paul. “How Did Economists Get It So Wrong?” The New York Times Magazine. 2 Sept 2009: 1-22. PDF. Cassidy, John. How Markets Fail: the Logic of Economic Calamities. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux, 2009. Iacono, Timothy. “Alan Greenspan’s Collapsing Reputation.” The Mess That Greenspan Made. 15 Dec 2008. Web. Hurd, Michael. “Alan Greenspan, Meet Reality (Part II).” Capitalism Magazine. 27 Feb 2009. Web. Sheehan, Fred. “Alan Greenspan, Party Boy.” LewRockwell.com. 12 Feb 2010. Web. The National Bureau of Economic Research. Business Cycle Dating Committee, National Bureau of Economic Research. 20 Sept 2010. NBER.org. Web. Testimony of Dr. Alan Greenspan. Committee of Government Oversight and Reform. 23 Oct 2008: 1-5. PDF. Greenspan, Alan. “The Fed Didn’t Cause the Housing Bubble.” The Wall Street Journal Online. 11 March 2009: 1-4. PDF.