Results - Department of Agricultural Economics

advertisement
Game Theory Application to Fed Cattle Procurement in an Experimental Market
Jared G. Carlberg, Robert J. Hogan, Jr., and Clement E. Ward
Revision submitted to
Agribusiness: An International Journal
February 2007
The authors are Assistant Professor, University of Manitoba, Assistant Professor and
Extension Economist, University of Arkansas, and Professor and Extension Economist,
Oklahoma State University, respectively. The authors acknowledge Wayne Purcell,
former Director of the Research Institute on Livestock Pricing at Virginia Tech
University, for financial support of this research.
1
Game Theory Application to Fed Cattle Procurement in an Experimental Market
Abstract
Consolidation in meatpacking has elicited many market power concerns and studies. A
game theory model was developed and an empirical model estimated to measure beef
packing firm behavior. Experimental market data from three semester-long classes using
the Fed Cattle Market Simulator were used. Collusive behavior was found for all three
data periods though the extent of collusion varied by data periods, due in part to market
conditions imposed by the experimenters. Findings underscore the need for applying
game theory to real-world transaction-level, fed cattle market data.
Key Words
Collusion, Meatpacking, Fed Cattle, Game theory, Industry conduct, Prices
2
Game Theory Application to Fed Cattle Procurement in an Experimental Market
Comprehensive literature reviews identify many studies related to noncompetitive behavior of meatpacking firms (Azzam and Anderson; Ward 2002; Whitley).
The high four-firm concentration ratio in steer and heifer procurement, i.e., approaching
or exceeding 80% since 1990 (Grain Inspection, Packers and Stockyards Administration)
is a primary structural characteristic in meatpacking leading to charges of noncompetitive behavior. A similarly high concentration ratio exists for wholesale beef sales
as well.
Previous studies differ significantly in data aggregation, data period length, and
methodology chosen (see summary table in Ward 2002). Several studies attempted to
link industry structure with performance, following the traditional structure-conductperformance (SCP) paradigm attributed to Bain. Much of the SCP empirical work was
based on the price-concentration hypothesis; namely, that output (input) prices increase
(decrease) with increasing seller (buyer) concentration. Critics of the SCP approach cite
its failure to have a solid theoretical foundation. Empirical applications have been
questioned regarding the measurement of key variables, causality direction between
prices or profitability and concentration, and model specification (Azzam and Anderson).
The preferred approach in recent literature is NEIO (new empirical industrial
organization) which links firm behavior more directly with firm or industry performance.
Most NEIO research involves estimating a conjectural variation (CV), thereby tying a
specific type of firm conduct or behavior to performance. Since Schroeter’s first
application of this approach to the meatpacking industry, several studies have relied on
similar methodology. However, NEIO is not without criticism; such as its use of
aggregated data, potentially unrealistic assumptions about firm conduct, static nature of
the analysis, and functional form in estimations (Azzam and Anderson; Hunnicutt and
Weninger; Sexton).
An extension of the NEIO approach with application to beefpacking procurement
includes concepts from game theory (Koontz, Garcia, and Hudson; Koontz and Garcia).
Use of game theory allows the repeated strategic interaction of packers to be modeled
more fully and provides a theoretical basis for observed behavior. The objective of this
paper is to develop and estimate a game-theoretic model of industry conduct and
supergame strategies in a dynamic oligopsony using experimental market data gathered
under varying experimental conditions. Specifically, the effects of imposing a marketing
agreement onto the market and limiting public information to market participants are
compared to a base market period.
This research extends previous game theory applications to fed cattle
procurement. Because experimental market data are more detailed than available
industry data for prior game theory applications, packer conduct was estimated with
known, key parameters rather than first estimating these unknown variables. Studying
the effects of varying market conditions on packers’ ability to collude provides further
insight about market behavior. Results presented here from an experimental market have
significance for further investigations of meatpacking firm behavior by regulatory
agencies and further research by economists. Implications include, most importantly, the
2
need to collect detailed, transaction-level data from the real-world fed cattle market for
game theory model estimation.
Theoretical Foundation
Friedman’s (1971) specification provides an appropriate basis for modeling
beefpacker behavior in a fed cattle procurement market.1 The single period, noncooperative ordinary procurement game consists of a fixed, finite set of beefpacking
firms which are restricted from making binding agreements. Each player (firm) is aware
of the strategy sets and payoff functions that apply to all participants but players are
unable to observe completely the strategic decisions made by others, i.e., thus complete
but imperfect information. For instance, each packer is unaware of exact prices paid or
quantities purchased by all rival packers for each trading period though each is aware of
the prevailing market price and quantity.
Quantity of fed cattle purchased is the strategic variable in the procurement game
and the strategy set for the overall game consists of all possible quantities procured for all
packers in a single period. The profit payoff to the ith player from processing fed cattle
into boxed beef is a function of its own strategy as well as those of other players.
Interdependence indicates the volume of cattle procured by each packer affects the
volume available to remaining packers, which in turn affects their payoff.
Nash equilibrium exists where each packer maximizes its payoff with respect to
its own choice of strategy, given the strategy choices of other players in the game.
Friedman (1971) noted that when the payoff functions are profit functions, the players are
firms, and the strategy choices are quantities, the game is a single period oligopoly and
3
the non-cooperative (Nash) equilibrium is the same as the Cournot quantity-setting
solution. Under the Cournot solution, firms take each rival’s output as given, and a
change in the quantity purchased by one firm does not affect quantities purchased by
other firms.
Packers in a single-period game choose a quantity to achieve static profit
maximization, but this strategy may not hold for a repeated game in which the same
ordinary game is played at each iteration (Friedman 1986). If players are able to tacitly
collude in a multi-period game, they may be able to achieve profits in excess of those
generated in a single-period game. The Nash equilibrium of a single-period game can
differ substantially from that which prevails in a repeated game because alternate
strategies can produce higher payoffs than in the single-period game.
A sequence of ordinary games with individual player strategy sets and payoff
functions, i.e., a supergame in extensive form, allows for the association of differing
strategies and payoffs across time. Players seek to maximize their payoffs over time for a
given discount parameter. Since all players’ past strategies form part of the information
set available to each player, the supergame strategy chosen by each player in the current
period is some mapping of the strategy vectors of players in previous periods. In the
beefpacking industry, past fed cattle purchase prices and volumes of rivals, to the extent
they are known for individual firms or the aggregate market, are taken into account when
setting quantity in the current procurement period. Further, Driscoll, Kamphampaty, and
Purcell concluded that static profit maximization was not necessarily packers’ goal.
Rather, they seek to maximize a discounted profit stream.
4
The concept of a trigger strategy equilibrium is central to the idea that packers can
tacitly collude to keep fed cattle prices from approaching those that would prevail in a
competitive market. Trigger strategy equilibria facilitate collaboration between players
that allow them to achieve cooperative (cartel) outcomes in games that have a noncooperative structure. A trigger strategy is a tacit agreement in each period to choose a
strategy vector that results in lower fed cattle prices than those occurring in an ordinary
game where each player chooses a Cournot strategy.
Any player can increase its single period payoff for any iteration within the
supergame by choosing a defection strategy. In beefpacking procurement, such a strategy
would see player pay slightly higher than the collusive price for fed cattle, thus increasing
its processing volume. If any player defects from the tacitly collusive strategy vector, it
triggers a reversionary (non-cooperative) episode in which the other players, who observe
that market prices have risen above some trigger level, must follow suit. As a result, all
players will choose the non-cooperative strategy for each remaining time period.
Because all players opt for a strategy resulting in the lowest price paid across each
ordinary constituent game of the supergame, there is no incentive for any player to defect,
as long as the chosen strategy exceeds the ordinary game strategy plus the discounted
payoff.
The fed cattle market exhibits patterns consistent with periodic reversionary
episodes. Based on the Green and Porter model, these episodes occur because cattle
supply fluctuations are not directly observed by firms, rather than due to defection by any
of the cartel members. Green and Porter assert that the punishment period does not
necessarily last for the remainder of the game after defection, but rather is T ordinary
5
game periods in length. They further suggest T may depend on the amount by which the
trigger price and market price differ in the first reversionary period.
If one or more players choose a defection strategy, the fed cattle market then
enters a reversionary period. Packer i’s expected aggregate procurement volume from
this strategy may not equal the cooperative strategy and payoff in normal (nonreversionary) periods. Each packer’s expected payoff in reversionary periods is the
expected discounted return to packer i in a single-period Cournot environment, plus the
discounted gain in returns due to participation in the cartel. Then the Nash equilibrium,
stated as a trigger strategy equilibrium, means that no strategy can produce a higher
payoff for players than the trigger strategy. The associated first order condition for this
expression indicates the marginal return to defecting from collusive output levels must be
exactly offset by the risk of suffering a loss in returns by triggering a reversionary
episode of length T.
A resulting implication is that the observed market price reveals information
about supply only, and does not cause players to revise their interpretation of what their
competitors have procured. Industry reversion from collusive states occurs regardless of
actual intentional defections by cartel members. The critical extension of this result is
that even though participants are aware reversionary episodes occur as a result of supply
conditions rather than intentional defection, it is rational for them to participate in the
episodes anyway. If firms failed to participate in the reversionary episodes when high
prices prevailed, i.e., due to low fed cattle supply conditions, the first order condition
would not hold during normal game periods and collusive behavior would not be
individually optimal for packers.
6
The beefpacking industry can be expected to exhibit both reversionary and
collusive periods. Reversionary periods may be caused by either unanticipated
fluctuations in the supply of fed cattle which cause higher prices that appear as
defections, or actual choice of a defection strategy by any individual packing firm. If
plant shutdown costs are sufficiently high, firms may purposely choose a defection
strategy as their optimal strategy. If fed cattle supply is particularly low, players will
understand this and the punishment period length T will be very short.
Experimental Market Description and Data
Plant-specific, transaction-level data for fed cattle are confidential and not
publicly available. Generally, such data cannot be accessed without Congressional or
regulatory authority due in part to industry consolidation, proprietary nature of the data,
and either pending or potential civil antitrust litigation.
Limited access to detailed market data led a team of economists to develop the
Fed Cattle Market Simulator (FCMS). As noted by Ward et al. (1996), the FCMS
integrates features of business simulation (Gentry) and experimental economics (Plott).
The market simulator generates plant-specific, transaction-level data similar to that not
publicly available for research. The empirical application of game theory to beefpacking
procurement utilized data from the experimental market. Therefore, an understanding of
the structure, operation, and economic behavior of participants in the experimental
market is important.
The FCMS was designed to resemble a real fed cattle procurement region, in
which there are typically several cattle feedlots (sellers) and only a few packers (buyers).
7
The experimental market consists of four packing firms of different sizes and eight
feedlots of nearly equal size. Packer and feedlot teams of 2-4 people trade paper pens of
fed cattle, each sheet of paper representing 100 head of steers. Participants trade in sevenminute, open-negotiation sessions with each trading period representing one week of real
time business. Participants negotiate cash (spot) or forward contract transactions, and
may either hedge or speculate in the futures market component of the experimental
market. Individual packing firms are aware of their efficient (minimum cost)
procurement volumes, which for packers 1 through 4 are 8, 9, 11, and 12 pens per trading
period, respectively. Output (boxed beef) price is determined by the volume of fed cattle
processed, both number and weight of fed cattle. Packers use the most recent boxed beef
price to determine their breakeven bid or price bid with a specified target margin. Cattle
feeders use known feeder cattle and grain costs to determine their breakeven offer prices
for various weights of fed cattle.
Market-ready fed cattle are placed on a “show list” for the packers at 1100 pounds
and continue to gain 25 pounds per week until they are sold, somewhere between 1100
and 1200 pounds. The number of new placements on the show list follows a preprogrammed, irregular but somewhat cyclical pattern, similar to a cattle cycle in the beef
industry. Thus, at times, supplies are plentiful and each packer can reach its minimum
cost volume relatively easily; and as a group, packers have the negotiating advantage
over price (Ward 2005). At other times, fed cattle supplies are tight relative to packing
capacity and each packer finds it difficult to purchase its minimum-cost volume. During
these tight-supply periods, negotiating strength in the market shifts to cattle feeders. This
finding parallels the asymmetric bargaining power argument of Sexton and Zhang.
8
Considerable market and performance information is provided to market
participants during and after each trading session. This information parallels what is
available to the real fed cattle market by the U.S. Department of Agriculture’s
Agricultural Marketing Service (AMS) and National Agricultural Statistics Service
(NASS) and from the Chicago Mercantile Exchange (CME). Current market data (e.g.,
volume and price range) on the most recent cash-market and futures-market transactions
are continuously scrolled across an electronic information display during each trading
period. End-of-week summary information (weekly volume traded, and average prices
for fed cattle, feeder cattle, and boxed beef) is posted each week. Cattle on feed reports
are issued every four trading weeks. Income statements are provided to each packer and
feedlot firm during the short intervals between trading sessions. Participants can access
private information from other teams depending on their propensity for such information
and willingness of rival teams to divulge the information. Such a scenario, which Fama
refers to as strong-form information efficiency, may be necessary for packers to behave
non-competitively.
Research reported here used data from three semester-long classes (1994, 1995,
and 1996), each of which used the FCMS weekly throughout the semester. In two of the
three semesters, a designed experiment was imposed on the experimental market. In
1995, researchers estimated impacts from imposing a marketing agreement between the
largest packer and the two largest feedlots at two, 16-week intervals (Ward et al.1999).
Student teams received cash awards for their profit performance during randomly
selected periods, as suggested for experimental economics research (Friedman and
Sunder). In 1996, researchers varied the amount and type of information available to
9
participants in randomly selected, 4- to 8-week periods to determine the impact public
market information had on marketing behavior and efficiency (Anderson et al.). Again, a
cash reward system was incorporated into the experiment based on team profit
performance.2
Data from the 1994 semester consisted of 2,748 transactions from 74 trading
periods; 1995, 3,530 transactions from 93 trading periods, and 1996, 2,197 transactions
from 60 trading periods. Figure 1 illustrates how consistent market prices were over the
three semesters, especially recognizing that two experiments were superimposed on
market participants in two of the three semesters. This consistency is further evidenced
by the fact that no significant differences were found across packers and semesters for fed
cattle purchases, i.e., both prices and volumes (Table 1). Thus, the game theory
application uses data from one semester featuring a normal functioning fed cattle market,
i.e., the FCMS market without an imposed experiment, and two semesters with designed
experiments. Differences in the data series provide the basis for comparing game theory
application results across three market scenarios to test how market conditions and
subsequent behavior affect results.
Empirical Model Development
Beefpacking at the industry level is modeled to determine whether or not firms
behave in the hypothesized non-competitive manner. The methodology focuses on firm
processing margins similar to previous work (Richards, Patterson, and Acharya;
Schroeter and Azzam). However, firm-level data for this application facilitates making
significant changes from previous models.
10
The objective function for packer i in the ordinary constituent game of the
supergame is
(1) max i = pqi – w(X,z)xi – c(qi)
where p and q are the price and quantity, respectively, of boxed beef sold in the
wholesale market, w(X,z) is the price of fed cattle, X is the total quantity of fed cattle
available for sale, z is a vector of supply shifting exogenous variables, and c(qi) is the ith
firm’s cost as a function of the quantity of cattle processed. The input transformation
function of the ith firm, which describes how fed cattle are processed into boxed beef, is
(2) qi =  xi
where  is the dressing percentage. Incorporating the input transformation function, the
firm’s objective function can be restated as
(3) max i = pxi – w(X,z)xi – c(xi)
and then the first order condition for profit maximization is
(4) i / xi = (p-cqi) – wi(X,z) – [(wi / X)  (X / xi )] xi = 0
where cqi is the marginal cost of firm i.
The conjectural variation of a firm describes its response to changes in output by
other firms, is denoted  = dxi / dxj. Since  must lie between -1 and +1, the market
conduct parameter, which describes the degree of oligopsony power being exerted by
packers, falls between 0 and 2 for extremes of perfect competition where dxi / dxj = -1,
and a monopsony where dxi / dxj = +1 (Binger and Hoffman; Richards, Patterson, and
Acharya). The intermediate case where  = 1 represents Cournot conduct.
The processing margin for packer i, having aggregated equation (4) over all
packers and assuming the conjectural variations are all the same, is
11
(5) mi = cq + ηX
where cq is marginal cost and η is the inverse slope of the fed cattle supply function. The
generalized Leontief (GL) cost function is of the form c(q,w) = λ1q2w1 + λ2q2w2 +
λ3q(w1w2)1/2 with w1 = live cattle prices and w2 = per-pen processing costs.
The supply function for fed cattle provided to packers by feedlots is
(6) X(w,z) = 0 + η-1(w(X,z) / zj) +   i z i + et
i j
where zj is the cost of gain, zi are other exogenous variables, and et is the disturbance
term.
Richards, Patterson, and Acharya note that processors’ ability to exert market
power is a function of capacity utilization. During periods when supply is plentiful,
coinciding with lower prices and higher capacity utilization, firms can be expected to
engage in collusive behavior. Conversely, during periods when supply is tight with
associated higher prices and lower capacity utilization, collusive behavior would be
expected to decline. The conduct parameter measuring this behavior is specified as:
(7) (k) = 0 + 1k
where k represents industry plant capacity utilization.
Methodology
A finite mixture estimation (FME) approach is used to estimate the percentage of
collusive and reversionary periods for each year as well as the degree of market power
that firms exert during these periods. This approach recognizes that packer margins
during collusive and reversionary periods are drawn from different distributions
12
characterized by distinct sets of parameters (Titterington, Smith, and Makov). The
probability density function for the margin is then a weighted average of the densities for
collusive and reversionary conduct, each of which possesses a mixing weight denoted τi
for i = 1, 2 which are collusive and reversionary periods, respectively.
As a result, the margin equation (5) can be written in regime-specific form. Then
the processing margin, with the GL cost function incorporated, becomes
(8) mc = λ1q2w1 + λ2q2w2 + λ3q(w1w2)1/2 + ηcXc
during collusive periods, and
mr = λ1q2w1 + λ2q2w2 + λ3q(w1w2)1/2 + ηrXr
during reversionary periods. However, since there is no obvious way to discern collusive
from reversionary periods, an estimation technique is needed that allows data
membership within one type of regime vs. the other to be decided.
The expectation/maximization (EM) algorithm of Dempster, Laird, and Rubin is a
latent variable method that may be used to assign periods into the collusive or
reversionary category. As Richards, Patterson, and Acharya describe, the algorithm
begins with the expectation step, during which segment weights are calculated, then
assigns observations to one regime or the other depending upon its dominant posterior
probability. In the maximization step, generalized least squares is used to calculate new
parameter estimates for the margin equations. New aggregate shares for the regimes are
then calculated, and a new iteration begins. The process thus iterates between expectation
and maximization until the log-likelihood function changes with each iteration by some
pre-selected amount. This allows the final mixing weights and market conduct parameters
for each regime to be observed.
13
Such a procedure presupposes that data are, in fact, generated by two separate
regimes. In practice, it is necessary to test whether this assumption holds. Wolfe’s
likelihood ratio test is used for this purpose. The calculated test statistic for each year is
compared to critical values from the Chi-Square distribution with a null hypothesis of a
single model (no switching behavior) vs. the alternative of a two-regime model.
Results
Equation (8) was estimated for each of the three data sets via the EM algorithm
using the IML procedure in SAS (SAS Institute). Tables 2 through 4 show the results of
OLS estimation of the single-regime model as well as the FME results for the dualregime model.
Results focus on the market conduct parameter (), both differences in magnitude
and statistical significance between collusive and reversionary periods and differences
across data periods and experimental conditions. The null hypothesis of the single model
was rejected for the 1994 semester in favor of a dual-regime framework. The estimated
collusive conduct parameter was 1.237 with collusive behavior occurring 78.5% of the
time (Table 2). The reversionary conduct parameter (0.924) was not significant.
Therefore, the existence of distinct collusive and reversionary periods was found, during
which the degree of market power being exerted by packers differed markedly.
Recall that the 1994 semester did not have an experiment imposed on the
simulated market, thus arguably mimicking most closely normal market behavior.
Results suggest during normal market behavior, supply conditions provide an opportunity
for firms to collude. This is consistent with the hypothesized effects from higher
supplies, lower prices, and higher capacity utilization rates. Evidence of the dual-regime
14
behavior is consistent with findings by Koontz, Garcia, and Hudson with real-market
data.
The null hypothesis of a single regime was rejected again for the 1995 semester
(Table 3). The FME collusive conduct parameter was significant (1.954) with packers
colluding 40.5% of the time. The punishment parameter again was not significant
(0.733). The conduct parameter for this semester was the highest of the three, suggesting
considerable levels of collusive behavior and, in fact, approaching the monopsonistic
value of 2.0.
The 1995 semester was the one during which a marketing agreement was imposed
between the largest packer and the two largest cattle feeding firms. This experimental
design resulted in fewer available cattle to satisfy the procurement needs of the three
packers not involved in the agreement. This raises the question whether the marketing
agreement gave the largest packer, the three packers not participating in the agreement, or
all packers together, more opportunity to behave collusively. In an examination of price
behavior during the experiment, Ward et al. (1999) found prices were higher but much
more variable during the marketing agreement periods. As a consequence, no conclusive
evidence exists that the marketing agreement adversely affected buyer competition.
Results for the 1996 semester were similar in several respects to those for the two
previous semesters (Table 4). The single regime was again rejected and the FME
collusive conduct parameter (1.201) was significant. Collusive behavior occurred 40.7%
of the time and the punishment parameter (1.178) was not significant, as was the case in
the previous two semesters.
15
During the 1996 semester, the amount of information available to the marketplace
varied systematically. The conduct parameters for the collusive and reversionary periods
were more nearly the same than for the other two semesters. Anderson et al. (1998)
found that limited information from the designed experiment caused increased price
variation and marketing inefficiencies. Cattle feeders were adversely affected by a lack
of information, as they were unable to use market data to better negotiate with packing
firms. The uncertainty created by limiting market information also may have hampered
packers from exercising collusive behavior. This finding is consistent with the corollary
situation when too much information can contribute to increased collusive behavior, as
shown by Albaek, Mollgaard, and Overgaard.
For two of the three semester-long periods (1995 and 1996), higher prices (λ1)
were associated with lower margins (Tables 2 and 3). For the 1996 semester, there was a
significant inverse relationship also between increased per pen processing costs (λ2) and
packer margins. In all three semesters (Tables 2-4), as plant utilization increased (δ1),
consistent also with higher supplies and lower prices, collusive behavior increased.
Summary and Conclusions
The objective of this paper was to develop and estimate a game theoretic model of
industry conduct and supergame strategies in a dynamic oligopsony, i.e., beefpacking
procurement. Data from the Fed Cattle Market Simulator (FCMS), an experimental
market for fed cattle, for three semester-long classes were used because real market data
were not publicly available. A non-cooperative, infinitely repeated game of beefpacker
procurement was developed in which players were hypothesized to behave differently
16
depending on fed cattle supply conditions and strategic considerations within the game.
Player goals were assumed to be maximization of a discounted stream of processing
profits.
The methodology focused on firm processing margins similar to previous work.
A finite mixture estimation (FME) approach was used to estimate the percentage of
collusive and reversionary periods for each data period as well as the degree of market
power that firms exert during these periods. This approach recognizes that packer
margins during collusive and reversionary periods are drawn from different distributions
characterized by distinct sets of parameters. The expectation/maximization (EM)
algorithm was used to assign periods into the collusive or reversionary category.
For all three semester-long periods, the single-regime model was rejected in favor
of a dual-regime alternative, consistent with a trigger-strategy equilibria. The market
conduct parameter was significant for the collusive regime in each semester, exceeding
the competitive value of zero and the Cournot level of 1.0. In the 1995 semester, it
approached a monosonistic solution (2.0). The reversionary period coefficients were
lower than the collusive values in each semester but were not significant for any period.
Higher fed cattle prices were associated with lower packer margins as were higher
processing costs. Higher plant utilization was associated with a higher level of collusive
behavior, as hypothesized.
Market conditions imposed by experimenters in two of the three semesters may
have contributed to results found. Imposing a marketing agreement between the largest
packer and two feedlots may have enhanced the ability to packers to behave collusively.
However, limiting the amount and type of public market information available to
17
participants, may have created sufficient uncertainty so as to reduce the opportunity to
behave collusively. In the “normal” market period where no designed experiments were
imposed onto the marketplace, packers were able to collude nearly twice as frequently as
in the other two semester-long periods.
Application of a game theory approach to data from an experimental market is
instructive because of the use of plant-specific, transaction-level data, given that such
data for a real-world application are not publicly available. While the structure of the
FCMS closely resembles that of the real fed cattle market, care must be exercised in
inferring conclusions from the experimental market directly to those existing in the realworld market. If – given similar conditions – firms in the real market behave in similar
ways to firms in the experimental market, then the evidence discovered here supports the
claims of those cattle industry stakeholders who assert that packers extract excess rents
from cattle feeders and in turn, from producers. However, the issue cannot be resolved
until regulatory agencies apply similar game theory models to industry data or provide
the necessary data they possess to academic researchers.
Results from the game theory approach applied to market simulator data in this
article is consistent in terms of evidencing a dual-regime, trigger-pricing strategy by
packers which was found in the only other game theory research applied to the
beefpacking industry by Koontz, Garcia, and Hudson. Evidence of collusive behavior
found in this research is also consistent with several previous studies using alternative
methodologies and data. In conclusion, this research provides evidence that a game
theory approach applied to beefpacker conduct needs to be conducted with real-world,
transaction-level data. Results potentially may differ according to regional differences in
18
buyer competitiveness, extent of pre-committed supplies to packers, and seasonal or
cyclical differences in cattle supply conditions.
19
Notes
1. Mathematical development of the theory can be found in Carlberg and Ward.
2. In comparing prices and volumes across the three semester-long classes, there is no
conclusive evidence that cash rewards contributed consistently and significantly to
eliciting desired economic behavior by participants.
20
References
Albaek, S., P. Mollgaard, and P.B. Overgaard. “Government-Assisted Oligopoly
Coordination? A Concrete Case.” Journal of Industrial Economics 45(1997):42943.
Anderson, J.D., C.E. Ward, S.R. Koontz, D.S. Peel, and J.N. Trapp. “Experimental
Simulation of Public Information Impacts on Price Discovery and Marketing
Efficiency in the Fed Cattle Market.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource
Economics 23(1998):262-78.
Azzam, A.M., and D.G. Anderson. Assessing Competition in Meatpacking: Economic
History, Theory, and Evidence. Grain Inspection, Packers and Stockyards
Administration report GIPSA-RR 96-6, Washington, D.C.: United States
Department of Agriculture, 1996.
Bain, J.S. “Relation of Profit Rate to Industry Concentration: American Manufacturing,
1936-1940.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 65(1951):488-500.
Binger, B. and E. Hoffman. Microeconomics with Calculus, 2nd ed. Reading, MA:
Addison Wesley. 1998.
Carlberg, J.G. and C.E. Ward. “Applying Game Theory to Meatpacker Behavior in an
Experimental Market: Implications for Market Regulation.” Virginia Tech
University, Research Institute on Livestock Pricing, Research Report 2-2002,
November 2002.
21
Dempster, A.P., N.M. Laird, and D.B. Rubin. “Maximum Likelihood from Incomplete
Data via the EM Algorithm.” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B
39,1(1977):1-38.
Driscoll, P.J., S.M. Kamhampaty, and W.D. Purcell. “Nonparametric Tests of Profit
Maximization in Oligopoly with Application to the Beef Packing Industry.”
American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79(1997):872-79.
Fama, E.F. “Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work.”
Journal of Finance. 25(1970):383-417.
Friedman, J.W. Game Theory With Applications to Economics. New York, NY: Oxford
University Press, 1986.
Friedman, J.W. “A Non-cooperative Equilibrium for Supergames.” Review of Economic
Studies 38(1971):1-12.
Friedman, D. and S. Sunder. Experimental Methods: A Primer for Economists. New
York: Cambridge University Press. 1994.
Gentry, J.W., ed. Guide to Business Gaming and Experiential Learning. Association for
Business Simulation and Experiential Learning. London: Nichols/GP Publishing.
1990.
Grain Inspection, Packers and Stockyards Administration. Packers and Stockyards
Statistical Report, 2004 Reporting Year. Washington, D.C.: United States
Department of Agriculture, SR-06-1, 2006.
Green, E.J., and R.H. Porter. “Noncooperative Collusion Under Imperfect Price
Information.” Econometrica 52(1984):87-100.
22
Hunnicutt, L. and Q. Weninger. “Testing for Market Power in Beef Packing: Where Are
We and What’s Next?” Virginia Tech University, Research Institute on Livestock
Pricing, Research Bulletin 7-99, 1999.
Koontz, S.R., P. Garcia, and M.A. Hudson. “Meatpacker Conduct in Fed Cattle Pricing:
An Investigation of Oligopsony Power.” American Journal of Agricultural
Economics 75(1993):537-48.
Koontz, S.R. and P. Garcia. “Meat-Packer Conduct in Fed Cattle Pricing: MultipleMarket Oligopsony Power.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics
22(1997):87-103.
Plott, C.R. “Industrial Organization Theory and Experimental Economics.” Journal of
Economic Literature. 20(1982):1485-1527.
Richards, T.J., P.M. Patterson, and R.N. Acharya. “Price Behavior in a Dynamic
Oligopsony: Washington Processing Potatoes.” American Journal of Agricultural
Economics 83(2001):259-71.
SAS Institute, Inc. SAS/ETS User’s Guide, Version 9.1, Cary, NC: SAS Institute, Inc.,
2003.
Schroeter, J., and A. Azzam. “Marketing Margins, Market Power, and Price
Uncertainty.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73(1991):990-99.
Schroeter, J.R. “Estimating the Degree of Market Power in the Beef Packing Industry.”
Review of Economics and Statistics 70(1988):158-62.
Sexton, R.J. “Industrialization and Consolidation in the U.S. Food Sector: Implications
for Competition and Welfare.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics
82(2000):5 1087-1104.
23
Sexton, R.J. and M. Zhang. “An Assessment of the Impact of Food Industry Market
Power on U.S. Consumers. Agribusiness: An International Journal
17,1(2001):59-79.
Titterington, D.A., A. Smith, and U. Makov. Statistical Analysis of Finite Mixture
Distributions. New York: John Wiley, 1985.
Ward, C.E. “A Review of Causes for and Consequences of Economic Concentration in
the U.S. Meatpacking Industry.” Current Agriculture, Food & Resource Issues
3(2002):1-28.
Ward, C.E. “Price Discovery and Pricing Choice Under Divergent Supply Scenarios in an
Experimental Market for Fed Cattle.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource
Economics 30(2005):580-96.
Ward, C.E., S.R. Koontz, T.L. Dowty, J.N. Trapp, and D.S. Peel. “Marketing Agreement
Impacts in an Experimental Market for Fed Cattle.” American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 81(1999):2 347-58
Ward, C.E., S.R. Koontz, D.S. Peel, and J.N. Trapp. “Price Discovery in an Experimental
Market for Fed Cattle.” Review of Agricultural Economics 18(1996):449-66.
Whitley, J. “The Gains and Losses from Agricultural Concentration: A Critical Survey of
the Literature.” Journal of Agricultural & Food Industrial Organization 1(2003)
www.bepress.com/jafio .
24
Table 1. ANOVA Results for Prices ($/cwt.) and Volumes by Packers, Three
Semester-Long Classes, 1994-1996.
Team
1994
1995
1996
Semester
Semester
Semester
Price
Price
Price
Price
Price
Price
Mean
Variance
Mean
Variance
Mean
Variance
p-Value
Packer 1
78.72
11.22
78.75
12.84
78.14
13.92
0.601
Packer 2
78.28
12.08
78.34
12.48
78.10
14.48
0.935
Packer 3
78.52
11.30
78.50
12.41
78.29
12.35
0.922
Packer 4
78.75
11.53
78.68
11.48
78.66
10.38
0.989
All Packers
78.67
11.06
78.66
11.73
78.43
11.11
0.906
Team
1994
1995
1996
Semester
Semester
Semester
25
Volume Volume Volume Volume Volume Volume p-Value
Mean
Variance
Mean
Variance
Mean
Variance
Packer 1
7.8
6.0
7.8
2.2
8.0
4.2
0.761
Packer 2
8.1
7.2
8.3
3.2
8.7
3.3
0.381
Packer 3
10.5
6.8
10.6
7.1
10.6
2.6
0.993
Packer 4
12.0
4.0
11.6
5.1
11.9
6.2
0.548
All Packers
36.6
39.3
36.8
37.5
36.7
57.9
0.983
26
Table 2. Ordinary Least Squares and Finite Mixture Estimation Results, 1994
________________________________________________________________________
OLS
Finite Mixture Estimation
Parameter
Single
Reversionary
Collusive
Model
Regime
Regime
________________________________________________________________________
λ1
-4.933
(-1.625)
-4.652
(-0.132)
λ2
-0.014
(-0.392)
0.033
(0.011)
-0.039
(-1.029)
λ3
786.480
(0.954)
46.761
(0.006)
1501.040
(1.586)
δ0
-1.450
(-1.499)
-0.488
(-0.004)
-2.560**
(-2.238)
δ1
2.236**
(2.408)
0.559
(0.051)
3.498**
(3.131)

1.056**
(2.653)
0.924
(0.611)
1.237*
(1.885)
τ
—
-7.956**
(-2.150)
0.785**
(5.779)
________________________________________________________________________
Note: t-ratios are given in parentheses. Double and single asterisks denote statistical
significance at the α = 0.05 and α = 0.10 levels, respectively.
27
Table 3. Ordinary Least Squares and Finite Mixture Estimation Results, 1995
________________________________________________________________________
OLS
Finite Mixture Estimation
Parameter
Single
Reversionary
Collusive
Model
Regime
Regime
________________________________________________________________________
λ1
-3.777
(-0.963)
7.056
(0.920)
-15.282**
(-2.134)
λ2
-0.056
(-1.174)
-0.066
(-0.654)
-0.105
(-1.142)
λ3
342.366
(0.292)
-1787.761
(-0.759)
3259.438
(1.352)
δ0
-4.760**
(-2.516)
-5.913
(-1.472)
-3.301
(-1.126)
δ1
5.845**
(3.215)
6.583*
(1.729)
5.287*
(1.846)

1.202**
(3.045)
0.733
(0.593)
1.954**
(3.034)
τ
—
0.405**
(2.064)
________________________________________________________________________
Note: t-ratios are given in parentheses. Double and single asterisks denote statistical
significance at the α = 0.05 and α = 0.10 levels, respectively.
.
28
Table 4. Ordinary Least Squares and Finite Mixture Estimation Results, 1996
________________________________________________________________________
OLS
Finite Mixture Estimation
Parameter
Single
Reversionary
Collusive
Model
Regime
Regime
________________________________________________________________________
λ1
-7.893
(-1.039)
-9.393
(-0.388)
-11.482**
(-2.754)
λ2
-0.051
(-0.500)
0.047
(0.167)
-0.187**
(-4.163)
λ3
1287.357
(0.669)
154.442
(0.024)
4289.764
(4.335)
-2.485*
(-1.940)
δ0
-2.126
(-0.895)
-1.369
(-0.156)
δ1
3.050*
(1.416)
1.549
(0.182)
4.370**
(3.846)

1.137**
(1.968)
1.178
(0.818)
1.201**
(1.969)
τ
—
0.407**
(3.757)
________________________________________________________________________
Note: t-ratios are given in parentheses. Double and single asterisks denote statistical
significance at the α = 0.05 and α = 0.10 levels, respectively.
29
Figure 1. Weekly average fed steer prices for semester-long classes of the
experimental market, 1994-1996.
95
90
80
75
70
Week
AveP94
AveP95
30
AveP96
93
95
89
91
85
87
81
83
77
79
73
75
71
67
69
63
65
59
61
55
57
51
53
47
49
43
45
41
65
37
39
$/cwt.
85
Download