Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Intentional Torts: BATTERY BATTERY: Intentional (desire OR knowledge to a substantial certainty to make contact, not necessarily to cause the resulted harm) Infliction (Voluntary Act + Causation) Harmful or Offensive (objective “reasonable person” standard) Contact (person to person OR transferred intent with object; no certainty of contact required) with the Person of the π (must be a reasonably identifiable person) Battery: the intentional infliction of harmful/offensive contact with the person of P: 1. Intentional: desire to bring about the consequences OR knowledge/certainty that consequences will ensue (statistical certainties are not sufficient.) Vosburg v. Putney, Garret v. Dailey (toddler’s prank) Now codified in RST 3rd § 1 Intent: 2. Infliction: voluntary act and causation 3. Harmful/Offensive: what a reasonable person would find harmful/offensive 4. Contact: person to person not required (transferred intent applies a. Talmage v. Smith (Mich 1984) (p.9)-intent can be transferred. Even though Δ meant to throw stick at different trespasser and ended up hitting Π in the eye, intent is transferred Π and he is still liable. 5. With the person of P: “contact”, no statistical certainty that it will hit P is required, transferred intent applies Defenses to Battery a. Consent: P consented to what otherwise would be harmful touching i. Subjective/free consent (“meant to say yes”) 1. Actual 2. Substituted judgment (for minors) ii. Objective consent 1. Implied consent Defenses to Battery 1. Consent a. Subjective/free consent i. Actual ii. Substituted judgment b. Objective i. Express ii. Implied c. No consent i. Not within scope of consent ii. Mistake iii. Duress iv. Can’t consent to illegal acts v. Uninformed consent 2. Insanity 3. Self defense 4. Trespass a. Defense of prop b. Necessity i. Private (incomplete privilege) ii. Public (complete privilege) 1 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng 2. Implied-in-fact/Constructive consent (ER doctor saving a life) iii. No consent: 1. Williams (Minn. 1905) D gets consent to operate on P’s right ear, but during operation decides that it is better to operate on the left ear. P’s consent could not be implied because every person has a right to complete immunity of his person from physical interference of others. However, unlawful intent must be shown for criminal tort. a. Games and sporting events: ordinary plays and even violations of rules are covered under implied. No implied consent to explicitly prohibited actions: Hackbart v. Cincinnati Bengals (injury sustained during football game.) b. Nurse for insane: McGuire v. Almy (Mass, 1937): P sues insane girl for injuries sustained during care. P could not have consented (under her duty as nurse) because she didn’t realize the risk until she was inside the room already. (Potential PP argument: encourage guardians to keep an eye on their wards.) 2. consent was a mistake. a. Mistake of fact: Π submits to eating candy, not knowing it’s poisoned) b. Mistake of law: Π submits to arrest warrant thinking it’s valid, when it’s not. 3. Consent was given in duress. 4. Cannot consent to unlawful acts. a. Minority of states you can consent to illegal acts. b. (Hudson): even though Π consented to boxing, consent was not a valid defense since it was an illegal activity. Thus, Δ promoter was still held liable for battery. 5. Uninformed consent iv. No consent: 1. battery was not within scope of consent: M: Mohr v. Williams (Minn. 1905) D gets consent to operate on P’s right ear, but during operation decides that it is better to operate on the left ear. P’s consent could not be implied because every person has a right to complete immunity of his person from physical interference of others. However, unlawful intent must be shown for criminal tort. a. Games and sporting events: ordinary plays and even violations of rules are covered under implied. No implied consent to explicitly prohibited actions: Hackbart v. Cincinnati Bengals (injury sustained during football game.) b. Nurse for insane: McGuire v. Almy (Mass, 1937): P sues insane girl for injuries sustained during care. P could not have consented (under her duty as nurse) because she didn’t realize the risk until she was inside the room already. (Potential PP argument: encourage guardians to keep an eye on their wards.) 2. Consent was a mistake. 2 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng a. Mistake of fact: Π submits to eating candy, not knowing it’s poisoned b. Mistake of law: Π submits to arrest warrant thinking it’s valid, when it’s not. 3. Consent was given in duress. 4. Cannot consent to unlawful acts. a. Minority of states you can consent to illegal acts. b. (Hudson): even though Π consented to boxing, consent was not a valid defense since it was an illegal activity. Thus, Δ promoter was still held liable for battery. 5. Uninformed consent b. Insanity: no ability to form requisite intent (For insane person to be liable, she must have cognized that she was in fact harming another human being, and not say an object.) i. Ie: deLisle’s bulked-out neighbor, who believes he is Antonio Salieri will not be liable for beating deLisle if Salieri thinks deLisle is a musical instrument. ii. (Mcguire v. Almy): P is hurt while nursing for insane woman. Where an insane person intends to harm another’s person or property, they are liable the same as a sane person. (Make caretakers more watchful, prevents harm to innocent victim, too difficult to determine who is insane.) c. Self defense: reasonable and actual belief of imminent bodily harm and proportionality of force with apparent danger. i. Non-Deadly Force: can be used when actor reasonably believes they are in danger of immediate harm. Force must be reasonable and can not go beyond the necessities of the situation. ii. Deadly Force: can be used when actor reasonably believes that another’s conduct will cause them death or serious bodily injury. 1. Courvosier v. Raymond: D accidently shoots a policeman, mistaking him for a rioter about to attack him. Where a reasonable person would view Π as endangering his life, and he uses self defense , he is justified 2. Duty to retreat a. Majority: No duty to retreat. b. Minority: Duty to retreat before using deadly force (RST view). c. No duty to retreat when in your own home. 3. Retaliation not okay: Can’t use self-defense to retaliate, since harm has passed. iii. No privilege of self defense when danger has passed or when excessive force is used. d. Defense of others: Same limitations of self defense i. Can extend to anyone who is endangered ii. Traditional view: actor can only use self defense if 3rd party could have. iii. Modern view: RST 2nd allow for a reasonable mistake in the exercise of the actor. e. Trespass: intentionally entering the property of another i. Defense against trespassing chattels 1. Can use reasonable force to remove trespassing chattels 3 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng 2. Must also consider loss of value of actor’s property compared to value of chattel. ii. Defense against trespassers: Can use only that force reasonably necessary to defend your property. Deadly force can only be used when invasion threatens death or serious bodily harm. 1. Reasonable mistake defense is ineffective here because it is not a reasonable use of force (Rest 85) b. Necessity: Do not get to use deadly force: Use of force as matter of defense has to be proportionate to harm that is being threatened and no less force will achieve the purposes 1. Private necessity: incomplete privilege: must compensate: (Vincent v. Lake Erie) 2. Public necessity: complete privilege (subject to constitutional constraints): immediate and imperative necessity in good faith for public good a. can enter land or interfere w/ chattels of another if it is reasonably necessary or if it reasonably appears necessary to avoid a public disaster. b. Common cases are preventing destruction of city by fire (Mayor of NY v. Lord) and destruction of property to prevent it from falling into enemy hands during war. c. To hold otherwise would result in asymmetry of incentives for public officials. (Limited benefit and unlimited loss) d. Need an immediate and imperative necessity, not just utilitarian e. Complete defense: Δ is not liable for any damage to land or chattels Intentional Torts: ASSAULT = BATTARY + APPREHENSION (no CONTACT required) D acts with intent to cause battery (or imminent apprehension of such contact) AND P is put into apprehension of such contact (no contact required) Hypo: A gets hit by B but never sees it coming battery but not assault because A never manifests apprehension (A’s apprehension is key) Test 1. An ACT by the Δ Usually requires an external movement, words insufficient (I. de S. and Wife v. W de. S: Δ swinging at Π with hatchet is assault, since it created fear of unlawful touching) Conditional Threat: Illegal demands that create illusory choices are still assaults. A threat of “your money or your life,” is assaultive because no real option exists. 2. INTENT of Δ to cause harm or at least fear thereof (Tuberville v. Savage: Π put hand on sword and said if the judges weren’t in town, I would not take this from you, and Δ 4 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng responded in self-defense. No defense because P knew judges weren’t in town, D’s words negated intent) 3. FEAR or APPREHENSION by Π Use an objective reasonable person test here (Even if Π had no apprehension, as long as reasonable person would have it is still assault; ie Delisle threatens to kill blackbeltstill assault) Brandishing an unloaded gun would still be assault because it creates fear, even though it could not result in harm (Allen v. Hannaford) Making threats by phone to “find you and kick your ass” does not qualify as assault because threat of harm is not immediate (Brower v. Ackerly). -CAUSATION -DAMAGES: same as battery. Defenses Consent Privilege (defense of others) Extra-sensitive P: Once D knows of P’s extra sensitivity, D is liable for less-thanreasonable threats Other intentional torts (without contact) False Imprisonment (must be intentional total confinement) Intention infliction of Emotional Distress (extraordinary instances only) Unintentional Torts: Strict Liablity Strict Liability: Liable even if free from negligence: Early cases Fletcher v. Rylands : D’s reservoir (built by negligent contracted engineers) breaks and floods P’s mines through ancient shafts. Verdict for P on SL. D is liable for consequences of his non-natural actions. (Turner v. Big Lake OH Co.: reservoirs become “natural” to Texas because of it’s terrain and need for water.) Natural v. Unnatural: Brown v. Collins (NH 1873) Δ’s horse becomes frightened and runs onto Π’s land and damages a post. Π sues under strict liability. Court refused to apply SL to escaping horse. Says that basically everything you do with you land unnatural, and thus you would be liable for anything that escaped. Powell v. Fall (1880) Δ operates a steam engine according to statutes, but a spark burns Π’s hay rick. The existence of a statute can not prevent Δ from strict liability. There was no attempt of statute to exempt Δ from SL. Reasonable that when Δ uses dangerous machine he should have to pay for damage. If profit of using machine does not exceed costs of damages, then it should not be used. 5 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng o Coase theory: It’s not about trains causing harm to farmers, but rather it is a deadweight loss that stems from incompatible activities trying to coincide. In Coasian world, parties would bargain with no transaction costs and this would lead to an efficient outcome regardless of initial allocation of property rights. Coase theory assumes perfect information, perfect markets, and 0 transaction costs. Modern cases: Bolton v. Stone (Eng. 1950) Π was struck by a cricket ball hit over a high fence from a neighboring cricket field. Δ argues that in past 30 yrs, only dozen balls had been hit over the fence, thus it was not a reasonably foreseeable risk. Verdict for Δ. The proper test is not merely foreseeability, but instead the substantiality of the risk caused by Π to Δ. o Lower court speaks the language of negligence standard, but D is still held liable (learning towards SL). The risk is non-reciprocal and there is causation with no consent of P to take this risk. Courts thought this was foreseeable because it has happened before. (Court distinguishes between “It has never happened” and “It has happened so rarely.”) Team should be punished for inaction. Defense: Act of God: (ie storm) that causes “escape”, then there is no SL according to Nichols v. Marsland (Exceptionally heavy rain caused artificial lakes, bridges and waterways to be flooded and damage adjoining land. The D was not liable; doubted by courts however.) NEGLIGENCE Negligence Action (prima facie case) I. Duty owed to P II. Breach III. Causation Landmark case: Brown v. Kendalli: D tries to break up dogfight between P and D’s dogs— uses cane and accidently hits P in the eye. Verdict for D. D acted as reasonable man would. (Question of duty: if it was not D’s duty to separate dogs—an “unnecessary act”—then he should have exercised “extraordinary care.” In this case, however, it was his duty because it was his dog) Problem with negligence standard: D can claim that there is no precaution that can be taken to make it cost/effective and courts may declare no negligence but neglect to ask the next question, which is, given this, whether the activity is socially effective to keep around. DUTY Duty of Reasonable Care 6 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Affirmative Duties: I. Rescue a. Peril of D’s creation b. Rendered P helpless after the harm (reminiscent of last clear chance) c. Negligent conduction of rescue d. Undertake & abandon (with worse off P) II. Gratuitous Undertakings a. Rest. 90 of Contracts (quasi-contracts) i. N increases risk to P and lease to reliance of P III. Owners & Occupiers IV. Special Relationships Duty to Rescue I. No Duty Owed a. Trespassers: Buch v. Amony Manufacturing Co. (NH, 1897, 565) P, 8 year old, trespassed in D’s mill and was told to leave. P failed to leave and then had his hand crushed in machine. D did not owe P a legal duty (thus not N for failure to eject him.) There is no difference between this lack of duty to an adult trespasser and a lack of duty to a child. Moral obligation does not equal duty. b. Doctors: Hurley v. Eddingfield ( Ind. 1901, 568)Family doctor refuses to come to the aid of a violently ill P without reason. P dies as a result. Doctors are not obligated to always respond. No common carrier obligations or “special relationship” c. Mental Impact: Yania v. Bigan (Pa., 1959, p568) Affirmative Duties: i. D taunts P into jumping into a cut. P drowns I. Rescue and sues for wrongful death. No physical a. Peril of D’s creation b. Rendered P helpless contact mental impact does not qualify after the harm for N unless P is mentally deficient or a (reminiscent of last child. D had no duty to rescue. clear chance) d. Theory: c. Negligent conduction i. Ames, Law and Morals (1908,569): Law is of rescue d. Undertake & abandon utilitarian but it is more reasonable to use a (with worse off P) standard of duty if there is no significant II. Gratuitous Undertakings cost or inconvenience for rescue. Hypo: a. Rest. 90 of Contracts hunter accidently shoots P and P falls face (quasi-contracts) down into shallow pool. Should hunter have i. N increases risk to P and duty to rescue? lease to ii. Epstein: A theory of SL (1973, 571) Ames’ reliance of P substantial cost/inconvenience standard III. Owners & Occupiers can be very problematic has far reaching IV. Special Relationships 7 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng potential applications that impinge on autonomy. iii. Posner: Epstein’s Tort Theory: A Critique (1979, 5733) We can see tort duties as a device for vindicating freedom of K if it were possible that all people could come together and K for a mutual duty (consideration being a commitment to reciprocate.) However, the obstacles of doing so are insurmountable so courts will sometimes use torts to enforce this. Stockberger v. US (2003, 574) If liability was imposed, it would serve as a strong deterrent, pushing people to avoid putting themselves in that position in the first place. Circle of potential liable nonrescuers would be difficult to draw. iv. Bender, A lawyer’s primer on feminist theory and tort (1988, 573) The law dehumanizes the real impact of this failure to act. In law, autonomy should not weigh less than our compassion for other humans. II. Duty Owed a. Duty based on prior conduct creating a risk of physical harm i. Montgomery v. Nat’l Convoy & Trucking Co. (S.C.1937, 579) D’s truck broke down on icy road (no N in breakdown.) They put up flares and lights on the truck, but had reason to know that this would not allow cars to stop in time. P’s car crashed as a result. 1. Duty and reasonable foresight that flares and lights are not sufficient (N, failure to act.) See Newton v. Ellis (580) (worker dug a hole in public highway and left it unlit at night.) 2. If SL were applied: P would be liable even though he was not N in blocking the highway strong incentives to take more precautions to warn cars at the top of the hill. b. Special Relationships c. Duty to continue rescue (botched/negligence OR undertaken and abandoned, causing net loss) (Rest. 324) i. Must rescue with reasonable care: Black v. NY (train conductor left drunk P halfway up stairs and he fell. D had not duty initially, but once he helped P he was bound by duty of reasonable care. One may not be guilty of malfeasance, but if attempt to rescue is initiated, then one must do so with reasonable care. ii. May not refuse to help rescuer: Soldano v. O’Daniels (1983, 682) D, a bartender, refused ot allow would-be rescuer to use phone. D is liable because his N prevents or disables the third person from giving aid (Rest 327 and is morally repugnant.) d. Owners and Occupiers Good Samaritan Duties Some courts have statutes that insulate Good Samaritan for liability (unless gross N or willful misconduct.) 8 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Arguments for affirmative duty o Potential social good if you can decide when the laws should apply Arguments against affirmative duty o People should not be bound to rescue someone when they did not cause the harm. o Enforceability when there are many bystanders o Problematic to determine when it should be enforced o Potential disincentives: people avoid those situations for fear of being held liable o Morality handles the problem (don’t need laws.) Theoretical takes Corrective Justice: o Focus on relationships/moral obligations (not nec effy) (duty to aid certain people, duty to help a rescuer) o Positive duty to go forward, esp when someone has relied on you to their detriment, that has created a ‘right’ of your aid/protection (gratuitous undertakings, reliance) o More opportunity for moral choice, especially where someone else lacks the choice in the sense we think about it being informed (i.e. child trespassers and attractive nuisance) o No sweeping omission liability – fairness of not holding people accountable for things they didn’t create or wouldn’t have been able to protect against o Private necessity/conditional privilege – create privileges that force someone to allow others to use property in order to save more valuable property or lives Economic o Putting certain duties on ppl with special relationships b/c often are cheapest cost avoiders and creates the right incentives to prevent harm (therapists, LLs, prison guards, etc.) o Sense of inefficiency of general omission liability – will probably create more harms (keep people away from areas where might be expected to aid, could cause blundered-rescues, lead to over-deterrence (too many rescues when neither desirable nor necessary, could result in more injuries). Too unclear, too difficult to administer, best left to moral considerations. (In a sense, could look at the unwillingness to create expansive affirmative duties as a rejection of tort law as reflective of morality. Seems to be saying that except in some egregious cases – where, for example there is a quasicontractual relationship, we don’t want to get involved in policing moral obligations). Gratuitous Undertakings 9 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 I. M. Cheng Manifested Duty a. Coggs v. Bernard (Eng., 1703, 606) Misfeasance: D breaks brandy barrels of P when moving them. P sues for assumpsit (breach of simple K) Verdict for P. D had duty to move the barrels w/o N once he undertook the activity. Consideration for the K was P’s trust in him. Court uses K theories like promissory estoppel and reliance in tort. II. Reliance creates duty: a. Erie R.R. v. Stewart (1930, 609) Railroad gratuitously voluntarily provided watchman for tracks. P was run over when watchman was not there. P relied on expectation of a watchman. D created a duty by setting higher internal standards for itself and thus is N for not meeting them. (See Lucy Webb Hayes Nat’l Training School v. Perotti, 229) D had a duty because P relied on this voluntary service. b. Marsalis v. LaSalle (La., 1957, 612) P gets scratched by D’s cat in D’s store. D promised to keep the cat locked up for 14 days to determine if it had rabies. Cat escapes and P engages in medical treatment in case the cat had rabies. She suffers extreme side effects from the rabies vaccine. Court held that D had a duty. One who voluntarily undertakes to care for or to afford relief or assistance to an injured or distressed person has a duty not to act negligently. III. Duties to 3rd parties a. Moch Co. v. Rensselaer Water Co. (N.Y.1928, 615) : No duty to 3rd party beneficiaries. P’s warehouse is engulfed by fire and P notifies D. D fails to provide more water/adequate enough water and water pressure to extinguish fire. P sues D for breach of contract, tort action, or breach of statutory duty. No breach of contract (D’s contract was with city to provide water. Had not contractual duty to P) Cardozo suggests that the cheap water costs meant that there was no assumption of duty to build in this liability to private owners (and P enjoyed the cheap water costs.) i. No tort: no duty. Might have failed to confer a benefit, but not a wrong. D is not insurer of P’s property. ii. No breach of statutory duty: they only have a duty to provide water, nothing more than that. iii. Potential reliance issue? iv. Cardozo suggests that the nonfeasance of D meant no duty. v. Rejected by Doyle v. South Pittsburgh Water Co (620) but affirmed by Strauss v. Belle Realty Co. (620) Duties of Owners and Occupiers Limited Duty Considered an area of “limited liability” – required to exercise reasonable care with regard to activities on her land for the protection of those outside the premises. 10 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng No duty of care is owed for “natural conditions” Have a duty to prevent unreasonable risk of harm to persons or property created by artificial uses (Rylands) Note: Many jurisdictions have done away with the common law categories distinguishing b/w types of visitors Types of Visitors 1. Trespassers: safe from nothing but “willful and wanton misconduct” of owner a. Owner must make the premises safe or at least post warnings for trespassers if she i. has knowledge (notice) that a limited portion of her land is frequently used by trespassers or is being used by a trespasser; or ii. when she knows children are likely to trespass, the area is dangerous to children who are unlikely to realize the danger, the benefit to children outweighs the cost of maintenance (CBA) iii. when the owner maintains an attractive nuisance (swimming pool). b. When the owner is not aware of the trespasser, then no duty. But can’t set traps. (Bird v. Holbrook—spring guns.) c. Attractive Nuisance Doctrine i. Allows children to recover when lured onto D’s property by some tempting condition created and maintained by D (e.g. swimming pool) 1. Maalouf v. Swiss Confederation (590); Child is attracted by sledding hill and then is injured by hidden wire. Doctrine says that the relevant is not what attracts the child, but rather the nuisance itself. 2. Robert Addie & Sons v. Dumbreck (1929, 584): No duty to take even reasonable care to trespassers. P’s 4 year old was warned not to play in field and then was mangled by a big wheel. D maintained a hedge that had sufficient gaps for children to climb through. D’s servants kept watch to protect property, not to watch trespassers. P had not duty to insure trespasser, even if it was a child. The wheel was not an attractive nuisance and P repeatedly spurned people from his land (no implied permission.) 2. Invitees (commercial expectation of mutual benefit from visit) a. Must take reasonable care that the land is safe (inspect/discover harms) b. Must warn of known dangers that are not obvious c. If the danger is obvious, no duty to warn. 3. Licensees (social) a. Must take reasonable care that the land is safe. (So if faucet was clearly cracked but didn’t think to/bother to inspect, this could violate std of reasonable care.) 11 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng i. Rowland v. Christian (Cal. 1968, 593) Rejection of Robbert Addie: D invites P to home and P’s hand is sliced by broken faucet. D knew of danger but neglected to warn. D had duty of reasonable care even if P was a social guest. Collapse of rigid classification, which is antiquated and inefficient. Reasonable under the circumstances works better. Owners have a duty to warn all people on their land, subject to circumstances. (Not all jurisdictions have collapsed the categ.) 1. Dissent: classifications serve an important practical purpose. Social guests/licensees should take the premises as he finds it (case-by-case adjudication based on reasonableness is unstable.) 2. While Licensee/Invitee categories have evolved, there is still resistance with trespassers. b. Must warn of known dangers. c. No duty to inspect premises or discover danger. Special Relationships Rest 2nd 315: There is no duty to control conduct of 3rd person as to prevent him from causing physical harm to another unless o Special relationship between actor & 3rd person which imposes a duty on actor to control 3rd person’s conduct. o Special relationship between actor or another which gives the other a right to protection. Landlord/Tenant Kline v. 1500 Mass. Ave. Ap. Corp (DC, 1970, 624): P, tenant, moves into D’s building which is secured by receptionist and security. Over the years, these disappear and increased crime in neighborhood. P complains and D has notice, but fails to act. P is attacked and court holds that D has duty. o L had special power to provide reasonable care and is the only one who is in a position to do so (even though L is not insurer of T.) o Dissent: P did not show L’s N was proximate cause for her injury and she had knowledge (notice) that things were changing o Kline provides new standard for L/T duties, but is still limited so as to no place undue burden on L. Burgos v. Aqueduct Realty (631): causation must be made between harm and L’s failure to provide adequate security (no causation for T who was forced back into her building by robbers, though possibility of proximate causation.) Colleges/Universities (students on campus) Common Carriers (reasonable if not unduly burdensome, Lopez v. So. CA Rapid Transit, 632) Condo Boards (owners on board become de facto L, Frances T. v. Village Green, 632) 12 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Shopping Malls (no duty because no foreseeability. T leases total control of shopping area. Ann M. v. Pacific Plaza, 632) Doctor-Patient (duty to warn potential victim?) o Tarasoff v. Regents of UC : therapist fails to warn potential victim that was was in danger of mental patient. Patient killed her despite doctor’s unsuccessful attempts to have him committed. CofA can be sustained for N failure to protect victim Duty of care regardless of confidentiality clause (extreme circum.) No duty to actually confine D (therapists and police offers immune) Police had no special relationship with victim to impose duty. Creating the circumstances o Weirum v. RKP General, Inc (CA, 1975, 623): teens in race to claim prize from radio station run P off the road. S.C. said that radio station had duty derived from specific intent to create this competitive circumstance. Ct. insists that this does not open Pandora’s Box for liability of entrepreneurs when faced with product scarcity. Negligence: Breach of Duty I. Breach of a Duty a. Objective Standard: what an average reasonable person would do under the circumstances i. Holmes (177): Importance of a set standard. The common man does not suffer from this standard (because they should be ingrained into his common sense.) The stupid and clumsy have to try harder in order to compensate. Question of defining what a “reasonable man” really is. ii. No adjustment for stupidity: Vaughan v. Menlove (Eng., 1837, 171): D builds hayrick on edge of property, ignoring warnings of people that it’s a fire hazard. Hayrick catches on fire and burns down 2 cottages of P. Verdict for P. D was not reasonable though he claims he was. Reasonableness does not take account stupidity or variable standards. i. No adjustment for age/infirmity: Roberts v. Ring (Minn, 1919, 178): D hits boy who runs in front of his car. D was driving at speed limit, but has sight and hearing impairments. Verdict for P. D needs to focus harder than common man in order to reach the same standard of care: he knows that he has these impairments before he got into the car (P is not CN because he’s only 7) iii. Reasonable foreseeability: 1. Fletcher v. City of Aberdeen (Wash 1959, 190) Blind man falls into trench because workman forgot to replace the barrier. Verdict for P. Reasonable city has to foresee that disabled people are using the streets. P is only required to act as a reasonable blind man would (ie use a cane) 13 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng 2. Robinson v. Proche (CA, 1855) Drunk man falls into open manhole. Verdict for P. City has to take into consideration that drunk people are a reasonable foreseeable risk (manhole should have been covered whether or not they thought a drunkard would fall in) 3. Blyth v. Birmingham Water Works (Eng.,1856, 194): abnormally high frosts freeze plug, D fails to remove accumulated ice and causes flood. D could not have foreseen the abnormal weather conditions (acted reasonably based on data) Bramwell says P has just as much responsibility as D to remove the ice. b. Subjective variations i. Youth/Beginners : adjustment (unless doing adult act.) 1. Beginners in adult activities held at same standard to encourage training, prevent double standards, and forestall risk of fraud (public can’t be expected to bear risk). Daniels v. Evans (NH, 1966, 180) P is a minor on a motorcycle (19yo) that was killed in collision with D’s car. P should be held to adult standard to (deter accidents by keeping higher standards) 2. Exception: no license needed: a. Gross v. Allen (183) 17 year old beginner skier not held to adult standard of care because youths do not need a license to ski. Problem with this: there are a lot of activities that are dangerous that do not require a license (ie ten-speed bikes) However, Dellwo v. Pearson (183): 12 year old on speed boat was held to adult standard even though there is no license needed for speedboats. b. Jackson v. McCuiston (p183) 13 year old on tractor held to adult standard. This was cut back in Purtle v. Shelton where 17 boy with firearm was held at minor standard because “hunting is not exclusively an adult activity.” (One dissenting judge argued that a bullet is dangerous whether coming from kid or adult.) ii. Insanity: 1. Breunig v. Am. Family Insurance (Wis, 1970,185): P has insane fit during driving (Batman delusion) and drives head-on to another car. P is not criminally liable (CL) because she was fine when she got in the car and then the sudden fit hit her like a heart attack. (Temporality difference between reasonableness at point 1 versus point 2 Breunig) iii. Emergencies: 14 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng 1. Lower standard of care for emergencies: Lyons v. Midnight Sun (Ala., 1996, 215): P pulls in front of truck causing collision though trucker tried to avoid her. Truck driver not CN. 2. No S/l in Careful Driving. Hammontree v. Jenner (Cal. Ct. App. 1971): D, w/ legal license, accidentally drove through P’s bicycle shop during an epileptic seizure. H: Not s/l but negl. at worse when D comporting with law and causes damage to another’s person and prop. No negl. b/c seizure not foreseeable. iv. Specialist/experts (adjust high- more care expected) v. Common carrier (adjust high- more care expected) II. Calculus of Risk (B<PLN)—cost benefit analysis Blyth, Eckert, Osbourne (benefit to driving is useful even given risk) a. Hand formula: US v. Carroll Towing Co (2nd circuit, p206) Barge breaks away and damages property. N of barge? b. Application of BPL: Breach of Duty to Exercise Reasonable Care i. Reasonable risks okay: Osborne v. Montgomery (Wis 1931, 201): Kid on bike runs into the open car door of D. D not N. Risk/utility calculus: risk of harming pedestrians is still lower than utility of driving under ordinary care. ii. Duty to protect the largest class in greatest harm: Cooley v. Public Service Co. (NH, 1940) (p203) loud noises from telephone scares P and she falls, injuring herself. P is traumatized by incident. D is not N (precaution that P suggests is taken at risk to others and increases collateral damage potential) P = low; B= high (due to the potential risk of pedestrians if a basket was made) iii. Where cost of B is low, π only need show minimal evidence for liability: Andrews v. United (9th circuit) (p217) Common Carrier Passenger struck by falling luggage when opening bin after landing. D claims their announcement at the beginning of each flight constitutes a B, but court says it is ineffective. Ct. says D would not be N if not for the common carrier wrinkle that obligates a higher standard Summary judgment denied and goes to jury L = relatively low ; P = low; B=tiny (small nets) iv. Allowable higher risk for saving a child: Eckert v. Long Island Railroad (NY, 1871, 196) P runs in front of train to save a child on tracks. Dies from collision with train. P was not N. Life is a very valuable and allows for higher risk. Also an emergency situation. P had reasonable belief that he could save the child and himself (was not rash or reckless given the PL.) Breach of CUSTOMS: standard known to potential D’s Assume rational players will have incentives to meet standard under N standard 15 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Generally: Is custom safety related? If not then doesn’t really matter. Custom in the community is admissible as evidence of the standard of care, but it is never conclusive. A custom may found to be negligent. Great sword, but bad shield. Most traction in medical malpractice cases. Compliance with custom is evidence of due care, but non-compliance is not necessarily evidence of negligence. The use of custom in setting standard of due care allows the benefit of some community knowledge. The community has already dealt with the calculus of risk, so we can trust it to do things right. I. The Sword and the Shield 1. Duty a. Theory 2. Breach i. Pros: a. Reasonable 1. Expertise Person (under the 2. Certainty circumstances) 3. Choice (CJ) b. Calculus of Risk 4. Efficiency (utility)—industry self adjusts (B<PLN) customs c. Custom ii. Cons d. Statutes and regulations 1. Risk of inefficiency: custom may not be e. Rule of Law reasonable 3. Causation 2. Without customs, people may think a. Res Ipsa inaction is okay 3. D sets rules (can set custom to least L) 4. Slow to change (time lag, fail to pick up efficiently) 5. Stranger is not put on notice (unaware of customs) 6. Evidence of but not conclusive determinant of rule 7. Problematic when some companies set bar higher than custom (held to self-established higher standards disincentive for others to set high standards) b. Shield: if there is no custom, D is not N (unless less than reasonable care) i. When the Shield works: 1. Titus v. Bradford (Pa. 1890) (p221) P, employee, gets run over by train when he jumps onto tracks in attempt to avoid being crushed by round bottomed cars on insecure cargo. D is not N. Non-stranger interaction (P is aware of custom.) Moves away from pure N. ii. When Shied does not work: custom is lower than reasonable duty of care (Compliance with custom is non-negligent, but not decisive) 16 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng 1. Mayhew v. Sullivan Mining Co. (1884, p223) Independent contracts falls through hole that D had dug without warning to P. D failed to put up a railway, saying it was not custom. D is N. D was acting according to custom of business (ie no want of ordinary care.) but that does not mean no N—it’s common sense and ordinary duty of care. 2. Variation From Custom May Ground Liability The T.J. Hooper I (D.S.N.Y. 1931, 191) T.J. Hooper and the Montrose, neither of which were equipped with working radios, lost two barges and their load of coal on their way from VA to NY, in a gale off the coat of NJ. Four other tugs, on the same route, received warnings of the gale from the radio and took safe harbor. Failure to meet the normal standard of seaworthiness by failing to conform to commonly held and applied standards of care, such as the use of weather warning devices, may be found negl when a loss of prop. could have been avoided by the use of ubiquitous and standard sea faring technologies. 3. The Issue is Cost/Benefit, Not Custom. The T.J. Hooper II : no established custom to have the radio sets but ∆ is still liable because the failure to have these radios amounts to a failure to exercise reasonable prudence. Injury was a direct consequence of the unseaworthiness. Custom is not in and of itself enough to alleviate negligence, nor is its want enough to require a finding of negligence. 4. Lucy Webb Hayes Nat’l Training School v. Perotti (p229): psychiatric hospital incident where D sets internal rules higher than custom, but is found N when they fail to meet their own standards. c. Sword: If there is a custom, D is definitely N for not meeting it i. Asymmetry: should we be more ready to punish when they do not meet custom than when there is no custom (wield sword most often than using the shield) ii. Lama v. Borras (F.3d, 1994)(p231) D (physician) fails to prescribe conservative treatment and proper pre and post surgery care (for ex., no antibiotic regiment). P gets infection. Nurses/hospital have improper method that delays his diagnosis. a. D is N. D fails to meet national standard of care. Hospital is also N for insufficient standards of nurse reports which delayed diagnosis. b. Causation problem: surgery may have been necessary anyway, even given the conservative treatment. c. Was the infection caused by surgery or poor post-op choices? 17 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Medical Malpractice: where custom has the most force even if potentially fails BPL calculus 1. Custom (Lama v. Borras) a. National standard—local variations not adequate (Brune v. Belinkoff) Because it is such a specialized find that we allow them to self-regulate (fact finder has very difficult time assessing N) b. Expertise level i. Expert class: higher standard for board certified doctors ii. Beginner class: lower standards for interns (strays from earlier forgiving standard): p242 c. Two battling schools of custom (compliance to either is fine) d. Disclosure i. Problems teasing out a custom: 1. Complexity and variety of what physicians do is very complex no identifiable customs to disclose 2. Different standards for different people? (different patients are psychologically affected by different info) 3. Solution: Reasonable Disclosure under the circumstances standard Doctor can start with objective person rules and then move to reasonable person under the circumstances, adjusting as he sees fit. ii. Informed consent (physician is obliged to provide material info to a reasonable person in the position that the doctor knows that the patient is in. This is subjective to the extent of notice of patient’s peculiarities harm operating through the vehicle of patient’s choice, which is subject to hindsight bias system tries to keep it objective as a result. 1. Canterbury v. Spence (DC, 1972, 244) P suffers permanent damage from operation. D did not disclose risks prior to operation.D is obligated to disclose “all perils bearing significance” (Any decision that could reasonably be expected to change his decision about treatment; in the capacity that doctor knows the patient, adjusting to individual circumstances. For example, don’t treat the foot fetishist the same as the normal person.) iii. Exceptions to duty to disclose 1. risk-disclosure poses such a threat as to be a detriment to the patient to make treatment infeasible 2. emergency circumstances (constructive consent) 3. patient is incapable of consenting (must get consent of family) 4. incredibly obvious disclosures (ie risk of infection), 5. incredibly rare possibilities/ materiality of risks known at the time (see United Blood Services v. Quintana, p255: AIDS case) or if disclosure is not in the patient’s best interests 18 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng (Information would lead to make an obviously poor choice, though this is still debated on for reasons of patient autonomy) 2. Reasonable Patient Standard (RPS): would a reasonable patient given all the relevant information, wanted the surgery? a. Paternalistic argument vs. Patient Autonomy: “Doctor knows best?”: D argues that full disclosure could produce psychological effects that unreasonably deters patient from getting the surgery (saying that Dr. can do the BPL best) b. Causation under RPS: If prudent patient in P’s circumstances would have made different decision, then causation is established (Quintanta, p255) c. Established when P would have chosen another route had he had all the relevant facts (This risks hindsight bias) 3. Medical Malpractice Theory a. Mello and Brennan Deterrence of Medical Errors: deterrence doesn’t really work because costs are externalized (other payers, such as med insurance foot the ill for N), making deterrence difficult and confuse the economic incentives to improve. Deterrent effect operates primarily on institutional level b. physicians are overly sued Breach: STATUTES AND REGULATIONS Rest2nd 286 (266): When standard of conduct defined by legislation or regulation will be adopted: The court may adopt as the standard of conduct of a reasonable man the requirements of legislative enactment or an administrative regulation whose purpose is found to be exclusively or in part (a) to protect a class of persons which includes the one whose interest is invaded and (b) to protect he particular interest which is invaded and (c) to protect that interest against the kind of harm which has resulted and (d) to protect that interest against the particular hazard from which the harm results. 1. 2. 3. Duty Breach a. Reasonable Person (under the circumstances) b. Calculus of Risk (B<PLN) c. Custom d. Statutes and regulations e. Rule of Law Causation a. Res Ipsa Rule 14: Statutory violation as Negligence per se: An actor is N if, without excuse, the actor violates a statute that is designed to protect against the type of accident the actor’s conduct causes and if the accident victim is within the class of persons the statute is designed to protect. (Restatement of the Law of Torts: Liability for Physical Harm) 19 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Generally: If you can sue under statute(explicit or implicitly) Π doesn’t need to prove negligence(majority view). Violation of statute creates negligence per se. When a statute explicitly creates a private remedy for those injured, the court merely need follow the statutory command. When a statute is silent, the courts must decide whether a private right to action may be implied. They ask: 1) Whether the plaintiff is one of the class for whose particular benefit the statute was enacted i. Coulter v. Superior Court (Ca., 1978, p279): bartender serves drunkard alcohol and the latter harms 3rd party. Court says bartender is proximately liable, but later, CA legislation is passed to say there is no proximate liability for bartenders. ii. Osbourne v. McMasters (Minn 1889, p265) D sued for selling poison in drug store without labeling it as so. D is N (affirmed prior decision) D violated statute and P is granted a common law remedy. D argues that there is no common law liability existent, but court says that the consumer was the party that the legislation meant to protect. 2) Whether recognition of a private right of action would promote the legislative purpose, and (Gorris and Kernan) iii. Statute designed to protect the interest invaded: Uhr v. East Greenbush Cent. School (NY, 1999, p280) School is expressly insulated from liability when they fail to administer the scoliosis test. There is no statutory duty. Statute’s immunity provision was meant to insulate schools against private action with the goal of minimizing costs in mind (no intent of allowing private litigation in mind.) b. Statute designed to protect that interest against the particular hazard from which the harm results. i. Statute designed to protect that interest against the kind of harm which has resulted (scope of harm) : Martin v. Herzog (NY, 1920, p270)P killed after collision with Ds car. P was driving without lights. PH said that driving without lights is not N. Reversed on appeal and P is found negligent because lights is a violation of statute requiring lights and this violation was the cause of the accident. P is C.N. 20 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng 3) Whether creation of the right would be consistent with the legislative scheme (Uhr) Showing of these elements often creates a negligence per se situation However, the converse does not apply: proving that one is in compliance with all stat. does not protect from negligence claim. Care sometimes must be taken beyond that proscribed by stat. Defenses to application (excuses for violating statute): (1) D unaware of stat; (2) D reasonably and diligently attempted to comply with stat; (3) emergency not of D’s own design; (4) compliance would have involved an increase risk of harm. Theory of Statutory violations: Enacted to protect a class of citizens and is determined by legislature Pros: o Closes off jury from making decisions based on reasonable standard o Avoids the too-low standards or faulty custom o Encourages private enforcement o Avoids pitfalls of relying on experts Cons o Grey areas o Interpreting what the intent of the statues are o D’s slipping through the cracks (p269: when P’s aren’t in the category meant to be protected or if the “mischief” wasn’t the mischief the statute sought to avoid. For example: the sheep in Gorris v. Scott p268 were nt the party the legislation meant to protect) Exceptions: when there is a custom that promotes the goal/intent of legislation (ie walking against traffic, p272) Breach: RULE OF LAW Generally, If an act was negligent as a matter of law(negligent per se), the judge will so instruct the jury. Thus, the “proper” standard of care is given the effect of law by the courts. If an act is not negligent per se, the judge will leave it to the jury to determine whether the act was negligent. This procedure has been adopted in order to prevent injuries from being overly swayed by their emotions. 21 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Holmes: If courts left everything to the jury, we would be saying that there is an inability to state a very large part of the law which the D is required to know, and would suggest that nothing could be learned by experience. Setting a common law rule is useful because it is o a predictable/knowable rule (lower transaction costs, higher uniformity) o promotes higher level of safety o truck driver may be CCA o court has ability to hire experts to investigate o policy aims and choices. Negligence per se: Baltimore and Ohio R.R. v. Goodman (US, 1927, p290) D is run over by train which crossing tracks in war even though he was reasonably careful. However his sight was blocked by a building. PH verdict for D. Reversed on appeal (D was CN to put himself in danger.) Holmes says that a man should know that the train will not stop for him. Ct. Created Duty is Not Absolute. (Goodman rule ignored here): Pokora v. Wabash Ry. (US, 1934, p291): P, in truck, tries to stop/look/listen but doesn’t see/hear anything so he drives across, getting run over. PH verdict for D saying P was CN for not getting out of car to check. Reversed on appeal. Getting out is an “uncommon practice” and potentially dangerous, not to mention probably useless in the end (by the time a P gets back into the car and starts it, their activity would have already been useless) CAUSATION : P’s Tools: RIL; Smoking Out 1. 2. Rest2d 328D (302): Res Ipsa Loquiteur: (1) It may be inferred that harm suffered by the P is caused by negligence of the D when (a) The event is of a kind which ordinarily does not occur in the absence of N (b) other responsible causes, including the conduct of the P and third persons, are sufficiently eliminated by the evidence; and (c) the indicated N is within the scope of the D’s duty to the P (2) It is the function of the court to determine whether the inference may be reasonable drawn by the jury, or whether it must be necessarily drawn. (3) It is the function of the jury to determine whether the inference is to be drawn in any case where different conclusions may be reasonably reached. 3. Duty Breach a. Reasonable Person (under the circumstances) b. Calculus of Risk (B<PLN) c. Custom d. Statutes and regulations e. Rule of Law Causation a. P’s tools i. Res Ipsa b. D’s tools i. Contributory Neg ii. A/R 22 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng “Res Ipsa Loquitar”: The thing speaks for itself invoked when π seeks to establish ∆’s negligence from circumstantial evidence The doctrine allows the plaintiff’s case to reach the jury when ordinarily the case will be lost. RIL Test: - the action does not ordinarily occur without negligence - the action must be caused by an instrumentality within the exclusive control of the defendant - action must not occur due to the voluntary action on the part the plaintiff Where RIL gets Π: 1) Most common allows case to go to jury based on assumed breach of duty of care 2) Other places make proving RIL a prima facie case, which then shifts burden to D to prove otherwise 3) Some approaches go as far to allow judge to find on directed verdict without submitting to jury. Defenses: Offer alternative explanations for injury other than Δs negligence Showing that injuries frequently happen without negligence. Showing that Δ did not have control, or that someone else did. I. Unknown causation: Pathway to the harm is unknown: RIL a. Classic Example: The event is of a kind which ordinarily does not occur in the absence of N: Byrne v. Boadle (Engl, 1863, p299): P is hit by barrel falling out of window of D’s shop. PH verdict for D (P could not furnish evidence of causation.) Reversed on appeal (P is not burdened to prove what the specific causes was—the fact that it happened proves N.) b. Other responsible causes, including the conduct of the P and third persons, are sufficiently eliminated by the evidence i. No Res Ipsa w/o Foreseeability and Exclusive Control. Larson v. St. Francis Hotel (p302): St. Francis was not held liable for chair that flew out of window during V-J day celebrations. Hotel has no mastery over their furniture. ii. Connolly v. Nicollet Hotel (p303): Nicollet Hotel is held liable for debauchery of Junior Chamber of Commerce national convention. c. the indicated N is within the scope of the D’s duty to the P: Exclusive Control Element can be Met by 3rd Party where Duty is Non-Delegable i. Colmenares Vivas v. Sun Alliance Insurance Co. (Puerto Rico, 1986, p307) P is injured when escalator malfunctions. Res Ipsa applied. D 23 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng had exclusive control of escalator even though the maintenance was handled by a contractor, Westinhouse. (RI can apply even when D shares responsibility with another arty, but D is ultimately responsible Westinhouse does not destroy Res Ipsa’s no 3rd party prerequisite) D’s duty of care is non-delegable. II. Specific D is unknown: Smoking Out a. Ybarra v. Spangard (Cal. 1944, p316) P is partially paralyzed after appendectomy. PH verdict for D, non-suit. Reversed on appeal. i. Diversity of D’s does not render RI inapplicable because all assistants and nurses are agents of head surgeon. ii. Causation: the fact that P is injured is evidence enough. b. “Smoke Out”: burden shift from P to D: sue everyone and hope that correct will D will emerge by threatening liability to everyone. i. Appropriate when D’s have more info than P (asymmetric knowledge) and it is knowable knowledge (someone has the information) ii. 3rd restatement rejects the smoke-out/asymmetric information agreement Issues of determination: how to know if the harm is caused by negligence or coincidence? Hypo: faulty hand grenade causes harm. How do we know if it’s Res Ipsa negligence or it’s just the 1/1000 chance that occurs even without negligence? Kaye (p314) #3 addresses this: “the probability of the injury given reasonable care is much smaller than the probability of the injury given N” D’S TOOLS: CONTRIBUTORY NEGLIGENCE (complete bar) Most states have gotten rid of CN in favor of Comparative Fault. Rule 465: Causal Relation between harm and Plaintiff’s Negligence: (1) The P’s N is a legally contributing cause of his harm IF BUT ONLY IF, it is a substantial factor in bringing about his harm and there is no rule restricting his responsibility for it. (2) The rules which determine the causal relation between the P’s negligent conduct and the harm resulting to him are the same as those determining the causal relation between the D’s negligent conduct and resulting harm to others. Reasonable Care of P Standard Butterfield v. Forrester (Eng., 1809, 328) P was riding hard (and possibly drunk) and failed to see an obstacle in the road that a reasonable person probably would have seen. P injures himself as a result. Verdict for D, P was CN (opposed to SL) Cooter and Porat: “Does risk to oneself increase the case owed to others? Law and economics in conflict.” One should calculate net 1. 2. 3. Duty Breach a. Reasonable Person (under the circumstances) b. Calculus of Risk (B<PLN) c. Custom d. Statutes and regulations e. Rule of Law Causation c. P’s tools i. Res Ipsa d. D’s tools i. Contributory Neg ii. A/R 24 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng cost of burden (harm to self and harm to others Hand neglects to also count driver’s self-imposed risk and savings in BPL calculus): PL(others) B – PL(self)* *PL(self) is a net gain Therefore, B PL(others) + PL (self) Non-stranger interactions: Employees Beens v. Chicago, Rock Island and Peoria R.R. (Iowa 1882, p329) P is run over when trying to uncouple two unsafe cars. P had signaled to engineers onboard to slow down the train, but they failed to do so. P’s foot was caught in the track and then was run over. Verdict of P (no CN) Gyerman v. US Lines Co. (Cal. 1972, p333) P is injured during unloading incorrectly stacked stacks of fishmeal. He noticed the dangerous potential, but failed to report it to supervisor. 3 days later, he is injured by a falling stack H: D did not meet burden of proof in showing P’s CN case remanded to determine P’s CN.) o P claims it was not unreasonable to continue to work while D claims that P was obligated to report the circumstances. Ct. determines that D failed to show that, if P had reported the incident, it would have absolutely prevented injury and removed the risk. The rules which determine the causal relation between the P’s negligent conduct and the harm resulting to him are the same as those determining the causal relation between the D’s negligent conduct and resulting harm to others. Smithwick v. Hall and Upson Co. (p340) D warns P to stay away from site lest he fall. P ignores this and ventures onto site. House falls on P. Verdict for P (no CN) because the resulting harm is not “within the risk” that made it dangerous for P to venture over in the first place. Sequential N Durheim v. N. Fiorito Co. (Wash., 1972, p345) D makes illegal left turn and runs into P, who is not wearing a seat belt. H verdict for P (no CN). P’s act of CN occurred before D’s N and D cannot say that P’s CN had any contributory effect on the accident itself (only the extent of injury, but P cannot be made to shoulder that burden.) Mahoney v. Beatman (p340) P was speeding in Rolls, D looses focus and veers into oncoming Rolls, sideswiping it. P veers out of control and crashes. D is liable for all damage even though the second crash (the big damage) probably wouldn’t have happened if P had not been speeding. Nonetheless, P is not CN and awarded full remedy. CN vs. SL: Leroy Fibre Co., v. Chicago, Milwaukee & St. Paul Ry. (US 340, 1914, p342) P is flax farmer who piled his flax within distance of tracks. Sparks from tracks burn his flax. Verdict for P (P not CN.) Mckenna says P has right to enjoy his property: SL: Holmes says P’s flax was too near (not reasonably safe distance from tracks): N 25 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Last Clear Chance/Gross negligence Fuller v. Illinois Central R.R. (Miss., 1911, p350) P is old man on donkey and fails to move out of the way of oncoming train, even though D signaled with whistle. D had last clear chance (enough time) to stop and save P, but failed to do so. P’s CN does not excuse P’s gross negligence. D was going faster than usual (breach of custom) and P is helpless. Question of knowledge: o Should D know P is helpless? D did not know but should have seen P had no reasonable way to save himself even given he is CN (D has LCC)P wins D knew, but continued anyway (D is in superior situation to know that information and to act, as well as LCC) P wins D had no reason to know D wins o Should D know P is inattentive? D knows and has LCC P wins D should know but doesn’t P wins (unless recklessness) D has not reason to know D wins o Should D know P is reckless D knows D wins D should know but doesn’t D wins D has no reason to know D wins D’s Tools: Assumption of Risk (bar on damages) EXPRESS (Contracted) ASSUMED RISK I. PRIMARY A/R (no duty of care or no breach of duty owed) II. IMPLIED A/R (A/R as affirmative defense against breach of duty of care) Express (Contracted) Assumed Risk Primary A/R (no duty of care or no breach of duty) o Lamson v. American Axe & Tool Co. (Mass 1900, p360) P injured from fallen hatchet on unsafe drying rack. P had already complained to employer about the potential risk and was told to take it or leave it. P stayed on and then was injured. P knew the risks, but stayed on the job he assumed the risk. Opposed to Gyerman (p333) which considers the probability of the harm being solved by a report. Employer/Employee relationship: risks are sometimes contracted into the salary (Fireman’s rule) o Dalury v.S-K-I Ltd. (Vt. 1995, p374) P signs full waiver in order to purchase a season pass in ski report. Runs into a pole and sues. Ct. says one cannot K around duty of care. One cannot enforce exculpatory agreements of this kind. 26 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Public Policy: “Premises liability”/ Affirmative duty of care (akin to Common Carrier standard) cannot contract around this Tunkl formula: cannot apply exculpatory agreements if it meets some or all of the following: It is a regulated industry Service is open to all public or all members of public meeting requirements (ex, ticket buyers) P was helpless in encountering the risk Service of essential nature (P lacks bargaining power) o Obstetrics and Gynecologists Ltd. v. Pepper (p378) P is forced to sign an adhesion contract (take it or leave it) in order to obtain care. P does not understand the terms, suffers stroke afterwards. Verdict for P (binding arbitration clause not applicable because D cannot prove a binding agreement had occurred.) Ct. rules that adhesion contracts are not enforceable if not within the reasonable exepectations of the weaker or “adhering” party” (#3 in Tunkl formula) Implied A/R ((A/R as affirmative defense against breach of duty of care) o Implied Assumption of Risk Primary A/R: P assumes risk of being non-negligently harmed. (No duty of care breached because D was not N.) Ex: In a football game, there is not longer a duty to watch where one’s going when both parties are players. However, each party still has a duty to play football in a reasonable manner (the only duty owed is careful football playing. P can still claim N if D plays football negligently.) Murphey v. Steeplechase Amusement Co. (NY 1929, p365) P gets on Coney Island ride, “The Flopper” and breaks kneecap from a sudden jerk. P had clear view of the risk . No express K to assume risk (no waiver of rights) but there is implied A/R. o One can assume R only if they know enough to do so. However, even knowing the risks, there are some that are too extreme to assume (though not the case here.) o Perhaps D was N for not having adequate padding in ride (not covered by reasonable assumed risk of P) Meistrich v. Casio Arena (NJ 1959, p371) P went on ill-prepared ice rink. D was N in not preparing it well. There was no waiver (P only agreed to regular skating risks even though he knew ice was slippery.) Secondary A/R: A subset of Comparative Fault: P consciously takes an unreasonable risk (N risk taking) (full defense, D is absolved) 27 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng P takes conscious, but reasonable risk (non-N risk taking) (Eckert v. Long Island RR) (Courts split, some say P should be able to recover while others say P had notice and this almost looks like an express A/R) COMPARATIVE FAULT Restatement (3d) of Torts- Apportionment of L (p399); Rule 7: Effect of Plaintiff’s Negligence when P suffers an indivisible injury: P’s N (or the N of another person for whose N the P is responsible) that is a legal cause of an indivisible injury to the P reduces the P’s recovery in proportion to the share of responsibility the factfinder assigns to the P (or other person for whose N the P is responsible) Comparative Fault Proximate cause and CN do not explain LCC where P is still allowed to recover. Prosser suggests that the explanation for the acceptance to the rule of barring P’s relief is the 19th century mentality and the IR, during which courts saw the rule as a “convenient instrument of control over the jury, by which the liabilities of rapidly growing industry were curbed and kept within bounds.” Prosser: CN (p383) 1. 2. 3. Duty Breach a. Reasonable person b. BPL c. Custom d. Statutes e. Law Causation a. Res Ipsa b. Cont. Neg. c. A/R d. Comp. Fault Common Law evolution: Landmark case: Li v. Yellow Cab Co. of California (Cal. 1975, p384) P drives through 3 lanes of oncoming traffic to get to service stop and is then hit by D, who sped through a yellow light. PH verdict for D (P is CN and barred from relief.) Reversed on appeal. CN fails to distribute fault inequitable Section 1714 of the Civil Code does not say that the “all or nothing” rule reigns supreme o The intent of the legislature was not to make CN immune, but rather just to codify and formulate existing common law. Court has right to change it (and indeed is encouraged to help it evolve.) Practical difficulties in determining CF can be surmounted o Hard for fact finder to evaluate CF when all responsible parties are not present o Difficulty of actually assigning the correct proportions. Can be solved by giving guidelines to juries to assist it in keeping focused upon the true inquiry, and the utilization of special verdicts or jury interrogatories o LLC and A/R statutes LLC disappears when a true CF system is in place. A/R is included in assessing liability in proportion o Willful misconduct CN does not apply to willful or wanton misconduct “Pure form” of CF is better than CN “50% rule” o Pure form: proportional L for proportional fault. 28 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng o 50% rule: apportionment based on fault up to the point at which the Ps N is greater than or equal to D’s fault. At this point, P is barred from relief. (Court says this is a distortion of the very concept of CF) New rule should be given a limited retrospective application creates good incentives for future parties to “bring up issues involving renovation of unsound or outmoded legal doctrines.” it seemed unfair to give Li CF, but not others before who tried the same defense. Joint and Several liability Joint liability: several obligors (any person who bears an obligation) can be responsible for the entire loss if the others are unable to pay Several liability: each obligor has an obligation parallel to that of the others. The share of any final judgment against one parts is not increased by the default of another Joint-and-Several liability: obligors are joint to the obligee but bear several liability amongst themselves (if all are available to pay.) American Motorcycle Association v. Superior Court (Cal. 1978, p409) Former D appeals from decision of court that did not allow D to claim CN of P’s parents as previously unjoined alleged concurrent tortfeasors. Verdict for P (trial court should permit AMA to do this) AMA argues that after Li there is a basis for dividing damages on CF basis. Ct agrees, but says this case is not a divisible injury (no proof that N of another proximately contributed to injury) Ct rejects this, saying that P’s failure to use due care for himself is not tortuous and thus not applicable a. Doctrine of partial equitable indemnity should be adopted at common law to permit apportionment of loss among coD’s on pure comparative principle. (permit a concurrent tortfeasor to obtain partial indemnity from other concurrent tortfeasors on a comparative fault basis.) b. California’s contribution statutes do not preclude the court from adopting comparative partial indemnity as a modification of the common law equitable indemnity doctrine (tortfeasor who has entered in good faith settlement with P should be allowed to claim from concurrent tortfeasors any partial or comparative indemnity. Direct Causation: Cause in Fact: Substantial factor test: whether D’s conduct was a “substantial factor” in producing the harm. I. Cause in Fact (tortuous conduct was necessary condition to the occurrence of injury/P would not have been injured absent tortuous conduct of D.) a. But For Test : Would, but for D’s N, P have suffered injury or harm? i. NO: cause-in-fact proved ii. YES: D not liable 29 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng b. Substantial factor test (D’s N was major factor, and makes the injury more probably than not) Can be seen as a variation of the But For Test c. Eliminate other possible causes i. Expert testimony: Daubert v. Merrell Dow (trial courts make preliminary assessment of reliability/applicability of testimony) d. Multiple Causes/Indeterminate Causes (an alternative to conventional test) i. Injury caused by Multiple Sufficient Causes 1. Two Simultaneous Causes, a. Both negligent: both L (better overdeterrence than underdeterrence) b. One N, one NOT N: courts split (but for test not satisfied, some hold negligent D liable, others do not.) 2. Sequential causes: Pre-emptive causation (Assuming both are N, only 1st D is L) e. Joint and Several Liability: P can only recover full extent of his harm (if he collects fully from one D, he cannot collect from other D) D’s have right of contribution from other tortfeasors, and, with comparative negligence, usually only has to pay for the amount of harm caused by his individual negligence. i. Joint Tortfeasors ii. Independent tortfeasors J/S liable for a single, theoretically indivisible harm (two cars both run red lights and one runs into a pedestrian neither alone would have been sufficient to cause the injury, however, no way to pinpoint the extent of each D’s causal responsibility.) iii. Independent tortfeasors J/S liable for a single, theretically divisible but particially indivisible harm. (Ex: one D caused one collision and second D caused second collision. Harm is indivisible for practical purposes, though each D is entitled to prove how much harm it caused.) f. Indeterminate Causes i. Alternative liability: burden shifts to each D to prove he did NOT cause the harm (Summers v. Tice) ii. Industry-wide liability: though D’s might not have acted together to cause injuries, threat of liability might encourage relatively small industries to act together to prevent industry to encourage safety. (Hall v. E.I Du Pont) iii. Last Chance Doctrine: (Medmal): already injured or ill P’s chance of recovery/survival are reduced by D’s N. 1. Usually D is liable for the reduction in the decendent’s chances of suriving (loss of 10% = 10% of damages.) PP issue of not encouraging doc’s to let people die when they already have bad chances at life. 30 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng iv. Market – Share Liability (rarely used.): each P can recover from each D a portion of her damages equal to each D’s share of the market: Sindell v. Abbot Labs (DES for pregnant women.) TEST: 1. “signature disease”: disease caused only by exposure to the product (100% of the market caused 100% of the harm) 2. All D’s produce a chemically identity product (Skipworth v. Lead Industries: no market-share L because D’s produced chemically different lead paint.) 3. Relevant market data is available 4. Substantial share of the market is represented in the suit (substantial number of D’s are named addresses the issue of D’s who have gone out of business, etc.) v. Unknown P’s: Toxic Harms and Statistical Proof of Causation: identified D has caused the injury but not possible to prove which P’s D has inujured. 1. Rely on statistical data (courts reluctant to do this.) Proximate Causation: 31 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Generally Causation = Cause in Fact + Proximate Causation The proximate cause requirement is a policy determination that a defendant, even one who has behaved negligently, should not automatically be liable for all the consequences, no matter how improbable or far-reaching, of his act. Today, the proximate cause requirement usually means that D will not be liable for the consequences that are very unforeseeable. Two Co-Existing Standards (both are still used, but Foreseeability is more common): o Directness (Polemis): if the harm is a direct consequence of the negligent act, proximate causation is established regardless of foreseeability o Foreseeability (Wagon Mound): limits proximate causation only where the risk imposed would have been foreseeable, both in kind of injury and person injured, by a reasonable person at the time of the negligent act Manner: Still liable if outcome is foreseeable even if the means to that outcome is novel or unique. Extent: Still liable for all the damages, though only a modicum of damages would have been expected (Vosburg). Improbability: Still liable even for highly unlikely results if they are foreseeable (Wagon Mound 2). Class of P’s: Though injury to a particular individual may not be foreseeable, liability will still lie when the P is of a class of people for which foreseeability of harm attaches (Palsgraf) Directness Standard: In Re Polemis and Furness, Withy & Co. (Eng. 1921, 452) (still good law in most US jurisdictions) Facts: ∆s unloading π’s ship and negligently dropped a plank into the storage hold striking an unknown substance or object, creating a spark which ignited the petroleum carried by the ship and it blew up. H: Once the negligence of a party has been established liability holds for consequences of the conduct, foreseeable or not. Damages are not too remote. So long as the damage is in fact directly traceable to the negligent act, and not due to the operation of independent causes having no connection with the negligent act. Once the act is negligent, the fact that its exact operation was not foreseen is immaterial. The Foreseeability Test. Wagon Mound No. 1 (Overseas Tankship v. Morts Dock) (Aus. 1961, 471) Facts: D carelessly discharged oil from their ship while berthed in Sydney harbor. The oil drifted over and pooled around P's shipbuilding dock, where welding operations were ongoing. The P’s dock supervisor suspended welding operations until he determined that the oil was not flammable while it was floating on the water, and when the welding was recommenced, the sparks set fire to some debris floating in the oil slick, and a conflagration ensued which destroyed the dock. H: No liability exists where the cause of harm is not reasonably foreseeable. 32 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Rationale: A person is only liable for the probable consequences of his negligent acts. The probable consequences are judged by the standard of foreseeability by the reasonable man. Significance of details test: The Wagon Mound rule of foreseeability of damages presents problems when the damages are neither routine nor freakish, but in the middle. Then the test becomes significance; if the unusualness of the details is significant in the outcome of the damage, then the damage was unforeseeable; if not significant, then the damage was foreseeable. The thin skull rule, or "you take your victim as you find him": left unshaken by Wagon Mound. (See Steinhauser v. Hertz Corp, 542, child developed schizophrenia after car crash. P awarded damages) Wagon Mound No. 2 (Overseas Tankship v. Miller Steamship) (Aus. 1967, 474) Facts: same as above, except here P lost his ship in fire H: Ships engineer should have known that oil would possibly be ignited if discharged into harbor; foreseeability is shown. D is liable for a remote, but foreseeable risk. American Response to Polemis and Wagon Mound : Kinsman Transit Co. (2nd Cir. 1964, 478), American Courts reject the foreseeability test where the consequences of the action are direct, such as in Polemis. "Unforeseeability is irrelevant if damage is direct" when a ship broke loose from its moorings, and drifted downstream to eventually block the river and cause substantial flooding damage. They reasoned that just because the risk of large damage is slight, that it should not be excused if it was direct. Manner: Doughty v. Turner Mfg. Co., Ltd. (541) the court held that when an asbestos lid was dropped into a vat of boiling chemicals, damage by splashing was foreseeable, but not damage by violent explosion. Contrast Hughes v. Lord Advocate, where the explosion of a paraffin lamp was held to be foreseeable, because it was not a "different type" of damage than that by burning. Improbability Georgia Ry. v. Price (GA 1898, 442), π dropped off at wrong RR stop, spent the night in a hotel b/c of it, hotel sets fire, π sues RR. Harm held to be too remote. Hines v. Gaerrett (VA 1921, 442), π dropped off at wrong RR stop, had to walk home, raped twice on the way back. ∆’s negligence directly exposed π to risk causing harm, π wins. (May have been PP policy) Virden v. Betts and Beer Construction Company (2003, 545) P, a maintenance worker at a high school, gets up on a ladder to fix a defect in the ceiling, and falls off ladder, injuring himself. Defect in the ceiling was a result of negligent installation by the contractor, D. P claims that the defect in the ceiling was the cause of his injuries H: D is not legal cause of injuries D’s N is not proximate cause even if it is cause in fact. The duty to install a solid ceiling is meant to prevent against it from falling and harming someone, not to protect against workmen getting on ladders. Proximate cause should 33 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng be defined by the purpose of the duty. Herbert v. Enos (2004, 547) D negligently lets his toilet overflow and P is electrocuted in his yard while watering his plants. The water had gotten into the electrical system and P suffered severe electrical shock when he touched the faucet. D is not liable because negligence is too remote. Cause in fact is met but proximate cause is not because there was no reasonable expectation that electrocution would happen if the toilet overflowed. The result was so extraordinary that the defendant cannot be expected to guard against it. Proximate cause cannot be found if a result is so extraordinary that it cannot be foreseen. Ryan v. New York Central R.R. (N.Y. 1966, 436) D negligently maintained one of its engines, which gave off sparks that set fire to its woodshed. The fire spread to Ps house, located nearby, and consumed it. The destruction of D’s own shed is the “ordinary and natural result” of the negligent operation of the engine, but the damage of P’s house is too remote. This is no longer good law, but does indicate beginnings of foreseeability Class of P’s Palsgraf v. Long Island R.R. (N.Y. 1928, 456) Man running to board D’s train, D workers help man on train, in process had his package jostled loose. Fireworks in the package exploded on the rails, when they fell, causing scales at the other end of the platform to fall, injuring P. H: (Cardozo, J.) : unforeseeable P’s are not covered because they are not within the scope of the risk (thus Ry’s duty to Paslgraf was not breached because harm was not foreseeable.) D violated no duty to P as to whom there was no foreseeable risk. Dissent: (Andrews, J.) P’s injury was within the scope of D’s N, regardless of foreseeability of victim (there was proximate causes, duty does not matter.) D bears a burden of due care to “protect society from unnecessary danger, not to protect A, B, or C alone.” Andrews uses a worth while metaphor: into a stream flow many tributaries and for a while it may be possible to distinguish from where one drop of water comes, but eventually they all blend to one. This is similar to attempting to trace an effect to its harm—after a time, the distinction of what effect caused the harm. Law arbitrarily picks that point. 34 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Third Parties & Causation Intervening Causes: an “intervening cause” is a force which takes place after ∆’s negligence and contributes to the negligence producing π’s harm o some intervening causes are sufficient to prevent ∆’s negligence from being held to be the proximate cause of the injury. There are called “superseding causes” Generally courts use the foreseeability rule to determine whether an intervening cause is superseding: if neither the intervening cause nor the kind of harm was foreseeable, the intervening cause will supersede ∆’s liability Coincidence: where the negligent act exposes π to the risk and that risk occurs, ∆ is proximate cause (Hines v. Garrett, 442) Independent and dependent causation: where a second cause is dependent on the first negligent act in order to impose a harm, the secondary harm is considered “dependent” and ∆ is only liable for the incremental damages. (Dillon v. Twin State Gas & Electric, 442) When each of two successive acts is sufficient to harm the P, but the P is exposed to the 2nd cause only because prior negligence of 1st: Dillon v. Twin State Gas & Electric: boy lost balance while trespassing on bridge and grabs D’s high voltage wires as he fell. Current kills him, but D is only liable for boy’s exposure to the uncovered wires, not his fall (P was deprived of only seconds) If the P acts in good faith to minimize the risk of loss from a dangerous situation of D’s making, then those actions do not sever causal connection. Jones v. Boyce; Tuttle v. Atlantic City (p501) What Does and Does Not Interrupt Causation? deLisle: Strong natural forces usually interrupt; Reactive and instinctive forces usually interrupt, unless caused by hypersensitivity or other anomalous conditions like mild dementia (full blown hallucinations, however do exculpate, remember Batman in Breunig); independent and reflective acts do not nec. interrupt (Wagner); criminal and tortous acts do not nec. interrupt (Brower). R2 §448: Causation where ∆ Negligently Creates an Opportunity for Criminal Activity ∆ is not liable for damages occurring by a 3rd party’s criminal activity even where ∆ created the opportunity for that criminal activity to occur through a negligent act Unless ∆ had reason to know the likelihood that his act would create such a situation and that a 3rd party might avail himself of the opportunity to commit a crime. 35 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Brower v. New York Central & H.R.R. (N.J. 1918, 444): D’s N freight train collided with P cart allowing bystanders to steal P’s goods. D claims that 3rd parties break causation. Court held Negligent D is liable for foreseeable harms of intervening third parties. Cargo was "lost" at the time of the accident because it put P in a position such that he could not protect his cargo. The intervention of the thieves was deemed foreseeable by the D because they employed their own detectives to prevent theft. Dissent: The chain of causation was broken by the intervening criminal acts. See Watson v. Kentucky (tank care with gas derailed b/c of D’s N. 3rd party threw match on spilled gas w/arson intent. D is not liable) Causality Not Truncated by Foreseeable Actions of Third Parties. Marshall v. Nugent (1st Cir. 1955, 467) P was a passenger in a car when they collide with negligent truck driver. Truck driver suggested to the P that he go around the curve to warn oncoming cars of the expected danger. As the P was getting into position, the D pulled over to the left, went into a skid, and ended up hitting P, causing serious injury. Court held truck driver liable for all harm caused by foreseeable extraneous circumstances, or intervening third parities, made possible by D’s careless acts (but for) where other circumstances do not intervene and break the causal connection leading back to D’s carelessness. The truck driver’s negligence could have been the proximate cause of the later accident, which injured the plaintiff. The case should be taken to a jury. The danger created by the negligent conduct was not completely over and the situation had not become stabilized or normal when the accident occurred. It does not matter that the exact situation was not foreseeable inasmuch as it created more of a risk than just normally operating a car. Danger caused by negligence is not completely over as soon as the negligent act ends. Thus, the chain of proximate causation can extend beyond the immediate event. The truck driver is liable if a jury finds causation here. Pittsburg Reduction Co v. Horton (506) A young boy picked up the caps, and played with them in plain view of his mother and father for a week before taking them to school and exchanging them for some writing paper. The recipient tried to clean the caps with a match and the explosion resulted in the child's loss of a hand. The mother's clearing away of the caps at night broke the causal connection between the mining company and the explosion. Last Wrongdoer standard necessarily breached when the N of one D did not sever causal connection (509) Suicide: modern cases usually allow jury to decide Johnson v. US, 512: convict hangs himself, psychological deterioration in jail. Posner says no reason to believe that underlying unhappiness was caused by D or that a session with shrink would have saved him. Fuller v. Pries, 512: doctor hangs seven months after accident. No causation. 36 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Duty Extends to Actors Not Breaking the Original Causal Link: Danger Invites Rescue Wagner v. International Railway (N.Y. 1921, 450) P and cousin were riding in a train. The conductor did not shut the doors before the train got underway, and Herbert fell out and over a bridge as the train turned a corner. P went to rescue (claims conductor instructed him to do so.) P fell off the bridge in the darkness, and sued the D for negligence, claiming that the failure to close the door was the cause of his injury because he was trying to rescue his cousin. D denies that the conductor instructed Po walk out on the bridge or followed with a light. Court held Liability for D. Volitional act by P does not excuse the D’s proximate cause because it could have been foreseen, as everyone knows, “Danger invites rescue.” D should expect and foresee that if they put a victim in harm's way, that someone will step forward and attempt a rescue. Ct. rejects the defense that the rescue was not immediate and "instinctive", stating that the rescue does not need to be continuous with the injury. Violation of Statute does not Mandate finding of Causation: Berry v. Sugar Notch Borough (PA 1899, 502) P driving in storm through D’s town, speeding (violation of statute.) Tree blows over and crushes P’s car, causing injury. P was speeding. And sues D for injury. Verdict for P. P’s speeding was neither the cause of the accident nor contributory negligence (violation of statute was coincidence, not cause, of the accident.) His actions did not increase foreseeability or risk that tree would crush his car. Strict Liability : areas that resisted incorporation into Negligence Steps in for liability even though D has exercised reasonable care. Theory: worry about activities that require a lot of risk for small benefit in utility Areas: Animals: within the scope of what makes the animal dangerous o Wild o Domestic Foreseeability of danger (warning signs) No foreseeability (unexpected lashing out) Abnormally dangerous activities Nuisance Products Liability Wild Animals defined by context and normal conditions of the animal (does it live in a zoo, a national park, the city, & etc.) 37 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Wild vs. domesticated animals: Wild animals : always SL Domesticated animals: only SL where there has been evidence of “dangerous propensities”(where owner knows or has reason to know of the danger); If owner does not know of dangerous tendency, then ordinary negligence principles of foreseeability will apply Gehrts v. Batteen (SD 2001, 645): D visited girl’s home and girl asks to pet dog in the back of her pickup truck secured by a harness attached to a restraining device. D lets her and as Gehrts reaches to pet the dog, he bites her face, causing injuries that require extensive medical treatment. H: Dog owner not liable. No evidence that knew or should have known of dog’s dangerous propensity; not foreseeable that the dog would attack someone petting it. Baker v. Snell (Eng. 1908, ): D leaves dog to servant and P is bitten as a result of a practical joke/dare by servant. H: Owner of dog is SL for harm caused when owner knows of her animal’s vicious tendencies. Question of whether the servant’s actions could have been a more appropriate place of blame (for liability issues, depends on whether he was in the employ of D when the incident happened. Judge says this is not relevant because D should be liable for keeping a dangerous animal regardless.) Colier v. Zambito (807): P bitten by unprovoked dog while visiting D. D had no knowledge, thus no liability. Dog bite statutes: removes the idea that the first bite is free Rationale for distinction: Reciprocal risks Extreme high cost of prevention Activity Level Adjustment - Assumption is that there is a requirement of relocation or activity level adjustment, not an increase in exercise of care (typical of SL cases) Owner is cheapest cost-avoider Deterrence for keeping wild animals in the first place Trespassing animals: SL for damage to property. Keepers of wild animals are always subject to SL even if the animals is not known to be dangerous. Exceptions: N must be shown for animals in Zoos Denver v. Kennedy, 651: improper to apply SL to zoos which are established in response to public demand. National parks: Rubenstein v. US, 651: D’s had put up signs warning of bears so were not N when P got mauled while camping in Yellowstone. Even under SL, D would be immune because the warnings dispatch duty and P considered A/R SL: Abnormally Dangerous Activities 38 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng SL for dangers associated with activity in scope of what makes it dangerous in the first place General Principles: Rest.2nd: 519: General Principle One who carries on an abnormally dangerous activity is subject to liability for harm to the person, land or chattels of another resulting from the activity, although he has exercised the utmost care to prevent the harm. This strict liability is limited to the kind of harm, the possibility of which makes the activity abnormally dangerous. Rest.2nd: 520: Abnormally Dangerous Activities: In determining whether the activity is abnormally dangerous, the following factors are to be considered: Existence of a high degree of risk of some harm to the person, land or chattels of others Likelihood that the harm that results from it will be great Inability to eliminate the risk by the exercise of reasonable care Indiana Harbor Belt R.R. v. American Cyanamid Co. (7th, 1990, 667): D’s train leaked toxic fluid. P, the switching line, was required to perform decontamination. H: (Posner, J.) The std. for liability shall not be strict liability when the accident would have been prevented with due care. This is not an ultrahazardous act b/c fails to meet reasonable care will eliminate risk. Posner takes all factors and gives them a BPL interpretation. Dangerous activity is the transportation of chemical, not its manufacture (ADA applies to activities and not just the production of the dangerous substance danger is derived from its transportation) Extent to which the activity is not a matter of common usage Justifications: no reciprocity of risk, common expectations (knowledge of how to take precautions) Inappropriateness of the activity to the place where it is carried on and; Extent to which its value to the community is outweighed by its dangerous attributes Rest.3rd 20: Abnormally Dangerous Activities – (latest iteration): A defendant who carries on an abnormally dangerous activity is subject to strict liability for physical harm resulting from the activity. An activity is abnormally dangerous if: The activity creates a foreseeable and highly significant risk of physical harm even when reasonable care is exercised by all actors; and The activity is not a matter of common usage. Spano v. Perini Corp. (N.Y.,1969, 656): D’s blasting wrecked P’s garage on nearby property. H: One who engages in abnormally dangerous activity, such as blasting is held SL. (Old analysis was physical invasion of property, flying debris and such; New analysis is just SL for abnormally dangerous acts.) Since it is not 39 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng possible to engage in blasting with sufficient care to reduce risks, then the harm should not be imposed on others. D is CCA. Extent of protection: : SL for harms that are within the scope of the unreasonable risk (not all harms in the world) Madsen v. East Jordan Irrigation Co. (Utah 1942, ): P’s minks are frightened by nearby blasting and eat their young. H: No liability where effect is unanticipated and unforeseeable (no proximate causation.)Mother minks interrupted chain of causation. Blasting may cause certain sorts of harms, but this is certainly not one we would expect. Has to fall within scope of harms that actually make the activity dangerous. Purpose of activity doesn’t matter. Not limited to D’s land (anywhere the activity is conducted.) SL: Nuisance: The intentional or negligent or abnormally dangerous activity that leads to unreasonable and substantial invasion of plaintiff’s possessory/property interest in private use and enjoyment of land. D may be acting reasonably, but action (if a nuisance) causes harm in SL sense. Test: 1. 2. 3. 4. Intentional (intent to act and know that acting may cause harm) Unreasonable Invasion Private use/enjoyment of land (must be activity that ordinary people would be bothered by.) Determining reasonableness More than P should be required to tolerate: harm > benefit. Suitability of the invading use to the neighborhood where it takes place; Values of the respective properties; Cost to the defendant to eliminate the condition complained of; and Social benefits of allowing the harm to continue (RST 826(b)) Degree of harm to the interest invaded. Substantial nuisance (significant harm) Courts in these cases tend to either come down either on the side of unreasonable or substantial nuisance. A lot of courts that apply unreasonable standard, however, will require some minimum level of substantiality. Why wouldn’t we want to have a SL standard for small harms (insubstantial) that do not meet BPL requirement for negligence? Inefficient, social costs Autonomy argument 40 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Property rights are a social ideal and don’t extend to absolute right to enjoyment of property free from any interference (property rights are legal creation) Analysis What is the value of the activity vs. the harm (to all actors in the community, not just the one harmed)? Rogers v. Elliot (692) What is a “substantial” invasion? Particularly sensitive P? Coming to the nuisance? How should damages be allocated? Injunction? Private vs. Public Nuisance Private Nuisance – non-trespassory interference with the P’s interest in the use of enjoyment of her property. Public Nuisance – act by D that obstructs or causes inconvenience or damage to the public in the exercise of rights common to all, or in the enjoyment or use of common property. Private Nuisance No intentional invasion when no knowledge of harm: Vogel v. Grant-Lafayette Electric Cooperative (Wis., 1996, 675): D provides electric power that causes excessive stray voltage that harms animals of P, dairy farmers and members of GLEC (coop that distributes electricity to their members.) Ps notify GLEC and they fix. P later sues for private nuisance and intentional invasion. Holding: The coop’s actions were not a private nuisance b/c was not intentional and once they knew of harm, they came in and fixed the situation. Therefore was unintentional and instead sounds in negligence. Nuisance law can apply to stray voltage claims (nuisance does not have to be a physical invasion onto land; definition is sufficiently broad to be flexible.) Question of what constitutes an “unreasonable or substantial invasion” seem to require knowledge. Deprivation of light and air is not nuisance: Fountainebleau Hotel Corp. v. FortyFive Twenty-Five. Inc. (Fl, 1959, 687) P builds tower that casts shadow over D’s pool and beach. P claims easement rights on the view, light, and air. D sues for injunction preventing P from building further (the development is already substantially underway.) PH: Temporary enjoinment grated, Fountainebleau appeals. Holding: Land owners may use their property in any reasonable and lawful manner, even if motivated by spite, so long as they do not thereby deprive the adjoining landowners of any right of the enjoyment of their property. Light and air is not a right of landowners recognized at law. As industrial ethic becomes less prevalent and economic ethic becomes more prevalent, courts are less likely to follow this. Flaherty v. Moran: Spite fences that have no other useful purpose are a nuisance. 41 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Pah v. Maretti (Wi, 1982, 690) neighbor builds house that blocks out P’s solar panels. Court repudiates Fontainbleau and says that unreasonable obstruction of sunlight may be considered private nuisance (takes into account emerging solar energy.) The Thin Skulled P: Nuisance must be objectively injurious: Rogers v. Elliot (Mass. 1888, 692): Church bell rang causing P, with serious sunstroke, to go into convulsions. Holding: Ringing of a loud bell is not a nuisance where an average person is not adversely affected, even if a particular P is so affected. Question of what is reasonable given the circumstances and the effect upon people generally (not those particularly over/under-sensitive, or upon the particular person who happens to be affected by it.) Coming to the nuisance is not a complete defense: Ensign v. Walls (Mich. 1948): Neighbors of dog-breeding allege private nuisance b/c of smells, barking, dogs roaming the neighborhood. Breeder was there before the complaining neighbors. Holding: There may be an actionable nuisance, even if the nuisance predated the arrival of neighbors who are complaining. Coming to the nuisance is but one factor to examine in a balancing test. Other factors are public health and safety. “Even if have carried on an offensive trade for a number of years remote from buildings and public roads, that does not mean that once houses and roads are built around you you can continue your trade at will if it is a nuisance. That would amount to control or impact on neighbor’s lawful use of land.” Although coming to the nuisance is usually not dispositive, it could be a factor the courts will consider, especially with regard to damages. ‘Coming to the Nuisance’ Rule Theory Pro o Provides notice o P’s choice to move in o Ps are best cost avoiders (Calabresi) o P already compensated by lower cost of housing (Boomer) Anti: o Nuisance a violation of property rights o Would essentially allow private citizens to determine zoning laws/control or impact neighbor’s lawful use of land o Perverse incentives – each side motivated to build as quickly as possible (over development) o Non-reciprocal risks Nuisance damages (not specific performance) where utility of nuisance > Harm: Boomer v. Atlantic Cement Co. (N.Y. 1970, 700): residential neighbors sue over classic nuisance effects (smoke, noise, vibrations) Holding: Court acknowledges nuisance but does not grant injunction, but instead damages to P. A single damage award is appropriate to compensate victims of nuisance where the value of the utility of the activity o/w the nuisance and where reparations would be 42 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng more feasible than either adjusting care level or discontinuing the bothersome activity. Trial court is interested in encouraging changes, but very reluctant to shut down factors (political reasons.) They have low confidence that the factory can change their practices (with new R&D.) Thus, efficiency gains overweigh property rights. Idea (theoretically) is to provide incentives to spur better technology b/c won’t want to keep having to pay damages. Weighing Remedies and Injunctive Relief Injunctive Relief Advantages: Can provide benefits to would-be plaintiffs who are negatively affected by the nuisance but whose AIC might not be sufficient to bring a suit or who might not have the resources to do so CJ - If estimating plaintiff’s loss is hard to do, then this is easier solution Damages Advantages: Efficiency - Avoid potential hold out for more money, (leading to possible of never reaching an agreement.)With damages, plaintiff gets what his property is worth and no more. Can compensate P for loss without forcing major economic loss for D. D pays for P’s loss to compensate for negative externality but it is worth it because his property/use is worth more. Disadvantages: Subjective valuations of property by homeowners Transaction costs and additional problems of multiple Ps Allows you to buy the right to engage in the nuisance (Boomer – buys right to pollute) Goes against CJ instincts (doesn’t stop harm, D can buy right to engage in nuisance, hard to quantify the harm to P) Purchased Injunction Plaintiff can enjoin the defendant but only if compensates him for loss incurred. (Ex. Spur Industries - plaintiff brought residents to the nuisance and now must compensate defendant for reasonable amount of moving or shutting down) Calabresi & Melamed, Property Rules, Liability Rules and Inalienability, (Supp, by deLisle ed., 1998). Four possible remedies for solving nuisance activity from the perspective of efficiency. In perfectly efficient world it would not matter which rule you chose b/c parties would simply buy and sell, and bribe their way to perfect equilibrium <In a perfectly efficient world the parties would not have bothered to go to court b/c they would have been able to negotiate w/ ea. other and come to a perfectly efficient resolution w/o the loss of admin. and ct. costs> 43 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng 1. Polluter Is Enjoined: This rule is used where the polluter is the cheaper cost avoider. Is efficient, if the ct. is correct in determining who really is the cheaper cost avoider. 2. Polluter Pays Damages: This rule is used where the ct. cannot determine whether the polluter desired to pollute more than the P desired to be free from pollution. The negative side effect is that sometimes it forces co. out of business. 3. Polluter Wins Litigation and the Status Quo Prevails: Good distributive effects (C&M mean that money is not redistributed, and they prefer it that way), but possibly bad efficiency effects if polluter tries to later buy out the P due to possible hold-out problem. 4. Polluter is Enjoined, but P must Pay Damages (Spur): This rule has the advantage of accomplishing distributional as well as efficiency goals. It is efficient to the extent that the P removes the nuisance that was previously preventing perhaps numerous homeowners from enjoying their property. We max efficiency by allowing more people to get more use out of their land than was possible before. This rule also accomplishes distributional goals to the extent that the polluter is not required to fire its employees, and instead may move and continue operations elsewhere. The employee’s jobs are thus not distributed away into the homeowner’s enjoyment of land. Critique: <This of course is not strictly true, since it may take years for a factory to move and employees will be forced to find new employment in the interim anyway. Most employees will never return. In addition, it assumes the polluters don’t just take the money and run. Polluters aren’t required to set up shop elsewhere, in which case employees lose their job, not only in the short run, but forever. C&M want to set this arg up as if P were really suing employees, making P’s look more repellant and litigious. C&M don’t want to discuss the issue of “distribution” is really from the pockets of the elites, to Boomer and the community, of which many of the employees are likely to be members.> Public Nuisance Private Action in Public Nuisance - General damages from public nuisances are controlled only by direct public action, usually administrative or criminal. Private action is maintainable only for “special” or “disproportionate” harm to the individual plaintiff. To maintain private action for public nuisance, have to show that your injury or inconvenience particularly extreme. (Ex: Obstruction on a public road is a public nuisance, but also a private nuisance if blocks my driveway.) Private Action for Public Nuisance Requires Disproportionate Harm: 532 Madison Avenue Gourmet Foods, Inc. v. Finlandia Center, Inc. (2001): Consolidated cases: All involving major construction collapses in NY that required streets and businesses to be closed for a number of weeks. Ps seek damages for economic loss, saying their businesses were more adversely affected. H: The injury suffered by the plaintiffs was common to businesses in the entire area – only difference perhaps some degree – so cannot recover. A 44 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng public nuisance is actionable by a private person only if it is shown that the person suffered special injury beyond that suffered by the community at large. Distinguishes from Leo where commercial fishermen brought private action against companies spilling PCBs into water based on severe economic loss b/c of affect on fish – in that case, they were distinctly harmed and their kind of harm was unique. This type of action can be seen as a tort action to a nonowner to prevent the premature destruction of valuable resources (so could maintain even though didn’t own the fish so couldn’t bring a tort action, e.g.) Public Nuisance Action Requires Control over Source of Nuisance: Camden County Board of Chosen Freeholders v. Beretta, USA Corp: Camden County bringing action against handgun manufacturers for damages incurred as a result of crime by guns that they say have been in part created and exacerbated by the defendant. H: Manufacturers of lawful products that are lawfully placed in the stream of commerce cannot be held liable for a public nuisance that results from the eventual unlawful use of the product. Too remote and intervening parties. For a public nuisance to be actionable, the defendant must exert a degree of control over its source. The limited ability of a defendant to control behavior outside of its sphere explains why public nuisance law has been limited to real property and violations of public rights. No duty to control the conduct of third parties. 45 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 Products Liability___________________________ M. Cheng ______________ Categories of Defects: 1) Manufacturing Defects a. In the manufacture of the product it was improperly made b. True S/L applies 2) Design Defects a. In the original design of the product there was a defect b. Closer to a neg std; if are aware of unavoidable danger then either must “obvious” or must have properly warned/guarded against i. Consumer Expectation ii. Risk-Utility Calculation 3) Warning Defect a. Failure to adequately warn about potential dangers b. Something slightly tougher than neg std Defenses by Manufacturers 1) Negligence: (1) contrib. negl.; (2) state of the art technology was used but no system is perfect and we all, as a society ought to bear that cost (a kind of reciprocal risk arg). Most cts apply comparative fault principles. 2) S/l: (1) assumption of risk implied where P had knowledge of risk (e.g. didn’t heed warning); (2) abnormal use or misuse that is not reasonably foreseeable is not protected; (3) argue that defect was not proximate cause of harm, (4) alteration after it was sold. I. Manufacturing Defects New Rule on SL – RST (3d) 1 : Liability of commercial seller or distributor for harm caused by defective products.: One engaged in the business of selling or otherwise distributing products who sells or distributes a defective product is subject to liability for harm to persons or property caused by the defect. Removed any distinction b/w bystanders and the consumer/user. This one has been slightly more controversial. Some courts follow. Comment i: Unreasonably Dangerous: Must be unreasonably dangerous in that must be dangerous beyond the extent contemplated by the ordinary consumer, with the ordinary knowledge common to the community as to its characteristics. (Ex: Knife is not unreasonably dangerous. ) Comment k: Unavoidably Unsafe Products There are some products that are incapable of being safe in their ordinary and intended use (certain drugs, vaccines) but whose use is justified b/c the benefits outweigh the risks/costs. 46 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Where something is unavoidably dangerous, if it is properly prepared and accompanied by proper directions and warnings, it is not defective and not considered unreasonably dangerous. Also would apply to new/experimental drugs that have not had adequate long-term testing in order to guarantee safety. Requirements for Liability: 1. Must actually have been defective when it was sold. Generally, SL does not apply to used goods or sellers of used goods. 2. No difference between product and its packaging. 3. Defects are not benign. 4. In order to prevent unreasonable use, sometimes must provide warnings or directions as to proper use. 5. Contributory negligence – like with all SL areas – does not apply when it refers merely to the failure to discover the defect or guard against it. But if it consists in voluntarily and unreasonably proceeding to encounter known danger (assumption of risk) it is a defense (again, as in other areas of SL). RST 402(A) (748): Special Liability of Seller of Product for Physical Harm to User or Consumer 1) One who sells any product in a defective condition unreasonably dangerous to the user or consumer or to his property is subject to liability for physical harm thereby caused to the ultimate user or consumer, or to his property if: a. The seller is engaged in the business of selling such a product , and b. It is expected to and does reach the user or consumer w/o substantial change in the condition in which it is sold. 2) The above-state ruled applies although a. Seller has exercised all possible care in the preparation and sale of the product, and b. The user or consumer has not bought the product from or entered into a contractual relation with the seller. 1. Doesn’t allow for recovery by third-party/bystander, but most courts will allow this. Old Privity Rule: Manufacturer and P had to be in “privity of contract” so that if the injured party didn’t purchase directly from the manufacturer, couldn’t sue. o Winterbottom v. Wright (Eng., 1842, 728) Plaintiff, a mail coach driver, was seriously injured when a vehicle broke down due to lack of repair. Defendant had contracted with the Postmaster General to keep the coach in safe and secure condition. Defendant failed to comply with this promise, resulting in Plaintiff’s injuries. Does P owe a duty? H: No. Judgment for the Defendant. P is not privy to the contract entered into between the D and the Postmaster General. D thus owes no duty (P wouldn’t be able to sue in K, so should not be able to sue in tort 47 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng MacPherson and Escola cases mark Shift to Strict Liability for Manufacturing Defects o MacPherson v. Buick Motor Co (NY 1916, 731) D buys wheels from a separate manufacturer and sold car to retailer, which sold the vehicle to P. Vehicle suddenly collapsed, because a spoke shattered which was manufactured with defective wood. Plaintiff was thrown from the car and injured. D did not inspect the wheel before selling the automobile to the retailer even though defect was easily discoverable if it had been inspected. P sues, saying D was negligent in not inspecting the wheels on the automobile. D claimed there was no duty of care to anyone but the immediate purchaser. H: There is a duty owed and D is negligent if a manufacturer is supplying goods in which a danger may be foreseen if its construction is defective, there is a cause for negligence. In this case, it was apparent that an automobile is a good which fits this description. It could be foreseen that if the wheels are defective, and an automobile is traveling at fifty miles an hour, an injury would almost be certain. It should have been apparent to defendant, however, that an automobile retailer, by nature of its business, would not use the vehicle and would resell it to the general public. Therefore, the court felt that it could be reasonably foreseen by defendant that plaintiff would be injured by a defect in the wheels and therefore a duty of care was owed. o Escola v. Coca Cola Bottling Co. of Fresno, CA (1944): Waitress puts coke bottles into fridge and bottle explodes as a result of a defect, causing injury. H: Shift to strict liability for manufacturing defects. Rationale: Least Cost-Avoider and Ability to Spread Loss: Consumers are unprepared for injuries caused by defective products. Such costs can be devastating for individual consumers and manufacturers are in a better position to insure against damages and distribute costs among public. Note: Fairly radical claim that goes outside of traditional area of torts. Public Policy: It is in the public interest to discourage the marketing of defective products. Technology-forcing – encourages development of safer products. Asymmetry of Access to Information: The inner workings of a manufacturer’s company are a mystery to most consumers and are often not in a position to refute or put forth evidence regarding the negligence of the manufacturer, as the manufacturer himself is. Manufacturer has information about other products and potential defects. More on notice than consumer. 48 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng It is hard to prove negligence. So this might be the only way to adequately discourage defective products. (RIL-type argument). Corrective Justice – people take these products into their home based on faith that product is safe. Reciprocity of risks. o But manufacturer’s liability should be defined in terms of the safety of the product in normal and proper use, and should not extend to injuries that cannot be traced to the product as it reached the market. o This is a move away from the rule that contract law governed liability for defects under law of express or implied warranty. Manufacturer can no longer define the scope of his liability – not governed by contract but by tort law. Warranties cannot indemnify against liability for injuries caused by defective products. Circumstantial evidence: Pouncey v. Ford Motor Co. (5th Cir. 1972): P injured when radiator fan blade broke away. H: Manufacturer liability may be proven by meeting a negl. std. based on circumstantial ev. Note: This is in fact a borderline negl. s/l case, though the ct. calls it negl. Modern trend is that you’re not required to show that the product wasn’t made acc. to design. That it broke is evidence enough of fault. Foreign contaminants: Mexicali Rose v. Superior Court (Cal. 1992): Choked on chicken bone. R: S/l std is met where (1) the foreign object could not be reasonably expected by the average consumer and (2) the product is unfit under theories of the implied warrant of merchantibility. H: Manufacturers strictly liable for foreign contaminants but only negligence std for natural contaminants. Ruling out other causes: Speller v. Sears, NY (2003): Basic idea is that P can win w/o proving that a particular defect existed or caused the harm, only has to rule out other causes. There is an RIL-type analysis, though is different b/c here there is no requirement that the plaintiff show that in the absence of negligence would not have happened, b/c we are talking about SL and don’t care about negligence. Design Defects: There are several standards for determining what is a design defect. Among them are: I. Consumer Expectations: products that fail to perform as an ordinary consumer would expect when used in an intended or foreseeable manner. Problematic when there are overly high or low stds. (New RST moves away from this) a. What would the reasonable, average consumer expect? (Linegar, Halliday) b. But do consumers always have expectations about safety? And can we measure that? Potter – keeps nominally the consumer expectation test but recognizes its limitations and allows for risk-utility test in other situations c. Consumer expectation test seems to only really apply to a narrow set of cases (guns, bullet-proof vest), b/c often expectation does not match the actual safety of a product (certain meds, cars) – consumers are not always 49 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng adequately informed. Depending on the situation, one test might be more exacting than another. d. Also what is foreseeable and intended use? e. So there is often need to apply risk-utility to better match reality of circumstances i. Risk-Utility Calculation: must balance safety w/ price, aesthetics and utility. 1. Alternative design? Feasible and not excessively expensive? 2. Gravity and likelihood of the harm? 3. Benefits? ii. Have we slid all the way back to negligence? 1. Courts do discuss negligence factors (CBA), but also add other factors 2. Not strictly limited to dangers that are foreseeable and undiscoverable 3. More backward-looking risk-utility balance than usual neg test (w/ exception of state of the art def and consideration of whether improvements came after the incident) S/L vs. Neg: Where do courts tend to fall in terms of design defects? The vast majority of courts will apply the risk-utility-balancing approach – will run the spectrum from pure negligence (Volkswagen) and need to show some alternative design that would have prevented harm (Barker, Piper)… to no need to show alt design if can show that it is unreasonably dangerous (Mushkin). Most courts often use both consumer expectation and risk-utility – balance against one another. Consumer Expectation/Foreseeable Risks: Foreseeable Use: Intended use and any reasonably foreseeable use. Not a defense to argue that didn’t use the way they were supposed to if that use was foreseeable. But the foreseeable misuse std creates moral hazard problems b/c could encourage reckless behavior. And it also transfers costs from careless to careful users b/c the manufacturer cannot differentiate to what kind of user they are selling. Defective Design & Foreseeable Harm - A Negligence Std o Volkswagen of America, Inc. v. Young (Md. 1974): P killed when seat ripped away from floorboards during a rear-end accident. Rule: An auto manufacturer is liable (but not s/l) for a defect in design which the manufacturer could have reasonably foreseen would cause harm, which was not patent or obvious to the user, and which does in fact cause injury in a collision. A car is not only intended to drive but to transport someone safely. Does not matter that this was a “second collision” as long as defect caused or aggravated harm. 50 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng This is a negligence standard and is an outlier -- is as far toward negligence standard as courts go with design defects. This standards is NOT the law in most jurisdictions. Defective Design & Foreseeable Harm – More S/L Std o Phillips v. Kimwood Machine Co. (1974): Employee is hurt while operating sanding machine, but employer had not purchased another instrument that was supposed to go with it and the machine had been used contrary to instructions by the manufacturer’s employee. Rule: To impose liability there has to be something about the article which makes it dangerously defective without regard to whether the manufacturers was or was not at fault for such condition. The test is whether the seller would have been negligent if he had sold the product knowing the risk involved (s/l imposes constructive knowledge of the condition). This is essentially the same test as the RST 402(a) test about consumer expectations – foreseeable risks. This moves back toward a strict liability test. Not just whether did or should have known, but whether might have known. With Knowledge of a Defective Design o The Pinto: Grimshaw v. Ford Motor Co. (Cal. 1981): Ford aware of Pinto’s dangerous structural problems and in this case a Pinto did burst into flames upon rear impact. H: Strictly liable where manufacturer acts maliciously and w/ a conscious disregard for public safety. Efficiency and BPL arguments are rejected. Ford did a B vs. expected litigation costs analysis and betting that prevention will still cost more. Ex. of defendants not really doing the full BPL analysis. Use of standards to see if negligent: statutory requirements or guidelines? Compared to other similar models? Cost of making the product safer? Knowledge of the potential harm? Risk-Utility Calculation: Utility and Consumer Expectation as Alternate SL Stds. in Product Design. o Barker v. Lull Engineering Co. (Cal 1978) P injured while operating D’s high lift loader on a construction site. Rule: A product violates s/l test of unreasonably dangerous design where (1) P proves the product failed to perform as safely as an ordinary consumer would expect (obj, test) when used as intended or in a reasonably foreseeable manner, OR (2) the P proves that the product design proximately caused injury and the D fails to rebut by proving that in light of the relevant factors, on balance, the benefits of the design o/w the risks inherent. (see below for factors). After P has made a prima facie showing that a design defect was the proximate cause of his injury, burden shifts to D to prove that his product is not defective. 51 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Alternative Design showing must demonstrate that by comparison the alt design would have prevented the harm and would be reasonable. Or, must show that there is no such reasonable alternative design. Essentially applying the CBA as method for determining liability, especially where CE doesn’t work. Consumer Expectation and Utility in Determining Design Safety o Linegar v. Armour of America (8th Cir. 1990): Police officer killed while wearing bullet proof armor. H: A Bullet proof vest not defective when (1) consumer doesn’t expect the performance at issue, and (2) utility doesn’t demand because alternative designs would decrease overall use of the vest, thus decreasing safety, and increase cost (itself decreasing safety through decreased use).Court applied the “open and obvious” approach (the fact that vest didn’t fully cover parts of the body was obvious and didn’t expect protection in those parts of the body). Reasons why a purchaser would choose this model (less confining, less expensive) and no reason manufacturer should be held accountable for that choice. To hold them liable would be to make the company an insurer for anyone shot while wearing a vest, regardless of whether shot actually penetrated the vest. Apply Risk-Utility to this Case: o Technical Feasibility – yes. D actually makes a vest that would cover that area. o Functionality/Safety – mobility. It alters the design and some of the benefits. o Cost – costs will be increased. And could prevent some from being able to afford vests at all. Modified Consumer Expectation Test w/ CBA. o Potter v. Chicago Pneumatic Tool Co. (Conn, 1997): Plaintiffs injured by repetitive use of tools caused permanent injuries as a result of excessive vibration of the tools. H: Court refuses to let go of the “consumer expectation” test for design defects, but allows that in certain situations where not useful or b/c product is very complex, then courts should weigh the risks and utilities (do CBA analysis). But the consumer expectation test is appropriate when the everyday experience of a particular product’s users permits the inference. Potter court is really recognizes the limitations of the consumer expectation test and is allowing for risk-utility balancing test in other situations Safety as One Element Among Many o Wilson v. Piper Aircraft Corp. (Or. 1978): 52 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Plane crashed due to icing conditions (P theory). H: P’s proof of a safer alternative design must also meet a general CBA of overall design, and further, older models need not be considered unsafe simply due to comparisons with newer, safer models. Negligence analysis. P has to offer an alternative that is practicable in terms of overall design/operation, and that considers other possible risks other than the one in question. Risk Utility Formula for Calculating Design Defect Liability (1) utility of the product to the public as a whole; (2) likelihood of product causing injury and gravity; (3) availability of substitute material with better safety properties/alternative designs; (4) manufacture’s cost of eliminating unsafe aspects of product, including potential to create other/greater risks; (5) user’s cost of avoiding the product’s proposed danger; (6) anticipated user awareness of product’s dangers; and (7) feasibility of manufacturer spreading the loss. Products Intended to Be Dangerous. o Halliday v. Sturn, Ruger & Co. (MD, 2002): Boy shoots himself with playing with his father’s handgun and his mother brings suit against the gun manufacturer for liability for death. Gun had come with safety warnings about where to store the gun so that kids couldn’t get to it, but father ignored. P bases claim on CBA (alt designs for childproof, etc.). Court applies consumer expectation. H: Legislature has not chosen to place this kind of burden on gun manufacturers so court decline to do so. o Martin v. Harrington & Richardson (7th Cir. 1984): Suit being brought against gun manufacturers for making a product that kills. R: Liability acc. to Rest 402A extends to dangerous activities not products that are dangerous. Rationale: Would have to likewise ban knives, drugs, alcohol, tobacco and red meat. Ex: Semiautomatic pistols (“Saturday night specials”) that have no other use other than sale to criminals. This kind of sub-category of product that might flunk CBA. This is about the design of a subcategory. Generally, courts won’t disallow an entire type of product (guns, tobacco, etc.). But this is an outlier-case. State of the Art Defense o O’Brien v. Mushkin Corp. (N.J. 1983): P dove into 3 1/2 feet of water head first, hands slipped off the slippery vinyl bottom and bashed his bone head. Rule: State of the art defense not sufficient to exculpate (i.e. D argued no other material was any less slippery or really used in any other pool). P’s CBA need not exhibit alternate safer designs, only need to show that the material/risk is just too dangerous. Very pro-P standard and extreme on the S/L side (opposite of Volkswagen). 53 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng This was overruled by NJ statute – this is not really good law any more. Limitation on “Open and Obvious” Defense o Micallef v Miehle Co. (N.Y. 1976): P injured hand chasing a hickey. H: Open and obvious danger is not enough in and of itself to exculpate a manufacturer from liability unless the design defect remedy would have been prohibitively expensive, or would have resulted in diminished effectiveness of the product. Rationale: Ct. critiques old Campo “open and obvious” defense: (1) is a hold-over notion of tort-as-fraud; (2) violates CJ notions of wrongful harm; (3) proximate cause is present b/c harm is foreseeable, and that is enough. deLisle Overview of Liability Std. for Drugs. Design defect has three stds. that have been applied to drugs. 1. Straight s/l in Barker: May use the two part Barker test: (1) consumer expectation or (2) causation with CBA of overall design, will find liability. 2. S/l most of the time in Kearl [840]: S/l for drugs generally, but negl. std. if the drug (1) was expected to confer exceptionally important benefits, (2) posed a substantial but unavoidable risk, and (3) was considered so valuable that its availability o/w public interest in enhanced accountability. 3. Negl. test generally, under Brown (infra): Do a CBA to test drug, and test for foreseeability of harms claimed by P. K. deLisle Explains Why Drugs are Ana Separately from Other Products: Most products produce a large number of medium to low level harms, whereas drugs tend to produce a few high level harms. Drugs of course also provide tremendous benefits. People are unable to subjectively process statistics, so that a few anecdotal cases of a tremendously rare side effect has a disproportionate affect on people’s opinion of the drug. deLisle thinks that drugs aren’t really different from other sorts of products in kind, just degree, and thus ought to be ana similarly. The cts., however, disagree. III. The Duty To Warn Duty to Warn: Used when changes in the design are not practicable b/c would alter their intended used (e.g. drugs). o Required Where: Known/should have been known Somewhere b/w obvious risk and weird/unintended – some level of reasonable foreseeability Above a certain threshold of danger/possibility o Requirements: 54 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng Warning must be sufficiently clear and intense to convey the danger to the average consumer. Warning may not be buried in other warnings, unless an learned intermediary (doctor) is available to sort the data. Open and obvious is only a defense when a warning would not have changed the P’s behavior (child with lighter, for ex.). o Standards/Defenses: Something slightly tougher than negligence std so even if didn’t know about the danger, could be held liable if cts determine that they should have known through reasonable testing and prudence. But still closer to neg than s/l. State of the art defense usually works (Vassallo) Can also raise federal standards/regs (FDA labeling stds), but this is NOT absolute defense, just a factor (Vasallo) What about if the possibility is very small? (mass vaccination) Reasonableness std. Cannot warn your way out of every defect. Some improvements might still be necessary. o Unintended uses: Completely weird and outside the realm of foreseeability – no liability (using a chain saw to file your nails) Foreseeable misuses – could be found liable (speeding w/ sports car) o Causation: Need to prove that if had provided adequate warning, would have prevented the harm/not taken X action. Defaults into reasonable std. o Problems: If there is too exhaustive a list of potential harms, could dilute the warning. You wind up under-deterring. RST 420: Comment j o Warnings may be necessary to prevent a product from being unreasonably dangerous. (Applies to unavoidably dangerous products. But warnings may not be sufficient – might need better design.) o If product contains an ingredient to which a substantial number of the population are allergic (peanuts, penicillin), and the ingredient is either one whose danger is not generally known (silicone) or which the consumer would reasonably not expect to find in the product, the seller is required to give warning against it, if he has/should have knowledge of the presence of the ingredient and the danger. o Manufacturers are NOT required to warn about ingredients that are normally safe but become dangerous if there is excessive consumption (not required to warn that if you drink 10 gallons of water at once could kill you). Duty To Warn the Patient Directly 55 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng o MacDonald v. Ortho Pharmaceutical Corp. (Mass. 1985): P injured from a stroke caused by birth control pills. The pills included warnings about other side effects, but not stroke. H: Prescription drugs (really just BCP in this csae) for which the patient is so actively involved in choice and dispension of the drug, so that the physician has a relatively passive role, must bear explicit warnings directed at the consumer, about its possible side effects. (The warning was also inadequate b/c stroke is a significant side effect.) Patient usually doesn’t have to take BCP over any other method, so is actively making a personal choice. Because of long-term use and annual refills, view that doctor isn’t really regularly revisiting. This case is an exception due to the nature of the product and the passivity of the intermediary. (see also vaccination campaign).Risks: The list gets so exhaustive that is ignored and dilutes warnings. The general rule is that manufacturers need only warn the “learned intermediary” and not the patient. Generally, the view is that the doctor is better equipped (has your medical history) to give useful and particular advice about a medicine to the patient. Can appropriately tailor the warning b/c differs from patient to patient. o Harris v. American Home (5th Cir, 1999): took opposite view, holding that drug manufacturers only had duty to warn the learned intermediary (doctor). o Perez v. Wyeth Labs (NJ, 1999): imposed drug manuf duty to warn consumers directly in light of Wyeth’s massive ad campaign directed at women, including in women’s mags. o Reyes v. Wyeth (5th Cir, 1974): court held that manufacturer of polio vaccine that was dispensed in a mass vaccination campaign where there was no opportunity for a physician to be involved had a duty to make sure the warnings about 1 in a million chance of causing polio. But should the court take into account the stats of what happens if no one gets the vaccine – would be much higher. Adequacy of Warnings to Patients o Vassallo v. Baxter Healthcare Corp. (Mass, 1998): Ps silicone breast implants ruptured, causing injuries. Company had info about tests done by company that supplied the silicone of toxicity and potential for rupture. Furnished warnings to physician about some possible side effects, but not others. And other dangers didn’t know about. H: D will not be held liable for failure to warn about risks that were not reasonably foreseeable at the time of sale or could not have been discovered by way of reasonable testing prior to marketing the product. A manufacturer will be held to the standard of knowledge of an expert in their field, and will remain subject to a continuing duty to warn of risks following sale of the product. 56 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng The state of the art defense. Most courts will employ something somewhat tougher than neg in that will not just look at what actually knew but will consider what should have known based on industry standards. (Few cts go all the way to s/l that don’t care whether was even possible to know about the danger.) o Seminal Asbestos Case - Borel v. Fiberboard Paper Products Corp. (5th Cir. 1973): Asbestos injured an insulation worker. H: Manufacturers have a duty to warn all workers of the dangers of that product so they could make informed choice. o Hood v. Ryobi America Corp. (4th Cir, 1999): o Man is injured when using a mitter saw that he purchased after he removed blade guards, which the instructions had explicitly warned against doing. He claims that the instructions never indicated the consequences of not following the warning. H: The manufacturer doesn’t need to warn of every possible mishap or source of injury, just a reasonable warning under the circumstances of what should/shouldn’t be done with the product. Open and Obvious/Foreseeable Risks o Liriano v. Hobart (2d Cir 1999) Seventeen yr-old P caught hand in meat grinder from which employer had removed the safety guard. No warnings were given that it was dangerous to remove the safety guard. Rule: If the injured person is fully aware of the hazard through general knowledge, observation or common sense, or participated in the removal of the safety device whose purpose is obvious, may obviate failure to warn. Theory Warnings in Products S/l: Guido Calabresi & Jon Hirschoff, Toward a Test for Strict Liability in Tort Adequacy in Warning in s/l product defect cases is really an analysis of which party is the cheaper cost avoider. o A warning does not necessarily preclude a user from recovery if the manufacturer was in a better position to avoid costs (know about the risks or discover them) by doing further research or by implementing risk reducing technology. Warnings are only adequate as a defense where the user was in fact the cheapest cost avoider. Ex. of where warnings are effective to avoid liability: birth control warns of cancer and there are other devices out on the market that do not pose such a risk. In such a case the user is the best cost avoider because she has a real choice to use or avoid the product. 2. Effective warnings are much like assumption of risks. o Under theory of strict liability, assumption of risk operates as a complete bar to recovery. “It is, and always has been, a kind of P s/l—the other side of the 57 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng coin of D’s s/l.” [218] There are limits on assumption of risk and they track who is the cheapest cost avoider (compare first vs. secondary implied A/R). “The first limit was usually put in terms of whether the injury stemmed from the risk whose presence was the reason for making the activity s/l.” For example a transporter of explosives may be s/l for harm done by the exploding, but not for the harm done when the barrels of explosives roll off the truck and crush your foot, absent explosion. “The second limit was usually put in terms of whether the victim had done something which, though not necessary negligent, had especially exposed him to the risk.” For ex. a zoologist may enter a tiger cage to study large cats, and do so carefully but suffer injuries. He has assumed the risk. 3. In products s/l the cts. prefer to analyze on a case by case basis to determine who is the cheapest cost avoider instead of just assuming that it tends to be manufactures or it tend to be victims. 4. In cases of a third party victim, that victim must prove that the party she has decided to sue, either user or manufacturer is in fact the cheapest cost avoider, in order to prevail. IV. Proper Defendants Who are “sellers” under RST 402(a)? o Includes not just the original manufacturer, but anyone downstream (wholesalers, retailers) – they are held strictly liable b/c they have no control over the design/manufacture. o Rationale: Holding intermediaries liable will put pressure on manufacturer to fix defects. May be in a good position to inform manufacturer of defects b/c of direct contact w/ consumers. So if are held liable then there is incentive for them to communicate complaints/injuries to manufacturer. Can spread costs by either paying manufacturer less or charging consumers more o Strict Liability for ppl downstream (b/c their lack of involvement is irrelevant) Issues: o But what happens when product is bundled with a service? (Cafazzo) Doc/pharmacists not held s/l for products o What about someone who buys a used product and re-sells as a business? (used goods store) Generally, they are not held s/l for defects (other than wear of use). Rationale: There aren’t the same sorts of incentives, ability to spread costs as there are w/ original retailers. Also view the used product market as valuable b/c provides access to goods that would otherwise 58 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng not be affordable – b/c are talking about lower market, the costs of inspection/liability would likely outweigh the benefits. o What about when altered in some way? Cafazzo v. Central Medical Health Services (PA, 1995): Patient tries to hold hospital and doctor strictly liable for the defective prosthesis they implanted. H: Doctors/hospitals are not “sellers” under the meaning of 402(a) and cannot be held liable for defective products. Doctors/hospitals can only be held liable for their own negligence. o Rationale: You are paying for a service. Generally, courts hold that when a product is ancillary to service, the intermediary is not held strictly liable for product defects. (Can always hold acc for neg.) o Doctors/Pharmacists NOT held strictly liable for injury caused by products. V. Plaintiff’s Conduct RST (3) 17: Apportionment of Responsibility Between or Among Plaintiff’s Sellers and Distributors of Defective Products o A plaintiff’s recovery of damages for harm caused by a product defect may be reduced if the conduct of the plaintiff combines with the product defect to cause the harm and plaintiff’s conduct fails to conform to generally applicable rules establishing appropriate standards of care. o The manner and extent of the reduction under (a) and the apportionment of plaintiff’s recovery among multiple defendants are governed by generally applicable rules concerning responsibility. So generally, plaintiff’s conduct is governed by comparative fault principles (either pure comp neg or partial comp neg). o Comment d: Latent Defects When D claims that P failed to discover a defect, there must be evidence that P’s conduct in failing to discover the defect failed to meet reasonable standard of care. o Comment a: Contracting Against Liability Courts rarely allow a disclaimer or limitation for liability to bar a valid products liability claim. In large part this is due to adhesive and unilateral nature of such disclaimers. Foreseeable Misuse o LeBouf v. Goodyear Tire and Rubber Co. (5th Cir. 1980): Overpowered car equipped with normal speed tires. Buried in owner’s manual was a warning to use high-speed tires for high speed driving. Drunk defendant was killed when tires separated at 100105mph. H: D shall be liable for injuries to P even where P misused 59 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng D’s product if D may have reasonably foreseen P’s misuse, and did not take steps to provide adequate warning. Rationale: Contrib. negl. and assumption of risk defense is rejected here. Ford marketed the car to be driven in excess of 85mph. Comparative Fault Still in Effect in S/l Product Cases o Daly v. General Motors Corp. (Cal 1978): Drunk P thrown from auto wreck due to prob with door. H: S/l in auto manufacturing defects does not preclude using comparative fault principles (in fact, more beneficial to P b/c under S/L assumption of risk completely bars recovery). A P’s negl. conduct should reduce his recovery. Dissent: (1) Econ -- under-deterrence b/c it reduces manuf. liability; (2) CJ -- defective products hurt good and bad users alike, they don’t discriminate, and neither should the ct. 1) But the counter-argument to dissent is that this doesn’t really decrease incentive b/c can’t count on the fact that plaintiff will be negligent. o deLisle Notes: Most jurisdictions do introduce comparative fault of plaintiff to reduce recovery.. Assumption of risk still stands in products liability (“Flopper”), but it tends to be construed very narrowly (Messick). A/R not Present in Use of Defective Product if Use is Not Both Voluntary and Unreasonable o Messick v. General Motors (5th Cir. 1972): P continued to drive car he knew to be faulty, and soon crashed due to those faults. H: P may recover even when he is aware of product defects as long as his use of the product is not both voluntary and unreasonable. Rationale: P had to use car to get to work. 4. Vicarious Liability (respondeat superior: “let the superior answer”): employer is liable for employee even without negligence (employer is added as additional D) usually pretty goal oriented a. Test i. Act of an employee (independent contractors excluded.) ii. within the scope of employment (acts committed during a “detour” but not a “frolic”) (Ira Bushey & Sons c. US: D is vicariously liable for drunken sailors) b. Defenses: Imputed contributory fault: needs true joint enterprises (rare) where P’s N is imputed to the actor.) c. Justifications i. Employer probably is in better to make activity level adjustments and research decisions ii. Cost spreads to a D that has deeper pockets (loss distribution) I. Compensatory Damages 60 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng a. Percuniary damages: tangible monetary losses i. Lost wages 1. Estimation 2. Inflation & interest 3. Mitigation ii. Out of pocket expenses (medical expenses: Duncan v. Kansas City: jury estimated a larger lifetime than was reasonable, P claims astronomical remedy for future medical expenses) (may produce perverse consequences: go back and make sure they’re dead) b. Non-Pecuniary i. Pain & suffering 1. Issue: coma patients (McDougald v. Garber: cognitive awareness is not a necessary prerequesite) ii. Lost enjoyment of life c. Calculation methods i. Per dium (suffering per day) ii. Plaintiff sovereignty: how much money P would have required to accept this harm (not really applied by courts) iii. Structured settlements help mitigate uncertainty iv. Remittitur: when jury award is excessive, P has the choice of new trial or a specified reduction v. Additur: when jury award is unreasonably low. vi. Some states have placed cap II. Non-Compensatory Damages/Punitive Damages a. Justifications i. Fix malice intent ii. Community abhorrence iii. Closet compensatories (to pad the P’s wallet a little bit indirectly) iv. Protects property or autonomous rights (so that tort system does not price everything) v. Private prosecution of criminal behavior vi. Posner: fear of vigilante action supports channeling this into civil suits b. Supreme Court trends i. Damages can be higher depending on reprehensibility of action, though ratio of punitive to compensatory damages cannot be unreasonably high (4:1 ratio may be okay, but 25:1 may not.) rd III. 3 Party Claims a. Subrogation: insurance company comes in and steps into the shoes of the P (addresses the issue of collateral sources) b. P is dead but tort survives death: Wrongful death suits i. Beneficiaries: heirs at law (those that would inherit should P dies intestate) ii. Measure of Damages: beneficiary’s recovery is measured by the losses she suffers as a result of P’s death. (percuniary costs—loss of 61 Torts, Delisle Fall 2010 M. Cheng benefit—as well as non-percuniary costs—loss of consortium for spouses and children.) iii. Defenses: comparative fault of decedent or the beneficiary himself. 62