PUBLIC POLICY FOR THE NEW EMPLOYEE/EMPLOYER RELATIONSHIP It is possible to envision two fundamentally different paths that the employee/employer relationship can take in the United States in the next 20 years. 55 One path continues the trend of job insecurity as firms respond to high levels of competition and technological change by weakening connections to any one group of employees-by treating workers as a variable cost who can be readily laid off or hired on a contingent basis in response to often-rapid changes in markets and technologies. In this arrangement firms focus on the current skills employees can provide, and are unlikely to make investments in employee training or in policies and benefits that encourage worker commitment. A second path has firms strengthening employee/employer connections in order to develop a highly-skilled and committed workforce that is an important resource in adapting to changes in markets and technologies. In this arrangement firms use extensive training, employee involvement, and flexible reward systems to create and take advantage of higher worker skills, motivation, and commitment. The next 20 years will undoubtedly contain plenty of examples of firms in both paths. We base our discussion of public policy on what can be done to further the second path-to create high-performance workplaces where workers and employers share the rewards of high performance, and workers have employment security and high skill levels while firms have productive, committed workforces. The policy recommendations we offer are meant to be provocative, to stimulate discussion of what the employee/employer relationship should look like and how that can be achieved. As reviewed in sections III and IV, existing research provides substantial support for positive performance effects from employee participation in ownership, profits, and other high performance work practices. Why then are they not used more frequently, particularly in combination with each other? As discussed, informational and other barriers may limit the diffusion of these practices; such 1 barriers may be addressed by public policies aimed at encouraging these systems. The agricultural extension system, for example, is justified by the public good of spreading information to farmers, ensuring that productive innovations are quickly diffused. Government-sponsored demonstration projects may be similarly justified both in testing and diffusing knowledge on innovations. In addition, existing laws and regulations can be reviewed with an eye toward removing obstacles to innovative practices; for example, uncertainty over the legality of some forms of employee participation in nonunion settings has made a majority of managers cautious about expanding such programs (Commission on the Future of Worker Management Relations, 1994: 53). A different type of public policy rationale is provided when certain behaviors or practices have positive externalities, or societal benefits not captured by the actors. While the benefits of productivity improvements are captured within the firm, there may be important societal benefits in the spread of profit sharing and employee ownership. This is particularly true for the share economy theory of profit sharing: gains from employment stability accrue to the entire economy, as macroeconomic stability is enhanced by the maintenance of worker output and purchasing power without unemployment benefits or government assistance. This can provide a strong case for tax incentives to encourage firms and workers to use profit sharing (Weitzman, 1984; Mitchell, 1995). A different type of rationale has been used to support public policy favoring employee ownership, in which it is seen as a "merit good" or serving a "social transformation" role (Mitchell, 1995). Sen. Russell Long was, as noted, an early proponent of ESOPs on the basis that they could help broaden the distribution of wealth in the United States. Viewed as an intrinsic good or as having important social consequences (such as keeping society from splitting further into the "haves" and "have-nots"), a more equal distribution of wealth through employee ownership may justify favorable public policy (as argued, e.g., by Gates, 1998). 2 Our policy ideas are based on several findings about the direction of employee/employer relations. Career-long commitment of companies to employees appears to be on the decline; nevertheless, companies often voice demands for more performance, more skill, more commitment, and more flexibility from the workers who remain on the job. Also, most employees voice desire greater participation on their jobs and there is widespread support for employee ownership and performance-based pay; in other words, the notion of an ongoing economic partnership between American workers and American companies-a kind of employee-led capitalism-has strong support. Despite all this, only a small minority of U.S. firms extensively involve employees in ownership, profits, and a combination of high performance work practices. Research findings indicate that significant expansion of these practices could boost overall economic performance; at a minimum, there is no support for the view that widespread use of them would harm performance. Given these findings and the positive role that public policy may play both in overcoming informational and other barriers and in encouraging practices with societal benefits, we offer the following specific policy ideas. These should be viewed as a preliminary attempt to provide the domestic policy group with a template for debate and re-finishing rather than as a finished set of recommendations. In fashioning these, we have tried to adhere to the principle that policy recommendations must be simple and easy to understand for companies, employees, government officials, and the general public if they are to have any chance of being adopted. There needs to be better documentation of high performance work practices, given their potential for increasing U.S. business performance. There is no current method for annual documentation of high performance work, and such practices cannot be encouraged and studied well if they cannot be measured and tracked. Therefore we recommend: 3 1. Establishing a national commission of business, labor, and government representatives to mobilize expertise, serve as an information clearinghouse, and sponsor objective research on work practices (similar to the government's role in health and safety research). 2. Increased data collection through the Bureau of Labor Statistics or Census Bureau, and possibly through business tax returns, to gather better information on high performance work practices: a. How much of the company's common and preferred stock is owned by different classes of employees, and what is the value of stock and stock options distributed to different classes of employees last year? Under what format was stock distributed (ESOP, 40 1 k, stock purchase, etc.), and what percent of employees participate? b. How much of the company's W-2 compensation was distributed through profitsharing or gainsharing plans to different classes of employees in the last year, and what percent of employees of each class participated in this program? What was the specific format of this profit-sharing or gain sharing? c. How many employees in different categories participate in formal employee involvement structures, such as self-managed work teams, and do employees below top management have bona fide representatives on the board of directors? d. How much is spent on worker training and on recruitment and selection, both overall and for specific employee classes? e.What types of pension and health insurance packages are offered to employees? 4 Tax incentives for profit sharing may be justified for encouragement of employment stabilizing systems, while ESOP incentives have been based on the value of broadening the wealth distribution and encouraging greater employee participation in the economic system. In addition, some targeted incentives may be justified to help firms overcome informational and other barriers to adoption of new work practices. We recommend that: 3. The basic tax benefit for all employee ownership plans, broadened stock option plans, profit sharing and gain sharing plans should be enhanced, expanded, and increased to represent a meaningful increased incentive for greater involvement of employees in the business. 4. A meaningful proportion of further business tax decreases (either reduced tax rates or increased tax credit) should be mainly driven by tax reductions based on the adoption of multiple high performance work practices. These can be based on the combination of the following grades of high performance workplace practices: a. More than 30% (or alternatively, 15%) of W-2 compensation for all employee classes spent on employee-owned stock, stock options, profit sharing, or gainsharing; b. More than 50% of employees in self-managed work teams; c. High percentage of annual labor costs spent on training-, d. High expenditures on recruitment and selection costs For a given number of job openings; e. At least one rank-and-file or supervisory employee or their representative on the board of directors-, 5 f. A minimum health insurance and pension package. g. An alternative dispute resolution program that ends in binding arbitration for all employees. Most basically, such policies will allow the public to track the development of the new employment relationship and provide incentives for valuable innovations. We see these ambitious recommendations as initiatives that can help to fundamentally reshape the nature of the typical employee/employer relationship for the 21st century-creating high-performance "shared capitalism" and avoiding a system based on job insecurity, inadequate worker skills, and low productivity levels and growth. Footnotes: 55. These paths were outlined by Alan Blinder of Princeton University, former Vice Chair of the Federal Reserve Board and member of President Clinton's Council of Economic Advisers, in his speech at the National Bureau of Economic Research conference on "Shared Capitalism", Washington, D.C., May 23, 1998. Back to Employee Participation in Ownership and Profits This email was cleaned by emailStripper, available for free from http://www.papercut.biz/emailStripper.htm 6