Internal Negotiation of KORUS FTA: Korean Perspective Hong Ryul Lee1 Abstract The main objective of this study is to analyze internal negotiations of KORUS FTA in Korean perspective using Putnam’s two-level game theory and Lohmann and O’Halloran”s model. In the KORUS FTA, the nature of negotiation issue is heterogeneous; the reaction of domestic interest groups is asymmetric; and the negotiation issue is politicized in Korea. President’s leadership variable is flexible. Presidents tend to consider the national interests than his or her political interests. The political leadership of the presidents had contributed significantly to the conclusion of the FTAs. The empirical results in the case of Korea show that except for inflation, other independent variables do not have statistical significance. The impact of inflation on the tariff rate shows negative. Regarding the effect of the President’s party, coefficients indicate that Republican presidents in Korea tend to decrease the tariffs. This effect, however, is not statistically significant at the 0 to 10 percent level. The result of the divided government shows that a shift from a unified to divided government increases the tariff rate. However, this impact is not clear, since it does not have statistical significance at the conventional level (0-10%). Key words: internal negotiation, free trade agreement, two-level game, president’s party, and divided government 1. Introduction Korea needs to set up an FTA-based network with major economies to complement the WTO’s multilateral trading system. Accordingly, pursuing FTAs on a multi-track 1 Senior Researcher of Institute of International and Area Studies, Sogang University 1 basis is a major pillar of its trade policy 2 . Korea enforces FTAs with Chile, Singapore, EFTA, and ASEAN and is awaiting ratification of the concluded FTA with the United States, EU, and India and is actively driving forward FTAs with Canada, Mexico, GCC, Australia, New-Zealand, Peru, and Columbia. However, Korea’s FTA shows slow progress due to the delay especially in its ratification. In fact, Korea has faced many difficulties in the process of FTA negotiations, especially in the phase of ratifications. Korea’s first FTA with Chile took four and a half years from the initiative to the implementation. Meanwhile, both Korea and the U.S. government reached an agreement on April 2, 2007, and signed the agreement on June 30, 2007, but it is unclear when the agreement will be ratified due to the domestic politics in both countries. The United States has long been the most important trading partner for the Republic of Korea. In 2006, the United States was Korea’s third-largest trading partner after China and Japan, its second-largest export market, and its largest supplier of foreign direct investment. In turn, Korea is one of the most important trading partners of the United States. The volume of trade between Korea and the U.S. increased steadily through the 1990s until 2000, when it saw a slight downturn due to a depression in the economy. By 2006, however, exports from Korea had reached $43.2 trillion, while imports from the U.S. had reached $33.7 trillion. The proportion of U.S. exports to Korea out of its total goods exported was 3.1% in 2006, indicating that Korea is the seventh largest exporter to the U.S. and the seventh largest importer. Over the past five years, Korea-U.S. two-way trade has increased by almost 25%, recovering from its sharp decline during the period from 2001-2002. KORUS FTA is the United State’s largest FTA since the completion of the NAFTA 2 Korea’s trade policy is based on a multi-track strategy. The primary objective of Korea’s trade policy is to build an advanced, free and open economy. To accomplish this, Korea is actively participating in international cooperative efforts to establish a freer and more open world economic system. Also, Korea is stepping up regional and bilateral cooperation efforts to respond to the new challenges of the global age. 2 and is the Korea’s largest FTA after enforcement of FTAs with Chile, Singapore, EFTA, and ASEAN simultaneously. To come into effect, the U.S. Congress and the Korean National Assembly must ratify the KORUS FTA. The FTA ratification processes are likely to become politically active over FTA issues. In Korea, issues such as agricultures, livestock, pharmaceuticals, intellectual property rights, and screen quotas are difficult to be solved. The objective of this study centers upon the following questions: First, what is the nature of the domestic political problems in internal negotiations of FTAs? Where do the domestic conflicts come from? What did interest groups do to affect the outcome of the FTA and what were the reactions of the governments? To answer these questions, we analyzed KORUS FTA and compared the determinants of the outcomes of FTAs using the Putnam’s two-level game theory. Second, what is the role of political factors, especially the president and the divided government, on the level of protection? To do so, we employed the model of Lohmann and O’Halloran (1994) to test the hypotheses. The study analyzes the impacts of presidential party and divided government on the outcomes of trade policy in the context of endogenous tariff formation. 2. Theoretical Framework Schelling (1960) first pointed out the importance of domestic politics in international negotiation. He introduced an intuitive idea, called “Schelling’s Conjecture,” that a negotiator can take an advantageous position in international negotiations due to domestic constraints. This “paradox of weakness” suggests that a negotiator is often more successful than its unconstrained counterpart. In other words, a country can take advantage of its divided government at the international negotiation table. 3 Studies of two-level games, initiated by Robert Putnam’s seminal 1988 study, attempted to confirm Schelling’s conjecture that the constraints imposed by domestic institutions could prove to be a bargaining asset in international negotiations. Putnam (1988) raised the possibility that international negotiators might be able to use domestic constraints to their advantage at the international negotiating table. 2. 1. The Nature of the Negotiation Trading issues in international negotiations can create winners and losers at home. Some constituents may enjoy the benefits from agreement, while others may face high costs. As a result, the former will support the implementation of the agreement, whereas the latter will strongly oppose it. Internal negotiation will therefore depend on the relative size of the group of winners (supporters) and losers (opponents). The success of FTA negotiation and ratification depends heavily on domestic politics. Unresolved conflicts among domestic interest groups may be unproductive and may prevent nations from cooperating for mutual benefit. This would appear to be the case in agricultural negotiations: The potential gains from reducing tradedistorting subsidies and barriers are enormous, but strong agricultural interest groups generally prevent the realization of these gains. In sum, the nature of the negotiation issue can be either heterogeneous or homogeneous. When the interests of constituencies are relatively homogeneous, it is not so difficult for government to conduct a level II game. However, if the interests of constituencies are heterogeneous—a typical example is FTA negotiation— domestic politics (level II game) become complicated and difficult (Ahn, 2007). 4 2. 2. The Reaction of Domestic Interest Groups Domestic interest groups often refer to Congress, government agencies, the business community, labor, farmers, and civil societies. They pursue their interests by pressuring the government to adopt favorable policies, and politicians can create political power by constructing coalitions among those groups. The reactions of domestic interest groups in FTA negotiations are different because they are affected differently by the agreement. Thus, the reactions of interest groups may take various forms to address their concerns in the negotiation of FTAs3. Government is the main body of FTA negotiation and implementation. It means that government has the treaty-making power while the Congress has the consent power to the treaty. Therefore, the government has generally open and liberal characteristics, while the Congress has more protectionist policy. For businesses, there will be severe oppositions by import-competing industries that bear the adjustment cost of FTA agreements, whereas the export-oriented industries will generally support the conclusion of FTAs since they can increase their export volume to FTA partners. The biggest concern of labors is employment. On the positive side, more jobs can be created if FTAs can bring about new investment and businesses. On the other hand, there can be significant job loss if FTAs resulted in relocation of industries and/or closure of businesses. Despite the welfare gains for countries as a whole by FTAs, trade negotiations have always been tensioned in the agricultural sector. Generally, the agricultural sector is not economically important but politically important. Because, even the agricultural output accounts for a small portion in a country’s total GDP, a large number of farmers in rural areas can have a strong impact on voting in the Congress. 3 For studies on the domestic politics of trade policy, see models of endogenous trade policy formation (e.g., Baldwin, 1985; Trefler, 1993; Mayer, 1984; and Heo and Chung, 2008). 5 Therefore, the size of ‘win-set’ depends on the distribution of power, preferences and possible coalitions among national constituents, as well as national political institutions. Asymmetric and unpredictable reactions of domestic constituencies raise transaction costs greatly (Cooper, 1995). 2. 3. Politicization of the FTA issue Politicization means that people become politically active over FTA issues. It often activates politicians and groups who are less concerned about the costs of negotiation issues (Wilson, 1975). Marginal groups like consumer groups and NGOs not belonging to either the winners or losers are persuaded to exercise political influence by allying with losing groups, consequently aggravating the level II game. Internal pressure has occurred from the increasing impact of citizen input and bureaucratic politicking on the negotiation process (Winham, 1977). As a result, the trade policy process is more likely to be subjected to political pressure from nontrade factors such as Congress, organized labor unions, consumer groups, and environmental groups. According to Putnam, side-payments are one of the two primary tactics of domestic bargaining used by chief negotiators to facilitate ratification on international agreement (Putnam, 1988). Side payment can be defined in a broader concept to include such practices as compromise, concessions, vote trading, reciprocity, bribes, and issue linkage (Milner, 1997). The existence of side-payment opportunities may help to make win-set size larger however once a FTA issue is politicized; the cost of compensation may outweigh the anticipated benefit from the opening market. 6 2. 4. Political leadership In FTA negotiations, political leadership refers to how a president exerts his or her political leadership against the political reaction of the losers and the legislature in the process of domestic ratification (Ahn, 2007). In a democratic country, the executive holds more liberal attitude towards trade policy than the Congress. Generally, President’s political leadership is subject to restriction by the Congress under the divided government. A divided government describes a situation in which one party controls the Presidency and the other party controls Congress. Regarding the relation of the President and Congress, O’Halloran (1990) shows that Congress delegates less authority to the president of an opposing party, with the consequence that divided government is associated with higher levels of protection. Political leadership plays a pivotal role in FTAs negotiation and ratification processes. presidential leadership can build up the national consensus on the trade policy by resolving conflicts among interest groups. In other word, strong political leadership makes the domestic politics easier. 2.5. Conclusion Domestic politics affect the behavior of nations when they negotiate trade agreements with other countries. This chapter focuses on the determinants of internal negotiation and its interactions for implementing FTAs. Studies of two-level games initiated by Putnam (1988) attempted to confirm Schelling’s conjecture (1960). Putnam introduced four variables for analyzing the internal negotiation: the nature of negotiation, the reaction of domestic interest groups, politicization of the FTA issue, and the president’s political leadership. It is 7 difficult to establish national consensus on FTA issues when the nature is heterogeneous, the reaction is asymmetric, the issue is politicized, and the president’s leadership is low. 3. Analysis of the Internal Negotiation of the KORUS FTA Robert Putnam highlights the importance of internal negotiation in his theory of twolevel games. Putnam (1988) observed that democratic governments trying to reach international agreements are obliged to negotiate with their domestic political and interest group leaders as well as with their foreign counterparts. The more open and pluralistic a political system, the greater the need for the government to legitimize agreements, and thus more energy must be devoted to this phase. In this session, the study analyzed KORUS FTA and compared the determinants of the outcomes of FTAs using the Putnam’s two-level game theory. 3.1 The Nature of the KORUS FTA The nature of the negotiation issue is either homogeneous or heterogeneous as noted by Putnam (1988). On the one hand, when the interests of constituencies are relatively homogeneous, it is not so difficult for governments to conduct domestic politics (Level II game). On the other hand, if the interests of constituencies are heterogeneous, then domestic politics (Level II game) become very complicated and difficult. ‘Heterogeneous’ means some domestic groups are winning in certain negotiation issues, whereas other groups are losing. Previous studies have noted that a KORUS FTA would mean economic benefits for 8 both countries, with substantial gains for Korea but modest gains for the U. S. (USITC, 2001; Choi and Schott, 2001). Under a bilateral FTA, the GDP and welfare of both countries is expected to improve, favoring U.S. agricultural exports and Korean clothing and textile exports. Accordingly, USITC (2001) identifies these areas as most likely to be sensitive issues during negotiations, as Korean clothing and textiles exports would increase by $70 billion, while U.S. agricultural exports (including processed goods) would increase by $140 billion. Expected winners and losers are the Table 1 as below. Table 1. KORUS FTA: Expected winners and losers Study USITC (2007) Winners Losers Textiles, motor vehicles Machinery and equipment, and parts, electronic chemicals, rubber and plastics, equipment, and wearing agricultural sector, pharmaceuticals, apparel and beef and other meat products Lee and Lee Textiles and apparel, motor Electronics and machinery (2006) vehicles and parts, equipment, processed food, other chemical products transport equipments Although estimates vary across research, the KORUS FTA is anticipated to provide significant economic advantages to both countries. Korea’s automobile, textiles and apparel, and electronic appliances sectors would benefit while agricultural, machinery and equipment, and pharmaceutical sectors would face great challenges. In both countries, the sectors that will lose are those that tend to fare poorly in a more competitive environment; therefore, those sectors will lobby their governments or protest for restrictions or exemptions due to their nature as “sensitive industries.” In the case of the KORUS FTA, the main elements of a support coalition are 9 government leaders who are negotiating the agreement, influential legislators who favor it and economic interests that see themselves as gaining from it. Therefore, those supportive were mainly Chaebols, research institutes, the MOFAT, and the Blue House. However, those opposed were mainly labor unions, anti-globalization groups such as the National Farmer’s Association, Korea Health and Medical Workers Union, and the Korea Alliance Against KORUS FTA, who see themselves as losers from the deal. This split suggests that the FTA issue is very heterogeneous. In other words, winners are easily distinguished from the losers. Specifically, opponents of the KORUS FTA are concerned with a massive inflow of products from the U.S., especially agricultural products. Conversely, proponents claim that free trade will spur competition, which will in turn enhance national competitiveness, ultimately contributing to enhanced national income and welfare. Firstly, business groups from both sides champion the KORUS FTA, including the Korea-U.S. Business Meeting and the American Chamber of Commerce in Korea (AMCHAM Korea). Contrary to the Korea-Chile FTA, the business groups were already prepared and guided as to how to exercise their political powers before the negotiation process. Alexander Vershbow, U.S. Ambassador to the Republic of Korea, addressed this issue by at the 2006 New Year’s Networking Dinner: “Business community support should come in the form of detailed input, since we need to understand your concerns and priorities and ideas for addressing market impediments. But the support should come in other forms as well, including outreach to legislators, the media, and the public. This support also needs to start now, and last throughout the process, up to and including when it comes time for ratification of the FTA by the U.S. Congress and the Korean National Assembly”. 10 Although it appears that a majority of Korea’s business groups support the pact, opposition has been intense at times, particularly among farmers, labor unions, and rural residents. In general, opposition to a prospective KORUS FTA is expected to come from Korean import-competing groups, particularly the agriculture sector, which has benefited from high trade barriers. To be sure, as soon as the two governments announced the beginning of the KORUS FTA negotiation, agricultural interest groups made an aggressive move to advance their demands. Table 2 shows the interest groups in KORUS FTA. Table 2. Interest groups in KORUS FTA Positions Strongly support Interest groups Research Institutes: KIEP, KITA Ministry of Foreign Affairs and Trade The Blue House (The President) Positive Chaebols The Federation of Korean Industries Ministry of Finance and Economy Ministry of Commerce, Industry, and Energy The Korea Chamber of Commerce and Industry The Korea Federation of Small and Medium Businesses Grand National Party; Uri Party Ministry of Agriculture and Fishery Negative Citizen groups, Labor unions Strongly oppose National Farmer’s Association Korea Health and Medical Workers Union The Korean Alliance Against KORUS FTA 11 Some of the opponents to the KORUS FTA are against economic liberalization altogether. They argue that potential damage to some industries caused by opening the market should be taken into greater consideration and that any market opening should be delayed until more uncompetitive industries are fully ready. Such urgings hark back to the 1997 financial crisis and the ensuing liberalization of the financial services market as a cautionary example. Some militant FTA opponents go so far as to oppose globalization itself, viewing any liberalization as a prelude to further income disparity in Korean society. 3.2 Reaction of Domestic Constituencies The reactions between the winners and losers of the KORUS FTA are asymmetric. Given its paramount importance, the prospective KORUS FTA has drawn great attentions and concerns from groups that are both for and against it. At the very beginning of the FTA’s announcement, opposing groups voiced their concerns regarding the trade pact and threatened to disrupt the FTA. On March 28 of 2006, 270 civic organizations representing millions of workers, farmers, intellectuals, artists, and citizens formed the Korean Alliance Against the KORUS FTA, and shortly thereafter on April 16, thousands of trade unionists, farmers, students, and major celebrities marched in Seoul to demand that the government both abandon talks and allow the public to view the earlier negotiation process (Kim, 2007). Therefore, under the umbrella of the Korean Alliance Against the KORUS FTA and Korean Confederation of Trade Unions, hundreds of demonstrations have taken place with tens of thousands of participants at various places such as the Central Government Complex, City Hall, National Assembly, and negotiation places (e.g., Shilla Hotel, Washington D.C.). They utilized various forms of protest, including mass demonstrations, handing out flyers, gathering signatures 12 (the target was to obtain 12 million signatures), launching cyber attacks by sending thousands of e-mails to the White House, and burning flags. Unlike in the case of Korea-Chile FTA, winners from KORUS FTA are very active to express their political support for the trade pact. Korean business communities that are under the umbrella of the Korea-U.S. Business Council, Korea Chamber of Commerce and Industry (KCCI), Korea International Trade Association (KITA), Federation of Korean Industries, and Korea Federation of Small and Medium Business, have all urged the government and political factions to conclude and ratify the trade deal. Their lobbying activities have included holding lectures, seminars, and press conferences; staging demonstrations; placing advertisements in the media; handing out flyers; and meeting with congressmen. This difference reflects that the stake of the trade pact is too big for them to ignore or be silent. “A KORUS FTA will expand bilateral trade and benefit both nations by increasing investment, strengthening technological cooperation, and promoting personal exchanges,” said the Korea-U.S. Business Council’s Chairman Cho Suck-rae. He added, “To facilitate the FTA, the two sides need to persuade those opposing it in each nation.”4 The trade pact also divided politicians across factions. In the main opposition Grand National Party, 46 lawmakers including Chairman Kang Jae-sup supported signing the FTA, whereas 12 lawmakers from rural constituencies opposed it. Some 36 were undecided. Uri Party lawmakers were evenly divided into supporters, opponents, and undecided. The Party Chairman Chung Se-kyun supported the trade deal on the condition that the agricultural industry would be protected. But Uri Party floor leader Chang Young-dal was against signing. In the group of Uri Party defectors, one was in favor of signing this year, six were against and seven undecided. In the Democratic Labor Party, all nine lawmakers opposed concluding the trade deal. 4 Korean, U.S. Business Leaders Vow to Support FTA, Chosun Ilbo, June 21 2006. 13 The survey results also consolidated these reactions. In a survey conducted by the Chosun Ilbo and Gallup Korea, 58.5 percent said they think the KORUS FTA is good for Korea, whereas some 30.6 percent regard the FTA as bad for Korea. However, it varies according to occupations. Most of those who are self-employed business owners and wage earners gave a positive response at 63.6 percent and 57.3 percent, respectively, but farmers and fishermen responded negatively at 61.6 percent5. In particular, leading business people and journalists alike are to be in favor of the proposed KORUS FTA, citing the competitive edge such a deal will bring to Korea. The Korean government began to implement the TAA6 system in May 2007 to financially support firms whose sales, production, and profits decrease and workers who are completely or partially laid off or threatened with job loss due to increased imports. This TAA program is not simply to compensate for their losses due to the intensified import competition, but to help them adjust to a more liberalized trade environment. According to the Korean Ministry of Commerce, Industry and Energy, Korea is planning to allocate 92% of the budget (US $2.85 billion) to firms and less than 8% to workers during the next 10 years. A study on import competition and job displacement using a regression model for the period of 1993-2003 shows that import competition raises the job displacement rate in the Korean manufacturing sector, but the elasticity is negligible in its magnitude. Workers’ characteristics, such as gender, age, job tenure, and education level proved to be significant in determining the displacement rate (Heo, 2008). However, the TAA program is essential for the Korean government to smoothly implement the KORUS FTA as well as other already concluded or prospective FTAs 5 Three in Five Koreans Support FTA: Poll, Chosun Ilbo, April 04, 2007. Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA) is a government compensatory and assistance program that aims to help reimburse domestic firms and workers for their material loss or expected loss as a result of policies implemented toward a freer trade regime. 6 14 by facilitating the internal negotiations. The Korean TAA system can be characterized as an industrial policy aimed at strengthening the manufacturing and related industries, expanding support to small and medium firms, and minimizing the roles of the Ministry of Labor. Therefore, the government is obliged to prove its efficiency based on operational results. It is reasonable to curtail or abolish the detailed programs that could create possible problems of ‘moral hazard’ or ‘adverse selection.’ If the newly introduced system adequately accomplishes the promotion of restructuring and operates successfully as an effective means for internal negotiations, the system will create a new “TAA model of Korea.” On the other hand, if the system fails to serve its objectives and simply succeeds in retaining “marginal firms in comparative disadvantage,” the system’s poor performance will threaten the system’s own existence. Even if the TAA system continues to exist, it will inevitably be converted into a workercentered program instead of a firm-oriented program (Heo, 2008). 3.3 Politicization of the KORUS FTA Given the general unwillingness of the Roh Administration to allow and facilitate an open discussion of the proposed FTA, and the failure of the National Assembly to take the lead in a public conversation about the merits and weaknesses of a proposed FTA, it should come as no surprise that important sectors have organized and emerged in opposition to both the negotiations and the FTA itself (Kim, 2007). Declaring themselves as losers, some 270 civic groups including the Korean Confederation of Trade Unions (KCTU)7, the Federation of Korean Trade Unions 7 The Korean Confederation of Trade Unions (KCTU) is a national trade union center officially established in 1995. With 682,418 members in 2007, the KCTU accounted for 40.6% of trade union 15 (FKTU) 8 , and the Korean Federation for Environmental Movement formed a coalition against the trade pact with the U. S. right after the announcement of KORUS FTA negotiation schedules9. Protest participants against a planned FTA with the U.S. increased from 8,000 in early April to 25,000 in early July, with most of those being farmers and firm industry people 10 . But many generally antiAmerican organizations that also led violent protests against a new U.S. Forces Korea headquarters in Pyeongtaek have joined them, leading to charges that the protests have turned into an anti-American movement. Protestors even used cyber attacks by sending a flood of 30,000 e-mails to the Web sites of the U.S. Department of Defense, the White House and President George Bush with a minimum of 10,000 participants11. Moreover, hunger sit-ins staged by three ruling-camp lawmakers, Chung Dong-young, Kim Geun-tae, and Chun Jung-bae, made the issues become very politicized. They all served as cabinet members in the Roh Moo-hyun administration, played key roles in the formation of the Uri Party, and are presidential contenders12. Their opposition is based on political calculations. They want to take full advantage of this opportunity to manipulate voters. They want to stay aloof from the unpopular President Roh Moohyun, a champion of the FTA, and to seize the initiative in reorganizing the ruling camp. Popular opposition to the FTA has developed quickly, and a general concern over members in Korea. The KCTU has more than 1,200 affiliated enterprise-level trade unions and it is the second-largest trade union in Korea, following the Federation of Korean Trade Unions (FKTU). 8 The Federation of Korean Trade Unions (FKTU) was formed in 1961 after a military revolution and the dissolution of the General Federation of Korean Trade Unions and its affiliates. The FKTU was placed under the guidance of the military authorities. The FKTU was the sole legal trade union center in Korea until the Korean Confederation of Trade Unions (KCTU) was finally recognized in November 1999. The FKTU is affiliated with the International Trade Union Confederation, and in 2007 had 740,308 members. 9 Government Faces Revolt Over Free-Trade Deal With U.S., Chosun Ilbo, April 10, 2006. 10 Massive Anti-FTA Protests Paralyze Seoul, Chosun Ilbo, July 12, 2006; Thousands March Against FTA With U.S., Chosun Ilbo, April 16, 2006. 11 Anti-FTA Faction to Launch Cyber Attack on U.S., Chosun Ilbo, April 10, 2006. 12 Anti-FTA Hunger Strikes Disrupt Parliament, Chosun Ilbo, March 28, 2007. 16 the potential negative consequences of a free trade agreement is now openly expressed in Korean civil society. As the Figure 1, the disapproval rate of the FTA increased from 29.2 percent on June 7, 2006 to 42.6 percent on July 6 and broke the 50 percent barrier on July 2213. More people are paying attention to the opposing voice after the launch of Pan-national Movement Headquarters to Frustrate the KORUS FTA, and some TV programs focusing on the lives of poor Mexicans after the implementation of NAFTA. Figure 1. Poll: Do you support KORUS FTA? 80 58.1 % 60 Yes 45.4 50.0 46.3 40 42.6 29.2 No 20 0 June 7 July 6 July 22 Source: Park, 2006 Moreover, most U.S. and Korean polls conducted in recent years have shown that Korean perceptions and attitudes toward the U.S. reveal the greatest degree of 13 Park, Song-wu, Half of Koreans Oppose US FTA, Korea Times, July 31, 2006 17 polarization across generations. Younger Koreans in particular are very critical of the U.S. For the much older Koreans who remember the cruelty of Japanese colonial rule and the devastation of the Korean War, the U.S. is viewed gratefully as a “savior.” As the perception of the North Korean threat diminished, however, Korean youths increasingly began to view the U.S. military forces in Korea as infringing on Korea’s national sovereignty rather than as a deterrent against the North (Lee, 2004). The FTA enjoys strong, high-level support within President Roh Moo-hyun’s Administration. Despite the government’s support, however, nearly a quarter of National Assembly members opposes the agreement and will seek to block its passage14 . This is because lawmakers are afraid of angering massive opposing groups ahead of elections in December and April. Thus, over 70 lawmakers have already indicated that they will submit a request for the National Assembly to examine the agreement’s negotiation process and its potential effects on Korea’s future trade policy. A number of prominent politicians, including two former chairmen of Roh’s Uri Party who are running for president, publicly stated their opposition to the KORUS FTA. To pass the trade pact, the agreement must receive a simple majority, with at least half of the National Assembly’s members present during the vote. Prior to a full vote, the agreement must undergo consideration by the Unification, Foreign Affairs, and Trade Committees. 3.4 Political Leadership Political leadership reflects the President’s ability to persuade opposing groups and lawmakers on the process of FTA negotiation and domestic ratification through direct dialogue with them. The Korean president is considered as the most influential factor in Korea’s FTA policymaking. With the launch of the Participatory Government in 14 Kim Sue-young, “Han Calls for FTA Ratification.” The Korea Times, September 7, 2007. 18 2003, President Roh Moo-hyun has taken a very active role in expanding FTA partners. In the case of the proposed KORUS FTA, President Roh has identified this FTA as one of his priorities for the remainder of his term. Therefore, President Roh has showed his strong political leadership on the ongoing KORUS FTA. He has appeared regularly on the press and made every effort to convince the public by repeatedly emphasizing how Korean people would gain from the prospective KORUS FTA. Actually, the agreement holds the potential of changing the Korean economy from top to bottom. In an extreme sense, it can be likened to a deal that forges the two nations together economically as one country. But it also entails the risk of subjecting the economy to that of the U.S. if Korea fails to adequately adapt itself to the new economic environment15. That's why it was a difficult job for any leader to initiate. In this regard, President Roh’s leadership deserves praise for the achievement. During his 2006 New Year’s address on January 18, President Roh first took up the KORUS FTA, saying: “We should conclude an FTA with the United States for the future of our economy.” His intension was to show the public that an FTA with the U.S. is not a short-term vision. President Roh emphasized the long-term perspective of the FTA’s role, which can make the Korean economy stronger. He believed that an open-door policy is the only means to bring further development and prosperity to the country. He also met and talked directly with opposing groups in order to persuade them or accommodate anti- KORUS FTA groups. As a result, rice is excluded from the concession lists; Korea will maintain current tariffs on oranges, beans, powdered milk, and other imported agricultural products, as well as maintain safeguard measures and a tariff rate quota (TRQ) on such goods as pork, beef, and other 15 Roh’s Determination Leads to Successful FTA, Korea Times, April 4, 2007. 19 agricultural products. He told them that “we can't become an advanced nation without challenge,” which did earned a great deal of support from many people. President Roh straightforwardly denounced anti-FTA protestors whose “groundless, exaggerated” arguments had “misled the public.”16 He also urged them to frame reasonable arguments in the future: Every time I meet someone opposed to it, I ask them what areas other than agriculture and pharmaceuticals are going to be in difficult times and see unemployment, but no one has been able to give me a clear answer. So it’s frustrating to have people just go on with vague talk about how socioeconomic disparity is going to get worse without showing me any evidential basis for that.17 In order to address the concerns and persuade domestic interest groups, President Roh also vowed to compensate farmers, fishermen, and other adversely affected sectors that are expected to be the losers from the deal, if they see their income dwindle or are driven out of business due to a surge in imports of their products. About US$ 131 billion will be provided to farmers and fishermen who are negatively affected by the KORUS FTA through 2013. In early November of this year, it will be determined that an addition fund of U$ 20.4 billion will be spent from 2014 to 2017 to bolster agricultural competitiveness and expand the market for local farm products as more imports are expected to enter the country. However, President Roh turned his political leadership after the conclusion of KORUS FTA. It makes the ratification of the agreement difficult. In fact, the KORUS FTA should have been ratified within the closing days of the Roh administration. Instead, President Roh intentionally shifted his responsibility for the 16 17 Korea must face FTA Challenge: Roh, Chosun Ilbo, April 3, 2007. Roh needs to talk to those opposed to FTA, The Hankyoreh, April 9, 2007. 20 ratification to the next government. To be sure, this maneuver was grounded on a political calculation aiming at the next presidential election and the general election of national assembly members. He concentrated his effort on the extension of his political power code, not on the future of the country. Moreover, on his website, Democracy 2.0, President Roh, who had pushed for the FTA talks and concluded them, emphasized the preparation of renegotiation instead of ratifying the agreement. His unpredictable behavior is one of obstacles to the ratification of the KORUS FTA. 3.5. Conclusion In KORUS FTA, the nature of negotiation issue is highly heterogeneous; the reaction of domestic interest groups is highly asymmetric; and the negotiation issue is politicized in Korea. The United States and Korea are both in a similar situation in this context only except for president leadership. However, the President’s leadership variable is flexible. Presidents tend to consider the national interests than his or her political interests. Due to the high domestic constraints in both countries, it will be difficult to ratify the KORUS FTA both in the U.S. and in Korea in the near future. In short, the role of the political leadership in the success of an FTA should not be ignored. The political leadership of the presidents had contributed significantly to the conclusion of the FTAs. Therefore, in this globalizing world, Korea’s political leadership should be advanced in order to ratify the KORUS FTA earlier and to competitively pursue many FTAs. 4. Analysis on the Role of President and Divided Government This section employs the model of Lohmann and O’Halloran (1994) to test the role of the president in trade policy and the Schelling’s Conjecture. The study analyzes 21 the impacts of presidential party and divided government on the outcomes of trade policy in the context of endogenous tariff formation. 4.1. Data Description and Sources In this section, the factors that may affect the level of protection (represented by the tariff rate) will be analyzed18. In an effort to identify the underlying factors that account for the variation of tariffs across countries, data on unemployment, inflation, the president, and divided governments19 are collected. Higher unemployment often stimulates interest groups in affected industries to intensify their efforts for protection, while voters might object less to the negative effects of the protection on equity grounds. Concerning to inflation, it may have two alternative impacts on the level of protection. Either higher inflation will lead to more imports and thus to pressure for more protection or higher inflation will lead to consumers as voters demanding less protection in order to lessen inflation (Bohara and Kaempher 1991). In terms of divided government, the hypothesis is that trade policy tends to be more protectionist under divided than under unified governments. This is because of the expectation that the members of the majority party in congress would never choose to constrain their president under a unified government. However, the members of the majority party may take measures to constrain fully or partially under a divided government. Therefore, in a given year, if Congress and the president are controlled by opposing parties, this variable takes on the value of zero. The dummy variable PRESIDENT takes on the value of unity if the President is a Republican and zero if the President is a Democrat. Table 3 describes how to derive these variables. 18 Another approach to determine the level of protection endogenously is based on the characteristics of industries such as establishments, industrial growth, employments, import penetration, and export intensity (see Heo and Chung, 2008; Trefler, 1993 for detail). 19 A divided government describes a situation in which one party controls the Presidency and the other party controls Congress. On the other hand, a unified government means that the Presidency and Congress are controlled by the same party. 22 Table 3: Description of Data Set Variable Description TARIFF Tariff Revenue/Imports x 100 (%) UNEMPLOY Unemployment Rate INFLATION Rate of change in the Urban Consumer’s Price Index: (CPIt – CPI t1) / CPI t-1 x 100 (%) PRESIDENT Dummy variable equals 1 if Republicans control the Presidency; 0 if Democrats control it DIVIDED Dummy variable equals 1 if Congress and the Presidency are controlled by the same party; 0 if Congress and the Presidency are controlled by opposing parties. Note: *) The majority is calculated by summing up the number of same party members in the House and the Senate for the U.S.A. and Chile. Korea has the unicameral system, while the U.S.A. and Chile have a bicameral system, respectively. Data for this study was drawn from the ranges of 1974 to 2006 depending on the available data for Korea. The time series approach adopted here is similar to the approach employed in previous studies (see Takacs, 1981; Gardner and Kimbrough, 1989; Magee, Brock and Young, 1989; Lohmann and O’Halloran, 1994; and Clark, 1998). The dependent variable is the level of protection, as measured by the value of duties collected as a percentage of the value of total imports (TARIFF). Tariff rates are often a good proxy of how protectionist trade policy is at a given time, so their trend gives us some idea of the changes in the stance of trade policy. Obviously, this measurement is limited in the sense that non-tariff barriers (NTBs) are not taken into account. This is because NTBs are difficult to measure and collect. The aggregate economic conditions are measured by the inflation (INFLATION) and the unemployment rate (UNEMPLOY). These variables are proxies for protectionist demands. These measures are similar to those used by Magee, Brock, and Young (1989), Bohara and Kaempher (1991), and Lohmann and O’Halloran (1994). To 23 achieve such a long time series, the tariffs from various sources were collected. Data on tariffs during the 1975 to 1990 period of Korea was extracted from Urata (1994), while its data during 1991 to 2006 was extracted from OECD Revenue Statistics (2008). Data on unemployment is obtained from the Korean Statistical Information Service. And inflation data is from the Economic Statistics System of the Bank of Korea. Table 4 summarizes for the statistics for these variables. Table 4: Descriptive Statistics of Korea, 1975-2006 Variable Obs. Mean Std. Dev. Min Max TARIFF 32 6.13 2.74 2.32 11.44 UNEMPLOY 32 3.59 1.12 2.00 7.00 INFLATION 32 7.70 7.03 0.80 28.70 PRESIDENT 32 0.72 0.46 0.00 1.00 DIVIDED 32 0.88 0.34 0.00 1.00 4.2. Regression Model Following the Lohmann and O’Halloran (1994) empirical study 20 , the basic econometric model is defined as the below: Lohmann and O’Halloran’s (1994) tested the level of protection using macro economic variables like inflation and unemployment, President’s party (Republican or Democrat), and Government form (Unified or Divided) for the case of the U.S.A. during 1949 to 1990. 20 24 Subsequent models extend the basic model by adding one or more differenced political variables to the right-hand side of this equation. TA TA Clark (1998) added ΔTARIFFt-1 to the right-hand side of the equation with the purpose of controlling the autocorrelation problem that is likely to occur. The final econometric model is thus processed as follows: 4.3. Estimation results and Discussions The result for Korea is presented in the Table 5. The empirical results in the case of Korea show that except for INFLATE, other independent variables do not have statistical significance. What can be the cause for these results? First, the negative impact of inflation on the tariff rate means that when inflation goes up, the tariff rate tends to decrease. Facing consistent high inflation rates during the 1970s and early 1980s, the Korean government had used the tariff rate as one of the major tools to curb inflation. The nominal average tariff rate was reduced from 23.7 percent in 1983 to 12.7 percent in 1989. Simultaneously, the percentage of freely importable items out of all imported commodities had been increased from 67.5 percent in 1979, to 93.6 percent in 1987 (World Bank, 1987; Kim, 2008). 25 Table 5. Regression Results for Korea Independent variable Constant Regression Results -0.11 (-0.53) 0.24 (1.40) -0.08* (-1.76) -0.39 (-1.18) -0.80 (-0.45) 0.62 (0.81) 32 0.15 2.21 TARIFFt-1 INFLATE UNEMPLOY PRESIDENT DIVIDED No. of observations Adjusted R2 Durbin-Watson Notes: 1. Dependent variable TARIFF 2. ** and * represent the statistical significance at 5 percent and 10 percent level, respectively. 3. Numbers in parentheses are t-statistics Regarding the effect of the President’s party, coefficients indicate that Republican presidents in Korea tend to decrease the tariffs. A shift from Democrats to Republicans leads to the average tariff decreasing by 0.8 percent. This effect, however, is not statistically significant at the 0 to 10 percent level. Again, the notion that not all Democrats act like Democrats, and not all Republicans act like Republicans, is well suited in explaining this result. President Roh Moo Hyun, for example, is a Democrat, but he initiated numerous FTA negotiations, including FTA negotiations with Singapore, ASEAN, Mexico, MERCOSUR, and the United States. The result of the divided government shows that a shift from a unified to divided government, on average, increases the tariff rate to 0.62 percent. However, this 26 impact is not clear, since it does not have statistical significance at the conventional level (0-10%). This result implies that the impact of a divided government is not robust and divergent enough to determine the differences between Democrats and Republicans. To be sure, despite considerable empirical studies exist regarding the impact of a divided government on the setting of trade policy, empirical results have been divergent. On the one hand, Lohmann and O’Halloran (1994) find that a divided government should lead to higher levels of protection. On the other hand, Sherman (2002) argues that divided government should lead to lower levels of protection, at least in the post-War United States, while Karol (2002) argues it should have no consistent effect. Ehrlich (2007) demonstrates how the access point theory can be used to investigate the role of a divided government and finds that a divided government has no significant effect. In addition, Tsebelis's results indicate that the more divided the government is in a foreign country, the less likely cooperation would be. Using Tarar (2001) theory, this negative impact of divided government on tariff level demonstrates that a country’s domestic constraint is weaker than its counterpart’s. 5. Conclusion The main objective of this study is to analyze internal negotiations of free trade agreement of KORUS FTA in Korean perspective using Putnam’s two-level game theory and the model of Lohmann and O’Halloran. The study provides evidences to support the Putnam’s two-level game theory on how domestic negotiations take place, what channels interest groups influence a government’s trade policy and negotiation strategies, and how domestic politics can be linked to the international negotiation. The study also analyzes the impacts of presidential party and divided 27 government on the outcomes of trade policy in the context of endogenous tariff formation. Major findings are summarized as follows. In sum, in the KORUS FTA, the nature of negotiation issue is highly heterogeneous; the reaction of domestic interest groups is highly asymmetric; and the negotiation issue is politicized in Korea. The president’s leadership variable is flexible. Presidents tend to consider the national interests rather than his or her political interests. In short, the role of the political leadership in the success of an FTA should not be ignored. The political leadership of the presidents had contributed significantly to the conclusion of the FTAs. The empirical results in the case of Korea show that except for inflation, other independent variables do not have statistical significance. The impact of inflation on the tariff rate shows negative. That is, when inflation goes up, the tariff rate tend to decrease. Regarding the effect of the President’s party, coefficients indicate that Republican presidents in Korea tend to decrease the tariffs. This effect, however, is not statistically significant at the 0 to 10 percent level. Again, the notion that not all Democrats act like Democrats, and not all Republicans act like Republicans, is well suited in explaining this result. The result of the divided government shows that a shift from a unified to divided government increases the tariff rate. However, this impact is not clear, since it does not have statistical significance at the conventional level (0-10%). This result implies that the impact of a divided government is not robust and divergent enough to determine the differences between Democrats and Republicans. 28 References Ahn, Se Young. (2007). Dealing with Domestic Conflicts in FTA Negotiations: Lessons from the Korea-Chile FTA and NAFTA, Broadening the Horizon for Pacific Economic Cooperation: Korean Perspectives, KOPEC, pp. 43-70. Baldwin, Robert. (1985). The Political Economy of U.S. Import Policy, Cambridge: MIT Press. Bohara, Alok and William H. Kaempher. (1991). A Test of Tariff Endogeneity in the United States, American Economic Review, Vol. 80: pp. 952-960. Choi, Inbom and Jeffrey Schott. (2001). Free Trade between Korea and the United States? Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics. Clark, William R. (1998). Presidents, Parties, and Trade Policy in the United States: an Empirical Reassessment, in Domestic Politics, Trade Negotiations and Regional Integration: the US, Japan and Korea, Chae-Han Kim, Ed.; Seoul: Sowha Publishing, pp.1-28. Cooper, Richard N. (1995). The Coase Theorem and International Economic Relations, Japan and the World Economy, Vol.7 (1): pp. 29-44. Cooper, William and Mark Manyin (2007). The Proposed South Korea-U.S. Free Trade Agreement (KORUS FTA). CRS Report for Congress, the United Staes. Ehrlich, Sean D. (2007). Access to Protection: Domestic Institutions and Trade Policies in Democracies. International Organization 61(3), pp. 571–606. Gardner, Grant and Kent P. Kimbrough. (1989). The Behavior of U.S. Tariff Rates, American Economic Review 79, pp. 212-18. Heo, Yoon. (2007). Trade Adjustment Assistance in Korea: Theory and Practice, The Korean Economy in the Era of Globalization: Issues and Policy 29 Implications, Seoul: KDI: pp. 133-152. Heo, Yoon. (2008). “Import competition and job displacement: A case study of Korean manufacturing industries,” The Social Science Journal. Vol. 45: pp. 182-193. Heo, Yoon and Yurie Chung. (2008). The Endogeneity of Tariffs in Korea, Journal of International Economic Studies, Vol. 22: pp. 113-122. Karol, David. (2002). Divided Government and U.S. Trade Policy: Much Ado About Nothing? International Organization, Vol. 54 (4): pp. 825–844. Kim, Chuk Kyo. (2008). Korea’s Development Policy Experience and Implications for Developing Countries, Seoul: Korea Institute for International Economic Policy. Kim, Thomas. (2007). Policy Brief on the Proposed U.S.-Republic of Korea Free Trade Agreement, California: Korea Policy Institute: California. Lee, Junkyu and Hongshik Lee (2006). Feasibility and Economic Effects of a KORUS FTA, Seoul: Korea Institute for International Economic Policy. Lee, Sook Jong. (2004). The Transformation of South Korean Politics: Implication for U.S.-Korea Relations, Center for Northeast Asian Policy Studies, The Brookings Institution. Lohmann, Susanne and Sharyn O’Halloran. (1994). Divided government and U.S. trade policy: theory and evidence, International Organization, Vol. 48 (4): pp. 595-632. Magee, Stephen, William Brock, and Leslie Young. (1989). Black Hole Tariffs and Endogenous Policy Theory, New York: Cambridge University Press. Mayer, Wolfgang. (1984). Endogenous Tariff Formation. American Economic 30 Review, Vol. 74 (5): pp. 970-985. Milner, Helen. (1997). Interests, institutions, and information: Domestic politics and international relations, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. O'Halloran, Sharyn. (1990). Politics, Process, and American Trade Policy, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). (2008). OECD Revenue Statistics 2008, Paris: OECD. Park, Song Wu. (2006). Half of Koreans oppose U.S. FTA, Korea Times, July 31, 2006. Park, Young Bae and Sang Bok Moon. (2006). Korea’s FTA Policy Structure, Paper presented at the Korea and the World Economy V, Korea University, Seoul, Korea. Putnam, Robert D. (1988). Diplomacy and domestic politics: The Logic of TwoLevel Games, International Organization, Vol. 42 (3): pp. 427-460. Schelling, Thomas C. (1960). The strategy of conflict, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Schott, Jeffrey. (2007). The Korea-U.S. Free Trade Agreement: A Summary Assessment. Policy Brief, Peterson Institute for International Economics. Washington D.C. Sherman, Richard. (2002a). Delegation, Ratification, and U.S. Trade Policy: Why Divided Government Causes Lower Tariffs. Comparative Political Studies, Vol. 35(2): pp. 1171–1197. Takacs, Wendy. (1981). Pressure for Protectionism: An Empirical Analysis. Economic Inquiry, Vol. 19: pp. 687-693. Tarar, Ahmer. (2001). International Bargaining with Two-Sided Domestic 31 Constraints, Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 45 (3): pp. 320-340. Trefler, Daniel. (1993). Trade Liberalization and the Theory of Endogenous Protection: An Econometric Study of U.S. Import Policy, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 101 (1): pp. 138-160. Urata, Shujiro. (1994). Trade Liberalization and Productivity Growth in Asia: Introduction and Major Findings. Developing Economies, Vol. 32 (4): pp. 363-372. USITC. (2001). U.S.-Korea FTA: The Economic Impact of Establishing a Free Trade Agreement (FTA) Between the United States and the Republic of Korea, Washington D.C.: USITC. USITC, (2007). U.S.-Korea Free Trade Agreement: Potential Economy-wide and Selected Sectoral Effects, Washington D.C.: USITC. Wilson, James Q. (1975). Political Organization. New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Winham, Gilbert R. (1977). Negotiation as a Management Process. World Politics, Vol. 30 (1): pp. 87-114. World Bank. (1987). Korea: Managing the Industrial Transition. Washington D.C.: the World Bank. 32 Appendices Appendix 1: Korean FTA Partners: Current and Future FTA Countries 2005 GDP* Korean merchandise trade, 2005 (million $) (billion $) Exports to Imports Two-way from Trade Balance 1678.98*** 37080 35479 72559 1601 ASEAN-Korea FTA 886.67 27432 26064 53496 1368 Chile-Korea FTA 111.34 1151 2279 3430 -1128 Singapore-Korea FTA 116.78 7407 5318 12725 2089 EFTA-Korea FTA 680.97 1090 1818 2908 -728 33395.31 120862 111461 232323 9401 India-Korea CEP 808.88 4598 2112 6710 2486 Japan-Korea FTA 4559.02 24027 48403 72430 -24376 Canada-Korea FTA 1131.76 3446 2604 6050 842 13671.41 43659 27296 70955 16363 768.44 3789 460 4249 3329 United States-Korea FTA 12,455.80 41343 30586 71929 10757 FTA Under Consideration 4650.10** 164476 149147 313623 15329 Australia-Korea FTA 709.45 3812 9859 13671 -6047 Thailand-Korea FTA 176.6 3381 2689 6070 692 MERCOSUR-Korea FTA 1003.21 2828 2903 5731 -75 South Africa-Korea FTA 242.05 1320 1094 2414 226 Malaysia-Korea FTA 130.77 4608 6012 10620 -1404 New Zealand-Korea CEP 109.61 670 891 1561 -221 China-Korea FTA 2278.42 61915 38648 100563 23267 CJK FTA 6837.44 85942 87051 172993 -1109 39724.40 322418 296087 618505 26331 Current FTA Partners Under negotiation EU-Korea FTA Mexico-Korea FTA Total Note: *) only GDP of partner countries; **) exclude Japan and China’s GDP; ***) exclude Singapore’s GDP, Source: United Nations; KITA, 2007 33 PRES Appendix 2: Regression Data for Korea YEAR GOVE TARF1) UNEP2) J.H. Park (R) 1975 Unified 6.18 4.1 25.3 1976 Unified 8.62 3.9 15.3 1977 Unified 9.68 3.8 10.1 1978 Unified 11.44 3.2 14.5 1979 Unified 9.99 3.8 18.3 K.H. Choi (R) 1980 Unified 8.18 5.2 28.7 D.H. Chun (R) 1981 Unified 7.15 4.5 21.4 1982 Unified 7.95 4.4 7.2 1983 Unified 9.41 4.1 3.4 1984 Unified 8.28 3.8 2.3 1985 Unified 7.61 4.0 2.5 1986 Unified 8.91 3.8 2.8 1987 Unified 10.03 3.1 3.1 1988 Divided 8.83 2.5 7.2 1989 Divided 7.09 2.6 5.7 1990 Divided 7.87 2.4 8.6 1991 Divided 5.82 2.4 9.4 1992 Divided 4.94 2.5 6.2 1993 Divided 4.29 2.9 4.8 1994 Divided 4.19 2.5 6.3 1995 Divided 4.45 2.1 4.5 1996 Divided 4.39 2.0 4.9 T.W. Noh (R) Y.S. Kim (R) 34 INFL3) D.J. Kim (D) M.H. Noh (D) 1997 Divided 4.21 2.6 4.4 1998 Unified 2.93 7.0 7.5 1999 Unified 3.29 6.3 0.8 2000 Unified 3.2 4.1 2.3 2001 Unified 3.25 3.8 4.1 2002 Unified 3.47 3.1 2.8 2003 Divided 3.21 3.6 3.5 2004 Divided 2.64 3.7 3.6 2005 Divided 2.36 3.7 2.8 2006 Divided 2.32 3.5 2.2 Sources: 1) Tariff Rate: 1975-1990; Urata (1994) and 1991-2006; OECD Revenue Statistics (2008), 2) Unemployment Rate: Korean Statistical Information Service (www.bok.or.kr), 3) Inflation Rate: Economic Statistics System of Bank of Korea (www.bok.or.kr). 35