Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Decoupling Briefing for the International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Contents 1. Decoupling Economic Growth from Environmental Pressures through Resource Productivity . 2 Why is development unsustainable? Is it economic growth or market failure? .................................... 2 What is Decoupling? ............................................................................................................................. 9 What is the required level of decoupling of economic growth from environmental pressures? ......... 11 Can humanity achieve significant decoupling fast enough and on a scale large enough?................. 13 Can the Economy afford to invest in Decoupling across major Environmental Pressures? .............. 16 Measuring Progress through Decoupling Indicators – How do we know if we are on track? ........... 17 2. Decoupling Economic Growth from Greenhouse Gas Emissions.............................................. 19 Multiple Benefits of Decoupling Greenhouse Gas Emissions ............................................................. 19 Costs of Inaction versus Costs of Action ............................................................................................. 20 Reducing the Costs of Action .............................................................................................................. 21 Policy Implications and Recommendations ........................................................................................ 25 3. Decoupling Economic Growth from Freshwater Extraction and Pollution ............................... 26 Multiple Benefits of Decoupling Freshwater Extraction and Pollution.............................................. 26 Costs of Inaction vs. Costs of Action ................................................................................................... 28 Reducing the Costs of Action .............................................................................................................. 29 Policy Implications and Recommendations ........................................................................................ 29 4. Decoupling Economic Growth from Waste Production ............................................................. 31 Multiple Benefits of Decoupling Waste Production ............................................................................ 31 Costs of Inaction vs. Costs of Action................................................................................................... 32 Reducing the Costs of Action .............................................................................................................. 33 Policy Implications and Recommendations ........................................................................................ 33 5. Policies to Underpin Decoupling and Address Major Social Factors that can Undermine or even Block Progress ................................................................................................................................. 35 Internalising Externalities to Achieve Decoupling ............................................................................. 36 Taking a Portfolio Policy Approach to Underpinning Decoupling .................................................... 38 Responding to Fears of Job Losses from Decoupling and Environmental Sustainability .................. 44 Appendix 1: Selection of Supporting Resources on Decoupling ..................................................... 47 Appendix 2: Selection of International Studies on Decoupling Economic Growth from Greenhouse Gas Emissions .................................................................................................................................. 50 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia 1. Decoupling Economic Growth from Environmental Pressures through Resource Productivity1 As the opening chapter to this scoping report has outlined, there is growing evidence of the potential to achieve significant resource productivity gains at the level of businesses, governments, institutions and other organisations, often referred to as the micro-economic level. As outlined above, a focus on resource productivity at the micro-economic level offers a key strategy to enable effective decoupling of increasing profits from increasing environmental pressures and negative impacts. An understanding of the potential of resource productivity across the economy is important however as it demonstrates that there also is significant potential to achieve decoupling of economic growth from environmental pressures at the macro-economic level. This provides valuable insight into how to begin to reconcile economic growth and environmental sustainability. This is now the focus of Chapter 2. Why is development unsustainable? Is it economic growth or market failure? Until the early 1970s it was a widely acknowledged that economic growth was strongly coupled with increasing resource usage and environmental pressures and further that the trends could not be separated to a meaningful extent. This belief was strengthened by the observation that there was an obvious relationship between growing economic growth and increasing levels of resource usage and pollution across the societies of the world, particularly in some extractive industry sectors such as mining, fishing, oil and gas and forestry. Some authors from the period even proposed that economic growth was the principle cause of rising environmental pressures and the emerging environmental crisis. 2 They argued that, unless economic growth was curbed, reduced or even stopped, ever increasing environmental degradation was inevitable. 3 As Jim MacNeill et al wrote in 1991 in Beyond Interdependence, Ever since the Club of Rome report The Limits to Growth was published in 1972, an important part of the environmental debate has been rooted in the assumption that environment and development are irreconcilable. The Limits to Growth assumed a set of relationships between population, industrialisation, pollution, and depletion of natural 1 Note that Sections 2-6 of this report have been developed by Michael Smith and Karlson Hargroves, The Natural Edge Project, Griffith University and the Australian National University, under the supervision of Professor Ernst von Weizsäcker. The content is based on research undertaken by Michael Smith as part of his PhD, with additional research and editing by Karlson Hargroves. 2 Mishan, E.J. (1967) ‘The Costs of Economic Growth’, Staples Press, London. Mishan, E.J. (1977) ‘The Economic Growth Debates: An Assessment’, George Allen & Unwin, London: Daly, H.E. and Cobb, J. (1989) ‘For the Common Good: Redirecting the Economy Towards Community, the environment and a Sustainable Future’, Beacon Press, Boston, MD (UK edition 1990, Green Print, Merlin Press, London). Douthwaite (1992) ‘The Growth Illusion’, Green Books, Devon, UK: Daly, H.E. (1996) ‘Beyond Growth: The Economics of Sustainable Development’, Beacon Press, Boston, MA. Parris, R. (1997) ‘Development in Wonderland: The Social and Ecological Sustainability of Economic Growth’, Issues in Global Development, no.9, February, World Vision Australia, Melbourne. 3 Ibid. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia resources that led inevitably to the collapse of world order. It gave birth to a widespread movement advocating zero or even negative growth. 4 However even a cursory review of the literature and practice reveals that there is in fact much that can be done to decouple business profits and overall economic growth from environmental pressures and pollution. Despite this many business leaders, politicians and decision makers assume that significant trade-offs between achieving sustainable development and economic growth are inevitable. This belief has been one of the biggest barriers to achieving sustainable development. Clearly this is important to reconcile because, slowing or halting economic growth is problematic as it is seen by most decision makers as being required to ensure favourable conditions for business investment, high employment and healthy revenues for governments to enable expenditure on social and environmental initiatives. Furthermore as Dr Kenneth Ruffing, Deputy Director and Chief Economist of the OECD Environment Directorate from 2000-2005, points out, ‘Economic growth is a necessary, but by no means sufficient condition, for achieving most of the Millennium Development Goals (and other poverty reduction agendas)’. Political leaders and their advisors are also very sensitive to fluctuations in economic growth, particularly in the short to very short term. They tend to see strong economic growth as providing an ideal environment to give them the best chance of being re-elected, however the challenge to societies in the coming decades is that this focus on strong economic growth in the short term at the expense of the environment is significantly undermining the foundations for sustaining economic growth in the medium to long term. This scoping report presents a range of evidence to demonstrate that the belief that major trade-offs between economic growth and environmental sustainability are inevitable is in fact false. This false assumption has meant that, in the past, corporations, businesses and political leaders have not made the necessary investments in infrastructure, industry and policies etc to underpin a sustainable economy, making this challenge much more difficult for the current generation. The prevalence of false assumption has also meant that the few times historically, such as in 1972 and 1992, when there has been global momentum to achieve a transition to sustainable development, this momentum was rapidly lost due to global developments.5 Once the global recessions hit the economy in 1974-75 and in 1991-3 respectively, many political and business leaders were put into a position where they were very reluctant to invest further in sustainable development related imitative and activities since it may further harm the rate of economic growth in the very short term. Over the last two years significant momentum has again been achieved towards action on climate change and environmental MacNeil, J., Winsemius, P. ,and Yakushiji, T. (1991) Beyond Interdependence: The Meshing of the World’s Economy and the Earth’s Ecology. Oxford University Press. 5 Tremendous momentum for action on sustainable development was built up by the 1972 UN Stockholm Conference on the Human Environment. However global recession and stagflation quickly hit in 1973 onwards and taking the world’s focus away from the environment onto the economy. Much of that momentum for change was lost. Similarly there was significant momentum for change to achieve sustainable development leading up to the 1992 World Summit on Environment and Development in Rio. However, again a global economic recession hit in 1992 and again a significant amount of that momentum was lost as the perception was strong, at the time amongst decision makers and voters, that investment and protection of the environment harmed economic growth and jobs. 4 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia sustainability, due to leading efforts such as the UK Stern Review,6 IPCC 4th Assessment Report,7 and the movie ‘An Inconvenient Truth’. 8 However, much like the experience in 1972 and 1992, momentum for sustainable development is currently being lost, and attention is being focused elsewhere. At the time of writing, as the world’s governments attention is focused on addressing the significant financial crisis emerging out of the US financial markets and the US sub-prime mortgage crisis. In light of the fact that the IMF warns of a significant slowdown in the global economy in 20099 there are signs that average voters are shifting their support for action on the economy ahead of action on the environment.10 When the world leaders meet in Copenhagen to negotiate a Post Kyoto Framework and targets for decoupling economic growth from greenhouse gas emissions it seems likely that they will be doing so at best during a global economic slowdown or at worst a global economic recession. Hence in 2008 it is vitally important to again revisit the questions of - whether or not pursuing environmental sustainability will harm economic growth? and - whether or not economic growth inevitably harms the environment? Over much of the last hundred years there has been a clear and demonstrated correlation between increasing economic growth, resource usage and environmental pressures, however correlation does not prove causation. Whilst some argue that environmentally unsustainable development is caused by economic growth, many more argue that unsustainable development is caused by complex market, information, institutional, and technological failures, failures that are enhanced by rising population growth, especially in developing countries, and compounded by the lack of adequate international cooperation in the area.11 Complex failures of this nature include the problem of market externalities, 12 under-pricing of physical resources and natural assets,13 lack of markets for ecosystem services,14 and the challenges in managing public goods, summed up in 1968 by Hardin in ‘The Tragedy of the Commons’ paper.15 Economists have explained, for almost a century, 16 that environmental pollution and degradation arises largely from the fact that the real environmental costs of development are externalised from the 6 Stern, N et al. (2006) The Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.p104 Available at www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/independent_reviews/stern_review_economics_climate_change/Sternreview.index.cfm Accessed 14 April 2007 7 IPCC (2007) Fourth Assessment Report. WG2: ‘Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation & Vulnerability’, IPCC. Available at http://www.ipcc.ch/SPM6avr07.pdf. Accessed 14 April 2007. 8 See Transcript of An Inconvenient Truth at http://forumpolitics.com/blogs/2007/03/17/an-inconvient-truth-transcript/ 9 IMF (2008) World Economic Outlook. Executive Summary. IMF. Available at http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/shared/bsp/hi/pdfs/09_04_08_imf_exec_sum.pdf Accessed 1 October 2008 10 See ABC News Survey finds priorities shifting from environment to economy at http://www.abc.net.au/news/stories/2008/09/29/2376613.htm Accessed 1 October 2008 11 MacNeil, J. Winsemius, P. and Yakushiji, T., (1991) ‘Beyond Interdependence:The Meshing of the World’s Economy and the Earth’s Ecology’. Oxford University Press. Markandya, A., Barbier, E.B., and Pearce, D., (1989) ‘Blueprint for a Green Economy’. London: Earthscan Publications Ltd. World Bank (2003) World Bank Development Report 2003: Sustainable Development in a Dynamic World, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 12 Aylward, B., Bishop, J., & Barbier, E.B., (1991) Guidelines for Applying Environmental Economics in Developing Countries. Gatekeeper Series No. LEEC 91-02. London: International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED 13 Pearce, D., Barbier, E.B., & Markandya, A., (1989) Blueprint for a Green Economy. London: Earthscan Publications Ltd. p154 14 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, (1994) Managing the Environment: The Role of Economic Instruments. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. p28. 15 Hardin, G. (1968) 'The Tragedy of the Commons', Science, vol 162, issue 3859, 13 December, pp1243-1248. 16 Pigou, A. (1932) ‘The Economics of Welfare’, 4th Edition, Macmillan, London. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia market, and hence not paid for at the time of undertaking.17 This is why Sir Nicholas Stern stated in his economic review of climate change that climate change is the biggest market failure ever.18 To counter those that persist in the assumption that economic growth is the cause of environmental degradation and that this can not be helped, one need only to point at the growing number of governments implementing economic incentives, regulation and policy measures to address these market failures, and the resulting decoupling. This has been shown by national and global efforts to reduce ozone depleting chemicals and other air pollutants such as SOx and NOx emissions, significantly reduce the use of asbestos and leaded petrol, reduce waste to landfill and restore forests and other ecosystems. 19 These ‘success stories’ show that, with appropriate policy and economic incentives to drive innovation, it is possible to achieve significant reductions in specific types of pollution with negligible negative effect on economic growth, even opening up new business opportunities. A leading example of this has been global and regional efforts to decouple economic growth from sulphur dioxide pollution through first the 1983 ‘Helsinki Protocol’ and the UNECE Second Sulphur Protocol in 1994. The Second Sulphur Protocol committed nations to targets of reductions of 50 per cent by the year 2000, 70 per cent by 2005, and 80 per cent by 2010. 20 The environmental objective of the Second Sulphur Protocol – eventually to bring sulphur depositions in Europe within the critical loads of receiving ecosystems – is a fundamental principle of ecological sustainability. The emission reduction required was of the order of a factor of five, or 80%. Initial perceptions were that it would be incredibly costly, but the arrival of cost effective low sulphur fuel and a range of supporting technologies altered the cost situation such that the goal was attainable for significantly less cost than anticipated, $90 per ton rather than the anticipated $1,000–1,500 per ton.21 When the costs of sulphur to health and the environment are taken into account, this phase out has had negligible net impact on economic growth (Figure 2.1). 17 Externalities refer to a situation where effects (harmful or beneficial) of production or consumption are imposed on others but cannot be traced or charged back to the originator. The main characteristic of an externality is the separation between the affected individual and the source of the effects. Because of this it is difficult to get the perpetrator to pay for the costs of the harmful effects or the beneficiaries to reimburse those who create benefits to society. Thus, externalities are not built into the market price of a good or service and hence not factored into many decisions by governments, businesses and individuals. Environmental pollution is a classic case of a negative externality. 18 Stern, N et al. (2006) The Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change , Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. 19 Smith, M. Hargroves, K (2008) ‘Cents and Sustainability: Making Sense of How to Grow Economies, Strengthen Communities and Revive the Environment in Our Lifetime’. Earthscan. London. (Forthcoming) Available at http://www.earthscan.co.uk/?TabId=42718&v=383365 Accessed 26 September 2008 20 UNECE (1994) The 1994 Oslo Protocol on Further Reduction of Sulphur Emissions. UNECE. Available at http://www.unece.org/env/lrtap/sulf_h1.htm Accessed 15 August 2008 21 Hodges, H. (1997) Cost of Complying With Environmental Regulations Almost Always Less Than Advertised, Economic Policy Institute. Available at http://www.epi.org/briefingpapers/bp69.pdf. Accessed 14 April 2007. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Figure 2.1: Sulphur Dioxide Emissions from Energy Usage versus GDP from 1990-1998 (Source: OECD Key Environmental Indicators Report, 2004) In this case economic growth and ecological sustainability have been quite compatible. 22 This experience is not unique to sulphur emissions. Historically, when governments have phased in regulation to phase out harmful chemicals, in most cases, innovation and competition has helped to significantly bring down the costs of action. (See Table 2.1) The net economic, environmental and social (health) benefits from reduced pollution loads have been shown to outweigh the costs of action in most cases.23 Table 2.1: Industry original estimates of the cost of particular forms of environmental protection versus the actual costs (in $US) Pollutant Initial Cost Estimate Actual Cost Estimate Overestimation as a Percent of Actual Cost $150 million $75 million 100% Asbestos (for the manufacturing and insulation sectors) Ekins, P. (2000) ‘Economic Growth and Environmental Sustainability’, Chapter 10, Sustainability and Sulphur Emissions: The Case of the UK, 1970-2010. Routledge Publishing, London, New York. 23 OECD (2008) OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030. OECD. Available At http://www.oecd.org/document/20/0,3343,en_2649_37465_39676628_1_1_1_37465,00.html Accessed 22.03.2008 22 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia $350,000 per plant Approx. $0 per plant Infinite Early 1980s: Predicted financial catastrophe as no ‘cheap’ alternatives existed. Total cost globally of implementing the Montreal Protocol US$235 billion in 1997.24 Less that Catastrophe $650-$1,200 per new car $40-$400 per new car 63%-2,900% $200 million – $1 billion $160 million 29%-1,500% $4 billion $250-400 million 900%-1,500% $700 million per year $205 million per year 241% 1989: phase out not considered possible. 1993: phase out considered technologically and economically feasible. n/a Landfill Leachate Mid-1980’s: $14.8 billion 1990: $5.7 billion 159% Sulphur Dioxide 1980s: $1,000–1,500 per ton of sulphur dioxide. 1996: $90 per ton of sulphur dioxide. ~750% Surface Mining $6-$12 per ton of coal $0.50-41 per ton 500%-2,300% Vinyl Chloride $109 million per year $20 million per year 445% Benzene CFCs CFCs-Auto Air Conditioners Coke Oven Emissions OSHA 1970’s Coke Oven Emissions EPA 1980s Cotton Dust Halons Source: Hodges, H. (1999)25 The evidence outlined here suggests that market, informational, institutional, technological design failures and lack of international co-operation are the major causes of unsustainable development rather than economic growth itself. These results outlined above suggest that addressing such failures Bornman, J.F. and van der Leun, J.C. (1998) ‘Frequently asked questions’, Journal of Photochemistry and Photobiology, vol 46. Available at http://www.gcrio.org/ozone/toc.html. Accessed 15 February 2008. 25 Hodges, H. (1997) Cost of Complying With Environmental Regulations Almost Always Less Than Advertised, Economic Policy Institute. Available at http://www.epi.org/briefingpapers/bp69.pdf. Accessed 14 April 2007. 24 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia with effective and purposeful environmental policies, global co-operation plus technological innovation can lead to meaningful levels of decoupling of economic growth from a range of environmental pressures. Despite this evidence still little action has been uncertaken in this area. Much of this lack of action arises from confusion around the use of the term ‘growth’,26 as the term growth means different things to different audiences. When businesses and governments talk about growth they generally mean economic growth: that is, (assuming the expenditure model of measuring GDP) the amount of economic value and monetary transactions as measured by the GDP. When environmentalists talk about growth they are focusing on the growth of physical throughput in the economy, or physical growth. Economic growth and physical growth are of course not the same thing, as: - Economic growth, measured by in terms of GDP of a country is defined as the total market (monetary) value of all final goods and services produced within a country in a given period of time, usually a calendar year. It is also considered the sum of economic value added at every stage of production (the intermediate stages) of all final goods and services produced within a country in a given period of time. - Physical growth of the economy means either that it spreads over more physical area, or that it has a larger material and energy throughput or that it has a larger stock of physical products, buildings or infrastructure. Environmentalists dislike physical growth because it correlates with increased environmental pressures, damage and resource depletion. Thus, based on this understanding, it is then possible for economic growth to be decoupled from physical growth of the economy and associated pollution. Alan AtKisson, leading sustainable development Author, sums it up well: The trick is in separating out two kinds of growth: so-called ‘economic growth’, on the one hand, from growth in the amount of stuff we use and discard on the other [physical growth]. These are two very different phenomena, and they have been falsely—and dangerously— confused for too long. Economic growth, remember, is nothing more than an increase in the flow of money. Because GDP growth has all too often been correlated with the destruction of nature, it’s a measurement environmentalists love to hate... Yet contrary to what many environmentalists believe, there’s nothing inherently ‘unsustainable’ about economic growth—as long as it gets decoupled from the flow of stuff. Money flow [value] can increase, even as material flow [resource use and waste] decreases.27 Paul Ekins, from The Policy Studies Institute in the UK, made the same point in Environmental Sustainability and Economic Growth: The Prospects for Green Growth namely that, ‘It is clear from 26 Philip Sutton has long promoted the clarification over the misunderstanding of the difference between economic and physical throughput growth. See Sutton, P. (2000) ‘Is it Possible for a Green Economy to have High Economic Performance?’ Green Innovations, Melbourne: Available at www.green-innovations.asn.au/econ-mdl.htm. Accessed 1 October 2008 27 See AtKisson Group at http://www.atkisson.com/Global/Home.html Accessed 6 July 2007 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia past experience that the relationship between the economy’s value and its physical scale is variable, and that it is possible to reduce the material intensity of GNP. This establishes the theoretical possibility of GNP growing indefinitely in a finite material world.’28 Thus, if sufficient decoupling can be achieved, it is possible to create a new form of economic growth that is environmentally sustainable and can be sustained for generations to come. What is Decoupling? Before proceeding much further, it is important that to clarify the term decoupling. According to the OECD:, decoupling, ‘has often been used to refer to breaking the link between the growth in environmental pressure associated with creating economic goods and services. Decoupling occurs when growth rate of the environmentally relevant variable is less than that of its economic variable (e.g. GDP) over a period of time.’29 Figure 2.2 provides a stylised version by the authors of a decoupling graph developed to demonstrate the various trends relevant to the decoupling concept. It is assumed that at the start of the time period the relative growth rates of both economic growth and environmental pressures are correlated so that the trend can be established. As can be seen the assumption is that economic growth continues to increase, however the resultant environmental pressures no longer grow at comparable rates. In the case where the growth rate of environmental pressures is less but is still rising, it is said to be ‘relatively’ decoupled, and in the case where the growth rate of environmental pressures is decreasing, it is said to be ‘absolutely’ decoupled. The goal is to first relatively decouple the trends and then absolutely decouple them, however it is unreasonable to expect that the environmental pressures will reduce to zero as they will hit a lower bound as to the minimum amount of pressure to deliver the economic growth. If this lower bound is still higher than the environments carrying capacity then options to offset, remediate or substitute for the damage will need to be developed and represented in the figure as ‘enhanced environmental outcomes’. It is intended that these enhanced outcomes are coupled with the economic growth and each contributes to the others growth. Ekins, P. (2000) ‘Economic Growth and Environmental Sustainability: Prospects for Green Growth’, Routledge Publishing, London, New York. 29 Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development (OECD) (2002) Indicators to Measure Decoupling of Environmental Pressure and Economic Growth. OECD. Paris. 28 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Figure 2.2: Conceptual and stylised representation of a decoupling graph. Source: The Natural Edge Project (2008) It is important to emphasize that there is this potential for nations to compliment decoupling of economic growth from environmental pressures with programs and initiatives to restore nature’s ecosystems and their resilience. South Korea is a good case in point. South Korea has had high economic growth rates for the last 30 years, yet South Korea offers one of the best examples of reforestation to the rest of the world. When the Korean War ended, half a century ago, the mountainous country was largely deforested. Since around 1960 the South Korean government has invested in a major national reforestation effort utilizing village cooperatives involving hundreds of thousands of people to dig trenches and to create terraces for supporting trees on barren mountains. Se-Kyung Chong, researcher at the Korea Forest Research Institute, writes, The result was a seemingly miraculous rebirth of forests from barren land. Today forests cover 65 percent of the country, an area of roughly 6 million hectares. While driving across South Korea in November 2000, it was gratifying for me to see the luxuriant stands of trees on mountains that a generation ago were bare. We can reforest the earth.30 30 Chong, S.K. (2005) Anmyeon-do Recreation Forest: A Millennium of Management, cit in Durst, P et al., (2005) In Search of Excellence: Exemplary Forest Management in Asia and the Pacific, Asia-Pacific Forestry Commission. FAO Regional Office for Asia and the Pacific. Bangkok, pp. 251–59. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia What is the required level of decoupling of economic growth from environmental pressures? In 2004, OECD nations agreed that the following conditions need to be satisfied to achieve sustainable development. The following criteria therefore inform what level of decoupling of economic growth from environmental pressures is needed to achieve sustainable development:31 - Regeneration means that renewable resources shall be used efficiently and their use shall not be permitted to exceed their long-term rates of natural regeneration. (Meaning that we need to improve demand management, increase efficiency of use, and enhance production capacity of renewable resources.) - Substitutability means that non-renewable resources shall be used efficiently and their use limited to levels which can be offset by substitution by renewable resources or other forms of capital. It is interpreted by the Authors that, substitutability then means that non-renewable resources can be used (assuming the other three criteria are met), but must be used efficiently and when they run out or are uneconomical they need to be able to be fully replaced by substitution by renewable resources, hence the ability to source substitutes is the limiting factor on the use of non-renewable resources if it the activity using the resource is to be sustained. (For example if we are to use coal for power generation we can only use it if the other three criteria are met and to the level that it is possible to source alternatives (that also satisfy the other three criteria) to take over once the supply is diminished or uneconomical, such as renewable energy.) - Assimilation means that releases of hazardous or polluting substances to the environment shall not exceed its assimilative capacity; concentrations shall be kept below established critical levels necessary for the protection of human health and the environment. When assimilative capacity is effectively zero (e.g. for hazardous substances that are persistent and/or bio-accumulative), effectively a zero release of such substances is required to avoid their accumulation in the environment. (For example the use of Coal in the above example would need to satisfy, for example, emissions requirements for toxins in waterways and greenhouse gases to the atmosphere to be able to operate sustainably. Hence to meet the criteria for instance, the greenhouse gas emissions from coal combustion would need to be captured and sequestered permanently.) - Avoiding irreversibility means that irreversible adverse effects of human activities on ecosystems and on biogeochemical and hydrological cycles shall be avoided; the natural processes capable of maintaining or restoring the integrity of ecosystems should be safeguarded from adverse impacts of human activities; and the differing levels of resilience and carrying capacity of ecosystems must be considered in order to conserve their populations of threatened, endangered and critical species. 31 OECD (2001) Environmental Strategy for the First Decade of the 21st Century, adopted by OECD Environment Ministers 16 May 2001. Available at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/33/40/1863539.pdf Accessed 5 January 2007. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Taking these four principles as a starting point, each nation needs to assess what level of decoupling is required to achieve sustainable development. There are many factors to consider. Firstly, a wide range of scientific studies have shown that humanity has already in many cases overshot ecological limits and the risks of irreversible effects taking hold over the coming decades are real. The OECD Environmental Outlook 2030 warns that: Without more ambitious policies, increasing pressures on the environment could cause irreversible damage within the next few decades.32 The Secretary General of the OECD in 2008 Angel Gurría stated that: If we want to avoid irreversible damage to our environment and the very high costs of policy inaction, we’d better start working right away.33 Research has shown that the scale of the human economy now overwhelms many of the Earth’s material cycles, such as the nitrogen,34 carbon,35 and water cycles.36 According to an analysis of the world's ecosystems prepared by the United Nations, the World Bank, and the World Resources Institute in 2000, ‘There are considerable signs that the capacity of ecosystems, the biological engines of the planet, to produce many of the goods and services we depend on is rapidly declining’. This evidence is also covered in detail in numerous publications such as The State of the World reports,37 Limits to Growth - The Twenty and Thirty Year Update,38 Ekin’s Economic Growth and Environmental Sustainability,39 And the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment.40 Therefore rapid and significant decoupling of economic growth from environmental pressures and impacts is needed. There are a number of factors responsible for environmental impact. The most common formula used to reflect this is the IPAT formula by Ehrlich and Commoner.41 - I=AxPxT where 32 OECD (2008) OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030. OECD. Available At http://www.oecd.org/document/20/0,3343,en_2649_37465_39676628_1_1_1_37465,00.html Accessed 22.03.2008. 33 Ibid. 34 Vitousek, P. M. (1994) ‘Beyond global warming: Ecology and global change’, Ecology, vol 75, pp 1861-1876; Vitousek, P.M. et al. (1997) ‘Human alteration of the global nitrogen cycle: Causes and consequences’, Ecological Applications, vol. 7, pp 737-750. 35 Houghton, J.T., Filho, L.G.M., Callander, B.A., Harris, N., Kattenberg, A. and Maskell, K. (eds.) (1996) Climate Change 1995: The Science of Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, p 572. Contribution of Working Group I to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. 36 Postel, S., Daily, G.C. and Erlich, P.R. (1996) ‘Human Appropriation of Renewable Fresh Water’, Science, vol. 271, pp 785-788. 37 Worldwatch Institute (n.d.) State of the World reports, Worldwatch Institute. Available at http://www.worldwatch.org/taxonomy/term/38. Accessed 12 December 2006. 38 Meadows, D.H. Meadows, D.L. and Randers, J. (2004) Limits to Growth-The 30 year Update. Earthscan/James&James, London. 39 Ekins, P. (2000) Economic Growth and Environmental Sustainability, Routledge Publishing, New York. 40 Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2005) Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Synthesis, Island Press, Washington, DC. 41 Commoner, B. (1971) ‘The Environmental Cost of Economic Growth’ in Shurr, S. (1971) Energy, Economic Growth and the Environment, John Hopkins University Press, Baltimore/London, pp 30-65. [It should be noted clearly though that the ’T’ for technology in The Commoner Ehrlich equation uses the word technology in the broadest sense of the word. The variable T in the Commoner-Ehrlich equation refers to two forms of reductions to environmental impact namely those due to economic structure (changing the composition of output towards less damaging products, changing the production- consumption system.) and technical change (substituting less damaging factor inputs for more damaging ones such as using renewable energy, and increasing the resource productivity)] Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia - I = Impact: the human impact on the environmental. - P = Population. - A = Affluence: the number of products or services consumed per person (i.e.: for economists the annual Gross National Product per capita.) - T = Technology: the environmental impact per unit of product/service consumed using a particular technology. Using this formula enables the approximate magnitude of decoupling to be calculated. Because of rising global population and affluence forecasts for the next 50 years, this formula shows that T, expressed as a function of the environmental impact per unit of product or service consumed needs to be reduced globally by at least 5-10 fold, Factor 5-10, by 2050 if economic development is to return within the ecological limits of the Earth’s ecological life support systems. This has been the finding of a major government study, the Netherlands Government’s Inter-ministerial Sustainable Technology Development Programme. The programme is one of the first to both work out the scale and speed of change required to achieve nationwide ecological and social sustainable development over the next 50 years. In setting a time-horizon of 50 years – two generations into the future – it was found that ten to twenty-fold eco-efficiency improvements will be needed to achieve meaningful reductions in environmental stress. It was also found that the benefits of incremental technological development could not provide such improvements. Leo Jansen, Chairman, Netherlands Inter-ministerial Sustainable Technology Development Program, 200042 Can humanity achieve significant decoupling fast enough and on a scale large enough? These targets may, on first impression, seem unachievable. However where governments have had the courage in the past to address pollution with strong policy mechanisms, industry has almost always found ways to reduce the costs of achieving decoupling. This has enabled industry and nations to achieve decoupling targets which, at first, were thought to be too ambitious. For example, in Massachusetts the USA government, business and R&D institutions working together, have achieved a 70 per cent reduction in toxic chemicals pollution from 1989 to 1997 without harming profits and economic growth.43 The following parts in this report will show that there are many other examples of where purposeful policy, combined with effective R&D has lowered costs of and enabled significant decoupling targets to be achieved. 42 Weaver, P., Jansen, L., van Grootveld, G., van Spiegel, E. and Vergragt, P. (2000) Sustainable Technology Development, Greenleaf Publishing, Sheffield, UK, Foreword, p 7. 43 See The Massachusetts Toxics Use Reduction Institute at http://www.turi.org/ Accessed 24 September 2008 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia There is a surprising amount of evidence to suggest that, through the latest strategies of advanced resource productivity and design for sustainability, significant factor 5 to 10 fold levels of decoupling can be achieved. Probably one of the most significant bodies of evidence comes from The Netherlands’ Government Sustainable Technology Development project, described in detail in Paul Weaver et al.’s Sustainable Technology Development. 44 It is one of the first national government programs to investigate and describe how it is possible to decouple economic growth and environmental damage by as much as 75-95 percent (a Factor of 4-20) over a 50-year period in many critical sectors of the economy. In addition to this, the examples in books like Factor 4: Doubling Wealth, Halving Resource Use,45 Natural Capitalism: The Next Industrial Revolution, 46 Cradle to Cradle, 47 and Design for Sustainability48 show that humanity now possesses enough knowledge, understanding and skills to achieve significant decoupling of economic growth from environmental pressures. The fact that innovations and sustainable design strategies exist to achieve large factor 10 style reductions in environmental pressures was acknowledged by World Bank as early as 1992. The World Bank argued that, ‘If the environmental policies required are put in place, it is possible to reduce pollution by factors of 10 or more in the most serious cases, even if energy consumption levels rise fivefold. Furthermore, developing countries would find themselves better-off both economically and environmentally’.49 This position is supported by a range of investigations including those presented in a background paper for the World Bank’s World Development Report in 1992 that brought together a range of impressive evidence to show that it is possible to reduce environmental pressures in a number of major fields of concern on the scale required of a Factor of 5-10. (See Table 2.2) Table 2.2: Relative Pollution (or Damage) Intensities of Polluting or Low-Polluting Practices Relative pollution intensities of polluting and low-polluting practices for selected activities and pollutants (polluting practice = 100) Source and type of emissions or environmental damage Index per unit of output Polluting Low-polluting practices LowPolluting Electricity production 44 Weaver, P., Jansen, L., Van Grootveld, G., Van Spiegel, E., and Vergragt, P. (2000) Sustainable Technology Development, Greenleaf Publishing, Sheffield, UK. Available at http://www.greenleaf-publishing.com/catalogue/std.htm. Accessed 12 December 2006. 45 von Weizsäcker, E., Lovins, A.B. and Lovins, L. H. (1997) Factor Four: Doubling Wealth, Halving Resource Use, Earthscan/James&James, London. 46 Hawken, P., Lovins, A. B. and Lovins, L. H. (1999) Natural Capitalism: Creating the Next Industrial Revolution, Earthscan/James&James, London. Available at www.natcap.org. Accessed 12 December 2006. 47 McDonough, W and Braungart, M (2002) Cradle to Cradle – Remaking the Way we Make Things, North Point Press. 48 Birkeland, J. (2002) Design for Sustainability: A Sourcebook of Integrated Eco-Logical Solutions, Earthscan/James&James, London. 49 Anderson, D. (1992) ‘Economic Growth and the Environment’, Background Paper for the World Bank, World Development Report 1992, World Bank, Washington, DC. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Particulate matter 100 < 0.1 Natural gas; clean coal technologies Carbon monoxide (CO) 100 < 0.1 Scrubbers; low-sulphur fuels Sulphur dioxide (SO2) 100 0 to < 5 Low NOx combustion methods Nitrogen oxides (NOx) 100 5 to 10 Emission control catalysts Motor vehicles: diesel engines Particulate matter 100 < 10 Clean fuels and particulate traps Sulphur dioxide (SO2) 100 5 Low-sulphur fuels Motor vehicles: gasoline engines Lead 100 0 Unleaded and reformulated fuels; catalytic converters Carbon monoxide (CO) 100 5 Unleaded and reformulated fuels; catalytic converters 100 20 Unleaded and reformulated fuels; catalytic converters 100 5 Unleaded and reformulated fuels; catalytic converters Nitrogen oxides (NOx) Volatile organic compounds All fossil fuels for electricity 100 < 01 Marine pollution 100 < 10 Surface water pollution 100 negligible Sewerage works, effluent control technologies Soil erosion 100 negligible Agro-forestry, soil erosion prevention practices Forestry 100 negligible Sustainable practises Carbon dioxide (CO2) Renewable energy sources Other areas of concern Industrial effluents 100 and wastes (Source: Anderson, D. (1992)50) small Effluent control technologies: waste reduction or prevention. Other publications go further and argue that it is possible to design buildings, 51 developments, industrial processes 52 , agriculture 53 and waste management processes 54 to not only reduce their negative impacts but to then achieve enhanced environmental quality, known as being ‘Restorative’. 50 Ibid. 51 Birkeland, J. (2002) Design for Sustainability: A Sourcebook of Integrated Eco-Logical Solutions, Earthscan/James&James, London. McDonough, W. and Braungart, M. (2002) Cradle to Cradle: Remaking the Way We Make Things, North Point Press, San Francisco. 53 Benyus, J. (1997) Biomimicry: Innovation Inspired by Nature, HarperCollins, New York. 54 Hargroves, K. and Smith, M. (eds) (2006) Waste streams to value streams, in: Marinova, D., Annandale, D., and Phillimore, J. (eds) (2006) The International Handbook on Environmental Technology Management, Edward Elgar, Northampton, MA, USA. 52 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Further evidence to support the claim that environmental pressures can be significantly decoupled from economic growth comes from the 2002 OECD report Indicators to Measure Decoupling of Environmental Pressure from Economic Growth.55 This report shows that, of all the areas currently measured by environmental indicators, there is at least one OECD country that has achieved significant decoupling. 56 OECD countries like the Netherlands have made significant progress on decoupling economic growth from a range of environmental pressures, as shown in Figure 2.3. Figure 2.3: Achieving decoupling in the Netherlands: 1985-2010 Source: Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency (2004)57 Can the Economy afford to invest in Decoupling across major Environmental Pressures? The OECD58 in 2008 published new economic modelling which looked at the economic costs of seeking to simultaneously decouple economic growth from a range of major environmental pressures. The OECD undertook economic modelling of the economic costs of action on the following policy package: - mitigating climate change to CO2 450 ppm equivalent by 2030, through implementing a carbon price of US$25/tonne of carbon.59 55 Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development (OECD) (2002) Indicators to Measure Decoupling of Environmental Pressure and Economic Growth, OECD, Paris. 56 Ibid. 57 Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency and the National Institute for Public Health and the Environment (2005) Environmental Balance 2004. The State of the Dutch Environment, Summary, Available at http://www.mnp.nl/en/publications/2004/Environmental_Balance_2004.html Accessed 1 October 2008. 58 OECD (2008) OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030. OECD. Available At http://www.oecd.org/document/20/0,3343,en_2649_37465_39676628_1_1_1_37465,00.html Accessed 22.03.2008. 59 Application of a price on carbon across all sectors, via a carbon tax starting at USD 25 per tonne of CO2eq, which increases in real terms by 2.4% per year. The carbon price was phased-in by region, starting in OECD countries in 2012, Brazil, India, Russia and China in 2020 and the rest of the world in 2030 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia - policies to bring forward the introduction and uptake of second generation biofuels, i.e. those using agricultural waste material or woody inputs developed on abandoned or marginal soils, rather than competing with agricultural land use. - ensure clean water and sanitation to 50 per cent of people who currently do not have it. Connecting all urban dwellers with improved sanitation by 2030. For existing sewage treatment, treatment is upgraded to the next best level in terms of removal of nitrogen compounds. - achieving “maximum feasible reductions” in air pollutant emissions. For instance, reduce SOx and NOx air pollution levels to 31 and 37 per cent less in 2030 to a business as usual baseline (and about one-third less than 2005 levels). The OECD modelling showed that these key environmental challenges can be addressed at a cost of just 0.5 and 2.5 per cent GDP by 2030 and 2050 respectively. This is equivalent to a reduction in annual GDP growth of just 0.1% of world GDP in 2030. As Kenneth Ruffing, former chief economist for the OECD Environment Directorate, writes; ‘In its recent report on the OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030, the costs of policy inaction were found to be particularly high for water pollution, especially in developing countries; for air pollution, as much as a few percentages of GDP in the US, the EU and China; important in the case of unsustainable natural resource management; and for climate change, in the range of 1 to 10 per cent of global output.’60 A range of studies now show clearly that the costs of action on decoupling significantly less than the costs of inaction, particularly for greenhouse gas emissions as presented in the following section.61 Measuring Progress through Decoupling Indicators – How do we know if we are on track? Measurement matters, because, unless reliable methods and relevant indicators are used to measure progress in the decoupling process, it will prove very difficult for governments, businesses and communities to know if their efforts are heading in the right direction and make adjustments accordingly to either accelerate efforts or slow them off. Measurement is also vitally important to ensure that government and business can be held accountable for their actions and policies. The point is not to be working endlessly towards decoupling but to achieve it to a meaningful level. It is important, therefore, that adequate decoupling measurement frameworks are developed and used by nations to assess progress. The OECD report published in 2002 “Indicators to Measure Decoupling of Environmental Pressure and Economic Growth” 62 provides nations with a starting set of See Ruffing, K (2008) ‘Decoupling Environmental Pressures from Economic Growth’. Forward in Smith, M. Hargroves, K (2008) ‘Cents and Sustainability: Making Sense of How to Grow Economies, Strengthen Communities and Revive the Environment in Our Lifetime’. Earthscan. London. (Forthcoming) Available at http://www.earthscan.co.uk/?TabId=42718&v=383365 Accessed 26 September 2008 61 Stern, N et al. (2006) ‘The Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change’ , Cambridge University Press, Cambridge . Available at www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/independent_reviews/stern_review_economics_climate_change/sternreview_index.cfm . Accessed 14 April 2007 OECD (2008) OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030. OECD. Available At http://www.oecd.org/document/20/0,3343,en_2649_37465_39676628_1_1_1_37465,00.html Accessed 22.03.2008 62 OECD Secretariat (2002) ‘Indicators to Measure Decoupling of Environmental Pressure and Economic Growth’. OECD. Paris. 60 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia decoupling indicators to enable measurement and comparison of progress to achieve decoupling of economic growth from environmental pressures. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia 2. Decoupling Economic Growth from Greenhouse Gas Emissions63 The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) declared in 2007 that the debate over whether or not climate change is human induced (mainly from the burning of fossil fuels and forests) is over. 64 Thanks to the IPCC process, there is now broad international consensus that, to avoid dangerous climate change, global warming needs to be kept to no more than 2 degrees Celsius above pre-industrial levels. A 2 degree rise will not be easy to avoid as to date global temperatures have increased an average of 0.74 degrees Celsius during the 20th century. 65 The International Energy Agency forecasts that if policies remain unchanged, world energy demand is set to increase by over 50 percent between now and 2030.66 At the same time, the IPCC has warned since 1988 that nations need to stabilise their concentrations of CO2 equivalent emissions, requiring significant reductions in the order of 60 percent or more by 2050.67 In the latest 4th Assessment, the IPCC argues that the avoid dangerous climate change global emissions need to start to decline no later than 2012-13 and that by 2020 global cuts of 25-40 per cent are needed. By 2050, at least 80 per cent cuts are needed. Hence significant efforts are required to decouple economic growth from the impacts of greenhouse gas emissions if we are to secure a vibrant economy and stable environment into the future. This decoupling may prove to be the most important issue in the 21st century, one that all others are affected by and will rely on strong results from, the true test of human ingenuity. Multiple Benefits of Decoupling Greenhouse Gas Emissions Whilst such decoupling targets may seem ambitious there are now numerous peer reviewed studies showing how such reductions can technically and economically be achieved for national economies. (See Appendix 2) In addition, the Climate Group’s 2005 report Profits Up, Carbon Down68 showed that 43 major companies have increased their bottom line by a total of $15 Billion whilst developing ways to reduce their greenhouse gas emissions by as much as 60%. Multinationals like IBM and Dupont have succeeded through such measures on reducing greenhouse gas emissions by over 60% since 1990 whilst saving over US$2 Billion each. These companies were able to decouple profits from greenhouse gas emissions through increasing their energy productivity and focusing on delivering a growing range of services with less energy. 63 Note that Sections 2-6 of this report have been developed by Michael Smith and Karlson Hargroves, The Natural Edge Project, Griffith University and the Australian National University, under the supervision of Professor Ernst von Weizsäcker. The content is based on research undertaken by Michael Smith as part of his PhD, with additional research and editing by Karlson Hargroves 64 IPCC (2007) Global climate projections, Climate Change 2007: The Physical Sciences Basis, Available at http://ipccwg1.ucar.edu/wg1/wg1-report.html Accessed 8.01.08 65 See Chair of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) Rajendra Pachauri’s 2007 Opening Session Speech at http://www.un.org/webcast/climatechange/highlevel/2007/pdfs/Pachauri.pdf Accessed 24 September 2008 66 International Energy Agency (2005) ‘World Energy Outlook 2005’, Press Releases, IEA, UK. Available at http://www.iea.org/Textbase/press/pressdetail.asp?PRESS_REL_ID=163. Accessed 3 March 2007. 67 The Climate Group (2005) Profits Up, Carbon Down, The Climate Group. Available at www.theclimategroup.org/assets/Carbon_Down_Profit_Up.pdf. Accessed 3 March 2007. 68 The Climate Group (2005) Profits Up, Carbon Down. The Climate Group. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Increasing energy productivity has one of the best rates of return of any investment. Studies show that the economic multiplier from energy efficiency investments is significant. 69 Investments in energy efficiency have a higher economic multiplier than general expenditure as energy efficiency investments provide a return on investment. Energy efficiency investments also have a higher economic multiplier because they reduce demand for energy and thus delay (and even in some cases prevent) the need to invest in new energy infrastructure and maintenance. Investments in energy efficiency also create jobs, meaning that more is spent in the local economy. Hence more of a city’s or town’s energy dollars are being spent in a way that helps the local economy to grow. Also these new local “green” jobs have a direct effect attracting more people to the city or town who contribute to that local economy. It can create a virtuous cycle. Several local and state governments have analyzed actual and projected economic development effects of energy efficiency or alternative energy projects. Osage Municipal Utilities chose to help its customers use less energy by helping them invest in energy efficiency. In doing so, the OMU’s Demand-Side Management Program, 70 saved its customers in this small rural town US$1.2 million annually, which is almost US$200 a year in energy bills per household. A study of economic multipliers in Osage, Ohio, found that a $1.00 purchase of ordinary consumer goods in a local store generated $1.90 of economic activity in the local economy. In comparison investments in energy efficiency generated $2.23.71 Costs of Inaction versus Costs of Action The Stern Review,72 published in 2006, demonstrated that rising greenhouse gas emissions and the resulting climate change now threatens the very economic growth which they have helped to foster. Stern called climate change the greatest market failure ever. The Stern Review states that: We estimate the total cost of business as usual climate change to equate to an average reduction in global per capita consumption of 5 per cent at a minimum now and for ever.73 The Stern Review describes how the cost would increase were the model to take into account direct impacts on the environmental and human health, the effects of positive feedbacks and the disproportionate burden of climate change on the poor and vulnerable globally. According to Stern, taking these three factors into account takes the cost of climate change up to as much as 20 per cent of global GDP. The Stern Review predicts that, if fast and dramatic action is not taken on climate change, then climate change could cause an economic recession to rival the great economic recession of the 1930s. As the Stern Review argues, if humanity fails to rapidly mitigate climate change, climate change will increase more rapidly due to positive feedback effects. Respected scientists like 69 Economic multipliers measure the increase in GDP for each dollar of government or business expenditure on different activities in the economy. The economic multiplier, also known as the multiplier effect, is a measure of how much economic activity can be generated in a community by different combinations of purchasing and investment. 70 US Department of Energy (1996) The Jobs Connection. US DOE Available at http://www.localenergy.org/pdfs/Document%20Library/The%20Jobs%20Connection.pdf Accessed 1 June 2008 71 Ibid. 72 Stern, N et al. (2006) The Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change , Cambridge University Press, Cambridge . Available at www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/independent_reviews/stern_review_economics_climate_change/sternreview_index.cfm . Accessed 14 April 2007 73 Ibid. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia NASA’s James Hansen argue that if rapid mitigation does not occur then the feedbacks and amplifications between environmental impacts will bring ecosystems to there “tipping points”, and that once this occurs it will cause a global catastrophe.74 Such tipping points related to greenhouse gas pollution occur when positive feedbacks from existing global warming lead to a jump in global average temperatures without any additional anthropogenic greenhouse gas emissions. A number of these positive feedbacks75 are now already occurring at a faster rate76 than scientists had previously predicted77 increasing the risks of dangerous climate change. These include: The weakening of the natural ocean carbon sinks reducing the amount of greenhouse gas that can be absorbed.78 The weakening of the natural land carbon sinks reducing the amount of greenhouse gas that can be absorbed and even begin to release it.79 The release of methane80 from peat deposits, wetlands and thawing permafrost.81 The melting of reflective sea ice which is replaced by dark heat absorbing water. Conversely the costs of rapid action on cliamte change are relatively small compared to the costs of inaction. Stern predicts that ‘… the costs of action – reducing greenhouse gas emissions is to avoid the worst impacts of climate change – can be limited to around 1 percent of global GDP each year. The investment that takes place in the next 10-20 years will have a profound effect on the climate in the second half of this century and the next. (Inaction now) and over the coming decades could create risks of major disruption to economic and social activity, on a scale similar to those associated with the great wars and the economic depression of the first half of the 20th century. And it will be difficult or impossible to reverse these changes.’82 Reducing the Costs of Action Our Common Future, published as the report to the World Commission on Environment and Development in 1987, was one of the first works to demonstrate that through implementing a range 74 Hansen, J., Sato,M., et al. (2007) Climate Change and Trace Gases, Phil. Trans. Royal Soc. 365: 1925-1954, doi:10.1098/rsta.2007.2052, Available At http://pubs.giss.nasa.gov/abstracts/2007/Hansen_etal_2.html Accessed 8.01.08 75 Ibid. 76 Pearman, G. et al (2007) Evidence of Accelerated Climate Change Prepared by the Climate Adaptation Science and Policy Initiative, The University of Melbourne for the Climate Institute. Available at http://www.climateinstitute.org.au/images/stories/CI056_EACC_Report_v1.pdf Accessed 8.01.08 77 Pittock, B. (2006) Are Scientists Underestimating Climate Change? EOS, Transactions American Geophysical Union 87, no. 34: 340341. 78 Le Quere, C. et al (2007) Saturation of the Southern Ocean CO2 Sink Due to Recent Climate Change. Science. Volume 316, Issue 5832, pp. 1735- (2007). 79 Cox, P., Betts, R., Jones, C., Spall, S. and Totterdell, I. (2000) Acceleration of Global Warming Due to Carbon-Cycle Feedbacks in a Coupled Climate Model, Nature, 408, pp184–187. 80 Wickland, K.P., Striegl, R.G. Neff, J.C Sachs. T. (2006) “Effects of Permafrost Melting on CO 2 and CH4 Exchange of Poorly Drained Black Spruce Lowland.” Journal of Geophysical Research 111, no. G02011. 81 Walter, K. M., Zimov S. A., et al. (2006) Melting Lakes in Siberia Emit Greenhouse Gas, Nature 443: 71 - 75, http://www.nature.com/news/2006/060904/full/060904-10.html Accessed 8.01.08 82 Stern, N et al. (2006) The Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change , Cambridge University Press, Cambridge . Available at www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/independent_reviews/stern_review_economics_climate_change/sternreview_index.cfm . Accessed 14 April 2007 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia of proven climate change mitigation solutions economic growth could cost effectively be decoupled from greenhouse gas emissions. As Our Common Future stated: During the past 13 years, many industrial countries saw the energy content of growth fall significantly as a result of increases in energy efficiency averaging 1.7 per cent annually between 1973 and 1983. And this energy efficiency solution costs less, by savings made on the extra primary supplies required to run traditional equipment… The costs of improving the end-use equipment is frequently much less than the cost of building more primary supply capacity. In Brazil, for example, it has been shown that for a discounted, total investment of $4 Billion in more efficient end-use technologies (such as more efficient refrigerators, street lighting, or motors) it would be feasible to defer construction of 21 gigawatts of new electrical supply capacity, corresponding to a discounted capital savings for new supplies of $19 Billion in the period 1986 to 2000. Our Common Future concluded that with the right mix of policy and a carbon price signal to further encourage, ‘the design and adoption of more energy efficient homes, industrial processes and transportation vehicles,… (and) investments in renewables…within the next 50 years, nations have the opportunity to produce the same levels of energy services with as little as half the primary supply currently consumed.’ In Beyond Interdependence, MacNeill, Winsemius and Yakushiji 83 built on from Our Common Future and brought together studies which provide further support for ambitious commitments to decouple economic growth from greenhouse gas emissions. They stated that ‘an increasing number of studies show that industrialised nations can make substantial reductions in greenhouse gas emissions through energy efficiency and other measures that, at best, return a profit, and at worst, break even.’84 The work brought together a range of studies which showed that the opportunities of energy efficiency make it possible to achieve short term targets very cost effectively.85,86 Ten years after the publication of Our Common Future, the book Factor 4: Doubling Your Wealth and Having Resource Usage87 lead by Ernst von Weizsäcker, was released as a report to the Club of Rome and highlighted a significant array of case studies demonstrating that large energy productivity gains can be made cost effectively. Building on from these significant works a 2007 study by The MacNeill, J, Winsemius, P. and Yakushiji, T. (1991) Beyond Interdependence: The Meshing of the World’s Economy and the Earth’s Ecology, Oxford University Press, Oxford. (MacNeill was the Secretary-General of the Brundtland Commission and co-author of Our Common Future) 84 Goldenberg, J. Johannson, T. Reddy, A. and Williams, E. (1985) Energy for Development. Washington D.C. World Resource Institute. D.C 85 The DPA Group, Inc (1989) Study on the Reductino of Energy-Related Greenhouse Gas Emissions. Commissioned by the Ontario Ministery of Energy (with support from all the federal and provincial energy departments of Canada). Prepared by DPA Group Inc., in association with CH4 International Ltd., RCG/Hagler, Bailly,Inc., Steven G. Diener and Associates Ltd., Ontario Ministry fo Energy. Jackson, T. (1991) ‘The Least Cost Greenhouse Planning:Supply Curves for Global Warming Abatement.’Energy Policy 19 January/February 1991. 86 Johannson, T. Bodlund, B. and Williams, R. (eds) (1989) The Challenge of Choices: Technology Options for the Swedish Electricity Sector in Electricity: Efficient End use and New Generation Technologies and Planning Implications. Lund University Press. Sweden. 87 Von Weizsäcker, E., Lovins, A.B. and Lovins, L.H. (1997) Factor 4: Doubling Wealth, Halving Resource Use, Earthscan/James&James, London. 83 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Natural Edge Project, in partnership with the Commonwealth Scientific and Industrial Research Organisation (CSIRO), Griffith University and the Australian National University 88 further demonstrated this, and resulted in the release of a 600 page free access online textbook that features existing case studies and/or designs of: Households rapidly retrofitted - reducing emissions by over 60 percent.i (Virtually) net climate neutral buildings.ii Net climate neutral manufactured products.iii Net climate positive paper and pulp mills.iv Food processors that can reduce emissions by 30-80 percent through energy efficiency, onsite co-generation and/or renewable energy.v Supermarkets and bakeries that use 40 percent less energy than market average through energy efficiency initiatives.vi Fast food retail outlets that use 40-70 percent less energy than market average through energy efficiency and better design.vii Lighting,viii HVACix and motor systems,x that use at least 30-60 percent less energy than the industry average. Office IT systems and servers that together use over 60 percent less energy.xi Public street lighting89 that is at least 50 percent more energy efficient than currently used street lighting. Overseas cities that are rapidly shifting to sustainable transport patterns.xii Carsxiii and trucksxiv that are at least 50 percent more fuel efficient than those using the internal combustion engine. Another way to help reduce the costs of action is through utilising the market and price signals. Such market based approaches do not impose a particular greenhouse gas reduction strategy on business but rather allow business themselves to innovate to find the most cost effective ways to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. As early as the late 1980s, Norwegian90 and Dutch91 studies showed that increasing indirect taxes on gasoline, heating and transport fuels, whilst offsetting this with tax reductions on income and payroll tax, would stabilise GHG emissions by 2000 at 1987 levels. Introducing a carbon price signal gives economic value to emissions reductions and motivates action. Direct emitters, such as electricity generators, change their fuel mix (away from coal towards natural 88 Smith, M., Hargroves, K., Stasinopoulos, P., Stephens, R., Desha, C., and Hargroves, S. (2007) Energy Transformed: Sustainable Energy Solutions for Climate Change Mitigation, The Natural Edge Project (TNEP), Australia.’ Available at www.naturaledgeproject.net/Sustainable_Energy_Solutions_Portfolio.aspx. Accessed 13. February 2008. 89 See ICLEI Public Street Lighting at http://www.iclei.org/index.php?id=6473. Accessed 13. February 2008. 90 Bye, B., Bye, T., and Lorentsen, L. (1989) ‘SIMEN: Studies in Industry, Environment and Energy Towards 2000.’Central Bureau of Statistics, Discussion Paper No.44, Oslo. 91 Netherlands Central Planning Bureau in National Environmental Policy Plan of the Netherlands, Ministry of Housing, Physical Planning, and the Environment, the Netherlands. cit. MacNeil, J, Winsemius, P. Yakushiji, T. (1991) Beyond Interdependence: The Meshing of the World’s Economy and the Earth’s Ecology, Oxford University Press, Oxford Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia gas and renewables), and introduce new technologies such as carbon capture and storage as these become cost effective in light of a rising ‘carbon price’. With a price on carbon, energy users including consumers and other businesses are motivated to: choose more energy efficient appliances and technologies, which can reduce energy use while maintaining or improving the underlying energy service provided (such as a hot shower or commuter travel). change consumption patterns over time towards products and services with lower embodied emissions and energy. The increased attention to emissions and energy efficiency also has an important role in supporting environmental awareness and helping to identify win-win opportunities to reduce costs and improve the efficiency of resource use. Invest in carbon offset programs. Re-vegetation projects also benefit from the introduction of the carbon signal, which provides a new revenue source for biodiversity plantings and other ‘carbon sinks’ that offset emissions. A carbon price signal plus other smart regulations and policies can effectively decouple greenhouse gas emissions and energy use from economic growth. In countries and states where a carbon price signal has been used with other complimentary greenhouse policies, like Sweden and California, USA there is already decoupling of economic growth and greenhouse gas emissions occurring. Other cost effective ways to reduce the costs of action include investing in avoided deforestation, sustainable transport, reducing emissions from non-CO2 greenhouse gases, increasing recycling and investing in sustainable transport. A comprehensive approach to decoupling economic growth from greenhouse gas emissions, which includes such measures will also achieve significant co-benefits: such as reducing air pollution (from the transport sector), reducing waste to landfill and increasing recycling and whilst also creating significant biodiversity and ecosystem service benefits through protection of forests and remnant vegetation and investment in carbon offsets. Aligning greenhouse gas reduction policies to ensure simultaneous reduction of additional environmental pressures helps to reduce the costs of action significantly. 92 As The Stern Review states, The world does not need to choose between averting climate change and promoting growth and development. Changes in energy technologies and in the structure of economies have created opportunities to decouple (economic) growth from greenhouse gas emissions. Indeed, ignoring climate change will eventually damage economic growth. Tackling climate change is the pro-growth strategy for the longer term, and it can be done in a way that does not cap the aspirations for growth of rich or poor countries.93 92 Smith, M., Hargroves, K., Desha, C. and Stasinopoulos, P. (2008) Analysis of the Costs of Inaction versus the Costs of Action on Climate Change for Australia, a submission by TNEP to the Garnaut Review. Available at http://www.naturaledgeproject.net/Documents/TNEPSubmission.pdf Accessed 26 September 2008 93 Stern, N. (2006) The Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change, Executive Summary Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, p10. Available at. http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/media/8AC/F7/Executive_Summary.pdf. Accessed 14 April 2007 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia More countries are beginning to understand that there are cost effective ways to achieve significant decoupling of economic growth from greenhouse gas emissions. This is shown by the fact that Iceland, New Zealand, Norway and Costa Rica have committed to becoming net climate neutral - 100 per cent decoupling of economic growth from greenhouse gas emissions - over the next 30 years through energy efficiency, demand management, renewable energy, sustainable transport options and carbon offsets. Policy Implications and Recommendations Sir Nicholas Stern has called climate change the biggest market failure ever. Hence no one single policy is going to be adequate to underpin decoupling of economic growth from greenhouse gas emissions. The world economy for the last two hundred years has achieved remarkable economic growth partly because of access to cheap fossil fuels. It will take time to transition to a low carbon energy economy. There are significant barriers for change, not just from vested interests, but from a wide range of market, informational and institutional failures, together with the inherent complexity of the issues. Hence international experience shows that those countries and cities which are succeeding in decoupling economic growth from greenhouse gas emissions are not simply relying on an emission trading scheme, or a carbon tax, or behaviour change programs, but are taking a multifaceted portfolio approach to climate change policy. Thus, in addition to an emission trading scheme or carbon tax, decoupling economic growth from greenhouse gas emissions is most likely to be achieved if countries implement a range of related complimentary policy measures and programs.94 A range of publications are available which provide an overview of policy recommendations to compliment emission trading schemes and carbon taxes to ensure barriers are overcome and instead there are clear incentives to invest in strategies that will reduce the costs of action.95 94 Centre for International Economics (2008) Discussion paper for the 9th National Business Leaders Forum for Sustainable Development, reports commissioned by the Property Council and the Australian Sustainable Built Environment Council. Available at http://www.webls.info/weblease/clientimages/nblf/National_Business_Leaders_Forum_-_Outcome_Statement.pdf. Accessed 15 June 2008. 95 Stern, N et al. (2006) The Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change , Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Saddler, H., Diesendorf, M. and Denniss, R. (2004) A Clean Energy Future for Australia Energy Strategies, WWF, Canberra. Available at http://wwf.org.au/ourwork/climatechange/cleanenergyfuture/ Accessed 14 April 2007. Smith, M., Hargroves, K,, Desha, C. and Stasinopoulos, P. (2008) Analysis of the Costs of Inaction versus the Costs of Action on Climate Change for Australia, a submission by TNEP to the Garnaut Review. Available at http://www.naturaledgeproject.net/Documents/TNEPSubmission.pdf Accessed 26 September 2008 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia 3. Decoupling Economic Growth from Freshwater Extraction and Pollution96 Climate change threatens to significantly reduce water availability and lead to greater frequency of droughts in many countries. Already one third of the world’s population lives in countries are experiencing moderate to high levels of water shortage. According to the OECD that number could rise to two thirds within 30 years unless serious efforts are made to decouple economic growth from freshwater extraction and water pollution.97 The IPCC Chair Dr Pachauri has stated in 2007 that: Glaciers in the Himalayas provide the water source for one-sixth of humanity. Their decline threatens the water supply of billions… The gross per capita water availability in India is projected to decline from 1820 cubic meters per year in 2001 to 1140 cubic meters per year in 2050.98 Around the world, groundwater extracted from deep wells is the main source of drinking water for over three billion people.99 The failure of governments to limit pumping to the sustainable yield of aquifers means that water tables are now rapidly falling in countries that contain more than half the world’s people, including the big three grain producers— China, India, and the United States. 100 Some experts fear that these risks of severe water shortages will lead to conflict. These facts explain why sustainable management of freshwater resources is so critical to achieving sustainable development as a whole. This is why the OECD Environment Directorate has established as two of its main decoupling indicators as ‘decoupling economic growth from freshwater abstraction’ and another to ‘measure water quality and water pollution levels’. (See Figure 4.1) Multiple Benefits of Decoupling Freshwater Extraction and Pollution Most nations’ water infrastructure assets total tens to hundreds of billions of dollars, at least half of which is for urban water supply and sewerage. Demand management and improving water productivity can significantly reduce the need for the construction of new dams, new treatment plants and reducing the maintenance of the pipes and associated infrastructure used to deliver and remove water. Numerous cost effective demand management and water productivity opportunities exist in most economies due to the fact that water has been subsidized to be cheaply priced for farmers and industry and because urban water utilities have not had incentives to encourage the efficient use of water. Rather water utilities have simply been required to ensure supply and sell more water to customers. Thus removing perverse subsidies and bringing in effective policies and market based 96 Note that Sections 2-6 of this report have been developed by Michael Smith and Karlson Hargroves, The Natural Edge Project, Griffith University and the Australian National University, under the supervision of Professor Ernst von Weizsäcker. The content is based on research undertaken by Michael Smith as part of his PhD, with additional research and editing by Karlson Hargroves. 97 OECD (2002) Sustainable Development Strategies: A Resource Book. OECD. Paris. 98 Pachauri, R. (2007) Coping with Climate Change: Is Development in India and the World Sustainable? 2007 K R Narayanan Oration, ANU. Available At http://rspas.anu.edu.au/papers/narayanan/2007oration.pdf Accessed 16 November 2007 99 Shah, T. et al. (2007) Groundwater: A Global Assessment of Scale and Significance, in International Water Management Institute (ed.) Water for Food, Water for Life: A Comprehensive Assessment of Water Management, Earthscan, London. 100 Shiklomanov, I. (1998) ‘Assessment of Water Resources and Water Availability in the World,’ Report for the Comprehensive Assessment of the Freshwater Resources of the World (St. Petersburg, Russia: State Hydrological Institute, 1998), cited in Gleick, P. (2000-2001) The World’s Water 2000–2001. Island Press, Washington DC., p. 52 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia approaches which encourage greater water efficiency and water recycling can significantly help to achieve decoupling of economic growth from freshwater use. Most homes and commercial buildings can cost effectively reduce water usage by over 50 per cent through improving water productivity and utilising and recycling rain and grey water. The use of fresh water on farms has halved in Israel since 1984, while the value of production has continued to climb. Farmers in India, Israel, Jordan, Spain and the US have shown that drip irrigation systems that deliver water directly to crop roots can reduce water use by 30–70 per cent and raise crop yields by 20–90 per cent.12 Rice farmers in Malaysia saw a 45 per cent increase in their water productivity through a combination of better scheduling their irrigations, shoring up canals, and sowing seeds directly in the field rather than transplanting seedlings. In the US between 1980 and 1995 the amount of fresh water withdrawn per American fell by 21 percent and water withdrawn per dollar of real GDP fell by 38 percent.101 This trend is being seen worldwide in OECD countries. (See Figure 4.1) For instance, in 1995 world freshwater withdrawals were only about half what planners had predicted thirty years earlier by basing their predictions on historical trends.102 Figure 4.1: Freshwater abstraction per unit of GDP, 1980-1998 (Source, OECD, (2001)103 There are multiple benefits from water resource productivity improvements such as lower business and household costs and delaying need for new and expensive water infrastructure. Greater water productivity improvements also help rural, urban and coastal communities adapt to the likelihood of reduced water availability this century in many parts of the world due to climate change. Also the more efficient use of water for agriculture and cities enables more water to become available for 101 Hawken, P., Lovins, A. and Lovins, L. H. (1999) Natural Capitalism: Creating the Next Industrial Revolution, Earthscan/James&James, London. 102 Gleick, P.H. (1998) The World’s Water 1998-1999: The Biennial Report on Freshwater Resources, Island Press, Washington, D.C. Available at www.worldwater.org. Accessed 12 December 2006. 103 OECD Secretariat (2002) ‘Indicators to Measure Decoupling of Environmental Pressure and Economic Growth.’ OECD. Paris Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia restoring environmental flows for river ecosystems and wetlands. Given that clean and freshwater will be an increasingly prized and relatively scarce resource this century, it is also important to improve water quality and ensure access of unpolluted clean water to all people and the environment. The health and environmental costs of polluted water are significant. Costs of Inaction vs. Costs of Action Whilst it is difficult to value the costs of inaction, one US study found that the increased water and water infrastructure costs from inaction on climate change amounted to US$950 billion over the next 100 years.104 Conversely studies show that the costs of action on demand management and water productivity improvements can be net positive over time. In the last two decades, whole system cost analysis has shown that water efficiency delivers far more benefits than previously imagined. Research lead by Professor Stuart White at the University of Technology Sydney, Institute for Sustainable Futures, indicates that in cities and towns facing water supply augmentation, investment in water efficiency can result in water savings of greater than 30% at a unit cost that is less than supply augmentation, yielding net present value economic benefits in excess of AUD$100m for some capital cities.105 Studies also show that improving water productivity in rural areas also provides a positive GDP return to the region.106 Investment to improve water quality by preventing and effectively removing water pollutants is also economically efficient. The studies reviewed by the OECD107 show that national measures to reduce agricultural runoff and improve storm water management – including introducing targeted measures to reduce a variety of different pollutants such as arsenic and nitrates - results in health benefits estimated to be in excess of US$100 million for large OECD economies. Studies on recreational water quality improvements through sewage treatment in France, Portugal, the US and the UK and drink water quality improvements in the US and show that the health cost benefits outweigh the costs of policy implementation. 108 In non-OECD countries, the costs of inaction with respect to unsafe water supply and sanitation are particularly acute. At the global level, water stress is a major issue, with 1.1 billion people without access to a safe water supply and 2.6 billion people do not have access to adequate sanitation facilities.109 Achieving the Millennium Development Goals (MDG) of halving the population without access to clean water and sanitation by 2015 is expected to cost about US$10 billion per year. But this figure is far outweighed by the costs of inaction if the MDG is not achieved, in terms of impacts on human 104 Natural Resources Defense Council (2008) The Cost of Climate Change What We'll Pay if Global Warming Continues Unchecked. Natural Resources Defense Council. Available at http://www.nrdc.org/globalwarming/cost/contents.asp Accessed 26 September 2008 105 Professor White, Private Communication. 106 Centre for International Economics (2004) Socio-Economic Assessment of Water Efficiency Investments in the Murrumbidgee Valley. The Pratt Water Initiative. Available at http://www.napswq.gov.au/publications/books/pratt-water/working-papers/pubs/socio-economic.pdf Accessed 27 September 2008 107 OECD (2008) Cost of Inaction: Technical Report, OECD, Paris. OECD (2008) Costs of Environmental Policy Inaction: Summary for Policy-makers. OECD. Paris. 108 ibid 109 WHO/UNICEF (2006) Joint Monitoring Programme for Water Supply and Sanitation. Available at www.wssinfo.org/en/welcome.html accessed 17 August 2008. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia health and economic productivity. The cost of not meeting this MDG (cost of inaction) has been estimated at some US$130 billion a year.110 This may seem large but many other studies have also found the rate of return is significant and thus justifies investment.111 Globally, the World Health Organisation (WHO) has estimated that the economic benefits of investments in meeting this target would outweigh costs by a ratio of about 8:1.112 Reducing the Costs of Action As explained above, improving water productivity in rural and urban regions is the most cost effective way to achieve decoupling of economic growth from freshwater abstraction. Hence policy changes which enable water utilities to encourage demand management and water efficiency are a solid starting point. Such policy changes will significantly help to reduce the costs of action on demand management and water productivity. However, there are other more challenging aspects to achieving sustainable water resource management because the current unsustainable usage of water is an example of the tragedy of the commons.113 Policy Implications and Recommendations Professor Jeffrey Sachs sums up well the complex policy challenge to achieve sustainable water resource management, explaining that: Water is characterized by pervasive spillover effects, to use the economic jargon. Water use by one group or region affects the water availability and security of others… When one group withdraws some river flow for irrigation, the impact may be reduced availability of water down stream... When a community drills boreholes for irrigation, the consequences can easily be a reduction in flow of water to other neighboring wells or even far downstream. A tradition of first come, first serve to the use of water can lead to massive losses for all – one of the greatest manifestations of the tragedy of the commons. Yet simply privatizing water114 without strong protections for the poor can end up denying the weakest part of the population the access to safe water it needs to stay alive. Privatisation of water rights may be contrary to basic ecological good management as well, for example, through overexploitation of ground water.115 110 Hutton, G. and Haller, L. (2004) Evaluation of the Costs and Benefits of Water and Sanitation Improvements at the Global Level, Water, Sanitation and Health, Protection of the Human Environment, World Health Organization, Geneva. 111 Rijsberman, F. (2008) The Water Challenge. Paper prepared as one of 10 challenge papers for the Copenhagen Consensus project of the Environmental Assessment Institute, Copenhagen, Denmark. 112 WHO, UNICEF (2005) Water for life. Making it happen. Geneva, World Health Organization. 113 For further information refer to Chapter 20 of ‘Hargroves, K. and Smith, M. (2005) The Natural Advantage of Nations: Business Opportunities, Innovation and Governance in the 21st Century, The Natural Edge Project, Earthscan, London’. 114 von Weizsäcker, E., Young, O., and Finger, M. (2005) Limits to Privatization – How to Avoid Too Much of A Good Thing. London, Earthscan 115 Sachs, J. (2008) Common Wealth: Economics for a Crowded Planet, Penguin Group. New York. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia A range of global116 and regional institutions117 have published extensive reports which address the complexity of policy and institutional change needed to underpin efforts to achieve decoupling in this area. 116 UNEP (2007) Global Environment Outlook: Environment for development (GEO-4) report. UNEP. Available At http://www.unep.org/geo/geo4 Accessed 23.03.08 117 See OECD Environment Directorate’s Water Program at http://www.oecd.org/department/0,3355,en_2649_34311_1_1_1_1_1,00.html Accessed 25 September 2008 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia 4. Decoupling Economic Growth from Waste Production118 Progress has been made in the last two decades in OECD countries to relatively decouple economic growth from waste production. In OECD counties in the mid-1990s, approximately 64% of municipal waste was sent to landfills, 18% for both incineration, and recycling. 119 In 2005, only 49% of municipal waste being disposed of in landfills, 30% being recycled and 21% being incinerated or otherwise treated.120 In 1980 America recycled only 9.6% of its municipal rubbish; today the rate stands at 32%. A similar trend can be seen in Europe, where some countries, such as Austria and the Netherlands, now recycle 60% or more of their municipal waste. Britain's recycling rate, at 27%, is low, but it is improving fast, having nearly doubled in the past three years. 121 Overall Municipal waste generation is still increasing in OECD countries, but at a slower pace since 2000, hence it has been relatively decoupled from GDP. (See Figure 5.1) Figure 5.1 Decoupling of OECD GDP from OECD country municipal waste generation, 1980-2030 (Source: OECD, 2008122) Multiple Benefits of Decoupling Waste Production Despite progress having been made, in most countries waste production is still increasing. This creates numerous problems. Landfill space in many countries is becoming increasingly scarce. Availability of suitable landfill options is not only a waste management issue but a political issue as was seen in Italy in late 2007 when demonstrators clashed with riot police in Naples over the proposed locations of rubbish dumps in surrounding areas to cope with Naples growth in waste production, involving the throwing of firebombs, cans and other garbage at officers. 123 Waste decomposing in landfills threatens waterways and drinking water supplies and contaminates the land 118 Note that Sections 2-6 of this report have been developed by Michael Smith and Karlson Hargroves, The Natural Edge Project, Griffith University and the Australian National University, under the supervision of Professor Ernst von Weizsäcker. The content is based on research undertaken by Michael Smith as part of his PhD, with additional research and editing by Karlson Hargroves. 119 OECD (2001) OECD Environmental Outlook, OECD, Paris. 120 OECD (2008) OECD Environmental Data Compendium, OECD, Paris. 121 OECD (2008) OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030. OECD. Available At http://www.oecd.org/document/20/0,3343,en_2649_37465_39676628_1_1_1_37465,00.html Accessed 22.03.2008 122 Ibid. 123 Demonstrators clash with riot police in Naples...over a rubbish dump, by Daily Mail Reporter, 27th September 2008, available at http://www.dailymail.co.uk/news/article-1063399/Demonstrators-clash-riot-police-Naples--rubbish-dump.html. Accessed 05.10.08. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia with a range of chemicals, some toxic and hazardous. Waste in landfill also produces methane gas, a recognised greenhouse gas, when municipal rubbish rots and degrades. There are significant societal and environmental benefits from decoupling economic growth from waste production through reducing, reusing and recycling waste. It also makes strong economic sense for business to reduce and reuse waste as this reduces landfill and resource input costs. It also makes sense for business to design products and processes so that waste produced can be easily recycled. As Amory Lovins states, It is extremely profitable to wring out waste, even today when nature is valued at approximately zero, because there is so much waste - quite an astonishing amount after several centuries of market capitalism. In the American economy, the material that we extract from the planet, that we mobilise for economic purposes, and process and move around and ultimately dispose of, totals about 20 times the body weight of a person per day. So worldwide this resource flow is in the order of a half-trillion tons per year. And what happens to it? Well, only about 1 per cent of it ends up in durable goods; the system is about 99 per cent waste. That’s a business opportunity.124 Some of business’s significant costs are capital and inputs, such as costs of building plants and equipment, and the cost of acquiring raw materials, energy and water, and the costs of transportation. It is in business’s interests to minimise these costs, and hence the amount of raw materials and other inputs they need to create their product or provide their service. Business produces only useful products and services or waste. It is in individual business’s interests to find markets for this ‘waste’ and/or design industrial processes so that waste is minimised and that which is produced can be used or sold elsewhere. Costs of Inaction vs. Costs of Action Local government and city councils gain economic benefits from implementing recycling programs, largely due to the reduced landfill costs. 125 A study conducted by the Technical University of Denmark found that in 83% of cases, recycling is the most efficient method to dispose of household waste.126 A study of municipal waste and landfill in Israel found that for 51% of the municipalities, it would be (economically) efficient to adopt recycling, even without accounting for externality costs. In the economic literature, when these externality costs of waste to landfill are taken into account, recycling has been found to almost always be economically efficient.127 Examples of the costs of externalities of waste include increased air pollution from incineration, hazardous waste leaching from landfills into groundwater supplies, loss of public land and risks from the spread of disease. See Amory Lovin’s Natural Capitalism Lecture at http://www.abc.net.au/science/slab/natcap/default.htm Accessed 25 September 2008 Lavee D. (2007) Is Municipal Solid Waste Recycling Economically Efficient? Environmental Management. New York 126 The Economist (2007) The Truth About Recycling. The Economist. Jun 7th 2007. Available at http://www.sehn.org/tccThetruthaboutrecycling.html Accessed 25 September 2008 127 Lavee D. (2007) Is Municipal Solid Waste Recycling Economically Efficient? Environmental Management. New York . Available at http://www.springerlink.com/content/r461lju585760316/fulltext.pdf accessed 25 September 2008 Brisson IE (1997) Assessing the waste hierarchy: A social costbenefit analysis of municipal solid waste management in the European Union. Samfund, Okonomi and Miljo, 19. AKF Forlaget, Kopenhagen 124 125 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Another significant externality from landfill is greenhouse gas pollution. The United States Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) has concluded in favour of recycling, saying that recycling efforts reduced the country's carbon emissions by a net 49 million metric tonnes in 2005. 128 In the United Kingdom, the Waste and Resources Action Programme stated that Great Britain's recycling efforts reduce CO2 emissions by 10-15 tonnes a year. 129 Recycling industries also contribute significantly to national GDP. Recycling employs over 1.5 million employees in more than 50 countries with an annual turnover exceeding US$160 billion dollars. Recycling processes over 600 million tonnes of commodities annually. A recent international review of life-cycle analysis work on key materials that are collected for recycling clearly demonstrated that recycling usually has more environmental benefits and lower environmental impacts than other waste management options. From 188 scenarios that included recycling, the overwhelming majority (83%) favoured recycling over either landfilling or incineration. 130 Recycling can also provide considerable economic and social (e.g. increased employment) benefits.131 Reducing the Costs of Action There are several exciting innovations in policy, product design and process design that can help reduce or even eliminate the amount waste being generated cost effectively. These innovations usually involve some combination of 1) directly reducing the amount of waste generated in producing and delivering a product or in operating an industrial process, 2) designing products such that their reuse and recycle is cost effective and easy, 3) designing service processes such that product take-back is cost effective and easy and 4) increasing markets for products with recycled content. These four features enable a much greater decoupling of waste from economic growth by reducing the costs of material inputs and enabling a market of secondary materials that are, in many cases, cheaper than the equivalent primary materials. Policy Implications and Recommendations These strategies can help nations shift from simply achieving relative to absolute decoupling of economic growth from waste production. This is acknowledged by the OECD which states that With continuous growth in the global demand for materials and the amounts of waste generated and disposed of, conventional waste policies alone may not be enough to improve material efficiency and offset the waste-related environmental impacts of materials production and use. New integrated approaches – with stronger emphasis on material efficiency, redesign and reuse of products, waste prevention, recycling of end-of-life materials and products and environmentally sound management of residues – could be used to 128 The Economist (2007) The Truth About Recycling. The Economist. Jun 7th 2007. Available at http://www.sehn.org/tccThetruthaboutrecycling.html Accessed 25 September 2008 129 Ibid. 130 WRAP (Waste and Resources Action Programme) (2006) Environmental Benefits of Recycling, WRAP, Banbury, UK. www.wrap.org.uk/applications/publications/publication_details.rm?id=698&publication=2838 . 131 US REI (2001) US Recycling Economic Information Study, A study prepared for The National Recycling Coalition by R. W. Beck, Inc., www.epa.gov/epaoswer/non-hw/recycle/jtr/econ/rei-rw/pdf/n_report.pdf Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia counterbalance the environmental impacts of waste throughout the entire life-cycle of materials.132 The OECD 2030 Environmental Outlook133 and other publications134 provide a detailed overview of leading examples of which such policies have been implemented to achieve greater decoupling of economic growth from waste production. This reports overview developments in leading policy in this area such as extended producer responsibility135. Other global institutions like the World Bank also provide a wealth of resources to help achieve better waste management.136 132 OECD (2008) OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030. OECD. Available At http://www.oecd.org/document/20/0,3343,en_2649_37465_39676628_1_1_1_37465,00.html Accessed 22.03.2008 133 Ibid. 134 See OECD Environment Directorate’s Waste Portal at http://www.oecd.org/topic/0,3373,en_2649_34395_1_1_1_1_37465,00.html Accessed 22.03.2008 135 See Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) website – Extended Producer Responsibility at http://www.oecd.org/document/19/0,3343,en_2649_34281_35158227_1_1_1_1,00.html. Accessed 15 August 2008; Lindhqvist, T. (2000) Extended Producer Responsibility in Cleaner Production: Policy Principle to Promote Environmental Improvements of Product Systems, Doctoral Dissertation, Lund University, Lund, Sweden. Available at http://www.iiiee.lu.se/Publication.nsf/$webAll/AE92DEB3FC71AEE0C1256C1A003E631F/$FILE/lindhqvist.pdf. Accessed 15 August 2008. 136 See World Bank’s web portal on Urban Solid Waste Management at http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/EXTURBANDEVELOPMENT/EXTUSWM/0,,menuPK:463847~pagePK:149018~p iPK:149093~theSitePK:463841,00.html Accessed 22 September 2008 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia 5. Policies to Underpin Decoupling and Address Major Social Factors that can Undermine or even Block Progress137 History shows that successful efforts to decouple economic growth from environmental pressures have been underpinned by effective policy which addresses a range of market, institutional and information failures. There is no evidence in any nation that the market and economic growth, on their own, can achieve significant and lasting decoupling of economic growth from environmental pressures. Even urban air and water pollution have required policy intervention from government to address these environmental pressures successfully. After the famous December 1952 smog in London, which killed thousands of people, new regulations were put in place restricting the use of fuels in industry and households to ensure that cleaner forms of energy were used to reduce air pollution. These included the Clean Air Acts of 1956 and of 1968, and the City of London (Various Powers) Act of 1954.138 Grossman and Krueger state: Even for those dimensions of environmental quality where economic growth seems to have been associated with improving conditions, there is no reason to believe that the process has been an automatic one. In principle, environmental quality might improve automatically when countries develop if they substitute cleaner technologies for dirtier ones, or if there is a very pronounced effect on pollution of the typical patterns of structural transformation … However, a review of the available evidence on instances of pollution abatement suggests that the strongest link between income and pollution in fact is via an induced policy response…139 History shows that there are two major social factors that can undermine government’s efforts to bring in such policies to underpin decoupling: 1. business and industry group opposition, media campaigns and lobbying based on fears that environmental policies and regulation will harm businesses profit margins and competitiveness, and 2. unions and workers opposition, media campaigns and lobbying based on fears of job losses. There is extensive historical evidence to show this because these concerns about pollution and environmental pressures are not new. There have been early warnings from scientists of the risks of over fishing (1865) 140 , acid rain (1872) 141 , ecological limits and thresholds (1864) 142 , dry land 137 Note that Sections 2-6 of this report have been developed by Michael Smith and Karlson Hargroves, The Natural Edge Project, Griffith University and the Australian National University, under the supervision of Professor Ernst von Weizsäcker. The content is based on research undertaken by Michael Smith as part of his PhD, with additional research and editing by Karlson Hargroves 138 Wise, W (2001) Killer Smog: The World's Worst Air Pollution Disaster.Blackprint. 139 Grossman, G., Krueger, A. (1994) ‘Economic Growth and the Environment’, NBER Working Paper no. 4634, February, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Quoted in Ekins, P. (2000) ‘Economic Growth and Environmental Sustainability’, Routledge Publishing London, New York p190 140 Bertram, J. G. (1865) The Harvest of the Sea, John Murray, London. 141 Smith R.A. (1872) Air and Rain. Longmans Green & Co., London. 142 Marsh,G.P. (1864) Man and Nature: Or, Physical Geography as Modified by Human Action. Edited, with a new introduction, by David Lowenthal. Foreword by William Cronon. Weyerhauser Environmental Classics Series. Seattle and London: University of Washington Press, reprint 2003 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia salinity (1864) 143, soil degradation and deforestation (~300 B.C) 144, materials like asbestos (1898) 145, chemicals such as PCB’s (1899) 146 , benzene (1897) 147 , radiation (1896) 148 , overuse of nonrenewable resources (1909) 149, chemical intensive farming (1924) 150, human induced climate change (1957) 151 . Reports like Late Lessons from Early Warnings: the Precautionary Principle 18962000 152 show that historically, affected business, industry groups and unions have usually fought efforts by government to bring in necessary policies to reduce pollution and achieve decoupling.153 Hence this section will look at how governments can use smart policy mechanisms to underpin efforts to achieve decoupling whilst also addressing the legitimate fears and concerns of businesses, industry groups, unions and workers. Internalising Externalities to Achieve Decoupling As outlined in section 2, economists have explained for many decades that current unsustainable development trajectories arise largely from the fact that the real environmental costs of development are externalised from the market. Without these impacts included in market prices, current goods and services are externalising the costs to be dealt with by governments. Where such market failures and externalities exist there is a legitimate role for government to act early to ensure that these costs are actually accounted for and offset. These issues are being widely discussed internationally. 154 As a case in point, historically governments’ policies have kept the price of water for farmers and industry low leading to unsustainable water usage of surface and ground freshwater, as discussed in section 4.155 Current market pricing on a range of goods and resources, doesn’t reflect the true cost to the environment and society of production, industry, and general consumption. To achieve decoupling of economic growth from environmental pressures these externalities will need to be internalised wherever possible, in a manner that is fair and equitable. Responding to Opposition from Industry to Government Policies to Underpin Decoupling 143 Bennett, D.,McPherson, D.K. (1983) A History of Salinity in Western Australia. Commonwealth Scientific and Industrial Research Organisation. Division of Groundwater Research. Technical Memorandum 83/1, 144 Hughes, J.D (1985) Theophrastus as ecologist, Environmental Review, 4, 296-307 145 Deane, L. (1898) ‘Report on the Health of Workers in Asbestos and Other Dusty Trade’, in HM Chief Inspector of Factories and Workshops, Annual Report for 1898, pp. 171–172, HMSO London (see also the Annual Reports for 1899 and 1900, p502). 146 Harremo, P., Gee, P., MacGarvin, M., Stirling, A., Keys, J., Wynne, B., and Vaz S.G. (2002) Late Lessons from Early Warnings: the Precautionary Principle 1896-2000. Environmental issue report No 22 European Environment Agency. Available at http://reports.eea.europa.eu/environmental_issue_report_2001_22/en Accessed 30 September 2008 147 Santessen, C. G. (1897) Chronische Vergiftungen Mit Steinkohlentheerbenzin: Vier Todesfalle Arch. Hyg. Bakteriol. Vol. 31, pp. 336– 376. LeNoir, Claude, (1897) On a Case of Purpura Attributed to Benzene Intoxication, Bul. Mem. Soc. Med. Hop. Vol. 3, pp. 1251–1261. 148 Edison, T. A. (1896) Effect of X-rays upon the eye, Nature Vol. 53, p. 421 149 See Proceedings of a 1908 Conference of Governors: Opening Address by the President at http://memory.loc.gov/cgibin/query/r?ammem/consrv:@field(DOCID+@lit(amrvgvg16div19)) Accessed 1 July 2008 150 Steiner, R. (1924) Spiritual Foundations for the Renewal of Agriculture. A course of eight lectures. M. Gardner (ed) (1993). Bio Dynamic Farming and Gardening Association, USA 151 Revelle, R. Fairbridge, R. (1957) ‘Carbonates and Carbon Dioxide.’ Memoirs of the Geological Society of America 67:1: 239-95 152 Harremo, P., Gee, P., MacGarvin, M., Stirling, A., Keys, J., Wynne, B., and Vaz S.G. (2002) Late Lessons from Early Warnings: the Precautionary Principle 1896-2000 Environmental issue report No 22 European Environment Agency. Available at http://reports.eea.europa.eu/environmental_issue_report_2001_22/en Accessed 30 September 2008 153 Ibid. 154 World Bank (2003) World Development Report: Sustainable Development in a Dynamic. World Bank 155 Ibid. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Business and industry groups have been historically wary of and often opposed to the introduction of environmental policies to internalise externalities such as through emissions trading schemes or ecotaxes, because they have feared the costs of compliance would affect their international competitiveness. This is especially true of companies who are trade exposed to companies operating in low cost regulatory environments in developing countries. For example, a number of OECD governments have decided not to introduce energy or carbon taxes due to strong and concerted opposition from energy-intensive industries like steel, aluminium and cement. These industry sectors have traditionally opposed purposeful policies on climate change such as emissions trading schemes and a carbon tax. The realisation now being made in many of these industries is that efforts to undermine and block progress in decoupling are actually threatening their own medium to long term viability as these efforts could be invested in updating processes to become less emissions intensive. Government’s today have a range of policy options to effectively respond to concerns about potential loss of competitiveness.156 These policy options include wholesale exceptions, negotiated agreements, and offsetting tax deductions and financial incentives for energy efficiency improvements. However, experts have demonstrated that the most effective policy option is to compensate trade exposed large energy using industries for a carbon tax or an emissions trading scheme through a border tax adjustment. This means that the government would pay the exporter of say aluminium exports a rebate to offset the increased costs in production caused by the carbon tax or emissions trading scheme. But the rebate would only be paid at the point of export thus ensuring that all companies producing and selling within a country would be subject to the carbon price signal. Border tax adjustments are not a radical idea and are used in a number of countries including in the Australian GST system and the European value added tax system. OECD studies of the effects of border tax adjustments on the cement157 and steel industries158 show that they can lead to carbon taxes having a negligible effect on the international competitiveness of steel and cement industries. The EU regulatory framework on the Registration, Evaluation and Authorisation of Chemicals (REACH) is another good example of how effective policy processes, balanced cost benefit analysis and consultation has helped overcome businesses fears of increased environmental regulation. Before its introduction in 2007, the REACH framework faced significant resistance from the chemical industry, because of the expected impact of higher compliance costs on sectoral competitiveness. Close consultations with the industry and other stakeholders, as well as extensive cost benefit impact assessments during the policy formulation phase (now a standard feature in the EU), were crucial in allying businesses fears and enabling the eventual adoption of REACH.159 Such consultative efforts 156 OECD (2008) OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030. OECD. Available At http://www.oecd.org/document/20/0,3343,en_2649_37465_39676628_1_1_1_37465,00.html Accessed 22.03.2008. 157 OECD (2003) Environmental Policy in the Steel Industry: Using Economic Instruments, OECD, Paris, available at at www.oecd.org/dataoecd/58/20/33709359.pdf Accessed 1 October 2008 158 OECD (2005) The Competitiveness Impact of CO2 Emissions Reduction in the Cement Sector, OECD, Paris, available at http://appli1.oecd.org/olis/2004doc.nsf/linkto/com-env-epoc-ctpa-cfa(2004)68-final Accessed 1 October 2008 159 OECD (2008) OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030. OECD. Available At http://www.oecd.org/document/20/0,3343,en_2649_37465_39676628_1_1_1_37465,00.html Accessed 22.03.2008 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia to address competitiveness concerns about environmental policies will be vitally important to enable the achievement of decoupling more broadly over the coming decades. Taking a Portfolio Policy Approach to Underpinning Decoupling The OECD’s research in this area, based on many years of experience, has found that a portfolio policy approach utilising a variety of government mechanisms and policies (See Table 6.1) is the most effective strategy to underpin decoupling of economic growth and environmental pressures and ensure minimal negative effects to business competitiveness. The OECD writes that: Significant environmental improvement can be achieved at relatively low cost to the economy and with little negative social impact if the right mix of policies is used. The necessary policies and technological solutions to tackle the key environmental challenges are both available and affordable. Even for a single environmental problem, an instrument mix may be needed given the often complex and inter-connected nature of many environmental challenges, the often large number and variety of sources exerting pressure on the environment, and the many market and information failures. Instrument mixes need to be carefully constructed to ensure that they achieve a given environmental goal in an effective and economically efficient manner, while providing consumers and producers with flexibility in how they meet the targets, so as to enable innovation. Social or equity impacts should be addressed. Instrument mixes should provide clear, short- and long-term policy signals to support appropriate investment decisions. The policy instruments used in a mix should be complementary and reinforcing, rather than duplicative or conflicting.160 A good example of effectively combining policy instruments has been the way several European OECD nations have combined ‘feebates’161 and Germany’s Best Available Technology legislation162 with also emissions trading schemes and eco-taxes. The German Best Available Technology legislation does not involve mandating specific technologies. Rather, the German Government upwardly adjusts standards that industry has to meet based on the standards met by the best and most cost effective available technologies. In theory then, whenever a new and improved technology is created globally, German industry is expected to meet the environmental standard achieved by that technology. Of course, regulatory practise is more flexible, ambiguous and much less instantaneous and are subject to industry pressure. However, it has provided significant incentive for German firms to develop new technologies that make it cheaper for them to meet the competition from the best available technologies globally. Feebates, very simply, combine both a fee on the most environmentally harmful brands of a certain product, whilst providing income to governments, allowing them to provide a rebate to encourage consumers to purchase the most environmentally benign products. Operationally feebates are very 160 161 162 Ibid. p432 von Weizsäcker, E., Lovins, A. and Lovins, H. (1997) ‘Factor Four: Doubling Wealth, Halving Resource Use’, Earthscan, London. Braithwaite, J. and Drahos, P. (2000) ‘Global Business Regulation’, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia simple. Take the example of the car. If you bought a new car, you would pay an extra fee if it were an inefficient user of fuel, or alternatively get a rebate if it were energy-efficient. The neutral point would be set so that fees and rebates balanced, so it becomes neither an inflationary measure nor a disguised tax. The key benefit of feebates is that they would ensure that industry knows that there will be clear market signals to the consumer to purchase more efficient products, thereby stimulating innovation in this direction. But government would still need to work with industry to phase in feebates to ensure industry has time to respond. To reduce administrative costs, feebates can be targeted at those consumer products that have the largest ongoing environmental impacts, such as cars and, within the home, refrigerators and washing machines. When feebates are coupled with best available technology regulation and clear market signals, from either emissions trading schemes or ecological taxes, this helps drive innovation and the uptake of green technologies and processes. As Professor Michael Porter, Harvard Business School, wrote as far back as 1991: As other nations have pushed ahead, US trade has suffered. Germany has had perhaps the world’s tightest regulations in stationary air-pollution control, and German companies appear to hold a wide lead in patenting and exporting air-pollution and other environmental technologies. As much as 70% of the air pollution-control equipment sold in the US today is produced by foreign companies. Britain is another case in point. As its environmental standards have lagged, Britain’s ratio of exports to imports in environmental technology has fallen from 8:1 to 1:1 over the past decade. In contrast, the US leads in those areas in which its regulations have been the strictest, such as pesticides and the remediation of environmental damage. Such leads should be treasured and extended. Environmental protection is a universal need, an area of growing expenditure in all the major national economies and a major export industry. The strongest proof that environmental protection does not hamper competitiveness is the economic performance of nations with the strictest laws.163 The following table provides an overview of the range of options and approaches available to governments to allow them to take a lead with industry, and the community, to underpin decoupling efforts in a way that does not harm competitiveness of industry but rather helps it. Table 6.1 Policy Instruments for Decoupling Policy Option Regulatory instruments 163 Overview e.g. bans on certain products or practices, emission standards, ambient quality standards, technology standards, requirements for the application of certain (“best available”) technologies, obligations for operational permits, Porter, M. (1991) ‘Green Competitiveness’, Scientific American, 5 April. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia land use planning and zoning, etc. These can make environmental outcomes more certain. It is important to emphasize that such regulations tend to be far more effective if they focus on an environmental outcome, rather than, for example, specifying the technologies to be used. This provides business with more incentive to find the lowest cost approaches to achieve the required environmental outcome. Environmentallyrelated taxes Help to ensure that prices reflect the negative environmental impacts and costs of various products and processes not included in the market price.164 These provide a clear market signal to drive decoupling by providing a greater economic incentive to invest in improving efficiency and cleaner production initiatives. In the long term these provide market signals to drive innovation in the development of new cleaner production methods. In this case the argument is often made that if the environmental impacts and costs are incorporated into the cost of the product then it will be too expensive. The reality is for products that this is true the price is already too expensive. The additional price on top of the market price that is not being paid is infact being paid by society, now and in the future, through avenues such as real costs of environmental management, costs related to increasing damage from natural disasters, and damage to critical environmental systems. Tradable permit systems These set limits, either as a maximum ceiling for “cap and trade” schemes, or as a minimum performance commitment for “baseline and credit” schemes. The limits can be either in absolute terms or in relative terms, and the permits can be denominated either in terms of rights to emit pollutants (e.g. greenhouse gas emissions), or rights to access natural resources (e.g. water, fish stocks). Cap and trade systems can combine a high degree of environmental certainty with economic efficiency – their flexibility helps to reduce the costs of abatement, while their environmental effectiveness is high because the environmental objective is explicitly reflected in the number of permits that are issued. Subsidies for environmental improvement Currently the majority of government subsidies go to industry practices which harm the environment, referred to as ‘perverse subsidies’. Instead, these subsidies could be used to encourage environmental improvement by encouraging the diffusion of environmentally benign products, processes and behaviours, and financing environmentally friendly infrastructure investments along with environmental regeneration projects. 164 von Weizsäcker, E. and Jesinghaus, J.(1992) Ecological Tax Reform: Policy Proposal for Sustainable Development London: Zed Books Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Voluntary approaches Governments can enter into voluntary agreements with industry whereby industry agrees to meet certain targets and in return government will hold back on bringing in new policy and regulation. Voluntary agreements are a useful way to get buy-in from business and industry on the need for action, but their environmental effectiveness has to be carefully assessed, and they need careful monitoring and reporting. History shows that they are most useful when used in combination with other policy instruments, or during a phase-in period for the use of another policy instrument. (Source: OECD, 2008)165 There is a great deal of experience in Europe of using combinations of different policy options to respond to competitiveness concerns from business and industry. This experience is well captured in the 2008 OECD’s Environmental Outlook 2030 publication 166 and related publications by the OECD.167 As the 2008 OECD Environmental Outlook 2030 report stated: (Designed well) in some cases, environmental policies may actually enhance the economic competitiveness of targeted sectors or industries. Firms that are forced to “clean up” can gain market advantages, either by being the first to exploit “green” markets or by moving into new technologies that can in turn be marketed or lead to efficiency savings. This sentiment is supported by a mounting body of evidence. Innovest’s 2004 extensive report, Corporate Environmental Governance: a Study into the Influence of Environmental Governance and Financial Performance, stated: The literature review found strong evidence for the existence of a positive relationship between environmental governance and financial performance. In 51 of the 60 studies reviewed, a positive correlation was found between environmental governance and financial performance ‘…results from fund, sector and company analysts are all generally positive’.168 Innovest’s extensive study clearly showed that, sector by sector, companies that are environmental leaders are financially outperforming the laggards. 169 The research literature shows clear links between improved environmental performance and a company’s financial results.170 165 OECD (2008) OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030. OECD. Available At http://www.oecd.org/document/20/0,3343,en_2649_37465_39676628_1_1_1_37465,00.html Accessed 22.03.2008 166 Ibid. 167 OECD (2007) Business and the Environment: Policy Incentives and Corporate Responses. OECD. Paris; OECD (2007) Environmental Innovation and Global Markets (ENV/EPOC/GSP(2007)2/FINAL).OECD. Paris; OECD (2007) Pollution Abatement and Control Expenditures in OECD Countries (ENV/EPOC/SE(2007)).OECD. Paris; OECD (2007) Instrument Mixes for Environmental Policy. OECD. Paris 168 Innovest Strategic Value Advisors (2004) Corporate Environmental Governance: A study into the influence of Environmental Governance and Financial Performance. Innovest. p10 169 Ibid. 170 Hart, S., and G. Ahuja (1996) ‘Does it Pay to be Green? An Empirical Examination of the Relationship between Emission Reduction and Firm Performance’, Business Strategy and the Environment 5: 30-37; Schaltegger, S., and F. Figge (1997) Environmental Shareholder Value (WWZ/Sarasin Basic Research Study No. 54; Basel: WWZ); Schaltegger, S. and T. Synnestvedt (2002) ‘The Link between “Green” and Economic Success: Environmental Management as the Crucial Trigger between Environmental and Economic Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia In 2007 at the United Nations Summit on Corporate Responsibility, Goldman Sachs released a report which found that environmental sustainability leaders outperformed the general stock market by 25 per cent over the previous two years and outperformed their same sector peers by almost 75 per cent over the same period.171 Markets in environmental sustainable solutions are also booming (See Table 6.1) Table 6.1: Fast growing markets Market Growth Investment with environmental and social sustainability criteria Overview Over 360 investment firms, totalling $14 Trillion plus worth of investments, have now signed the UN Principles of Responsible Investment.172 60 banks, have endorsed the Equator Principles (EP), an international standard of sustainability investment for large investments.173 The EPs have become the global standard for project finance and have transformed the funding of major projects globally. In 2007, of the US$74.6 billion total debt tracked in emerging markets, US$52.9 billion was subject to the EPs, representing about 71 per cent of total project finance debt in emerging market economies.174 Renewable Energy Since 2003, Clean Energy Technologies - solar, biofuels, geothermal, tidal and hydropower – produced more electricity globally than the total energy created by nuclear power plants. Global investment in renewable energies jumped to a record $100 billion in 2006 and will likely rise to about $120 billion in 2007, according to the U.N. Environment Program.175 U.S. bank Morgan Stanley has estimated that global sales from clean energy sources like wind, solar and geothermal power and biofuels could grow to as much as $1 trillion a year by 2030. 176 Cambridge Energy Research Associates Performance’, Journal of Environmental Management 65: 339-46; Waddock, S., and S.B. Graves (1997) ‘The Corporate Social Performance–Financial Performance Link’, Strategic Management Journal 18.4: 303-19. Wagner, M. (2001) A Review of Empirical Studies Concerning the Relationship between Environmental and Economic Performance: What Does the Evidence Tell Us? (Lüneburg, Germany: University of Lüneburg,Centre for Sustainability Management); Schmidheiny, S. (1992) Changing Course: A global business perspective on development and the environment. Boston: MIT Press. Halliday, C.O, Schmidheiny, S, Watts, P, (2002) ‘Walking the Talk:The Business Case for Sustainable Development’, World Business Council for Sustainable Development. Greenleaf Publishing; Verschoor, C. (1999) ‘Corporate Performance is Closely Linked to a Strong Ethical Commitment’, Business and Society Review 104.4: 407; Repetto, R., and Austin, D. (2000) Pure Profit: The Financial Implications of Environmental Performance. Washington, DC: World Resources Institute; Pfeffer, J. (1998) The Human Equation: Building Profits by Putting People First, Harvard Business School Press. 171 Baue, B. (2008) State of the World 2008. Chapter 13 Investing for Sustainability. WorldWatch Institute. Earthscan, London. 172 See UNEP FI Principles of Responsible Investment at http://www.unpri.org/ Accessed 1 October 2008 173 Ibid. 174 See Reuters (2008) Equator Principles Celebrate Five Years of Positive Environmental Impact and Improvement at http://www.reuters.com/article/pressRelease/idUS142792+08-May-2008+BW20080508 Accessed 1 October 2008 175 Reuters (2007) $1 trillion green market seen by 2030. Environmental News Network Available at http://www.enn.com/business/article/23958 Accessed 1 October 2008 176 Ibid. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia 2008 report predicts that alternative energy investments will top $7 trillion by 2030.177 Eco-Tourism Beginning in 1990s, ecotourism has been growing 20% - 34% per year.178 In 2004, ecotourism/nature tourism was growing globally 3 times faster than the tourism industry as a whole.179 According to Travel Weekly, sustainable tourism could grow to 25% of the world’s travel market by 2012, taking the value of the sector to approximately US$473 billion a year.180 Organic Agriculture With global revenue surpassing twenty-five billion dollars annually, organic agriculture is a highly visible and rapidly growing.181 Recycling and Remanufacturing In the USA the re-manufacturing market is now worth almost $53 billion dollars. The USA recycling sector is worth over $250 billion per annum. A recent report by the Recycling Coalition Group182 found that the industry in the US created more than 56,000 public and private sector recycling facilities, with 1.1 million jobs, $236 billion in gross, annual sales, $37 billion in annual payroll. Source: Compiled by The Natural Edge Project. There are a number other ways governments can design and implement programs and policies to effectively underpin decoupling efforts, including: Funding efficiency initiatives and R&D in related innovation, Providing better information on the risks and opportunities, Recycle environmental tax revenues back into affected sectors and utilising border taxes, Co-operating internationally to creating a level playing field, Providing a well planned and transparent phasing in of the policy to allow for adjustments and ensuring a consistent whole of government approach to policy, and Policy co-ordination efforts to ensure that business and industry are given effective support to ensure a cost effective transition. 177 Cambridge Energy Research Associates (CERA) (2007) Crossing the Divide:The Future of Clean Energy. CERA. Available at http://www.cera.com/aspx/cda/client/knowledgeArea/serviceDescription.aspx?KID=199 Accessed 1 October 2008 178 Mastny, L. (2001) Treading Lightly: New Paths for International Tourism, Worldwatch Paper 159 (Washington, DC: Worldwatch Institute, December 2001), p. 15. 179 See World Tourism Organization, press release, June 2004 cit International Eco-Tourism Society’s Eco-Tourism Factsheet at http://www.ecotourism.org/WebModules/WebArticlesNet/articlefiles/15-NEW%20Ecotourism%20Factsheet%20Sept%2005.pdf Accessed 20th of September 2008 180 Shum, K.(2007) Green Travel: Trends in Eco-Tourism.The International Eco-Tourism Society. Lifestyles of Health and Sustainability. Available at http://www.lohas.com/journal/ecotourism.htm Accessed 1 October 2008 181 Kristiansen, P. Taji, A. Reganold, J. (2006) Organic Agriculture:A Global Perspective. Available at http://www.publish.csiro.au/nid/21/pid/5325.htm Accessed 1 October 2008 182 See Recycling Coalition Group at http://www.nrc-recycle.org/ Accessed 1 October 2008 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Responding to Fears of Job Losses from Decoupling and Environmental Sustainability The other major social factor that has held back efforts to achieve decoupling has been the fear that environmental policy and regulation would lead to avoidable job losses. Studies show that most people still believe that higher environmental standards and tougher environmental regulation and penalties have led to many companies fleeing to developing countries to escape these tougher environmental regimes.183 Many believe that at the macroeconomic level, higher environmental standards and environmental regulation has contributed to long term unemployment. It is a common perception that environmental protection has been responsible for plant shutdowns and layoffs in certain industry sectors such as coal mining, forestry, fishing, chemical and manufacturing industries. It is a common belief amongst workers that they may lose their jobs in the future as a result of environmental protection. A 1990 nationwide poll, conducted in the USA found that 33 per cent of those polled felt themselves “likely” or “somewhat likely” to lose their job as a consequence of environmental regulation.184 Goldstein has studied the jobs-environment debates in detail.185 In reality, at the economy wide level, Goldstein concludes that these fears are not substantiated and that there has simply been no trade off between jobs and the environment186. He writes that … at the local level, in sharp contrast to the conventional wisdom, layoffs from environmental protection have been very, very small. Even in the most extreme cases, such as protection of forests or closing down fisheries or steps to address acid rain, job losses from environmental protection have been minute compared to more garden-variety layoff events.187 Implemented effectively the likely economy wide effect of environmental regulation is to shift jobs without increasing the overall level of unemployment, and even create new jobs. Globally there are now significant numbers of people who work in the “environmental industry sector” as a result of these regulatory changes. In fact, regulation-induced plant closings and layoffs are very rare. Goldstein shows that in the USA, about 1,000,000 workers are laid off each year due to factors such as import competition, shifts in demand, or corporate downsizing. In sharp contrast, annual layoffs in manufacturing due to environmental regulation are in the order of 100 to 3000 per year.188 There is significant evidence to suggest that efforts to underpin decoupling can help create significantly higher employment, for example ecological tax reform, done well can lead to net job creation. This is because, according to von Weizsaeker et al, employment (a social good) is currently taxed in a variety of ways, such as payroll taxes, whilst environmental pollution (a social bad) 183 Ibid. Goldstein, E. (1999) The Trade Off Myth: Fact & Fiction About Jobs and The Environment. Island Press. Washington DC. P5. 185 Ibid. 186 The real economy wide effect of environmental regulation is to shift jobs without increasing the overall level of unemployment. Globally there are now significant numbers of people who work in the “environmental industry sector”. 187 Goldstein, E. (1999) The Trade Off Myth: Fact & Fiction About Jobs and The Environment Island Press. Washington DC.p15 188 Ibid,p46. 184 Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia receives relatively little taxation countries.189 In 1994, DRI and other consultancies commissioned by the European Commission modelled a scenario where all the revenues from pollution taxes were used to reduce employer’s non-wage labour costs, such as social security payments, superfund payments, and payroll tax. The study showed that employment in the United Kingdom would be increased by 2.2 million through such tax shifting.190 There are a number of other reasons why a strategic approach to underpinning decoupling efforts can lead to higher jobs growth than business as usual worthy of further investigation, including: 191 - The greater labour intensity in retrofitting the built environment, identifying and implementing efficiencies, and investment in distributed sustainable forms of energy and water supply, - the greater labour intensity of new industrial processes where the technology and the manufacturing and operational techniques are not yet highly refined, and - the economically stimulating affect of bringing forward investments to achieve a more rapid transition to sustainability which would also create new jobs.192 Whilst it has been much maligned in some countries such as the USA and Australia, there is strong evidence that, as long as carbon tax revenue is recycled effectively, a carbon tax would have a strong employment dividend and assist the economy to become far more energy efficient. Part of the benefit of this derives from the relative labour intensity of the low carbon intensive sectors (services, retail, finance, education and health). These sectors could significantly benefit from such a relative price shift. This effect was thoroughly studied by Proops et al.193 Why then does this myth, that environmental regulation to achieve decoupling leads to job losses, continue and lead to such opposition from business and industry? This myth persists because there are some industries that are currently extracting resources and creating pollution at unsustainable levels, which will need to be reduced in order to decouple economic growth from environmental pressures to the levels required to sustain prosperity. Some industries are currently operating at such unsustainable levels that they will need to be scaled down and their operations significantly redesigned. Workers currently working within those industries – some fisheries, some native forest logging, destruction of rainforests for agriculture, certain types of mining – fear any reduction in production rates will lead to them losing their jobs and livelihoods. So whilst the real economy-wide effect of environmental regulation is to shift jobs without increasing the overall level of 189 von Weizsäcker, E. and Jesinghaus, J.(1992) Ecological Tax Reform: Policy Proposal for Sustainable Development London: Zed Books 190 DRI, et al. (1994) Potential Benefits of Integration of Environmental and Economic Policies, Graham and Trotman and the Office for Publications of the European Communities, Brussels. 191 Supported by the following findings: INFRAS and ECOPLAN (1996) ‘Economic Impact Analysis of Eco-tax Proposals: Comparative Analysis of Modeling Results’, European Commission, Directorate-General XII, Brussels. 192 Sutton, P. (2000) ‘Is it Possible for a Green Economy to have High Economic Performance?’ Green Innovations, Melbourne: Available at www.green-innovations.asn.au/econ-mdl.htm Accessed 1 October 2008 193 Proops, J., Faber, M. and Wagenhals. G. (1993) Reducing CO2 Emissions: a Comparative Input-output Study for Germany and the UK, Springer Verlag, Berlin. Heidelberg, New York Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia unemployment, this is little comfort to fishermen and woman, timber or mine workers who do not have any other skills to do anything else. It is little comfort to regional communities whose incomes and property values depend on the existence of such industries and the local timber mill or mining plant. Often they are 3rd or 4th generation fishermen and woman, timber workers and miners and their whole identify is understandably attached to that tradition. This is rarely recognised or acknowledged by the environmental movement nor incorporated in to the design of policy responses. Dealing with this issue may be one of the most important roles of Government in the 21st Century. Government needs to work with industry, communities, and a range of institutions, to design ways to provide structural adjustment and compensation packages and re-training for those workers and businesses in the sectors and regions of the economy that will be significantly negatively affected – such as parts of the fisheries, forests, farming, and mining sectors. Workers in regional economies that are dependent on one main industry are understandably very concerned about anything that would affect the future of that industry. Hence governments have a role to play in looking at alternative sustainable futures for regional communities which have currently intrinsically unsustainable industries. Hence a great effort is needed by governments to help these workers and communities revise the basis of their ongoing prosperity by investigating and acting early to find and support new more sustainable industries in these communities that would be affected by reducing the production of and even phasing out certain unsustainable industries. Governments should work with such communities to investigate alternative sustainable business opportunities including sustainably managed mixed specie plantations, sustainable agriculture, eco-tourism, recycling plants, wind farms, biofuel production. As Table 6.1 showed the markets for such sustainable products are rapidly growing. Hence it is in towns, cities, regions and nation’s interests to help support and foster these sustainable industries. To conclude, there is great experience and understanding globally of how to better achieve decoupling whilst ensuring both business competitiveness is not harmed and jobs are created overall. There is also a great deal of experience in how to manage effectively structural adjustment processes for communities and regions that are negatively affected by structural reform. It is important that this knowledge is more widely understood to assist business, governments and civil society to more effectively work together to chart a fair and just course to a sustainable future. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Appendix 1: Selection of Supporting Resources on Decoupling194 Anderson, D. (1992) ‘Economic Growth and the Environment’, Background Paper for the World Bank, World Development Report 1992, World Bank, Washington, DC. Arrow, K. et al (1995) ‘Economic Growth, Carrying Capacity and the Environment’, Science, no. 268, pp 520521 Arrow, K., Dasgupta, P., Goulder, L., Daily, G., Ehrlich, P., Heal, G., Levin,S., Maler, K.G., Schneider, S., Starrett, D., Walker, B., (2004) Are We Consuming Too Much? Journal of Economic Perspectives, Volume 18(3), pp 147-172 Braithwaite, J. and Drahos, P. (2000) ‘Global Business Regulation’, Cambridge University Press Brown, L.R., Flavin, C. and French, H., (2000) ‘State of the World 2000: A Worldwatch Institute Report on Progress Toward a Sustainable Society’, WW Norton, New York Davies, G. (2004) Economia: New Economic Systems to Empower People and Support the Living World, ABC Books, Australia. Dodds, S. (1997) ‘Economic Growth and Human Well-Being’, in Hamilton, C. and Diesendorf, M. (eds) ‘Human Ecology, Human Economy: Ideas for an Ecologically Sustainable Future’, Allen & Unwin, Sydney, p99–124 Dovers, S (2005) Environment and sustainability policy: creation, implementation, and evaluation, Federation Press DRI, et al. (1994) ‘Potential Benefits of Integration of Environmental and Economic Policies, Graham and Trotman and the Office for Publications of the European Communities, Brussels Ekins, P. (1999) Economic Growth and Environmental Sustainability – The Prospects for Green Growth, Routledge Publishing, New York. Fukasaku, Y. (1999) ‘Stimulating Environmental Innovation’, The STI Review, no. 25, Issue 2, OECD, Paris. Goodland, R., Daly, H., El Serafy, S., and von Droste, B. (1991) ‘Introduction. in ‘Environmentally Sustainable Economic Development: Building on Brundtland’, eds. Goodland, et al. United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization, New York Grossman, G and Krueger, A. (1994) ‘Economic Growth and the Environment’, NBER Working Paper no. 4634, February, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA Hamilton, C (1999) ‘The Genuine Progress Indicator: methodological developments and results from Australia’, Ecological Economics, vol, 30., p13-28 Hargroves, K. and Smith, M. (2005) The Natural Advantage of Nations: Business Opportunities, Innovation and Governance in the 21st Century, Earthscan/James&James, London. 194 Compiled by Michael Smith, The Natural Edge Project, Griffith University and the Australian National University, under the supervision of Professor Ernst von Weizsäcker. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Hatfield-Dodds, S. (2004) ‘Economic Growth, Employment, and Environmental Pressure: Insights from Australian experience 1951-2001’, Joint Proceedings of the National Conference on Unemployment and the Australia New Zealand Society for Ecological Economists (ANZSEE) Conference, 8-10 December (2004), University of Newcastle Hawken, P., Lovins, A. and Lovins, L. H. (1999) Natural Capitalism: Creating the Next Industrial Revolution, Earthscan, London. Chapter 9, pp176-177. Kwon Chung, R. (2005) Achieving Environmentally Sustainable Economic Growth in Asia and the Pacific, UNESCAP, Bangkok. Lovins, A., Datta, K., Feiler, T., Rábago, K., Swisher, J., Lehmann, A. and Wicker, K. (2002) ‘Small Is Profitable: The Hidden Economic Benefits of Making Electrical Resources the Right Size’, Rocky Mountain Institute Publications, Colorado McDonough, W. and Braungart, M. (2002) ‘Cradle to Cradle: Remaking the Way We Make Things’, North Point Press, San Francisco. OECD (2008) OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030, OECD, Paris. OECD (2007). Business and the Environment: Policy Incentives and Corporate Responses. OECD. Paris OECD (2007) Environmental Innovation and Global Markets (ENV/EPOC/GSP(2007)2/FINAL). OECD. Paris OECD (2007) Pollution Abatement and Control Expenditures in OECD Countries (ENV/EPOC/SE(2007)). OECD. Paris. OECD (2007) Instrument Mixes for Environmental Policy. OECD. Paris OECD (2006) Cost-Benefit Analysis and the Environment: Recent Developments. OECD. Paris OECD (2005) Costs of Policy Inaction with Respect to Key Environmental Challenges. OECD, Paris. Available at http://www.oecd.org/document/60/0,3343,en_2649_33713_34723644_1_1_1_1,00.html Accessed 1 October 2008 OECD (2004) OECD Environmental Strategy 2001-2011. Review of Progress. OECD. Paris. OECD (2002) Indicators to Measure Decoupling of Environmental Pressure and Economic Growth, Paris, France. OECD (2002) Sustainable Development Strategies: A Resource Book. Paris, France OECD (2001) OECD Environmental Strategy for the First Decade of the 21st Century. Available at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/33/40/1863539.pdf Accessed 1 October 2008 OECD (1984) ‘The Impact of Environmental Measures on the Rate of Economic Growth, Rate of Inflation, Productivity and International Trade’, Background Papers Prepared for the International Conference on Environment and Economics, vol. 1, Paris Parris, R. (1997) ‘Development in Wonderland: The Social and Ecological Sustainability of Economic Growth’, Issues in Global Development, no.9, February, World Vision Australia, Melbourne. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Pascala, S., Socolow, R. (2004) ‘Stabalization Wedges: Solving the Climate Problem for the Next 50 years With Current Technology’, Science, vol. 305 Aug. 13 p.968 Paton, B. (2001) ‘Efficiency Gains Within Firms Under Voluntary Environmental Initiatives’, Journal of Cleaner Production, vol.9 p167–178 Porter, M. (1991) ‘Green Competitiveness’, Scientific American, 5 April Porter, M. and van der Linde, C. (1995) ‘Green and Competitive: Ending the Stalemate’, Harvard Business Review, September–October, pp 121–134; Porter, M. and van der Linde, C. (1995) ‘Toward a New Conception of the Environment–Competitiveness Relationship’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol IX-4, Fall, pp 97–118. Ruffing, K., 2007. “Indicators to Measure Decoupling of Environmental Pressure from Economic Growth”, Ch. 13 in SCOPE 67, Sustainability Indicators (Eds. Tomas Hak, Bedrich Moldan, Arthur Lyon Dahl), Island Press (ISBN 978-1-59726-130-2). Shafik, S. (1994) ‘Economic Development and Environmental Quality: An Econometric Analyses’, Oxford Economic Papers, vol. 46, pp. 757-73 Stern, N et al. (2006) The Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Sutton, P. (2000) ‘Is it Possible for a Green Economy to have High Economic Performance?’ Green Innovations, Melbourne: Available at www.green-innovations.asn.au/econ-mdl.htm . Accessed 1 June 2006 Tapio, P. (2003) Economic growth, traffic volume growth and the CO2 policy of EU15 and Finland 19702001, Tutu Publications, Turku School of Economics and Business Administration Korkeavuorenkatu 25 A 6, FIN-00130 Helsinki, Finland. UNESCAP (2007) Green Growth at a Glance: The Way Forward for Asia and the Pacific. UNESCAP, Bangkok. Available at http://www.unescap.org/esd/water/publications/sd/GGBrochure.pdf Accessed 1 October 2008 Von Weizsacker, E., Lovins, A.B. and Lovins, L.H. (1997) Factor 4: Doubling Wealth, Halving Resource Use, Earthscan/James&James, London. Von Weizsäcker, E. and Jesinghaus, J. (1992) Ecological Tax Reform: Policy Proposal for Sustainable Development London: Zed Books Weaver, P., Jansen, L., Van Grootveld, G., Van Spiegel, E., and Vergragt, P. (2000) Sustainable Technology Development, Greenleaf Publishing, Sheffield, UK. Womack, J. and Jones, D. (1996) ‘Lean Thinking: Banish Waste and Create Wealth in Your Corporation’,Touchstone & Design, New York Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Appendix 2: Selection of International Studies on Decoupling Economic Growth from Greenhouse Gas Emissions195 Australian Business Roundtable on Climate Change (2006) The Business Case for Early Action, ABRCC. Available at www.businessroundtable.com.au. Accessed 14 April 2007. Bailie, A., Bernow, S., Castelli, B., O’Connor, P. and Romm, J. (2003) The Path to Carbon Dioxide-Free Power: Switching to Clean Energy in the Utility Sector, A study by Tellus Institute and Center for Energy and Climate Solutions for WWF, USA. Available at http://assets.panda.org/downloads/wwf_powerswitch_scenario_usa.pdf Accessed 20 April 2007. Department of Trade and Industry (2003) Our Energy Future – Creating a Low Carbon Economy, Energy White Paper, UK Department of Trade and Industry, Version 11. Available at http://www.dti.gov.uk/energy/energy-policy/energy-white-paper/page21223.html. Accessed 10 April 2007. Hatfield-Dodds, S., Jackson, E.K., Adams, P.D. and Gerardi, W. (2007) Leader, follower or free rider? The economic impacts of different Australian emission targets, The Climate Institute, Sydney, Australia. Available at http://www.climateinstitute.org.au/images/stories/CI058_ER_FullReport_NEW.PDF. Accessed 4th March 2008. Interlaboratory Working Group (2000) Scenarios for a Clean Energy Future, Oak Ridge National Laboratory, Berkeley, CA; Lawrence Berkeley Laboratory; and Golden CO: National Renewable Energy Laboratory. Available at www.nrel.gov/docs/fy01osti/29379.pdf. Accessed 14 April 2007. McKinsey & Company (2007). ‘Curbing global energy demand growth: the energy productivity opportunity.’ McKinsey & Company. Available at www.mckinsey.com/mgi/publications/Curbing_Global_Energy/index.asp Accessed 12 August 2008 Mintzer, I., Leonard, J.A. and Schwartz, P. (2003) US Energy Scenarios for the 21st Century, Pew Center on Global Climate Change. Pascala, S. and Socolow, R. (2004) ‘Stabalization Wedges: Solving the Climate Problem for the Next 50 years With Current Technology’, Science, vol. 305, p 968. Repetto, R. and Austin, D. (1997) The Costs of Climate Protection: A Guide For The Perplexed, World Resources Institute, Washington D.C. Available at www.wri.org/wri/climate/. Accessed 12 December 2006. Saddler, H., Diesendorf, M. and Denniss, R. (2004) A Clean Energy Future for Australia Energy Strategies, WWF, Canberra. Available at http://wwf.org.au/ourwork/climatechange/cleanenergyfuture/. Accessed 14 April 2007. Schneider, S. and Azar, C. (2002) ‘Are the Costs of Stabilising the Atmosphere Prohibitive?’, Ecological Economics, vol 42, pp 73-80 Smith, M., Hargroves, K., Stasinopoulos, P., Stephens, R., Desha, C. and Hargroves, S. (2007) Energy Transformed: Sustainable Energy Solutions for Climate Change Mitigation, The Natural Edge Project (TNEP), 195 Compiled by Michael Smith, The Natural Edge Project, Griffith University and the Australian National University, under the supervision of Professor Ernst von Weizsäcker. Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008) Submission to International Panel for Sustainable Resource Management Division of Technology, Industry and Economics - Division Technologie, Industrie et Economie - División de tecnologia, industria y economia Australia. Available at www.naturaledgeproject.net/Sustainable_Energy_Solutions_Portfolio.aspx Accessed 13 February 2008 Stern, N. (2006) The Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Turton, H., Ma, J., Saddler, H. and Hamilton, C. (2002) Long-Term Greenhouse Gas Scenarios: a pilot study of how Australia can achieve deep cuts in emissions, Australia Institute Paper No 48, The Australia Institute. Available at (http://www.tai.org.au/documents/dp_fulltext/DP48.pdf) . Accessed 14 April 2007. i Ibid. Lecture 9.1 http://www.naturaledgeproject.net/Sustainable_Energy_Solutions_Portfolio.aspx#EnergyTransformedLecture9_1 Smith, M., Hargroves, K., Stasinopoulos, P., Stephens, R., Desha, C., and Hargroves, S. (2007) Energy Transformed: Sustainable Energy Solutions for Climate Change Mitigation, The Natural Edge Project (TNEP), Australia. See Lectures 2.1-2.3, 5.3, 9.1 and 9.2 Available at www.naturaledgeproject.net/Sustainable_Energy_Solutions_Portfolio.aspx. Accessed 13. February 2008. iii Ibid. See Lecture 5.2: Opportunities for Energy Efficiency in Manufacturing Industries at http://www.naturaledgeproject.net/Sustainable_Energy_Solutions_Portfolio.aspx#EnergyTransformedLecture5_2. ii iv Ibid, Lecture 5.2. v Ibid. See Lecture 6.2: Opportunities for Energy Efficiency in the Food Processing and Retail Sector at http://www.naturaledgeproject.net/Sustainable_Energy_Solutions_Portfolio.aspx#EnergyTransformedLecture6_2. vi Ibid. See Lecture 6.2. vii Ibid. See Lecture 6.3: Opportunities for Energy Efficiency in the Fast Food Industry athttp://www.naturaledgeproject.net/Sustainable_Energy_Solutions_Portfolio.aspx#EnergyTransformedLecture6_3. viii Ibid. See Lecture 2.2: Opportunities for Energy Efficiency in Commercial Buildings http://www.naturaledgeproject.net/Sustainable_Energy_Solutions_Portfolio.aspx#EnergyTransformedLecture2_2. ix Ibid. See Lecture 2.3: Opportunities for Improving the Efficiency of HVAC Systems http://www.naturaledgeproject.net/Sustainable_Energy_Solutions_Portfolio.aspx#EnergyTransformedLecture2_3 x Ibid. See Lecture 3.1: Opportunities for Improving the Efficiency of Motor Systems http://www.naturaledgeproject.net/Sustainable_Energy_Solutions_Portfolio.aspx#EnergyTransformedLecture3_3. xi Ibid. See Lecture 5.3: Opportunities for Energy Efficiency in the IT Industry and Services Sector http://www.naturaledgeproject.net/Sustainable_Energy_Solutions_Portfolio.aspx#EnergyTransformedLecture5_3. xii Ibid. See Lecture 8.2 at http://www.naturaledgeproject.net/Sustainable_Energy_Solutions_Portfolio.aspx#EnergyTransformedLecture8_1. Ibid. See Lecture 8.2: Integrated Approaches to Energy Efficiency and Alternative Transport Fuels – Passenger Vehicles at http://www.naturaledgeproject.net/Sustainable_Energy_Solutions_Portfolio.aspx#EnergyTransformedLecture8_2. xiii Ibid. See Lecture 8.3: Integrated Approaches to Energy Efficiency and Alternative Transport Fuels – Trucking at http://www.naturaledgeproject.net/Sustainable_Energy_Solutions_Portfolio.aspx#EnergyTransformedLecture8_3. xiv Prepared on invitation by The Natural Edge Project (2008)