PROPOSED MALAYSIA-UNITED STATES FREE TRADE AGREEMENT (MUFTA): IMPLICATIONS FOR MALAYSIAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL DEVELOPMENT TWN Third World Network twnet@po.jaring.my 25 February 2007 Contents 1. INTRODUCTION ............................................................................................................................. 5 2. DISADVANTAGES OF FTAS COMPARED TO MULTILATERAL TRADE AGREEMENTS...................................................................................................................................... 5 3. CHANGING VIEWS ON THE EFFECTS OF LIBERALISATION ............................................ 7 4. “RECIPROCITY” AS A PRINCIPLE IN FTAS ........................................................................... 8 5. MAIN FEATURES OF FTAS INVOLVING UNITED STATES ................................................. 9 6. MARKET ACCESS IN GOODS ...................................................................................................... 9 TRADE IN GOODS: IMPLICATIONS OF MUFTA FOR MALAYSIA ......................................... 12 1. Manufacturing.......................................................................................................................... 12 2. Agriculture ............................................................................................................................... 13 Limited gains for Malaysia ........................................................................................................... 13 Problems facing Malaysia ............................................................................................................ 14 7. SERVICES ....................................................................................................................................... 16 A. GENERAL ....................................................................................................................................... 16 B. FEATURES OF SERVICES CHAPTERS IN FTAS .................................................................................. 17 C SPECIAL CHAPTERS AND TARGETING OF KEY SECTORS, I.E. FINANCE AND TELECOMMUNICATIONS 21 D. DOES THE DEGREE OF LIBERALIZATION MATTER FOR DEVELOPMENT? .......................................... 22 E. NEED FOR A COMPREHENSIVE NATIONAL SERVICES PLAN ............................................................. 23 F. SERVICES: IMPLICATIONS OF MUFTA FOR MALAYSIA.................................................... 23 Basic Telecommunications ............................................................................................................ 25 Distribution Services, including Direct Selling............................................................................. 26 Banking ......................................................................................................................................... 26 Insurance ...................................................................................................................................... 27 Securities ....................................................................................................................................... 27 Audio-Visual and Broadcasting .................................................................................................... 28 Legal Services ............................................................................................................................... 28 Architectural Services ................................................................................................................... 29 Engineering Services .................................................................................................................... 29 Accounting and Taxation Services ................................................................................................ 29 8. INVESTMENT: LIBERALISATION AND INVESTOR PROTECTION ............................... 29 A. SINGAPORE ISSUES ........................................................................................................................ 29 B. BACKGROUND TO INVESTMENT ISSUE ........................................................................................... 30 C. MAIN DESIGN AND STRATEGIC AIM OF THE US .............................................................................. 31 D. THE NEED FOR SPACE AND FLEXIBILITY FOR INVESTMENT AND DEVELOPMENT POLICIES AND THE EFFECTS OF AN INVESTMENT AGREEMENT .......................................................................................... 32 E. CONCLUSIONS ................................................................................................................................ 34 F. INVESTMENT: IMPLICATIONS OF MUFTA FOR MALAYSIA ............................................ 34 9. TELECOMMUNICATIONS ........................................................................................................ 38 10. FINANCIAL SERVICES.............................................................................................................. 46 11. LIBERALISATION OF GOVERNMENT PROCUREMENT. ................................................ 49 A. GOVERNMENT PROCUREMENT IN TRADE AGREEMENTS ............................................................... 49 B. FEATURES OF GOVERNMENT PROCUREMENT IN FTAS INVOLVING USA ....................................... 50 C. NATIONAL POLICY CHANGES NEEDED DUE TO FTA....................................................................... 52 2 D. EROSION OF POLICY SPACE AND IN THE ROLE OF GOVERNMENT PROCUREMENT ........................... 53 E. EFFECTS OF GOVERNMENT PROCUREMENT LIBERALIZATION UNDER FTA ..................................... 54 F. GOVERNMENT PROCUREMENT: IMPLICATIONS OF MUFTA FOR MALAYSIA ........... 55 12. COMPETITION POLICY ........................................................................................................... 62 A. BACKGROUND TO THE ISSUE ............................................................................................... 62 B. TOWARDS A DEVELOPMENT FRAMEWORK ON COMPETITION FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES ..................................................................................................................................... 65 C. WHAT THE US PROPOSES ON COMPETITION IN ITS FTA: ANTI-COMPETITIVE BUSINESS CONDUCT, DESIGNATED MONOPOLIES AND GOVERNMENT ENTERPRISES ........................................................... 67 D. COMPETITION POLICY: IMPLICATIONS FOR MALAYSIA OF MUFTA ........................... 70 14. ENVIRONMENT, BIOSAFETY AND FOOD SAFETY ........................................................... 74 A. BIOSAFETY AND LABELLING OF GENETICALLY MODIFIED ORGANISMS ................. 74 B. OTHER ENVIRONMENT ISSUES ............................................................................................. 76 1. Convention on Biological Diversity .......................................................................................... 76 2. Environmental implications in relation to the Investment chapter ........................................... 77 3. Government procurement and implications for the environment .............................................. 78 15. INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS (IPRS) ..................................................................... 78 A. BACKGROUND ......................................................................................................................... 78 1. WTO’s TRIPS Agreement......................................................................................................... 78 2. IPR negotiations shift to FTAs ................................................................................................. 79 3. Industry influence...................................................................................................................... 81 B. MUFTA WILL OBLIGE MALAYSIA TO SIGN UP TO MANY INTERNATIONAL IP TREATIES ........................................................................................................................................ 82 C. IMPACT OF MUFTA ON ACCESS TO MEDICINES ............................................................... 83 The Effects..................................................................................................................................... 86 D. EFFECTS ON PATENTING OF LIFE, BIODIVERSITY, GENETIC RESOURCES, AGRICULTURE AND FARMERS .................................................................................................. 89 1. Background .............................................................................................................................. 89 2. UPOV 1991, Plant Varieties protection and Effect on Farmers’ Rights ................................. 90 3. Budapest Treaty on the International Recognition of the Deposit of Microorganisms for the Purposes of Patent Procedure ...................................................................................................... 92 Implications for Malaysia ............................................................................................................. 93 4. Data exclusivity and farmers ................................................................................................... 94 E. PATENT COOPERATION TREATY.......................................................................................... 95 Effects on the 9th Malaysia Plan ................................................................................................... 96 Health/quality of life ................................................................................................................................ 96 Moving up the value chain ....................................................................................................................... 96 Biotechnology .......................................................................................................................................... 96 Malaysia’s economic growth is affected if Malaysians are sicker ............................................................ 96 F. SCOPE OF PATENTABILITY .................................................................................................... 97 Software patents ............................................................................................................................ 98 G. COPYRIGHT ............................................................................................................................... 98 1. .Background .............................................................................................................................. 98 2. Copyright term extensions ..................................................................................................... 102 Expressions of concern in Australia about the extension of copyright duration to 70 years .................. 103 Australian Federal Government concerns .............................................................................................. 103 State Government concerns .................................................................................................................... 104 Librarians’ concerns ............................................................................................................................... 105 Application of Agreement to Existing Subject Matter ........................................................................... 108 3. Anti-circumvention provisions .............................................................................................. 108 When circumvention is needed .............................................................................................................. 111 4. MUFTA obliges Malaysia to join WIPO 1996 Internet Treaties ........................................... 112 5. Some implications of Copyright section for Malaysian society ............................................. 114 H. TRADEMARKS ........................................................................................................................ 115 I. ENFORCEMENT ........................................................................................................................ 116 1. General ................................................................................................................................... 116 2. Internet service provider liability............................................................................................ 116 How ISP liability works in USFTAs ...................................................................................................... 117 3 The cost of ISP liability.......................................................................................................................... 120 J. IMPLEMENTATION ................................................................................................................. 121 K. IPRS: SUMMARY ON EFFECTS OF MUFTA ....................................................................... 121 16. NEED FOR POLICY FRAMEWORK AND ASSESSMENT OF COSTS AND BENEFITS .............................................................................................................................................................. 123 EXAMPLE OF FTA COST-BENEFIT FRAMEWORK .............................................................................. 125 REFERENCES ................................................................................................................................... 126 4 PROPOSED MALAYSIA-UNITED STATES FREE TRADE AGREEMENT (MUFTA): IMPLICATIONS FOR MALAYSIAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL DEVELOPMENT Third World Network 1. INTRODUCTION This paper deals with the FTA that is being negotiated between Malaysia and the United States or MUFTA (Malaysia-US FTA). It begins with some general aspects of bilateral FTAs. It then briefly states the architecture of issues in the MUFTA and does a description and analysis of each issue or chapter. It is quite a task to analyse the text of an agreement when none exists yet. MUFTA is still being negotiated. Moreover the drafts of the negotiations are not available to the public. However, it is still possible to give a summary of what MUFTA may look like, because it is quite well known that the US makes use of a “template” for its negotiating position in its bilateral FTAs. Its recent bilateral FTAs are rather similar in chapter headings as well as in text. It may well be that the US would not agree to conclude an FTA unless its text basically is in accordance with the template. Thus, some of the FTAs, particularly the Singapore-US FTA has been used as a likely draft of what a Malaysian-US FTA may be like, and a description and analysis is undertaken based on such a “model.” As there are so many topics, this report has been able to deal with several but not all. Perhaps a subsequent report can be more comprehensive. We hope this contributes to the on-going discussion on the MUFTA. 2. DISADVANTAGES OF FTAS COMPARED TO MULTILATERAL TRADE AGREEMENTS It is generally recognized that bilateral agreements, especially between a developing and a developed country, are not the best option and that multilateral negotiations and agreements are preferable. The reasons for this include: 1. Bilateral agreements usually lead to “trade diversion”, in that the partners divert away products that may be more cheaply priced in favour of products from the FTA partner, even if they are not cheaply priced, thus resulting in inefficiency. 5 2. In an FTA between a developed country and a developing country or countries, the latter are usually in a weaker bargaining position due to the lack of capacity of their economies, their weaker political situation, and their weaker negotiating resources. 3. In the WTO, the principles of special and differential treatment, and less than full reciprocity, are recognized. Thus, developing countries are better able to negotiate on the basis of non-reciprocity and for non-reciprocal outcomes, in which they are not obliged to open up their markets (or undertake other obligations) to the same degree as developed countries. However, these “development principles” are usually absent in FTAs, or they are only reflected in longer implementation periods for the developing country. The FTAs are basically on the basis of reciprocity. This “equal treatment” of parties that are unequal in capacity is likely to result in unequal outcomes. 4. The FTAs contain many items that are not part of the rules of the WTO. Many North-South FTAs include rules on investment, government procurement and competition law, which have so far been rejected by developing countries as subjects for WTO negotiations or rules. Developing countries also refused that labour standards and environment standards be subjects of discussion in the WTO. All these topics are now entering “by the side-door” through the FTAs, even though the same reasons for developing countries to reject rules on these issues should apply in FTAs as they do in the WTO. 5. Even where issues are already the subject of rules in the WTO (e.g. intellectual property and services), there were many “flexibilities” and options open to developing countries in interpreting and in implementing obligations in these areas. However, there are attempts by developed countries to remove these flexibilities for developing countries in the FTAs. If these attempts succeed, the “policy space” for developing countries to pursue development and socio-economic goals would be significantly reduced. 6. The proliferation of so many agreements also puts pressure on personnel and financial resources in developing countries and requires a lot of technical expertise which may be not adequately available, given the large number of agreements and the limited resources. The report “The Future of the WTO” commissioned by the WTO Director-General and which was published in January 2005 has criticized the proliferation of bilateral and regional trade agreements (RTAs), which it says has made the “MFN” (most favoured nation) principle the exception rather than the rule, and which has led to increased discrimination in world trade. However, it appears that FTA negotiations are moving ahead and negotiations on even more FTAs and RTAs are being announced. Several researchers have pointed out that whilst bilateral agreements may be tempting for a developing country to get some specific advantages from its developed-country partner, such as better market access for some of its products, there are also several 6 potential dangers and disadvantages. Developed countries such as the US and Japan are known to want to use the instrument of bilateral agreements to obtain from their partners what they failed to achieve at the WTO, in which the developing countries have been able to oppose or resist certain negative elements in various agreements. 3. CHANGING VIEWS ON THE EFFECTS OF LIBERALISATION Whilst an advanced developing country which is already highly liberalized may be able to bear the pressures of faster liberalization, other developing countries may not be able to compete with the faster opening of their markets or with other demands of the developed country. Up to a few years ago, there was a widespread belief in the orthodoxy (promoted especially by the IMF and World Bank, and by policy makers in developed countries) that liberalization is necessarily good for development, and the faster the liberalization the better it is for development. This was the intellectual basis for developed countries to pressurize developing countries to quickly and deeply cut their tariffs and remove non-tariff barriers, as well as open up their services sector, financial sector and investment regime. However, there has been growing skepticism not only from civil society but also policy makers regarding this orthodoxy, mainly because such rapid liberalization has led to import surges in many developing countries, with adverse effects on the local industrial and agricultural sectors, and on the balance of payments and the debt position. The emerging paradigm is that developing countries require certain degrees of protection to enable the local firms and farms to compete in their own domestic markets, and that this was the way the now-developed countries arranged their own trade and industrial policies when they were at the development stage. Such protection is especially required by developing countries when many agricultural products are heavily protected by tariffs and subsidies in the developed countries, and where export and domestic subsidies enable these countries to sell artificially-cheapened products on the world market. Tariff protection is the means by which developing countries can defend their farmers from unfair competition, especially since quantitative restrictions were prohibited under the Uruguay Round. Arguments have been put forward by developing countries along the above lines in the WTO. The developing countries are also pursuing three tracks to strengthen the development dimension in the WTO: (1) proposals to clarify, review or amend existing WTO rules, due to problems of implementation of these rules; (2) proposals to strengthen existing SDT (special and differential treatment) provisions, and to introduce new ones where they do not exist but are required; (3) proposals to have adequate SDT provisions in new rules or revision of rules in current negotiations (especially in agriculture and industrial products). Some developed countries are beginning to change their previously strict insistence on liberalisation in developing countries. For instance the UK government has declared that it will not seek to “impose” liberalization on African countries and on least developed countries. The recent G8 summit also has a statement along similar 7 lines. Notably, this change in attitude is stated only for “least developed countries” (LDCs) and thus presumably does not apply to non-LDC developing counties. But it can be noted that a change in attitude towards liberalization has started even in developed countries’ policy circles. 4. “RECIPROCITY” AS A PRINCIPLE IN FTAs There is a significant lack of a similar “development track” within FTAs between developed and developing countries. Instead, the FTAs are being negotiated mainly on the basis of “reciprocity”, i.e. that both sides take on similar levels of obligations. The focus is almost strictly on “Market Access” and “National Treatment”i.e. how to open up markets in order to get more business opportunities. There is hardly any development content as such, not is there much sympathy for the unequal capacity the developing country faces, both in its level of development, and in its negotiating capacity. This is mainly due to the demand for such a basis by trade policy makers of developed countries. They also point to the need for FTAs and RTAs to be consistent with WTO rules, in particular Article XXIV of GATT 1994 (covering customs unions and free trade areas). (WTO 1994: p522-525). This Article enables FTAs to be established under certain conditions. One provision is that “the purpose of a customs union or a free trade area should be to facilitate trade between the constituent territories and not to raise barriers to the trade of other contracting parties with such territories.” It also defines a free-trade area as a group of two or more customs territories in which the duties and other restrictive regulations of commerce are “eliminated on substantially all the trade between the constituent territories in products originating in such territories.” [GATT, Article XXIV.8(b)]. This is widely taken to mean that FTAs have to be reciprocal in nature, since SDT provisions are not mentioned in the Article, and that tariffs and other trade restrictions have to be eliminated on “substantially all trade” between the parties. It is not defined what constitutes “substantially all trade.” In the course of discussions between the European Union and African-Caribbean and Pacific (ACP) countries, which are negotiating economic partnership agreements (EPAs), it is understood that the EU considers this to mean at least 90% of trade, while some ACP countries interpret it to mean at least 60% of trade. There have been recent proposals to revise or clarify Article XXIV so that it clearly enables non-reciprocal relations to prevail in FTAs between developed and developing countries. The ACP Group has made such a proposal. Recently, China has also made a development-oriented proposal on Article XXIV. If the Article is not clarified or revised, if reciprocity remains the principle in an FTA between a developed and developing country, and if the FTA covers almost all products, then a typical developing country is likely to be at a serious disadvantage, as it has less production capacity and probably has significantly higher tariffs, especially on industrial products. Elimination of tariffs will thus hurt the business or viability of local industries and even farms of the typical developing country. 8 5. MAIN FEATURES OF FTAs INVOLVING UNITED STATES The main issues in FTAs that involve developed countries such as the US, EU and Japan typically include the following: 1. Market access in goods Manufactured goods Agricultural goods 2. Services in general 3. Specific services sectors -- financial services, telecommunications 4. Intellectual property rights 5. Investment liberalization and investor protection 6. Liberalisation of government procurement 7. Competition issues: Business practices, monopolies and government-linked companies 8. Environment and food safety issues 9. Labour standards Only the first item has traditionally been the subject of an FTA. The second and fourth issues were introduced into the multilateral trading system through the Uruguay Round that concluded in 1994. They are the new issues in GATT, and are now in WTO. The set of issues in items 5-7 (investment, procurement, competition) are known as the Singapore issues as they were first introduced into the WTO through its Ministerial Conference in 1996 in Singapore. However they were only subjects for discussion in working groups and there has been opposition from developing countries to make them subjects of binding rules. In July 2004, the WTO General Council agreed that there would not be any negotiations on them during the Doha work programme period, and work in the working groups on these issues stopped. However, the FTAs involving the US include these items as subjects of rules. On the last two issues, it was also agreed that labour and environment standards not be part of rule-making in WTO. Labour standards are not even a subject of discussion in the WTO. This is due to the fear of developing countries that they would become the basis of protectionist measures against their products. However in the FTAs, “environment” may cover environmental issues broadly and not just standards. In this paper, we include the sensitive issue of biosafety and labeling of products containing genetically-modified organisms (GMOs) in this section. It can be seen that subjects that have been rejected by developing countries as topics of negotiations or even discussion have made a comeback through the FTAs. 6. MARKET ACCESS IN GOODS Given the problems arising from FTAs, some developing countries decide to negotiate an FTA with a developed country is the fear of being left behind, as they see other countries, especially in their region, entering FTA negotiations with developed 9 countries, which constitute their major markets. There is a fear that those developing countries that are entering FTAs will gain a competitive edge and thus leave those that do not join an FTA behind. The developing country may also believe that entering an FTA will give it benefits in terms of greater access into the markets of the partners, as the FTA will provide preferences in terms of lower tariffs or quotas. It is thus crucial that the developing country identify the products which are important for it, whose exports it hopes will expand through the FTA, and to assess whether realistically whether there will be an increase in market access and to what extent. This will then have to be measured against the costs to be incurred by the country, in terms of market access to its own markets by the partner, as well as in terms of concessions in other areas (such as services, investment and intellectual property). Many countries that had hoped to obtain significant expansion of market access to the major developed countries have been disappointed in the results of the negotiations. A major reason for this is that there are structural, legal and political impediments that prevent the developed country from opening its market beyond a certain limit, in respect of its sensitive products (where further opening will cause dislocation to its producers). As Smith (2005) points out, there are a number of structural problems that make it difficult for developing countries to obtain market access in sectors of interest to them in FTAs with developed countries. Firstly, there is usually unequal bargaining power in developing-developed country bilateral negotiations, with the developing countries in a weaker position. Secondly, it is not possible for developed countries to reduce or withdraw agricultural export and domestic subsidies on the products that the developing county partner are exporting, as the subsidies would have to be removed for all the products, which would then also benefit non-FTA partners. Thirdly, there may exist laws that frame the terms of reference for what the developed country can offer. The United States negotiators are also constrained in the terms they can offer in FTAs by their Bipartisan Trade Promotion Authority Act of 2002 (Smith 2005). This Act prevents US negotiators from concluding FTAs which: ‘reduce any rate of duty (other than a rate of duty that does not exceed 5 percent ad valorem on the date of the enactment of this Act) to a rate of duty which is less than 50 percent of the rate of such duty that applies on such date of enactment’ ‘reduce the rate of duty below that applicable under the Uruguay Round Agreements, on any import sensitive agricultural product;’ o ‘The term “import sensitive agricultural product” means an agricultural product— (A) with respect to which, as a result of the Uruguay Round Agreements the rate of duty was the subject of tariff reductions by the United States and, pursuant to such Agreements, was reduced on January 1, 1995, to a rate that was not less than 97.5 10 percent of the rate of duty that applied to such article on December 31, 1994; or (B) which was subject to a tariff-rate quota on the date of the enactment of this Act’ Besides the above, the Act does not enable special and differential treatment as its negotiating objectives include ‘reciprocal market access’,1 ‘to obtain reciprocal tariff and non-tariff barrier elimination agreements’2 and to obtain rules which are comparable to US ones3. Besides the legal constraint posed above, it must be expected that the US negotiators will find it very difficult to make offers in agriculture or in sensitive industrial products where increased market opening for imports will be met with a political backlash from lobby groups such as big farmers, food companies, labour unions, domestic firms and from Congress. The episode in the US Congress in 2005, in which the bill authorizing the US-CAFTA agreement faced massive opposition and was passed by only two votes, shows how difficult it will be for market access demands of developing country FTA partners to be met, even though the exports from CAFTA countries were too small to have an appreciable impact on the US economy. On textiles and apparel (politically extremely sensitive products for the US), even a strong negotiating party like Singapore, was unable to overcome the US demand to apply the “yarn forward rule” to qualify for immediate duty-free entry into the U.S’. The ‘yarn forward’ rule means that ‘textiles and apparel from Singapore must be made from yarn sourced from Singapore or the U.S. This means that US yarn has to be used, instead of cheaper yarn and fabric sourced from the Asian region. (Smith 2005; Koh and Chang, 2004). Singapore also had to agree to additional and cumbersome customs procedures to verify that textiles/apparel are made in Singapore (including allowing on-site inspections of enterprises by US officials) and additional safeguard measures. On agricultural products, the negotiations on certain sensitive products can also be expected to be very difficult. Most importantly, the US will not include lowering of agricultural subsidies in its FTAs, thus depriving its trading partners what would probably be the most important concession that could lead to greater market access for agricultural-exporting countries. Even a developed country like Australia found that it could not gain any ground with the US on expanding its market access on sugar, which is an important Australian export and is highly protected in the US. Before its FTA with the USA, Australia had a sugar quota of 87,402 tonnes per annum. During the FTA negotiations, the Australian Government repeatedly promised ‘no sugar, no deal’. The Australian government fought very hard to increase the quota but failed to do so. The USAustralia FTA did not provide any extra quota for Australia. (Smith 2005). 1 S2102(a)(1). S2102(b)(10): “RECIPROCAL TRADE IN AGRICULTURE.—(A) The principal negotiating objective of the United States with respect to agriculture is to obtain competitive opportunities for United States exports of agricultural commodities in foreign markets substantially equivalent to the competitive opportunities afforded foreign exports in United States markets” which includes (ii): reducing tariffs to levels that are the same as or lower than those in the United States; 2 S2102(b)(1)(B) 3 For example in investment: s2102(b)3 and intellectual property: s2102(b)4(A)(i)(II) 11 On beef, which is Australia’s main export to the US, Australia obtained an 18.5 per cent increase in beef quotas, but this was confined to manufacturing-grade beef (mainly hamburger mince and pet food) and spread over 18 years. It meant that Australia’s share of the American beef market could actually decline, according to Australian projections. Australian academics calculated the benefits for beef farmers from the extra market access under the FTA to be about half a cow, per farm, per year. Furthermore, the US has reserved the right to employ safeguards to raise tariffs again if the quantity of Australian imports or the price of beef changes suddenly. (Smith 2005). The developing country partner in an FTA may have limited products where it can effectively make use of increased market access opportunities, due to limited supply capacity or inability to market. For instance, most of the ACP countries and the LDCs have been unable to make use of the preferential access they have to the EU market. And for products that the developing countries have an advantage in, these are usually “sensitive” to the developed country and thus some may be excluded from the FTA market opening. Also, developed countries like the USA and Europe are well known for making use of “non tariff barriers” (such as safety regulations and anti-dumping measures) to block imports of developing countries. The market access hopes may become illusory. On the other hand, the developing country is expected to reciprocate by opening up its own market to the developed country, by eliminating its tariffs on a wide range of products. This can result in significant dislocation of local producers. Under NAFTA, Mexico agreed to total trade liberalization of all agricultural products by 2008 (even though it had a 15-year adjustment period for corn and beans). According to Carlsen (2003), imports of corn (the most widely grown crop in Mexico) nearly tripled after NAFTA, and the price has dropped. Other crops fared worse, as imports of soybean, wheat, poultry and beef have risen over 500%, displacing domestic production. Exports especially of fruits and vegetables have risen but this failed to compensate for the import rise. About 2 million rural jobs were lost since NAFTA. TRADE IN GOODS: IMPLICATIONS OF MUFTA FOR MALAYSIA 1. Manufacturing Malaysia’s tariffs in manufacturing are much higher generally than those of the United States. Since both parties will have to eliminate tariffs for “substantially all products”, Malaysia would thus have to make more sacrifices or more concessions overall as compared to the US, in terms of tariff reduction and elimination. This in turn could displace Malaysian industries that cannot compete with the cheaper U.S. imports. The US Trade Representative’s Office, during the launch of the MUFTA on 8 March 2006 issued a document on the “Economic and Strategic Benefits” of the FTA to the U.S. It states that US exporters have much to gain from FTA with Malaysia. It gives data that Malaysia’s average bound industrial tariffs are 12 nearly 4 times higher than US tariffs (14.5% compared to 3.7%). Malaysia’s average applied tariff is 8.4% or more than double the 3.7% of the US. In a sector-by-sector table, the US paper gives some examples of the higher Malaysian tariffs compared to US tariffs, for example in transport equipment (1.5% comprade to 3.2%), wood, pulp, paper and furniture (10.9% vs 0.7%), leather, rubber, footwear and travel goods (14% vs 4.3%), electric machinery (6.7% vs 1.9%), non-electric machinery (3.7% vs 1.2%), textiles and clothing (13.5% vs 9.6%), mineral products (8.8% vs 1%). The US National Association of Manufacturers forecast that US manufacturing exports to Malaysia could double by 2010 under a FTA. For the US, a major target is Malaysia’s present import restrictions on motor vehicles, which were highlighted in the Malaysian chapter of the USTR’s report on Foreign Trade Barriers. The USTR comments that Malaysia has long protected its automobile industry from foreign competition using high tariffs and non-tariff trade barriers, that government policies distinguish between “national” and “non-national” cars, and that they continue to block open trade through the approved permit system and offering rebates for national manufacturers. It notes non-Asean CKD cars are charged 10% tariff and 80200% excise tax. The US is likely to demand elimination of tariff and non-tariff barriers for motor vehicles into Malaysia. If agreed to, this has serious implications for national cars. Malaysian textiles companies are expecting to benefit from increased access to the US market. However they will also face a number of hurdles, including the “yarn forward rule” (imposed on other FTA partners like Singapore) to qualify for immediate duty-free entry into the U.S. This rule means that textiles and apparel from Malaysia must be made from yarn sourced from Malaysia or the U.S, i.e. that US yarn has to be used, instead of cheaper yarn and fabric sourced from the Asian region. Malaysia will also have to agree to additional and cumbersome customs procedures to verify that textiles/apparel are made in Malaysia (including allowing on-site inspections of enterprises by US officials) and for the US to have additional safeguard measures to be used on Malaysian textiles. 2. Agriculture In the agriculture market access part of the FTA, Malaysia is likely to get a negative deal. Firstly, there will be limited gains to Malaysia in terms of access to the US agricultural market. Secondly, Malaysia will have to open up its agricultural sector to US exports, and the US will probably not agree to having sensitive products such as rice exempted. Limited gains for Malaysia The US is unlikely to be able to offer any significant market access. In the USAustralia FTA, Australia was unable to gain any additional access for its sugar 13 exports. The gain to Australia in beef (through a higher quota) was not significant, estimated by academics to be equivalent to “about half a cow, per farm, per year.” Most importantly, the US will not offer to reduce its domestic farm subsidies in the FTA. It argues that this can be done only through the WTO. The high US subsidies keep the prices of its farm products artificially low, with three effects: This prevents other countries like Malaysia to penetrate the US market more. For example if soya bean subsidies were removed, prices would reflect the cost of production more, and increase, making palm oil more competitive. Malaysia could insist that US subsidies be removed, but this will be unacceptable to the US. Subsidies enable the US to export its otherwise uncompetitive farm products, because they lower the price, often to far below the cost of production. To defend themselves from this unfair practice, countries need higher tariffs, otherwise the US products can take over the market with their artificially cheap prices. According to a recent UNCTAD paper, "Studies show that under the existing US policy, the cost of producing major crops has been much higher than the prices realized for them.In the year 2001, market prices were 23% below the cost of production for corn, 48% for wheat, 32% for soybean, 52% for cotton, and 45% for rice. In 2001, the US had a significant share in world exports in these commodities which is as high as 35% in cotton, more than 20% in wheat and around 10% in rice." Because of the subsidies, US exports sell at low prices, thus out-competing more efficient producers. For example, if subsidies were removed and US soya bean export prices increased, Malaysian palm oil (which competes with soya oil) would be more competitive. Problems facing Malaysia While the gains are limited, Malaysia can face problems since the US will demand that agricultural tariffs be brought to zero, within a time frame. Under NAFTA, Mexico expanded its farm imports from the US dramatically, nearly tripling its imports of corn (the most important crop) and increasing more than five-fold its imports of soybean, wheat, poultry and beef. have risen over 500%. Rural job losses were 2 to 3 million since NAFTA. The US government has said that it wants to export more farm products to Malaysia in particular rice, soyabeans, chicken and beef. It wants Malaysia’s tariffs on American farm products to be reduced to zero. A USTR fact sheet on the FTA states that there will be opportunities for US agricultural exporters. The US exported US$400 million of farm products to Malaysia in 2005. It said that US growers of fruit, vegetables, nuts, processed horticultural products and other food producers would benefit (USTR 2006). 14 The product that has raised most concern is rice. Malaysia currently has a 40% tariff on rice to protect Malaysia’s rice farmers. It also follows a policy of having a single importer for rice, viz. BERNAS and imposes quotas on how much foreign rice may be imported. In the FTA negotiations, the US is likely to ask for the rice tariff to be reduced to zero (over some years) and for non-tariff barriers to be dismantled, which could include the quota and import monopoly by BERNAS. The rice sector in Malaysia is relatively protected in view of ensuring food security and protection of rural livelihoods. Presently, around 296,000 farmers depend on rice for their livelihood, with 116,000 farmers exclusively involved in the cultivation of padi. Further, in the 9th Malaysia Plan, the government has set a self-sufficiency target of 90% for rice in 2010 (from 72% in 2005). If the rice tariff were reduced to zero then the US rice (which has subsidies from the US government so that it can be sold at 25% below the cost of growing it) could seriously undermine local rice production. According to press reports, rice and tobacco have been listed in Malaysia’s exclusion list in the FTA negotiations (The Star 15 Jan 2007). The Agriculture Minister, Tan Sri Muhyiddin Yassin, was reported to have said that the Cabinet had decided that the government would not compromise on the livelihood of local farmers. The Minister said: “Whatever happens, if rice is the cause for the FTA not to be signed, then let it be because the Government will not compromise on anything that can affect the interest of our farmers. If the US decides to raise the matter, we will tell them to take it or leave it,” (The Star | 15 Jan 2007) The Minister’s comments came in the wake of protests by farmers and NGOs that the MUFTA would involve the import of subsidized US rice with no border protection and this would jeopardize local rice, thus affecting farmers’ livelihoods and income. Although Malaysia has demanded that rice, tobacco and alcohol products be on its exclusion list, trade media reports from Washington indicate that the US will not agree to products being excluded. If its stance is maintained, then Malaysia will face demands that its rice and tobacco tariffs will be reduced to zero, perhaps with a transition period. At present there is not much import of US rice into Malaysia. This could be due to the 40% tariff and the quota maintained by BERNAS. If the 40% tariff is removed, and US rice is allowed to compete freely, its price may become competitive with local rice. Research by Oxfam (2005) shows that American rice is heavily subsidized. According to Oxfam (2005): It (the USA) is the world’s third largest rice exporter — even though US rice costs over twice as much to grow as it does in export-leading Thailand and Viet Nam. This is only possible because of lavish state funding: in 2003 the US government ploughed $1.3bn into rice sector subsidies, supporting farmers 15 to produce a crop that cost them $1.8bn to grow — effectively footing the bill for 72 per cent of the cost of production. Between 2000 and 2003, it cost on average $415 to grow and mill one tonne of white rice in the US. But that rice was dumped on export markets for $274 per tonne, 34 per cent below its true cost. The real winner from this combination of subsidy bonanza in the US and rapid trade liberalisation in developing countries is US agribusiness. No wonder the country’s rice millers and exporters invest so much in lobbying alongside the US government, to open up new export markets for their dumped surpluses. In the period 2000-2003, the cost of production and milling of milled rice was US$415 per tonne (41 cents per kilo) while the export price as US$274 per tonne (27 cents per kilo). The export price was thus 34% below the cost of production, reflecting the high degree of subsidy. Without the subsidy US rice would not be globally competitive. With the subsidy, the US is now the third largest rice exporter in the world. In some years the export price is even lower, and the degree of subsidy even higher. In 2002 for example, the export price was 22.7 cents per kilo, while the production and milling cost was 39.5 cents. The export price was 43% below the cost. According to the US Department of Agriculture’s Rice Outlook (12 Feb 2007), the export price of US long-grain milled rice on 6 February was US$419 per ton. This is equivalent to 41 cents per kilo, or 143 sen (given the exchange rate US$1 to MR3.5). If there is a 40% tariff, the US rice would not be competitive in the Malaysian market. However at zero tariff, it would be competitive as local rice varieties are currently retailing at RM1.70 to RM2.00 per kilo (depending on the grade of rice). Currently US rice is higher priced than Thai rice. The USDA report cites US$321 per ton as the export price of Thai high-quality milled rice, which is currently lower than the US price (US$419 per ton). However the gap is narrower in some months, and at one point in the second half of 2005 the Thai and US rice prices converged at around US$300 per ton. If a lower tariff is applied to US rice as compared to Thai rice, then the price gap between Thai and US rice could be narrowed. In any case, it is most unfair to allow the tariff on US rice to be reduced or even eliminated, when there is such a huge subsidy given to US rice growers and exporters. The position that rice should be excluded from the FTA commitments should be maintained. 7. SERVICES A. General Developing Before the Uruguay Round was launched, many developing countries had tried to resist the inclusion of new areas like trade in services and trade-related intellectual property rights as they believed agreements in these areas would be against their interests as they would not have the capacity to gain from them, whist they and their local companies would stand to lose. Despite this reluctance, services 16 became a part of the Round on the understanding that developing countries would gain in other areas, especially in enjoying more market access for their goods in agriculture, textiles and clothing and other areas in which they have comparative advantage and where their exports faced tariff and non-tariff barriers. However, given the actual outcome in textiles and clothing and in agriculture, the developing countries did not get their expected benefits. The WTO allows each member to commit in the WTO to services liberalization according to the extent and rate that it chooses and which suits its conditions. This is especially true for developing countries. These countries may want to try out liberalization in some sectors to see the extent to which it is beneficial, but they do not have to commit the liberalization measures in the WTO (as this makes it irreversible, or difficult to reverse). The WTO has a positive list approach. A country makes commitments to liberalise only in sectors that it places on its schedule. And if a sector is included in the schedule, the country can decide the extent of liberalisation to commit in that sector, in each of the 4 modes of service delivery. Restrictions and limits can be placed, for example restrictions on foreign equity ownership or on national treatment in Mode 3 on “commercial presence.” Additional “special and differential treatment” clauses have been established in the GATS and in subsequent documents that clarify that developing countries should be allowed to liberalise less than developed countries and to choose their own pace of liberalisation. These development provisions are especially contained in Article IV of the GATS, Article XIX (2) of the GATS, and the Guidelines and the Procedures for the Negotiations on Trade in Services of March 2001, which is the main document guiding the present services negotiations. B. Features of Services chapters in FTAs Many developing countries have attempted to make use of the flexibilities in GATS, to choose their own pace and sectors to liberalise. They have been cautious to increase their binding commitments in the WTO, as (1) they are worried about the possible consequences, especially since it is difficult to backtrack even if the commitment turns out to be an error; (2) they are unable to benefit from the liberalization of other countries, due to supply constraints (and due to continued protection of the labour market in the North) and thus if they were to themselves liberalise, they would have more costs than benefits; (3) they are within their rights to choose whether to liberalise, in which way, and in which sectors, if at all. Developed countries have been frustrated by what they perceive as the slow movement by developing countries in the WTO. The reason for their frustration is that services now comprise the largest sector, and their big services enterprises are pushing to have access to the markets of the developing world. The developed countries are now seeking the use the FTA mechanism to accelerate the liberalization process in developing countries. 17 In contrast to the WTO’s positive list approach to liberalization (under which a country does not commit to liberalise except in the sectors it lists down in a schedule), US FTAs4 use the more drastic negative list approach (in which everything is committed to be opened unless specified in the schedule). The positive list approach was insisted on by the developing countries to enable them to have more flexibility and policy space as to what and when to commit. It is also less risky than the negative list approach as a country may not be aware of the full range of sectors, nor on what it should select to exclude. The developed countries prefer the negative list approach, as this would make it easier for developing countries to commit to liberalization measures in more sectors. The US has chosen this negative list approach in its FTAs with developing countries. For example, the US-Singapore FTA has a negative list approach, in which only sectors placed on a schedule can have limitations to the principles of national treatment, market access, local presence, etc. Such an approach reduces policy space for developing countries, and goes against the more development-friendly positive list approach of the WTO. It also goes against the principles and services structure that the developing countries fought so hard to attain in the WTO. Among the dangers of the negative list approach are: 1. Due to this methodology, the developing country will be vulnerable to greater pressure to liberalise. 2. The country may not be sufficiently aware of all the service sectors and subsectors, and thus may not list all the sub-sectors it wishes not to liberalise. 3. The country may not be able to predict or plan which sectors it may wish to promote domestically in future and thus may agree to liberalise sectors which in future it may regret doing. 4. The country may not be aware of risks in liberalizing particular sub-sectors and may find it difficult to “back track” when circumstances require it to protect domestic firms or the economy (e.g. as happened or may happen during financial crises). 5. The country will not be able to predict which new services sectors may emerge in future, and thus cannot exclude these in the list. The US-FTA chapter on cross-border services covers cross-border supply of services, but does not cover commercial presence or investment (known as Mode 3 in GATS), as this is covered (with its own dispute settlement system) in the investment chapter of the FTA. However, the annexes in the services chapter with reservations covers the exceptions for services sectors from commitments relating to both the services and the investment chapters. The definition of “Cross-Border Supply of Services” in the US-Singapore FTA is the supply of a service: a) From the territory of one Party into the territory of the other Party. For example, a consultant located in one country giving advice to a client located 4 Except for the Jordan-USFTA which was one of the first USFTAs (signed in 2000 before the current fast track legislation). 18 in another country by mail, phone or internet service. (This is similar to Mode 1 or cross-border trade in GATS), b) In the territory of one Party by a person of that Party to a person of the other party. (This is similar to “consumption abroad” or Mode 2 in GATS, for example a student from Singapore traveling to the US to attend university). c) By a national of a Party in the territory of another Party. (This is movement of persons, similar to Mode 4 in GATS). [However Article 8.2.4 in the USSingapore FTA says this chapter does not impose any obligation on a party with respect to a national of the other party seeking access to its employment market, or employed on a permanent basis in its territory, and does not confer any right on that national with respect to that access or employment.]. The non-inclusion of the investment dimension of services does not mean that this aspect (the most prominent one in GATS) is absent. It is covered instead as part of the investment chapter, in which the rights of the foreign investor are very clearly spelt out. The chapter covers measures by a Party affecting cross-border trade in services by service providers of the other Party. Some articles also apply to measures affecting the supply of a service by an investor or investment of the other Party as defined in the investment chapter. Such measures include the production, distribution, marketing, sale and delivery of a service; purchase or use of a service; access to distribution, transport or telecommunications in connection with supply of a service; and provision of a bond or security as condition for supply of a service. The main principles and provisions include: national treatment for the foreign service suppliers; most favoured nation treatment; and market access (where both parties agree not to impose limitations on the other party’s number of service providers, on the total value of service transactions or assets, on the total number of service operations and on the total number of natural persons employed in a particular service sector. There are also provisions on freedom for transfer of funds and payments, on domestic regulation, transparency and professional services. In the US FTAs, since there is a negative list approach, there are annexes with schedules of exceptions. It is understood that every sector and activity is totally liberalized, except those placed in the annxes. In the Singapore FTA, there are two annexes of exceptions. Annex I actually has two sets of exceptions. The first set comprises existing “non-conforming measures” that are maintained by a Party. Since “conforming” means total liberalization and national treatment, “non-conforming” refers to those existing measures that restrict or limit the market access, national treatment, MFN and local presence provisions. If listed in Annex I, these measures can continue. The second set in Annex I comprises amendments to any non-conforming measure, “to the extent that the amendment does not decrease the conformity of the measure as it existed immediately before the amendment.” 19 The implication is that the existing measures that do not conform to these provisions are allowed to be exempted but the level of their “non-conformity” can only be decreased, and cannot be increased. This implies that there the existing “applied” levels of liberalization are notified and a “standstill” is imposed, in that the degree of liberalization can be increased but not decreased. The developing country party would give up the flexibility and policy space that is presently available in GATS, to be able to liberalise unilaterally in certain services sectors, yet not “bind” the full degree of that liberalization. Having a distance between the “applied” and the “bound” levels allows a country to experiment, with the possibility of backtracking, should it be necessary to do so. However there is also Annex II in which the country lists the sectors and activities it wants to exclude so that it can take more restrictive measures (than what already exists). The exclusion is in respect to market access, national treatment, MFN and local presence. The US-Singapore FTA excludes application of the chapter to -“services supplied in the exercise of governmental authority….which is supplied neither on a commercial basis nor in competition with one or more service suppliers”. (Article 8.2.5.b) As pointed out by Shashikant (2005), neither of the criteria is defined. This provision is the same as Article 1 in GATS, which has been the subject of controversy. Many service sectors involve the public interest and thus are delivered by governments through a mixed system that is wholly or partly funded with a minimum charge being paid by consumers, but tightly regulated by governments at the central, regional and local levels. Often these systems co-exist with other private for-profit delivery systems. Following the criteria above, these systems would fall outside the purview of the exclusion and be subject to the terms of the agreement unless expressly reserved. For example in Malaysia there are public hospitals which are funded by the government with consumers paying for their treatment according to their income, with some being subsidized. Could it be argued that this system is providing treatment on a commercial basis? There are also private hospitals which provide the same treatment as public hospitals and in a way are competing for the same patients. As a consequence the health service sector (it can be argued) may not fall within the exception. As many of the essential public services may not be eligible for exclusion, foreign service providers will likely be able to access public interest sectors such as water, health, education, national parks, and pension funds. These providers are likely to target only the profitable sectors or the higher income earners. Consequently not only does the government lose income but it may also be saddled with having to provide the less profitable service sectors or subsidizing low income earners who cannot afford the prices of foreign service providers. (Shashikant 2005). In the US-Singapore FTA, a provision on Domestic Regulations states that measures relating to qualification requirements and procedures, technical standards and licensing requirements are to be “based on objective and transparent criteria” and should be "no more burdensome than necessary to ensure the quality of the service". 20 Besides the investor-state dispute settlement process in the investment chapter, the FTAs also have a general dispute settlement mechanism, which allows a government to claim that a law or policy of the other country is inconsistent with the FTA obligations or the other party has failed to fulfill its obligation or a benefit expected from the agreement is being nullified and impaired as a result of a measure not inconsistent with the Agreement. The dispute process requires initial consultations, and if that fails, it must be referred to a dispute panel. The Panel can declare that a Party to the agreement has not conformed to its obligations. In effect the infringing law would have to be eliminated or compensation be paid. Parties can also under certain conditions take retaliatory action suspending benefits of equivalent effect. Trade sanctions taken by a small developing country against U.S. will hardly make a difference but if positions were reversed the developing country’s economy would be affected. (Shashikant 2005). C Special chapters and targeting of key sectors, i.e. finance and telecommunications In US FTAs with developing countries, there are usually special chapters on financial services and telecommunications, two of the most important and sensitive service subsectors. The FTAs with Singapore and Chile, for example, have these special chapters. The financial services chapter in the US-Singapore FTA applies to investors and investments as well as cross-border trade. Besides the usual principles of national treatment and MFN, the market access clause states that measures by a Party shall not impose limitations on the number of financial institutions, the total value of financial service transactions, the total number of financial service operations and the total number of natural persons employed; nor should the parties restrict or require specific types of legal entity or joint venture. Each Party shall also permit a financial institution of the other Party to supply any new financial service that is permitted to its own institution. There are also liberalization clauses for cross-border trade and senior management and boards of directors. There are also annexes of “non-conforming measures” similar to the chapter on services in general, as well as general exceptions. There are generally similar clauses on financial services in the US-Chile agreement. In the chapter on telecommunications in the US-Singapore FTA, there are provisions to ensure that enterprises of the other Party have access to and use of any public telecommunications transport networks and services offered in the country. There are other provisions with obligations on parties to ensure that suppliers of telecom services provide interconnection with facilities of suppliers of public telecommunications services of the other Party, and additional obligations regarding treatment by major suppliers, competitive safeguards, unbundling of network elements, co-location, resale, interconnection, pricing of leased circuit services etc. 21 There are also provisions relating to independent regulation and privatization, universal service, licensing process, allocation and use of scarce resources, etc. To meet the requirements and obligations desired by the US in the financial services and telecommunications chapters, a typical developing country partner would have to very significantly re-orientate its policies on these two key sectors, with also significant consequences. D. Does the degree of liberalization matter for development? Developed countries advocate for developing countries the fastest and broadest liberalization in services. Institutions such as the World Bank also encourage or pressurize developing countries to liberalise services so that they can become more efficient. However it is wiser for developing countries to take a cautious approach towards services liberalization. There are several reasons why it is important for a developing country to maintain or expand beyond a certain degree of local participation (including ownership and control) over services. During the colonial period, the foreign firms were able to control a large and overwhelming share of the services sectors in many countries, including the financial and distribution sectors. Following independence, governments took measures to increase the share of citizens in services. There developed significant local ownership and control in banking, insurance, construction, wholesale and retail trade, transportation, professional services, etc. Governments tended to have monopolies in railways, telecommunications, water, postal services, energy and power resources. When these were privatized or partly privatized, or when private companies were allowed to compete in these areas, local companies were among those that took up local shares. The increased participation of local firms and persons usually developed with the assistance of the government, including preferential treatment to locals and restraint over the growth of foreign companies. Presently, the services sector is in many developing countries the largest sector, and it is the area where local firms have larger participation and are better able to compete, as compared with the manufacturing sector. While it is important to upgrade technology and techniques, this can often be done by the local firms including through importing modern technology. It does not necessarily require that large foreign firms take over, in order for a country to have modern and efficient services. There are natural advantages of local firms and people in activities that require presence and knowledge of local conditions and customers. Thus it is a sector in which strengthening and development of domestic economy, training and development of local entrepreneurs, restructuring of social imbalances, can and should take place. Also the service sector has many sub-sectors that are strategic in many aspects – (a) Economically strategic sectors, eg finance, distribution); (b) Essential to national economic security (energy and power, telecommunications, transport, postal, water); (c) Critical for the public interest and to meet social needs (water, education, health, etc). 22 While there are benefits to foreign investment, there are also costs, and thus a balance is required. The services sector usually produces services that are “non-tradables”. Thus, there is significant foreign exchange loss associated with foreign service providers, as there is an outflow of profits, while most of the output is for local use. For strategic and security reasons, it is also important that there be local control over several services sectors, including water, electricity, finance, telecommunications, etc. To avoid or cushion financial crises, there should also be significant local participation in banking, insurance, etc. Public services that meet basic needs, such as water, education, health and electricity, should also be carefully guarded. Primary importance should be placed on meeting the needs of the public, especially the poor. It is thus crucial that this sector is carefully regulated under national development policy. Foreign participation has a role to play, but this has to be carefully considered and given its proper place, within a planned framework, taking into account the factors above (participation of domestic firms and institutions, economic, financial, infrastructure, public needs, social development). Accelerated and excessive liberalization of key sectors, or worse an across-the-board liberalization, under legally binding rules of an FTA, would disrupt or hinder the process of establishing a national services strategy. E. Need for a comprehensive national services plan Developing countries need to have a comprehensive national services master plan, in order that there be a coherent policy framework. Based on such a plan and framework, the country can formulate positions to take in its national interests, whether in the WTO or in a possible FTA. Among the issues to resolve in such a services plan is the degree of local and of foreign participation in the various sub-sectors, and the development of each subsector. Strategic and public consideration has to be given to key sectors such as finance, telecommunications, water, health services. Many countries do not have such a comprehensive plan. At best they have a plan for subsectors, such as financial services or health services. Until such a services plan is formulated, it would not be possible for a country to properly decide on which sectors to commit to liberalise and to what extent. F. SERVICES: IMPLICATIONS OF MUFTA FOR MALAYSIA There will be limited gains to Malaysia from a services chapter in the MUFTA. If Malaysia wants to export more services to the USA because of the USFTA, there are a number of legal problems. Let’s look at the example of construction services which is one of Malaysia’s services most ready to be exported (so far we are exporting them to developing countries). 23 The first problem is that to export construction services to the USA, Malaysia usually has to send engineers, architects, surveyors etc to the USA. However it is difficult for Malaysians to get visas to enter the USA and the USTR cannot promise more visas for Malaysians because according to the American Constitution only the American Congress has that power. (The USTR tried to promise more visas to Australia in its USFTA but the US Congress got very angry and did not agree). Secondly, even if Malaysia could somehow export its construction services by emailing plans etc to the USA without visiting the USA even to look at the site, the qualifications of Malaysia’s engineers, architects etc must be recognised by the USA. These regulations that set what qualifications are acceptable are usually decided by the state governments in the USA. So it is not in the USTR’s power to be able to say she will allow Malaysian lawyers or architects to practise in the USA. More generally, Malaysia could gain if the US were to allow more generous immigration treatment regarding visas to Malaysians to work in the US. However, both the language of the FTA as well as the political situation in the US will not allow for this. On the other hand, Malaysia will face many serious problems that will entail changing the structure and policies of many of the service sub-sectors. Firstly, the US is insisting on a negative list approach (everything is liberalized unless explicitly stated in an exception list). This methodology makes Malaysia much more vulnerable to greater pressure to liberalise (see above). Malaysia may not be sufficiently aware of all the service sectors and sub-sectors, and thus may not list all the sub-sectors it wishes not to liberalise; the country may not be able to predict or plan which sectors it may wish to promote domestically in future and thus may agree to liberalise sectors which in future it may regret doing; the country will find it difficult to “back track” after committing, when circumstances require it to protect domestic firms or the economy (e.g. as happened or may happen during financial crises); and the country will not be able to predict which new services sectors may emerge in future, and thus cannot exclude these in the list. Secondly, the exceptions are such that Malaysia has to list (in an Annex I) existing “non-conforming measures” (i.e. that do not conform to total liberalization in relation to market access, national treatment and MFN), and these measures can only be amended towards greater liberalization but not stricter regulation. This imposes a “standstill”, disallowing back-tracking, and erodes policy space. Only if measures in particular sub-sectors are placed in an Annex II can there be some space between present measures and future possible measures. Thirdly, the U.S. administration is assisting its companies in their demands for opening up the Malaysian services sectors for full access to American companies. 24 Thus the FTA talks will put pressures on Malaysia to: (1) remove or substantially reduce measures that presently help local firms to maintain or strengthen their position; (2) remove regulations and policies that impose limitations or conditions on foreign firms. If the US does not get significantly what it wants, it will not want to conclude the FTA. On the other hand if it does get what it wants, then Malaysia will have to largely change its policies, with serious economic and social consequences. The “investment” or “commercial presence” part of services will not be in the services chapter but in the investment chapter of the MUFTA, at the request of the US (if its previous FTAs are followed). One reason for this is that the investment chapter contains an aggressive investor-to-state dispute mechanism (which will encourage implementation of obligations) and thus the services investment component will fall under that. An idea of the demands that the US is making on services investment can be seen from the USTR’s trade barriers report on Malaysia. This lists the regulations that Malaysia is presently having in various sub-sectors. These are the regulations that the US presumably will negotiate to eliminate or substantially relax. The following are some examples of what the USTR report 2006 says about Malaysian services. What the report says gives an idea of the concerns that the US will raise in the negotiations and their demands. Basic Telecommunications Foreign companies are entitled to acquire only up to a 30 percent equity stake in existing fixed line operations, an investment ceiling codified as part of Malaysia's WTO services offer which limits market access commitments to facilities-based providers. [The USTR report says “These restrictions constitute one of the most restrictive regimes for an economy of Malaysia’s level of development.”]. Value-added service suppliers are similarly limited to 30 percent foreign equity. The report says “Restrictions on these activities tend to benefit the dominant provider, government-controlled Telekom Malaysia, and hamper the development of a more efficient information infrastructure.” It adds that Malaysia has made marginal improvements to this regime reflected in its January 2005 revised services offer in the WTO, reflecting new domestic licensing categories, but these changes remain disappointing. The new licensing categories introduced now allow for up to 49 percent foreign equity in suppliers categorized as “application service providers,” but precisely what this category encompasses is unclear. 25 Distribution Services, including Direct Selling Malaysia’s requirements for the licensing and operation of direct selling companies include a provision that a locally incorporated direct selling company must allow for 30 percent Bumiputera equity. The Ministry also “recommends” local content targets. Local companies that seek multi-level direct selling licenses require paid-in capital of RM 1.5 million ($397,000), while companies with foreign shareholders must have paid-in capital of RM 5 million ($1.3 million). The Malaysian government also included local content requirements in new "Guidelines on Foreign Participation in the Distributive Trade Services" that came into effect in December 2004. Among other provisions, department stores, supermarkets and hypermarkets must reserve at least 30 percent of shelf space in their premises for goods and products manufactured by bumiputera owned small and medium size industries. The guidelines also require that at least 30 percent of a store’s sales consist of bumiputera products, a rule that does not take into account discretionary behavior on the part of consumers. Banking The Malaysian government limits foreign participation in financial services to encourage the development of domestic financial services providers. The government’s policies are guided by the Banking and Financial Institutions Act of 1989 (BAFA) and the ten-year Financial Sector Masterplan unveiled in 2001. The plan is focused on building competitive domestic banks, in large part through banking consolidation, and defers the introduction of new foreign competition until after 2007. Foreign institutions are allowed to hold an equity stake in investment banks of up to 49 percent currently, foreign participation in commercial banks is still restricted to an aggregate maximum stake of 30 percent. Foreign banks currently operate in Malaysia under a grandfathering provision. No new licenses are being granted to either local or foreign banks; foreign banks must operate as locally controlled subsidiaries. Foreign commercial banks are only allowed to open new branches if they also add other branches as directed by Bank Negara. In 2004, Bank Negara pressed existing foreign banks, including U.S. banks, to expand back office operations or establish significant computing operations in Malaysia. On October 14, 2004, Bank Negara completed the issuance of three Islamic banking licenses to three Middle Eastern Islamic banks. Bank Negara encourages all commercial banks operating in Malaysia to set up full-fledged Islamic banking subsidiaries in which foreigners may take a 49 percent equity stake. 26 On April 1, 2003, the government removed the restriction that foreign-controlled companies were required to obtain 50 percent of their local credit from Malaysian banks. However, sourcing of funds of more than RM 50 million ($13.2 million) from local banks still requires approval from Bank Negara. On December 28, 2005, Bank Negara announced that locally incorporated foreign banking institutions currently operating in Malaysia would be allowed to open up to four additional branches in 2006 (one branch in a market center, two in semi-urban centers, and one in a non-urban center). Insurance The insurance industry remains dominated by foreign providers, including several U.S. firms. The 2001 Financial Sector Masterplan recommends phased liberalization of the insurance industry, including increasing caps on foreign equity, fully opening the reinsurance industry to foreign competition, and lifting existing restrictions on employment of expatriate specialists. Branches of foreign insurance companies were required to incorporate locally under Malaysian law by June 30, 1998, although Malaysia’s government has granted individual extensions. Foreign shareholding exceeding 49 percent is permitted only with Malaysian government approval. As part of the 1997 WTO Financial Services Agreement, Malaysia agreed to allow existing foreign shareholders of locally incorporated insurance companies to increase their shareholding to 51 percent. New entry by foreign insurance companies is limited to equity participation in locally incorporated insurance companies, and aggregate foreign shareholding in such companies may not exceed 30 percent. However, this limit has been subject to negotiation. Securities Malaysia currently allows 49 percent foreign ownership in stock-broking companies and a 30 percent foreign stake in unit trusts. The Securities Commission’s ten-year Capital Market Masterplan, released in February 2001, proposed liberalizing foreign participation limits by 2003, at which time foreigners would be permitted to purchase a limited number of existing stock-broking licenses and to take a majority stake in unit trust management companies. Fund management companies may be 100 percent foreign-owned if they provide services only to foreigners, but they are limited to 70 percent foreign ownership if they provide services to both foreign and local investors. On March 22, 2005, the government allowed five foreign stock brokerages and a foreign fund management company to set up operations in Malaysia. More foreign fund management companies are expected to utilize four of the remaining licenses. 27 In September 2003, the Securities Commission began allowing foreign firms operating in Malaysia to seek listing on the Kuala Lumpur Stock Exchange. Futures brokerage firms may now be 100 percent foreign-owned. Audio-Visual and Broadcasting Malaysia’s government maintains broadcast content quotas on both radio and television programming. Eighty percent of television programming is required to originate from local production companies owned by ethnic Malays (an increase from the previous limit of 60 percent). However, in practice, local stations have been granted substantial latitude in programming due to a lack of local programming. Sixty percent of radio programming must be of local origin. Foreign investment in terrestrial broadcast networks is prohibited. As a condition for obtaining a license to operate, video rental establishments are required to have 30 percent local content in their inventories. Malaysia regularly censors movies and television shows deemed offensive on religious or sexual grounds. Advertising Commercials are restricted to a maximum of 20 percent foreign film content. The government recently relaxed enforcement of regulations governing the appearance of foreign actors in commercials shown in Malaysia. The Government of Malaysia has an informal and vague guideline that commercials cannot “promote a foreign lifestyle.” Legal Services Foreign lawyers may not practice Malaysian law, nor may they affiliate with local firms or use their international firm’s name. Foreign law firms may not operate in Malaysia except as minority partners with local law firms, and their stake in any partnership is limited to 30 percent. Under the Legal Profession Act of 1976, the practice of Malaysian law is normally restricted to Malaysian citizens or permanent residents who have apprenticed with a Malaysian lawyer, are competent in Bahasa Malaysia (the official language), and have a local law degree or are accredited British Barristers at Law. The Attorney General has authority to grant limited exceptions on a case-by-case basis, provided the applicant has seven years of legal experience. Malaysian law does not allow for foreign legal consultancy except on a limited basis in the Labuan International Offshore Financial Center (see “Banking” below). Malaysia limits such foreign attorneys’ scope of services to advice concerning home country and international law. Persons not licensed as lawyers are subject to criminal penalties if they directly or indirectly undertake activities relating to the Malaysian legal system, including drafting documents. 28 Architectural Services A foreign architectural firm may operate in Malaysia only as a joint-venture participant in a specific project with the approval of the Board of Architects. Malaysian architectural firms may not have foreign architectural firms as registered partners. Foreign architects may not be licensed in Malaysia but are allowed to be managers, shareholders, or employees of Malaysian firms. Only licensed architects may submit architectural plans. Engineering Services Foreign engineers may be licensed by the Board of Engineers only for specific projects, and must be sponsored by the Malaysian company carrying out the project. The license is only valid for the duration of a specific project. In general, a foreign engineer must be registered as a professional engineer in his or her home country, have a minimum of 10 years experience, and have a physical presence in Malaysia of at least 180 days in one calendar year. To obtain temporary licensing for a foreign engineer, the Malaysian company often must demonstrate to the Board that they cannot find a Malaysian engineer for the job. Foreign engineers are not allowed to operate independently of Malaysian partners, or serve as directors or shareholders of an engineering consulting company. A foreign engineering firm may establish a non-temporary commercial presence if all directors and shareholders are Malaysian. Foreign engineering companies may collaborate with a Malaysian firm, but the Malaysian company is required to submit the plans for domestic approval. Accounting and Taxation Services Foreign accounting firms may provide accounting and taxation services in Malaysia only through affiliates. All accountants who wish to provide auditing and taxation services in Malaysia must register with the Malaysian Institute of Accountants (MIA) before they may apply for a license from the Ministry of Finance. Citizenship or permanent residency is required for registration with MIA. Malaysian citizens or permanent residents who received degrees from local universities or are members of at least one of the 11 overseas professional bodies recognized by Commonwealth countries may apply for registration. The American Institute of Certified Public Accountants (AICPA) is not recognized by Commonwealth countries. 8. INVESTMENT: LIBERALISATION AND INVESTOR PROTECTION A. Singapore Issues The “Singapore issues” -- defined as investment, competition and government procurement -- are now off the WTO negotiating agenda, at least for the duration of the Doha work programme. Many developing countries, including India, Malaysia, 29 Indonesia and the Philippines, worked hard to keep them off the rubric of the multilateral trade agenda. However these topics are proposed by the US and other developed countries in bilateral FTAs. B. Background to investment issue Many developing countries opposed the introduction of an investment agreement in the WTO, as they were concerned this would prevent or reduce their policy space to determine their own investment policies, such as choice of and conditions for foreign investment, including entry requirements, equity requirements, performance requirements, regulation on funds transfer, etc. Most bilateral FTA agreements with developed countries now include investment agreements, which can incorporate the elements and “standards” preferred by the developed countries. The US-Singapore FTA allows for a broad definition of investors and investments, “high” standards for the right of establishment, national treatment, prohibition of performance standards, freedom for funds transfer, expropriation clause, as well as investor-to-state dispute settlement (i.e. the foreign investor and not only his government can take the host government to an international court for claimed violation of the agreement). In FTAs involving the US, the expropriation clause typically has a broad definition of expropriation, that may include “regulatory takings”, or loss of profit and revenue due to an application or change of government regulation or policy. Investors claiming to have suffered losses due to expropriation within this broad definition can take up cases against the host government for compensation. Many such investor-to-state cases have been taken up under NAFTA. Developing countries should be very cautious, as to whether (a) they would like to include an investment component to their FTA; (b) if yes, that such a component does not commit them to standards and elements that may be detrimental to their investment and development policies. Present national policy and legal space to determine the definition and scope of investment, right to establishment, type of foreign investment to welcome and not welcome, national treatment, transfer of funds, and on performance requirements, dispute settlement system, etc. should not be narrowed or removed by the FTAs. It should be noted that some of the policies undertaken by Malaysia during the financial crisis of 1997-2000 may not be allowed under provisions that could be proposed under an FTA. There is a strong case that binding rules relating to investment should not be part of a developed-developing country FTA. This is especially since the WTO members have decided not to start any negotiations on an investment agreement in the WTO, as developing countries are concerned about the adverse implications for development. The investment issue has been a controversial subject at the WTO. It was part of the Doha agenda agreed to in 2001, but there was a groundswell of opposition to starting negotiations on investment and other “Singapore issues” at Cancun in 2003. In July 2004, investment was dropped off the Doha negotiations agenda by the WTO General Council. 30 However the investment issue in a deeper and broader way has made a comeback in bilateral free trade agreements. At present this is the main arena where the battle is being fought, of whether to include investment or what kind of investment chapter to include within the FTA. There is a long history of developed countries attempting to persuade developing countries to agree to a binding international investment treaty. During the Uruguay Round, the developed countries included investment rules in the Agreement on TradeRelated Investment Measures (TRIMS) negotiations. However, developing countries were unable to accept this and succeeded in restricting the TRIMS agreement to only trade-related measures. The developed countries tried again in 1995-96 to have the WTO negotiate an investment agreement but the Singapore Ministerial only agreed on setting up a working group for discussion on trade and investment. They tried again through the OECD to have an investment agreement, but this failed. They then tried to have the issue as part of the Doha Round, but they failed again. The attempt is being made now through bilateral FTAs. C. Main design and strategic aim of the US The main features of an international investment agreement (and of an investment chapter in bilateral FTAs) as advocated by the major developed countries are rather well known and have remained constant in the past many years, although there may be differences in some of the details. Among these main features are the following: Obligations on the right to entry and establishment: These provide foreign investors the rights to entry and establishment in member countries without (or with minimal) conditions and regulations and to operate in the host countries without most conditions now existing. In FTAs involving the USA, the foreign investor is given “pre-establishment” rights. This means that rights are provided to potential investors even before they enter the country, implying that there would be no or minimal regulation on the entry of investments. In contrast, postestablishment rights means that the host country can decide whether or not to accept a potential investor or investment and can impose conditions on the investment if it decides to allow entry to the investor. “Non-discrimination” and national treatment principles: National treatment and MFN status would be given to foreign investors and investments. National treatment means that the foreign investor would be given rights to be treated no less favourably than local investors (the meaning is that the foreign investor can be given treatment better than or equal to but not less than the local). Measures that promote or give preferential treatment to local investors may be curbed as these are seen to be discriminating against foreign investors. Scope and definition: The original definition of investment has been very broad (eg in the proposed OECD Multilateral Agreement on Investment (MAI) it covers FDI, portfolio investments, credit, IPRs and even non-commercial organisations, and in all sectors except security and defence.). This broad definition is adopted in FTAs involving the USA. 31 Ban on Performance Requirements: The host state would be prohibited from imposing performance requirements on the foreign investor or investment (unless it is listed as an exception in the FTA). For example, regulation on limits and conditions on equity, obligations for technology transfer, measures for using local materials and for increasing exports or limiting imports would be prohibited or disciplined. Rights given for funds transfer: Obligations to allow free mobility of funds into and out of the country, thus restricting or prohibiting regulations/controls on funds transfer. Protection of Investors’ rights against expropriation: There would also be strict standards of protection for foreign investors' rights, especially in relation to "expropriation" of property. A wide definition is given to expropriation in the MAI model; it includes "creeping expropriation". In FTAs involving the US, “direct and indirect” expropriation are included. Indirect expropriation usually includes the loss of goodwill and future revenue/profits of a company or an investor, as a result of a government measure or policy. If there is such expropriation, the host state is liable to compensate the investor in full including interest at a commercially reasonable rate. The agreement is legally binding and subject to dispute settlement in designated international courts. In most FTAs involving the USA, the dispute settlement system includes enabling investors to bring cases against the host state, in the designated international courts. D. The need for space and flexibility for investment and development policies and the effects of an investment agreement Foreign investment is a complex phenomenon with many aspects. Its relationship with development is such that there can be positive as well as negative aspects. There is an important need for the role of government and government policy to regulate investments so that the positive benefits are derived, while the adverse effects are minimized or controlled. The experience of countries shows that governments have traditionally made use of a wide range of policy instruments in the formulation of investment policy and in the management of investment. It is crucial that developing countries continue to have the policy space and flexibility to exercise their right to such policies and policy instruments. Due to its particular features, foreign investment can have the tendency towards adverse effects or trends that require careful management. These include: (a) possible contribution to financial fragility due to the movements of funds into and out of the country, and to some types of financially destabilizing activities; (b) possible effects on balance of payments (especially increased imports and outflow of investment income, which has to be balanced by export earnings and new capital inflows; if the balance is not attained naturally, it may have to be attained or attempted through regulation); 32 (c) possible effects on the competitiveness and viability of local enterprises; (d) possible effects on balance between local and foreign ownership and participation in the economy. (e) possible effect on the balance of ownership and participation among local communities in the society. On the other hand foreign investment can make positive contributions, such as: (a) use of modern technology and technological spillovers to local firms. (b) global marketing network (c) contribution to capital funds and export earnings (d) increased employment In order that these potential benefits be realized, and that a good balance is attained between the negative and positive effects, so there be a overall net positive effect, there is a crucial role for governments in a sophisticated set of investment and development policies. An investment agreement or chapter of the type envisaged by the proponents would make it much more difficult to achieve a positive balance as it would severely constrain the space and flexibility for investment and development policies. Such an agreement or chapter is ultimately designed to maximise foreign investors' rights whilst minimising the authority, rights and policy space of governments and developing countries. This has serious consequences in terms of policy making in economic, social and political spheres, affecting the ability to plan in relation to local participation and ownership, balancing of equity shares between foreign and locals and between local communities, the ability to build capacity of local firms and entrepreneurs, etc. It would also weaken the position of government vis-à-vis foreign investors (including portfolio investors) in such areas as choice of investments and investors, transfer of funds, performance requirements aimed at development objectives such as technology transfer, protecting the balance of payments, and the formulation of social and environmental regulations. It is argued by proponents that an investment agreement will attract more FDI to developing countries. There is no evidence of this. FDI flows to countries that are already quite developed, or there are resources and infrastructure, or where there is a sizable market. A move towards a binding investment agreement is thus dangerous as it would threaten options for development, social policies and nation building strategies. It is thus proposed that the strategy to be adopted should be to prevent the investment issue from entering the mode of "negotiations." In the working group, cogent points should be put forward on why an agreement on investment rules is not suitable nor beneficial for the WTO or for FTAs. In the discussion on "clarification" and on "modality", points should be made towards this end. 33 E. Conclusions There should not be an investment chapter of the kind envisaged by the developed country proponents in a FTA. There should not be a legally binding agreement for securing establishment rights and national treatment for foreign investment and investors, and especially it should not allow for investor-state dispute settlement (i.e. investors to be able to take cases against the host states). The principles that originate for the purposes of trade relations (eg in GATT and WTO) including national treatment and MFN were meant to apply to trade in goods and are inappropriate when applied to investment. Instead, their application to investment would be damaging to the development interests of developing countries. Traditionally developing countries have had the freedom and right to regulate the entry and conditions of establishment and operation of foreign investments; restricting their rights and policy space would have adverse repercussions. A more appropriate framework must be a balanced one, with the main aim of regulating corporations (instead of regulating governments); it could be one that is not legally binding. An attempt to establish such a balanced framework was made at the UN in the 1980s, when a code of conduct on transnational corporations was negotiated. However the negotiations failed to produce an outcome. F. INVESTMENT: IMPLICATIONS OF MUFTA FOR MALAYSIA The US administration has listed its dissatisfaction with the present Malaysian regulations on foreign investment, which it calls “investment barriers.” It is asking for these policies to be changed through the FTA. The USTR’s Foreign Trade Barriers report, in a comment on “investment barriers” has this to say about Malaysia: Malaysia encourages foreign direct investment in export-oriented manufacturing and hightechnology industries, but retains considerable discretionary authority over individual investments, and restricts foreign investment in other sectors. Especially in the case of investments focused toward the domestic market, it has used this authority to restrict foreign equity (normally to 30 percent) and to require foreign firms to enter into joint ventures with local partners. As noted above, foreign investment in the financial services industry is restricted;foreign investment in terrestrial broadcasting is prohibited. To alleviate the effects of the regional economic crisis, in 1998, Malaysia temporarily relaxed foreign-ownership and export requirements in the manufacturing sector for those companies that did not directly compete with local producers. In June 2003, the government extended indefinitely the policy, permitting 100 percent foreign ownership in new investment, if it was for the expansion of existing investments in 34 manufacturing concerns. In September 2004, the government announced that venture capital firms could be 100 percent foreign-owned. The US will try through the FTA negotiations to get Malaysia to withdraw or reduce its investment policies that regulate many sectors, and to enable US firms to establish themselves freely in Malaysia, to be given national treatment and not subject to control. The implications include: 1. Granting pre-establishment rights to US investors and companies. Even before entering the country, the potential investor has the right to invest. The role of the foreign investment committee to screen and approve/not approve or to impose conditions on intending foreign investors would be much reduced. 2. American investors will have “national treatment”, i.e. the right to be treated as well or better than local investors. This prevents government from having positive policies that favour local investors and firms. 3. Many “performance requirements” (conditions for allowing a foreign firm to operate) will have to be banned in relation to US investors. These were imposed so that the US firms would be obliged to contribute to the Malaysian economy, by for example establishing joint ventures with locals, transferring technology and using local materials. 4. US investors would have the right to own 100% of their own companies. Limits on the extent of ownership by American investors can only be placed if these limitations are listed down in an exclusion list within the FTA. 5. There cannot be restrictions placed on the inflow and outflow of funds of American investors. Several of the measures adopted by Malaysia during the financial crisis of 1997-1999 (such as a moratorium on the outflow of ringgitdenominated assets held by foreigners in Malaysia) would not be allowed under the FTA rules. Investors who feel their rights have been violated and have suffered a loss can sue the government for compensation for expropriation. 6. Malaysia would be bound by rules prohibiting "expropriation" of the American investors’ property. A wide definition is given to expropriation in the FTA, which will include “direct and indirect” expropriation are included. Indirect expropriation usually includes the loss of goodwill and future revenue/profits of a company or an investor, as a result of a government measure or policy. If there is such expropriation, the host state is liable to compensate the investor in full including interest at a “commercially reasonable” rate. 7. Malaysia would be subject to investment “dispute settlement” under the FTA in which either the US government or US investors can sue the Malaysian government for compensation for losses claimed by the investors for expropriation. The cases are to be brought before an international court (one choice is the International Centre for Settlement of Investment Disputes). The cases can involve claims worth millions or hundreds of millions or even more 35 than a billion dollars, as the experience of other countries having an FTA with the US (eg Canada, Mexico) has shown. Through the FTA, Malaysia would thus be agreeing to subject itself to legal suits by American investors claiming that they have suffered or will suffer losses and potential losses resulting from government measures and policies. 8. The scope of the investment chapter will be very broad. Following the Singapore-US FTA, investment means every asset owned or controlled, directly or indirectly, by an investor, that has the characteristics of an investment. Forms that an investment may take include: (a) an enterprise; (b) shares, stock, and other forms of equity participation in an enterprise; (c) bonds, debentures, other debt instruments, and loans; (d) futures, options, and other derivatives; (e) turnkey, construction, management, production, concession, revenue-sharing, and other similar contracts; (f) intellectual property rights; (g) licenses, authorizations, permits, and similar rights conferred pursuant to applicable domestic law; and (h) other tangible or intangible, movable or immovable property, and related property rights, such as leases, mortgages, liens, and pledges. This means that all these forms of investments (and the investors) will be subject to the rules on pre-establishment rights, market access and national treatment, as well as funds transfer, expropriation and investor-to-state dispute. 9. The investment chapter also takes a “negative list approach”, in that every sector is taken to be totally liberalized unless exceptions are specifically listed. There are many disadvantages with this “negative list approach”: (a) Malaysia is much more vulnerable to greater pressure to liberalise; (b) Malaysia may not be sufficiently aware of all the sectors and sub-sectors for which protection of local industry or firms are required and thus may not list all the sub-sectors it wishes not to liberalise. (c) The country may not be able to predict or plan which sectors it may wish to promote domestically in future and thus may agree to liberalise sectors which in future it may regret doing. (d) The country will find it difficult to “back track” after committing, when circumstances require it to protect domestic firms or the economy (e.g. as happened or may happen during financial crises). (e) The country will not be able to predict which new sectors may emerge in future, and thus cannot exclude these in the list. 10. As in the services chapter, the exceptions are to be explicitly listed in three categories. Annex I will contain (a) a list of existing “non-conforming measures” (i.e. that do not conform to national treatment, MFN, performance requirements and senior management/board of directors) and (b) an amendment to any nonconforming measure as long as it does not decrease the conformity of the measure. Thus Annex I installs a “standstill” and prevents any existing measure from becoming stricter. It is important to note that the exceptions cover only national treatment, MFN, performance requirements and senior management/board but there is no exception for other provisions, including minimum standard of treatment, transfer of funds and expropriation, nor the investor-to-state dispute system. 11. Exceptions can also be entered into an Annex II, in which Malaysia can list sectors and activities it wants to exempt for measures it wants to adopt or maintain. However, again, these measures are only in relation to national 36 treatment, MFN, performance requirements and management/board. measures such as transfer of funds and expropriation are not exempted. Other 12. As part of the New Economic Policy and its subsequent variations, the Malaysian government has been actively making use of investment and equity measures as its main instrument for socio-economic strategy in boosting the participation of local people, with special reference to Bumiputra. The original NEP target was to reduce the foreign share of corporate equity from about 70% while increasing the Bumiputra share from 1% to 30%, without affecting the share of non-Bumiputra. Various mechanisms, institutions and policy measures were introduced and maintained towards this end, including institutions such as PNB, ASN, Khazanah and measures such as limitations on foreign equity ownership in various sectors, and specific measures for allocating equity share and shares to Bumiputra. The FTA with the US will considerably erode this approach, as the main strategic principle under the FTA is that the countries should as a rule “conform” to the principles of the right of entry and establishment of American iuvestments, that their investors be allowed 100% ownership of their own companies and that equity requirements or the joint-venture structure should not be imposed, nor should there be any performance requirements, and these investors are to be granted “national treatment.” Any measure that goes against these are considered “non-conforming” and has to be listed as an exception. These exceptions are also subject to negotiations. The FTA would thus be a major instrument to substantially erode the policy, and may well be the start of its overall elimination, as (a) there will be pressures from the US for progressively decreasing the so-called “non conforming measures” and (b) other countries other than the US will also demand similar treatment be given to them, including through upgrading their FTAs with Malaysian (Japan) or wanting it included in the FTAs they negotiate with Malaysia (Australia, New Zealand, European Union, etc). 13. The sectors in which American companies want Malaysia to eliminate or erode its present policies are mainly in services. Their demands in specific subsectors are in the USTR report on Trade Barriers, summarized in the section of this paper on services. The measures include restrictions and limitations on foreign ownership, and requirements that a certain amount of local (Bumiputra) products be displayed on shelves of hypermarkets. These measures are likely to be negotiated by the US for elimination or phasing out. 14. The provision on free and unrestricted transfer of funds (inflows and outflows) for American investors has the potential to increase financial instability, and to prevent measures that can be taken to lessen financial instability or crises. It would be more difficult to prevent the entry of speculative funds and instruments (given the provisions on pre-establishment rights and free funds transfer) and to take measures that restrict the outflow of funds, as during an emergency. In the negotiations for the Singapore-US FTA, Singapore wanted an exception to freedome of funds transfer in the casse of short-term speculative funds during an financial emergency, but the US did not agree. The only 37 concession is that for only certain types of funds, Singapore would not be liable to pay compensation if the restriction on outflow is less than a year and does not “substantially impede transfers”. (This was explained by a Singapore negotiator as meaning that a levy or tax can be imposed on funds leaving the country, but not the prohibition of outflow). 15. The expropriation and dispute-settlement provisions open the government to legal suits by both the US and its investors, including for “indirect” expropriation, which can include measures taken by government on economic, social, health or environmental grounds. The disadvantages include: (a) Government not being able to undertake many policies which may be construed to be expropriation; (b) Even if the government believes the measure is not “expropriation”, there can be a “chill effect” of not wanting to be sued, and thus a reluctance to introduce policies that are unpopular with the investors; (c) Government opens itself to being liable for legal suits for compensation directly from US investors and in international courts, with potential claims of many millions or billions of dollars. 16. Intellectual property will also be listed as an “investment”. Thus, IPR holders could make use of the investment chapter to file claims for compensation on the grounds that their property is being “expropriated”. 9. TELECOMMUNICATIONS The FTA with the US will have to contain a special chapter on Telecommunications. This chapter combines the issues of services and investment, and it also has important aspects of “competition policy”. In fact it is a “model” of how the US would like to make use of all three issues (services, investment, competition) in each sector. Regarding services and investment, the US demand is for liberalization and national treatment for its firms to set up and operate in the local market. Regarding “competition”, there are key elements regarding anti-competitive business practices, designated monopolies and government-linked companies (where the aim is to set rules that oblige the local companies/institutions to allow American companies to make use of their facilities; and to prevent government authorities to give assistance to local telecom GLCs or to be influenced by them. In the chapter on telecommunications in the US-Singapore FTA, there are provisions to ensure that enterprises of the other Party have access to and use of any public telecommunications transport networks and services offered in the country. There are other provisions with obligations on parties to ensure that suppliers of telecom services provide interconnection with facilities of suppliers of public telecommunications services of the other Party, and additional obligations regarding treatment by major suppliers, competitive safeguards, unbundling of network elements, co-location, resale, interconnection, pricing of leased circuit services etc. 38 There are also provisions relating to independent regulation and privatization, universal service, licensing process, allocation and use of scarce resources, etc. To meet the requirements and obligations desired by the US in the financial services and telecommunications chapters, Malaysia would have to very significantly re-orientate its policies on these two key sectors, with also significant consequences. Below are some key elements of the Telecommunications chapter in the Singapore-US FTA, which gives a picture of what is in store for the Malaysia-US FTA. SCOPE AND COVERAGE: Covered are measures affecting trade in telecommunications services. It does not apply to measures relating to cable or broadcast distribution of radio or television programming. ACCESS TO AND USE OF PUBLIC TELECOMMUNICATIONS TRANSPORT NETWORKS AND SERVICES: Each Party shall ensure that enterprises of the other Party have access to and use of any public telecommunications transport network and service, including leased circuits, offered in its territory or across its borders on reasonable, non-discriminatory (including with respect to timeliness), and transparent terms and conditions. Each Party shall ensure that such enterprises are permitted to: (a) purchase or lease, and attach terminal or other equipment that interfaces with the public telecommunications network; (b) provide services to individual or multiple end-users over any leased or owned circuit(s); (c) connect leased or owned circuits with public telecommunications transport networks and services in the territory, or across the borders, of that Party, or with circuits leased or owned by another enterprise; (d) perform switching, signaling, processing, and conversion functions; and (e) use operating protocols of their choice. Each Party shall ensure that enterprises of the other Party may use public telecommunications transport networks and services for the movement of information in its territory or across its borders and for access to information contained in data bases or otherwise stored in machine-readable form in the territory of either Party. INTERCONNECTION WITH SUPPLIERS OF PUBLIC TELECOMMUNICATIONS SERVICES: Each Party shall ensure that suppliers of public telecommunications services in its territory provide, directly or indirectly, interconnection with the facilities and equipment of suppliers of public telecommunications services of the other Party. CONDUCT OF MAJOR SUPPLIERS Treatment by Major Suppliers 1. Each Party shall ensure that any major supplier in its territory accords suppliers of public telecommunications services of the other Party treatment no less favorable than such major supplier accords to itself, its subsidiaries, its affiliates, or any nonaffiliated service supplier regarding: 39 (a) the availability, provisioning, rates, or quality of like public telecommunications services; and (b) the availability of technical interfaces necessary for interconnection. A Party shall assess such treatment on the basis of whether such suppliers of public telecommunications services, subsidiaries, affiliates, and non-affiliated service suppliers are in like circumstances. Competitive Safeguards 2. (a) Each Party shall maintain appropriate measures for the purpose of preventing suppliers of public telecommunications services who, alone or together, are a major supplier in its territory from engaging in or continuing anti-competitive practices. (b) For purposes of subparagraph (a), anti-competitive practices include: (i) engaging in anti-competitive cross-subsidization; (ii) using information obtained from competitors with anti-competitive results; and (iii) not making available, on a timely basis, to suppliers of public telecommunications services, technical information about essential facilities and commercially relevant information that is necessary for them to provide public telecommunications services. Unbundling of Network Elements 3. (a) Recognizing that both Parties currently provide for access to unbundled network elements, each Party shall provide its telecommunications regulatory body the authority to require that major suppliers in its territory provide suppliers of public telecommunications services of the other Party access to network elements on an unbundled basis at terms, conditions, and cost-oriented rates, that are reasonable, nondiscriminatory (including with respect to timeliness), and transparent for the supply of public telecommunications services. (b) Which network elements will be required to be made available in the territory of a Party, and which suppliers may obtain such elements, shall be determined in accordance with national law and regulation. (c) In determining the network elements to be made available, a Party’s telecommunications regulatory body shall consider, at a minimum, in accordance with national law and regulation: (i) whether access to such network elements as are proprietary in nature are necessary; and whether the failure to provide access to such network elements would impair the ability of suppliers of public telecommunications services of the other Party to provide the services it seeks to offer; or (ii) whether the network elements can be replicated or obtained from other sources at reasonable rates, such that the unavailability of these network elements from the major supplier will not impair the ability of other suppliers of public telecommunications services to provide a competing service; or (iii) whether the network elements are technically or operationally required for the provision of a competing service; or (iv) other factors as established in national law; as that body construes these factors. 40 Co-Location 4. (a) Each Party shall ensure that major suppliers in its territory provide to suppliers of public telecommunications services of the other Party physical co-location, at premises owned or controlled by the major supplier, of equipment necessary for interconnection or access to unbundled network elements on terms and conditions, and at cost-oriented rates, that are reasonable, non-discriminatory (including with respect to timeliness), and transparent. (b) Where physical co-location is not practical for technical reasons or because of space limitations, each Party shall ensure that major suppliers in its territory provide or facilitate virtual co-location on terms and conditions, and at costoriented rates, that are reasonable, non-discriminatory (including with respect to timeliness), and transparent. (c) Each Party may determine, in accordance with national law and regulation, which premises in its territory shall be subject to subparagraphs (a) and (b) Resale 5. Each Party shall ensure that major suppliers in its territory: (a) offer for resale, at reasonable rates, to suppliers of public telecommunications services of the other Party, public telecommunications services that such major supplier provides at retail to end-users; and (b) do not impose unreasonable or discriminatory conditions or limitations on the resale of such public telecommunications services. Poles, Ducts, and Conduits 6. (a) Each Party shall ensure that major suppliers in its territory provide access to poles, ducts, and conduits, owned or controlled by such major suppliers to suppliers of public telecommunications services of the other Party, under terms, conditions, and cost-oriented rates, that are reasonable, non-discriminatory (including with respect to timeliness), and transparent. (b) Nothing shall prevent a Party from determining, under its domestic law and regulation, which particular structures owned or controlled by the major suppliers in its territory, are required to be made available in accordance with paragraph (a) provided that this is based on a determination that such structures cannot feasibly be economically or technically substituted in order to provide a competing service. Number Portability 7. Each Party shall ensure that major suppliers in its territory provide number portability to the extent technically feasible, on a timely basis and on reasonable terms and conditions. Interconnection 8. (a) General Terms and Conditions Each Party shall ensure that any major supplier in its territory provides interconnection for the facilities and equipment of suppliers of public telecommunications services of the other Party: (i) at any technically feasible point in the major supplier’s network; (ii) under non-discriminatory terms, conditions (including technical standards and specifications), and rates; 41 (iii) of a quality no less favorable than that provided by such major supplier for its own like services or for like services of non-affiliated suppliers of public telecommunications services or for its subsidiaries or other affiliates; (iv) in a timely fashion, on terms, conditions, (including technical standards and specifications), and cost-oriented rates, that are transparent, reasonable, having regard to economic feasibility, and sufficiently unbundled so that the supplier need not pay for network components or facilities that it does not require for the service to be provided; and (v) upon request, at points in addition to the network termination points offered to the majority of suppliers of public telecommunications services, subject to charges that reflect the cost of construction of necessary additional facilities. (b) Options for Interconnecting with Major Suppliers Each Party shall ensure that suppliers of public telecommunications services of the other Party may interconnect their facilities and equipment with those of major suppliers in its territory pursuant to at least one of the following options: (i) a reference interconnection offer or another standard interconnection offer containing the rates, terms, and conditions that the major supplier offers generally to suppliers of public telecommunications services; or (ii) the terms and conditions of an existing interconnection agreement or through negotiation of a new interconnection agreement. (c) Public Availability of Interconnection Offers Each Party shall require each major supplier in its territory to make publicly available either a reference interconnection offer or another standard interconnection offer containing the rates, terms, and conditions that the major supplier offers generally to suppliers of public telecommunications services. (d) Public Availability of the Procedures for Interconnection Negotiations Each Party shall make publicly available the applicable procedures for interconnection negotiations with major suppliers in its territory. (e) Public Availability of Interconnection Agreements Concluded with Major Suppliers (i) Each Party shall require major suppliers in its territory to file all interconnection agreements to which they are party with its telecommunications regulatory body. (ii) Each Party shall make available for inspection to suppliers of public telecommunications services which are seeking interconnection, interconnection agreements in force between a major supplier in its territory and any other supplier of public telecommunications services in such territory, including interconnection agreements concluded between a major supplier and its affiliates and subsidiaries. (f) Resolution of Interconnection Disputes Each Party shall ensure that suppliers of public telecommunications services of the other Party, that have requested interconnection with a major supplier in the Party’s territory have recourse to a telecommunications regulatory body to resolve disputes regarding the terms, conditions, and rates for interconnection within a reasonable and publicly available period of time. 42 Provisioning and Pricing of Leased Circuits Services 9. (a) Each Party shall ensure that major suppliers of leased circuits services in its territory provide enterprises of the other Party leased circuits services that are public telecommunications services, on terms and conditions under pricing structures, and at rates that are reasonable, non-discriminatory (including with respect to timeliness), and transparent. (b) Each Party may determine whether rates for leased circuits services in its territory are reasonable by taking into account the rates of like leased circuits services in comparable markets in other countries. SUBMARINE CABLE LANDING STATIONS 1. Where under national law and regulation, a Party has authorized a supplier of public telecommunications services in its territory to operate a submarine cable system (including the landing facilities and services) as a public telecommunications service, that Party shall ensure that such supplier provides that public telecommunications service to suppliers of public telecommunications services of the other Party on reasonable terms, conditions, and rates that are no less favorable than such supplier offers to any other supplier of public telecommunications services in like circumstances. 2. Where submarine cable landing facilities and services cannot be economically or technically substituted, and a major supplier of public international telecommunication services that controls such cable landing facilities and services has the ability to materially affect the price and supply for those facilities and services for the provision of public telecommunications services in a Party’s territory, the Party shall ensure that such major supplier: (a) permits suppliers of public telecommunications services of the other Party to: (i) use the major supplier’s cross-connect links in the submarine cable landing station to connect their equipment to backhaul links and submarine cable capacity of any supplier of telecommunications; and (ii) co-locate their transmission and routing equipment used for accessing submarine cable capacity and backhaul links at the submarine cable landing station at terms, conditions, and cost-oriented rates, that are reasonable and non-discriminatory; and (b) provides suppliers of telecommunications of the other Party submarine cable capacity, backhaul links, and cross-connect links in the submarine cable landing station at terms, conditions, and rates that are reasonable and non-discriminatory. INDEPENDENT REGULATION AND PRIVATIZATION 1. Each Party shall ensure that its telecommunications regulatory body is separate from, and not accountable to, any supplier of public telecommunications services. To this end, each Party shall ensure that its telecommunications regulatory body does not hold any financial interest or maintain an operating role in such a supplier. 2. Each Party shall ensure that the decisions of, and procedures used by its telecommunications regulatory body are impartial with respect to all interested persons. To this end, each Party shall ensure that any financial interest that it holds in 43 a supplier of public telecommunications services does not influence the decisions of and procedures of its telecommunications regulatory body. 3. Where a Party has an ownership interest in a supplier of public telecommunications services, it shall notify the other Party of any intention to eliminate such interest as soon as feasible. UNIVERSAL SERVICE Each Party shall administer any universal service obligation that it maintains in a transparent, nondiscriminatory, and competitively neutral manner and shall ensure that its universal service obligation is not more burdensome than necessary for the kind of universal service that it has defined. LICENSING PROCESS 1. When a Party requires a supplier of public telecommunications services to have a license, the Party shall make publicly available: (a) all the licensing criteria and procedures it applies; (b) the period of time normally required to reach a decision concerning an application for a license; and (c) the terms and conditions of all licenses it has issued. 2. Each Party shall ensure that an applicant receives, upon request, the reasons for the denial of a license. ALLOCATION AND USE OF SCARCE RESOURCES 1. Each Party shall administer its procedures for the allocation and use of scarce resources, including frequencies, numbers, and rights of way, in an objective, timely, transparent, and nondiscriminatory fashion. 2. Each Party shall make publicly available the current state of allocated frequency bands but shall not be required to provide detailed identification of frequencies assigned or allocated by each government for specific government uses. ENFORCEMENT Each Party shall ensure that its telecommunications regulatory body maintains appropriate procedures and authority to enforce domestic measures relating to the obligations under Articles 9.2 to 9.5 on telecom transport networks; obligations relating to telecom suppliers; additional obligations of major suppliers; submarine cable landing stations. Such procedures and authority shall include the ability to impose effective sanctions, which may include financial penalties, injunctive relief (on an interim or final basis), or modification, suspension, and revocation of licenses. RESOLUTION OF DOMESTIC TELECOMMUNICATIONS DISPUTES Recourse to Telecommunications Regulatory Bodies 1. Each Party shall ensure that enterprises of the other Party have recourse (within a reasonable period of time) to a telecommunications regulatory body or other relevant body to resolve disputes arising under domestic measures addressing a matter set out in Articles 9.2 through 9.5. Reconsideration 2. Each Party shall ensure that any enterprise aggrieved or whose interests are adversely affected by a determination or decision of the telecommunications 44 regulatory body may petition that body for reconsideration of that determination or decision. Neither Party may permit such a petition to constitute grounds for noncompliance with such determination or decision of the telecommunications regulatory body unless an appropriate authority stays such determination or decision. Judicial Review 3. Each Party shall ensure that any enterprise aggrieved by a determination or decision of the telecommunications regulatory body may obtain judicial review of such determination or decision by an impartial and independent judicial authority. TRANSPARENCY Each Party shall ensure that: 1. rulemakings, including the basis for such rulemakings, of its telecommunications regulatory body and end-user tariffs filed with its telecommunications regulatory body are promptly published or otherwise made available to all interested persons; 2. interested persons are provided with adequate advance public notice of and the opportunity to comment on any rulemaking proposed by the telecommunications regulatory body; 3. its measures relating to public telecommunications services are made publicly available, including: (a) tariffs and other terms and conditions of service; (b) specifications of technical interfaces; (c) conditions applying to attachment of terminal or other equipment to the public telecommunications transport network; and (d) notification, permit, registration, or licensing requirements, if any; and 4. information on bodies responsible for preparing, amending, and adopting standards related measures is made publicly available. FLEXIBILITY IN THE CHOICE OF TECHNOLOGIES A Party shall endeavor not to prevent suppliers of public telecommunications services from having the flexibility to choose the technologies that they use to supply their services, including commercial mobile services, subject to the ability of each Party to take measures to ensure that end-users of different networks are able to communicate with each other. FORBEARANCE AND MINIMAL REGULATORY ENVIRONMENT The Parties recognize the importance of relying on market forces to achieve wide choice and efficient supply of telecommunications services. To this end, each Party may forbear from applying regulation to a telecommunications service that such Party classifies, under its laws and regulations, as a public telecommunications service upon a determination by its telecommunications regulatory body that: (a) enforcement of such regulation is not necessary to prevent unreasonable or discriminatory practices; (b) enforcement of such regulation is not necessary for the protection of consumers; and (c) forbearance is consistent with the public interest, including promoting and enhancing competition among suppliers of public telecommunications services. In a side letter from Singapore’s Trade Minister to the USTR, the Singapore government states it is committed to privitisation of Sing Tel and ST Telemedia aimed at reducing its stakes in these companies to zero. Singapore will establish a plan to divest its majority share in these two companies; it understands the 45 US’s interest in seeing such divestment completed as soon as possible. The government exercises no control over the commercial policy of the companies, and does not have veto rights. The companies do not get government subsidies and are fully subject to independent regulatory oversight. 10. FINANCIAL SERVICES In US FTAs with developing countries, there is usually a special chapter on financial services. The FTA with Malaysia will not be an exception. The financial services chapter in the US-Singapore FTA applies to investors and investments as well as cross-border trade. Besides the usual principles of national treatment and MFN, the market access clause states that measures by a Party shall not impose limitations on the number of financial institutions, the total value of financial service transactions, the total number of financial service operations and the total number of natural persons employed; nor should the parties restrict or require specific types of legal entity or joint venture. Each Party shall also permit a financial institution of the other Party to supply any new financial service that is permitted to its own institution. There are also liberalization clauses for cross-border trade and senior management and boards of directors. There are also annexes of “non-conforming measures” similar to the chapter on services in general, as well as general exceptions. There are generally similar clauses on financial services in the US-Chile agreement. To meet the requirements and obligations desired by the US in the financial services, Malaysia would have to very significantly re-orientate its policies on these two key sectors, with also significant consequences. Below are some key elements of the Financial Services chapter in the SingaporeUS FTA, which gives a picture of what is being demanded by the US for the Malaysia-US FTA. SCOPE AND COVERAGE: Measures relating to: (a) financial institutions of the other Party; (b) investors of the other Party, and investments of such investors, in financial institutions in the Party’s territory; and (c) cross-border trade in financial services. Several provisions of the services and investment chapters also apply to this chapter, including those on Expropriation, Transfers of funds, Investor-State Dispute Settlement (for claims that a Party has breached Articles on Expropriation, Transfers, Denial of Benefits, and Special Formalities and Information Requirements). NATIONAL TREATMENT 1. Each Party shall accord to investors of the other Party treatment no less favorable than that it accords to its own investors, in like circumstances, with respect to the 46 establishment, acquisition, expansion, management, conduct, operation, and sale or other disposition of financial institutions and investments in financial institutions in its territory. 2. Each Party shall accord to financial institutions of the other Party and to investments of investors of the other Party in financial institutions treatment no less favorable than that it accords to its own financial institutions, and to investments of its own investors in financial institutions, in like circumstances, with respect to the establishment, acquisition, expansion, management, conduct, operation, and sale or other disposition of financial institutions and investments. 3. For purposes of the national treatment obligations, a Party shall accord to crossborder financial service suppliers of the other Party treatment no less favorable than that it accords to its own financial service suppliers, in like circumstances, with respect to the supply of the relevant service. MOST-FAVORED-NATION TREATMENT 1. Each Party shall accord to investors of the other Party, financial institutions of the other Party, investments of investors in financial institutions, and cross-border financial service suppliers of the other Party treatment no less favorable than that it accords to the investors, financial institutions, investments of investors in financial institutions and cross-border financial service suppliers of a non-Party, in like circumstances. 2. A Party may recognize prudential measures of the other Party or of a non-Party in the application of measures covered by this Chapter. 3. A Party according recognition of prudential measures under paragraph 2 shall provide adequate opportunity to the other Party to demonstrate that circumstances exist in which there are or would be equivalent regulation, oversight, implementation of regulation, and, if appropriate, procedures concerning the sharing of information between the Parties. MARKET ACCESS FOR FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS A Party shall not adopt or maintain, with respect to financial institutions of the other Party measures that: (a) impose limitations on (i) the number of financial institutions whether in the form of numerical quotas, monopolies, exclusive service suppliers or the requirements of an economic needs test; (ii) the total value of financial service transactions or assets in the form of numerical quotas or the requirement of an economic needs test; (iii) the total number of financial service operations or the total quantity of financial services output expressed in terms of designated numerical units in the form of quotas or the requirement of an economic needs test; or (iv) the total number of natural persons that may be employed in a particular financial service sector or that a financial institution may employ and who are necessary for, and directly related to, the supply of a specific financial service in the form of a numerical quota or the requirement of an economic needs test; or (b) restrict or require specific types of legal entity or joint venture through which a financial institution may supply a service. 47 CROSS-BORDER TRADE IN FINANCIAL SERVICES 1. Each Party shall permit, under terms and conditions that accord national treatment, cross-border financial service suppliers of the other Party to supply the services it has specified in an Annex. 2. Each Party shall permit persons located in its territory, and its nationals wherever located, to purchase financial services from cross-border financial service suppliers of the other Party located in the territory of the other Party. This obligation does not require a Party to permit such suppliers to do business or solicit in its territory. NEW FINANCIAL SERVICES Each Party shall permit a financial institution of the other Party to supply any new financial service that the first Party would permit its own financial institutions, in like circumstances, to supply without additional legislative action by the first Party. A Party may determine the institutional and juridical form through which the new financial service may be supplied and may require authorization for the supply of the service. Where a Party requires such authorization of the new financial service, a decision shall be made within a reasonable time and the authorization may only be refused for prudential reasons. SENIOR MANAGEMENT AND BOARDS OF DIRECTORS 1. A Party may not require financial institutions of the other Party to engage individuals of any particular nationality as senior managerial or other essential personnel. 2. A Party may not require that more than a simple majority of the board of directors of a financial institution of the other Party be composed of nationals of the Party, persons residing in the territory of the Party, or a combination thereof. NON-CONFORMING MEASURES Articles relating to national treatment, MFN treatment, market access, cross-border trade, senior management/boards) that do not apply to: (a) any existing non-conforming measure that is maintained by a Party listed in the relevant Annex. (b) the continuation or prompt renewal of any non-conforming measure referred to in subparagraph (a); (c) an amendment to any non-conforming measure referred to in subparagraph (a) to the extent that the amendment does not decrease the conformity of the measure, as it existed immediately before the amendment. EXCEPTIONS A Party shall not be prevented from adopting or maintaining measures for prudential reasons. Nothing in this Chapter applies to nondiscriminatory measures of general application taken by any public entity in pursuit of monetary and related credit policies or exchange rate policies. (However this paragraph shall not affect a Party’s obligations 48 on Transfers and Payments (in the services chapter) and on Transfers and Performance Requirements (in the investment chapter). A Party may prevent or limit transfers by a financial institution to an affiliate through measures relating to maintenance of the safety, soundness, integrity or financial responsibility of financial institutions. TRANSPARENCY There are many clauses on transparency including: Each Party shall publish in advance any regulations it proposes to adopt; and provide the other Party a reasonable opportunity to comment on such proposed regulations; A regulatory authority shall make an administrative decision on a completed application of an investor in a financial institution, a financial institution or a crossborder financial service supplier of the other Party relating to the supply of a financial service within 120 days, and shall promptly notify the applicant of the decision.; At the time it adopts final regulations, a Party should, to the extent practicable, address in writing substantive comments received from interested persons with respect to the proposed regulations. OTHER Other provisions: (1) establish a FINANCIAL SERVICES COMMITTEE to supervise the implementation of this Chapter and its further elaboration; and consider issues referred to it by a Party; (2) deal with provisions on CONSULTATIONS regarding any matter arising under this Agreement that affects financial services; and DISPUTE SETTLEMENT. 11. LIBERALISATION OF GOVERNMENT PROCUREMENT. A. Government Procurement in Trade Agreements Government procurement is in some countries even more important than trade in terms of the value and volume of goods and services involved. In some countries it could account for 15 to 30 per cent of the GNP. It comprises the expenditures of government on goods and services (including projects), excluding personnel costs. It is a very important tool of government policy (economic, social and political). Most governments have guidelines that favour the granting of projects to local companies and people (for example by reserving some purchases or projects only for locals, or by allowing local proposals to be up to 10 or 20 per cent higher in cost than foreign ones). Procurement has been excluded from the rules of the WTO, such as market access and national treatment. There is only a plurilateral agreement on government procurement in the WTO, which is not compulsory for WTO members to join, and almost no developing country has signed up to it. 49 The developed countries tried very hard to introduce a multilateral agreement on government procurement, which would make it mandatory for all WTO members to join. The developing countries were extremely reluctant to agree, as they consider this to be a subject of national policy and that the trade rules of WTO are unsuitable for this subject. Developed countries then proposed that an agreement confined to only “transparency” in government procurement be introduced, which would exclude market access or national treatment. In other words, governments would only have to introduce more transparent rules on what projects are up for tender, who is eligible to apply, and the results, but would not have to open up the projects to foreigners. After years of discussion, even this limited agreement was rejected in July 2004, and remains outside the WTO arena. As procurement is a trillion-dollar business, the developed countries are determined to break into this business for their companies. They are thus now including a fullfledged procurement chapter (dealing with market access and national treatment) in their FTAs. B. Features of government procurement in FTAs involving USA In the FTAs involving the US, the chapter on government procurement goes far beyond what was being discussed in the WTO for many years (with the discussions eventually suspended). The WTO working group had been given the mandate only to discuss “transparency in government procurement”, with possible rules to be limited to only the transparency aspects, and excluding market access aspects. However, the FTA chapter on government procurement covers the market access aspects, i.e. enabling foreign companies to bid on equal terms with local companies for government contracts. This would drastically limit or eliminate policy space for the developing-country government to give preferential treatment to local companies and persons, and remove a crucial instrument for boosting the domestic economy. The FTA chapter typically involves: (1) Market access for each party to the government procurement market of the other party; (2) National treatment for the foreign firms and products; (3) A wide definition of government procurement, involving various levels of government (national, regional and municipal) and various types of government business. (4) The chapter also contains “threshold levels” representing monetary values; the agreement applies only if the contracts put out by the governments are valued at the threshold levels or above. The US-Chile FTA provides an example of such a government procurement chapter. One of the objectives is to “strive to provide comprehensive coverage of procurement markets by eliminating market access barriers to the supply of goods and services, including construction services.” The scope and coverage applies to any measure relating to a procurement “by any contractual means, including purchase and rental or lease, with or without an option to buy, build-operate-transfer contracts, and public works concession contracts.” Not included are non-contractual agreements or assistance provided by government, 50 such as grants, loans and subsidies; purchases funded by international grants; hiring of government employees; and services for regulated financial institutions. The agreement covers procurement carried out by entities listed in an annex. For Chile, these include 20 federal Ministries, many regional governments and 341 municipalities. For the US, they include 79 federal departments and many offices of state governments. The same annex, has also specified the same threshold levels for both countries. The threshold levels are $56,190 for procurement of goods and services and $6.48 million for procurement of construction services for the central government level and threshold levels of $460,000 and $6.48 million respectively for the sub-central level. The main general principles are National Treatment and Non-Discrimination. In any measure governing government procurement, each Party shall give to the goods and services of the other Party, and to the suppliers of the other Party, “treatment no less favourable than the most favourable treatment the Party accords to its own goods, services and suppliers.” Also, neither Party may treat a locally established supplier less favourably than another local supplier on the basis of degree of foreign affiliation or ownership, or discriminate against a locally established supplier on the basis that the goods or services offered by that supplier are goods and services of the other Party. The major implications of this are that (1) The government must give the foreign country’s companies treatment as good as or better than it gives its national companies; (2) Preferential treatment to national companies in the award of contracts will not be allowed in future; (3) If a local company is providing or distributing the goods and services of the foreign country, it shall not be discriminated against as compared to a local company supplying its own goods and services that are locally made. Another general principle is the prohibition of offsets. It says: “An entity shall not consider, seek or impose offsets at any stage of a procurement.” Several developing countries make use of “offsets” to reduce the net cost of purchase or payment for goods and services procured. The agreement includes a provision requiring the entities to publish in advance a notice inviting interested suppliers to submit tenders for that procurement. The notice will include a description of the procurement, conditions for suppliers to fulfill, time limits to submit tenders and delivery dates for the goods to be procured. There are many detailed provisions on (1) publication of procurement measures (2) publication of notice of intended procurement; (3) time limits for the tendering process; (4) information on intended procurements; (4) technical specifications; (5) conditions for participation; (6) tendering procedures; (7) awarding of contracts; 51 (8) information on awards; (9) ensuring integrity in procurement practices; (10) domestic review of supplier challenges. These provisions in effect formulate in detail what a country’s procurement policy and practice should be. For example, under awarding of contracts, there is the prescriptive provision that the government institution “shall award the contract to the supplier that the entity has determined to be fully capable of undertaking the contract and whose tender is determined to be the most advantageous in terms of the requirements and evaluation criteria set out in the tender documentation.” Under domestic review of supplier challenges, the companies applying for government contracts can bring cases to an independent “impartial administrative or judicial authority”. The authority must be given the opportunity to take “prompt interim measures” to preserve the supplier’s opportunity to participate in the procurement and to ensure the country complies with measures in the procurement chapter. This includes “suspending the contract award or the performance of a contract that has already been awarded.” Also the country has to ensure that “all documents related to a challenge to a procurement” are made available to the review authority. The authority must allow the supplier to review relevant documents and to be heard in a timely manner, and the entity complained against must respond in writing to the supplier’s challenge, and the authority must give prompt decisions in writing with an explanation of the grounds for each decision. The country can also modify its coverage only if it offers “acceptable compensatory adjustments to the other party” to maintain a level of coverage comparable to th that existing before the adjustment, within 30 days. A procurement committee shall also be set up, including to consider further negotiations to broaden the coverage including with respect to sub-federal entities and state-owned enterprises. In terms of the treatment of which goods and services are covered by the agreement, the US FTAs seem to take the following approach. Firstly, there are thresholds for the value of goods, services and construction services; only those projects valued at the threshold levels or above are covered. Each country lists the departments in the federal and sub-federal level, and the “other covered entities” under which the thresholds apply. Secondly, for goods, each country lists down the government departments that will be covered by the agreement. Thirdly, for services, each country indicates the departments that are excluded from coverage. C. National policy changes needed due to FTA To implement the obligations, a developing country would have to undertake reforms and new procedures. 52 Most developing countries provide preferential treatment to local suppliers in government procurement. Thus, the most important reform would be to give up this preferential treatment, and to give equal (or superior) treatment to foreign suppliers, in accordance with the FTA. There are many consequences for such a significant change in policy. There are also many new procedures that have to be followed. For instance, the FTA specifies what kind of conditions can or cannot be imposed on suppliers interested in participating in a procurement. It specifies what kind of tendering procedures should be followed. Importantly, it obliges the country to set up independent review institutions and processes to enable a supplier to challenge the decision on granting of procurement contracts. D. Erosion of policy space and in the role of government procurement There is a significant role of government procurement in socio-economic development and national policy. This role would be much eroded by the FTA. A large part of an average developing country’s income is made up of the spending of its federal government, on the purchase of goods, payment for all kinds of services, and a variety of projects, from the building of schools and roads to billion-dollar mega-dams and industrial complexes. Add also the expenditure of state and municipal governments, statutory bodies and state-run enterprises, and the total amount of money spent by the public sector becomes enormous; for many countries, much larger even than their total imports or exports. For example, in some countries, public sector expenditure may comprise 30 to 50 percent of GNP, while imports may comprise 10 to 30 percent of GNP. Even if the salaries of government employees are excluded, government expenditure is often higher than imports. So far, governments have been able to decide for themselves how this money is to be spent, the system of procuring goods and services, and the tendering, scrutiny of applications and award of projects, subject of course to each country’s laws and procedures. The system of government procurement has been taken for granted as very much a matter of national prerogative, often challenged in some countries by Parliaments, opposition parties or public interest groups, but seldom or never questioned as an issue that lies within the sovereign right of a country to determine. Because of the sensitive nature of government procurement, government procurement has so far been excluded from the rules (such as national treatment and most favoured nation) of the WTO, including the GATT, agriculture agreement and the services agreement. There is a plurilateral agreement on government procurement; however members can choose whether or not to join it, and most developing countries have chosen not to do so. 53 Government procurement and policies related to it have very important economic, social and even political roles in developing countries: --- The level of expenditure, and the attempt to direct the expenditure to locally produced materials, is a major macroeconomic instrument, especially during recessionary periods, to counter economic downturn. Governments often change the level of expenditure as the major tool of fiscal policy to steer the level of demand and growth in the economy. --- In many developing countries, there are national policies to give preference to local firms, suppliers and contractors, in order to boost the domestic economy and participation of locals in economic development and benefits. In fact, government procurement is a major policy tool for putting into effect a policy of increasing the opportunities for local enterprises to increase their share of the economy. --- Also in several developing countries, there are policies aimed at providing preferences for certain groups or communities, especially those that are underrepresented in economic standing. Procurement policy is a major policy tool for attaining greater balance in the participation shares among various communities within a nation. Similarly, it can be used to redress regional imbalances, for instance by specifying that certain provinces be allocated a particular share of procurement business. --- For procurement or concessions where foreign firms are invited to bid, there could be a preference to give the award to firms from particular countries (eg other developing countries, or particular developed countries, with which there is a special commercial or political relationship). E. Effects of government procurement liberalization under FTA There would be serious effects from a FTA’s government procurement chapter on developing countries Countries that sign on to FTAs containing a chapter on government procurement in future will not be allowed to give preferences to local companies for the supply of goods and services and for the granting of or concessions for implementing projects. (There is however a positive list approach where parties state what sectors they are offering, and thresholds). The effects on developing countries would be severe. Should government procurement be opened up through the national treatment and MFN principles, the scope and space for a government to use procurement as an instrument for development would be severely curtailed. For example: If the foreign share increases, there would be a “leakage” in government attempts to boost the economy through increased spending, during a downturn. This is because an increased part of any expansion in government expenditure would be spent on imported products, thus decreasing the multiplier effects of public spending on the domestic economy. 54 The ability to assist local companies, and particular socioeconomic groups or ethnic communities, or underdeveloped regions, would be seriously curtailed. This is because “national treatment” would have to be given to foreign firms to bid for supplying goods and services as well as development projects. The ability to give preferences to certain foreign countries would similarly be curtailed, under the most-favoured-nation clause. [This would be the case if government procurement became a multilateral agreement in the WTO]. Given the great importance of government procurement policy as an important tool required for economic and social development and nation building, it is imperative that developing countries retain the right to have full autonomy and flexibility over its procurement policy. Therefore, it is important to avoid government procurement as an item in a bilateral trade or economic agreement. This is especially so because the developing countries have fought such a controversial battle to exclude this as a negotiating issue within the current Doha work programme in the WTO. At the least, there should be national debates about the ramifications of having a government procurement clause within an FTA. In an FTA involving a developed and a developing country, it is more likely that the developed country can take advantage of a government procurement market access chapter as it has the supply capacity. Most developing countries will not be able to take advantage, or at least to the same degree, because they lack the supply capacity. Thus there is an inherent imbalance in including this in an FTA. F. GOVERNMENT PROCUREMENT: MALAYSIA IMPLICATIONS OF MUFTA FOR A government procurement chapter in an FTA with the USA will have especially serious effects on Malaysia, including the loss of policy space to make use of government procurement as a main instrument for national economic, social and political goals. In Malaysia, government procurement and expenditure have been major instruments for economic management and for socio-economic planning, as well as political stability among ethnic communities. The FTA will oblige Malaysia to give market access and national treatment to US companies in its government procurement business. Present policies that reserve contracts to supply goods and services to only local firms, and that give preference to locals in other projects, will have to be changed. The levels of procurement, especially if state and local authorities are also included, and if government-related enterprises are included, are very large. 55 According to estimates by the WTO, the Malaysian government procurement market was worth RM 92.7 billion or 20.6% of GDP in 2004, of which over RM 49 billion was federal government expenditure on supplies and services, and development. A further RM 33.5 billion was expenditure by non-financial public enterprises (GLCs). The estimates are based on budget allocations. The WTO itself says that: “The scale of government procurement in Malaysia provides a great deal of scope for its use as an instrument of economic policy.” Malaysian Government procurement, 2001-04 (RM million) Federal Government expenditure on supplies and services Federal Government development expenditure State Government development expenditure Local Government expenditure Statutory bodies development expenditure Non-financial public enterprises Total 2001 2002 2003 2004 10,703 11,269 13,968 18,133 35,235 35,977 39,353 31,131 4,704 3,772 3,817 4,710 2,176 3,088 2,322 3,841 2,482 4,180 1,931 3,374 24,033 79,939 32,297 89,478 40,160 103,960 33,454 92,733 Source:World Trade Organisation (2005), Trade Policy Review Malaysia. Estimated from Ministry of Finance, Economic Report 2004/2005, Annex tables 4.4, 4.6, 4.10, 4.11, 4.12 and 4.13. Available at: http://www.treasury.gov.my/le2005/le-05.htm. The WTO report says that: “Malaysia's government procurement policy is consistent with the national policy of nation-building. It is used to support national objectives such as encouraging greater participation of the bumiputeras (indigenous Malays), in the economy, transfer of technology to local industries, reducing the outflow of foreign exchange, creating opportunities for local service-oriented companies, and enhancing export capabilities. It intends to maintain its requirement for all government agencies to procure supplies and services from local sources. International tenders will be invited only if goods and services are not available locally. Bumiputera tenders receive preferential treatment, which varies from 10% for contracts of RM 100,000 to 2.5% for contracts of over RM 15 million. Locally produced goods receive a preference of 10% for contracts below RM 10 million and up to 3% above this value. The Malaysian authorities have pointed out that 56 tenders will be invited only from local manufacturers and therefore Bumiputera manufacturers will not be competing with international bidders. Where local contractors do not have the requisite expertise and capability, agencies may call for joint-venture bids (between local and foreign contractors) to encourage the transfer of technology. For projects funded by foreign sources, procedures for tenders are as stipulated by the respective sources. The Ministry of Finance has main responsibility for government procurement issues. The Ministry's government procurement management division undertakes open local tenders for items such as office supplies. Government agencies, both federal and state, are then required to purchase those goods from the successful bidder. All goods and services tenders in excess of RM 30 million and works (such as construction or engineering services) over RM 50 million must be referred to the Ministry of Finance for decision. Tenders below these thresholds can be considered by Tender Boards in each federal government ministry. Government-linked companies (GLCs) require government approval for purchases exceeding defined limits and, for example, Petronas, Telecom Malaysia, Tenaga Nasional have to refer to the Ministry of Finance when procuring goods and services valued at or exceeding RM 100 million. The Government encourages GLCs to follow government policies on procurement as far as possible. Regarding the legal and regulatory framework, the Government Contract Act 1949 provides legal validity for the ministries to represent the Government in engaging contracts and the Financial Procedure Act 1957 outlines the mode of control and management of public finances. The latter lays out procedures for the collection and payment of public monies as well as procedures for the purchase, custody and disposal of public property. In addition, government procurement is regulated by treasury instructions, treasury circulars, and central contract circulars. Malaysia aims to achieve a high standard of transparency in its procurement policies and practices; it subscribes to the elements agreed upon in the NonBinding Principles and to the APEC Transparency Standards. All agencies are required to procure all supplies, services and works above RM 200,000 through open tenders. To ensure transparency, tenders must be advertised widely in local daily newspapers, agencies' websites and on the myGovernment Portal. In 2000, the Government introduced an electronic procurement (eP) system, an on-line system designed to encourage competition among contractors and to expedite the procurement processes. The eP system also aims to reduce bidding costs and make the process more efficient and transparent; it is in the second phase of implementation. In 2004, the Treasury launched quotation and tendering modules in 14 selected ministries on a pilot basis.” 57 The following functions have been made use of by Malaysia as a key policy tool: Malaysia has made use of the level of government expenditure as a means to influence the level and growth of economic output, for example by boosting public-sector spending during recessionary conditions, thus reducing economic instability. Procurement has been used to expand the opportunities for local enterprises. For example, the use of local banks in government business was a major method of increasing the share of local banks in total banking business, after Independence. Procurement policy has also been a major instrument in increasing the opportunities for the Bumiputra community, for instance in construction projects, within the context of the New Economic Policy and its subsequent variations. Procurement policies have in other ways been used to meet national goals. For example, government has been encouraging the use of opensource software in government departments, in order to save costs (commercial proprietary software is expensive and costs will increase) and to gain a certain degree of non-dependence on one or a few companies that own proprietary software. If MUFTA is along the lines of other US FTAs, then it would result in Malaysia having to change its procurement policies in many ways, and with many effects (especially for departments whose procurement is offered): For a large part of contracts and projects, the “use Malaysian” policy can no longer be used as they have to be opened up to American firms. The FTA’s procurement chapter’s main provision is that in any measure governing government procurement, each Party shall give to the goods and services of the other Party, and to the suppliers of the other Party, “treatment no less favourable than the most favourable treatment the Party accords to its own goods, services and suppliers.” This will result in greater “leakage” away from the national economy, as the contracts won by American firms will have much less “multiplier effect” on the domestic economy, thus limiting the use of government expenditure as a tool to boost economic growth. The present policy that tenders are only open to local firms will have to be changed, to allow American firms to apply on terms that are as favourable or more favourable than local firms, except for small projects below the threshold levels. The policy of giving up to 10% preference margin for Bumiputra firms will also have to be changed, except for small contracts below the threshold level. These policies providing “national treatment” to Americans will also have to apply to government-linked companies, which will not be able to give preference to local firms to supply good or services. 58 The new policies will also apply to “sub-federal” entities, which include state governments and probably municipal councils as well. Another FTA provision would be that Malaysia cannot treat a locallybased supplier (who has more foreign affiliation or ownership) less favourably than another local supplier (who has no or lesws foreign affiliation and ownership). Malaysia also cannot discriminate against a locally established supplier on the basis that the goods or services offered by that supplier are goods and services of the other Party. The major implications of this are that (1) The government must give the foreign country’s companies treatment as good as or better than it gives its national companies; (2) Preferential treatment to national companies in the award of contracts will not be allowed in future; (3) If a local company is providing or distributing the goods and services of the foreign country, it shall not be discriminated against as compared to a local company supplying its own goods and services that are locally made. Another general principle is the prohibition of offsets. It says: “An entity shall not consider, seek or impose offsets at any stage of a procurement.” Several developing countries make use of “offsets” to reduce the net cost of purchase or payment for goods and services procured. One reason why the procurement chapter will have such a large effect is that its scope and coverage is very broad, i.e. many levels of government and many projects and contracts will be affected. In the US-Chile FTA, one objective of the procuremnent chapter is to “strive to provide comprehensive coverage of procurement markets by eliminating market access barriers to the supply of goods and services, including construction services.” The scope and coverage applies to any measure relating to a procurement “by any contractual means, including purchase and rental or lease, with or without an option to buy, buildoperate-transfer contracts, and public works concession contracts.” Not included are non-contractual agreements or assistance provided by government, such as grants, loans and subsidies; purchases funded by international grants; hiring of government employees; and services for regulated financial institutions. The agreement covers procurement carried out by entities listed in an annex, including federal Ministries, state governments and municipalities. Government-linked companies and other entities could also be covered. It can be expected that the US will insist on a comprehensive list of government departments. Malaysia can list down certain services to be exempted; however, it will be under pressure to keep these to a minimum. In its FTA with the US, Singapore excluded only a few services (such as research and development; police and 59 security, radio and TV, urban planning, asset management for managing official foreign reserves, water supply; government printing). Given the experience of some previous US FTAs, we can expect threshold levels to be set at around US$56,190 for procurement of goods and services and US $6.48 million for procurement of construction services for the central government level and threshold levels of $460,000 and $6.48 million respectively for the sub-central level. Contracts and projects above the threshold levels will be covered. The methods and procedures governing procurement would have to be changed, including in (1) publication of procurement measures (2) publication of notice of intended procurement; (3) time limits for the tendering process; (4) information on intended procurements; (4) technical specifications; (5) conditions for participation; (6) tendering procedures; (7) awarding of contracts; (8) information on awards; (9) ensuring integrity in procurement practices; (10) domestic review of supplier challenges. These FTA provisions in effect formulate in detail what Malaysia’s procurement policy and practice should be. For example, under awarding of contracts, there is the prescriptive provision that the government institution “shall award the contract to the supplier that the entity has determined to be fully capable of undertaking the contract and whose tender is determined to be the most advantageous in terms of the requirements and evaluation criteria set out in the tender documentation.” Should an American (or even local) company not agree that its application has been fairly treated, it can take the government to court, demand that the documents and basis for decision be revealed, and ask for a revision. The court is called an independent “impartial administrative or judicial authority” in the FTA. . The authority must be able to preserve the opportunity of the supplier (who has made the complaint) to participate in the procurement, including “suspending the contract award or the performance of a contract that has already been awarded.” Malaysia has to ensure that “all documents related to a challenge to a procurement” are made available to the review authority. The authority must allow the supplier to review relevant documents and to be heard in a timely manner, and the entity complained against must respond in writing to the supplier’s challenge, and the authority must give prompt decisions in writing with an explanation of the grounds for each decision. Malaysia can modify its coverage (of government procurement that falls under the FTA) only if it offers “acceptable compensatory adjustments to the other party” to maintain a level of coverage comparable to th that existing before the adjustment, within 30 days. 60 A procurement committee shall also be set up, including to consider further negotiations to broaden the coverage including with respect to sub-federal entities and state-owned enterprises. Thus there can be continuous pressure, even after the FTA is signed, to extend further the coverage of the procurement that is to fall under the FTA, and pressure on enforecement. It is no exaggeration to state that the serious limits and conditions placed on government policy should government procurement be integrated into the WTO, would have very serious social, economic and political ramifications. The main instrument for re-structuring Malaysian economy and society so as to give more opportunities to local firms, especially Bumiputra firms, would be very seriously eroded. It was because of its awareness of the dangers of a procurement agreement that Malaysia took a leading role to reject proposals by the developed countries to introduce an agreement on transparency in government procurement at the WTO. The Minister of Trade Rafidah Aziz played the leading role in putting this subject off the table at the WTO’s Cancun Ministerial conference in 2003. The proposal only involved having greater transparency and did not include market access or national treatment, yet it was considered too dangerous. Malaysia has also not signed on to the plurilateral agreement on government procurement at the WTO (which includes market access). If it were to sign on to an FTA with the USA, Malaysia would have to undertake the most strict market access/ national treatment rules far beyond what it had rejected at the WTO. The US has made it clear it would not agree to an FTA without a government procurement chapter, and it normally has a common template for such a chapter. The FTA also theoretically gives Malaysian firms the opportunity to have greater access to the United States procurement market. However, in reality, the opportunities and benefits are limited. According to a press report: ‘The US government will open approximately US$250 billion worth of procurement to Malaysia under the US-Malaysia Free Trade Agreement.’ How much of this US$250billion are Malaysian companies likely to be able to access if a Malaysia-USFTA is signed? In the WTO Secretariat’s 2006 trade policy review for the USA (WT/TPR/S/160/Rev.1), it mentioned the US Government’s Federal Procurement Data System (FPDS), the upgraded version of which is now at https://www.fpds.gov/. Based on a very quick analysis of the data in the FPDS database, it seems that for the year 1/1/2005-31/12/2005: 94% of the action obligation (payments made or initial contract value) went to companies located in the USA. 61 The remaining 6% was split between companies located in 170 countries and territories. (WT/TPR/S/160/Rev.1 explains how so many countries are eligible to supply to the US Government (countries who have signed the WTO Government Procurement Agreement, bilateral/regional trade agreements which include government procurement, the WTO plurilateral Agreement on Trade in Civil Aircraft, the 50 least developed countries, countries eligible under the Caribbean Basin Economic Recovery Act, defence equipment produced in countries with an MOU and other exceptions to the Buy American Act, eg if it is determined that domestic preference is inconsistent with the public interest, in case of U.S. non-availability of a supply or material, or for reasonableness of cost)). 99.1% of that 6% went to: unspecified, Kuwait, Canada, South Korea, Germany, UK, Australia, Switzerland, Netherlands, Russia, Japan (in order of most to least). Of course this may change from year to year (although the 94% to companies located in the USA seemed to be about the same for the few years checked). A preliminary examination of the changes in the US government procurement market access that Chile achieved after their USFTAs were signed found that for Chile, contracts signed between 1/1/2003 and 31/12/2003 had an action obligation of US$32,090. Chile’s USFTA came into force on 1/1/2004. Contracts signed between 1/1/2004 and 31/12/2004 had an action obligation of US$635,516. Contracts signed between 1/1/2005 and 31/12/2005 had an action obligation of US$233,570 Note: The information on the procurement chapter of a typical US FTA is taken from the US-Chile and US-Singapore FTAs. 12. COMPETITION POLICY A. BACKGROUND TO THE ISSUE Competition policy is a complex subject, especially when put in the context of trade agreements. At first glance, “competition policy” is taken to mean restricting the power and scope of activities of the large corporations, especially transnational companies. However, “competition” is usually taken to mean something different by trade officials of developed countries. They have been trying to make use of “competition policy” as a concept linked to market access, in which foreign firms and their products and services should have the right to “free competition” vis-à-vis local firms in markets of developing countries. “Free competition” would, in their approach, mean that the preferences given to local firms, and any advantages or assistance they enjoy, should be curtailed or eliminated, so that the foreign firms can compete on a level playing field. 62 In this paradigm, the transnational corporations of the US, Europe, Japan, etc, would be able to compete on “equal ground” as local companies in the local markets. In actual fact, these TNCs already enjoy great advantages, including big size, large financial resources, high technology, marketing networks, and brand names. Thus there is no “level playing field” to begin with. Without some assistance, preferential treatmnent, or home-ground advantages (such as being familiar with the local language and customs, and having a distribution system built over generations), the local companies of developing countries will not be able to survive the competition from foreign firms. A few years ago, the EU backed by Japan and the US tried introduce a competition agreement in the WTO that would enable foreign firms and their goods and services to compete “equally” with local firms, through the removal of preference and subsidization of local firms. Later, the proposal was narrowed down to initial topics such as principles of non-discrimination, transparency and procedural fairness, as well as hard core cartels and modalities for voluntary cooperation. This did not preclude the later full-scale introduction of the initial broad proposal. The FTAs that involve the US typically require the developing country to establish competition legislation. Development economists have questioned whether the framework of competition policy and framework now in place in the US and other developed countries are appropriate for developing countries which are now in their developmental stage. Their concern is that this framework, which the FTA promotes, may hinder the growth of local firms and make them even less able to compete or survive against the large foreign companies especially in the face of globalization. The competition issue in FTAs is thus extremely complex. These economists argue that developing countries should have competition policy and law, but that these must be tailored to their development needs. Ajit Singh, for example, concludes that the kind of competition policy adopted by Japan in its developmental period (1960s-1970s) is more suitable for developing countries. In this model, competition policy and law were formulated that prevented the full onslaught of large foreign firms that were anti-competitive because of their size and monopolitistic characteristics, but local firms were able to develop end expand. In the typical US FTAs there are also typically competition policy elements in some chapters, beside the chapter on competition itself. For example there are competition elements in the telecommunications chapter in the FTA with Singapore in which the parties are obliged that if there is a government linked company involved in telecoms activity, it should not be able to influence government policy-making; and that the companies of the FTA partner should have access to certain telecom infrastructure in the country. The aim of the US is apparently to make use of the competition principle to erode the ability of local firms to have a market advantage or to have preferential treatment or to be promoted by the national government, on the ground that this discriminates against the foreign firms. Another aim is to limit or reduce the influence and position of government-linked companies by arguing that it would be anti-competitive for government to assist a company (even if it is owned by government) in its market operations. 63 Competition law and policy, in appropriate forms, are beneficial to the country. However each country must have full flexibility to choose a model which is suitable, and which can also change through time to suit changing conditions. Having an appropriate model is especially important in the context of globalisation and liberalisation where local firms are already facing intense foreign competition The developed countries’ approach, that competition policy should provide “effective opportunity for competition” in the local market for foreign firms, and thus to apply the WTO “core principles” to competition law/policy would affect the needed flexibility for the country to have its own appropriate model or models of competition law/policy. What is required is a paradigm to view competition from a development perspective. Competition law/policy should complement other national objectives, eg industrial policy, or the need for local sectors to compete in the context of liberalisation. Therefore the traditional or the UK and US models of competition may not be appropriate for a developing country. On the other hand the Japan model of the 1950s-70s may be more appropriate but may not be allowed under the US-EU framework of applying WTO or “national treatment” and “market access” principles to competition policy. Along the same lines, in a development perspective, a competition and development framework requires that local firms and farms must build up the capacity to become more and more capable of competing successfully, starting with the local market, and then if possible internationally. This requires a long time frame, and cannot be done in a short while. It also requires a vital role for the state, which has to play the role of nurturing, subsidising, encouraging the local firms. The build up of local capacity to remain competitive and become more competitive also requires protection from the "free" and full force of the world market for the time it takes for the local capacity to build up. This means that development strategy has to be at the centre, and competition as well as competition policy has to be approached to meet the central development needs and strategy. At present, there is hardly any common understanding let alone agreement among countries on what the competition concept and issue means in the WTO context, especially in terms of its "interaction" with trade and its relationship with development. The whole set of issues of competition, competition law and competition policy and their relation to trade and to development is extremely complex. The proposal of the proponents of a WTO agreement (especially the EU) is to have multilateral rules that discipline Members to establish national competition law and policy. According to the advocates, these laws/policies should incorporate the “core principles of WTO”, defined as transparency, non-discrimination (MFN and national treatment.) Thus, the location of the venue of the competition issue and the agreement within the WTO would bias the manner in which the subject and the agreement is to be treated. In this case, the "core WTO principles" would be applied to competition. Competition law and policy, in appropriate forms, are beneficial, including to developing countries. However each country must have full flexibility to choose a 64 model which is suitable, and which can also change through time to suit changing conditions. Having an appropriate model is especially important in the context of globalisation and liberalisation where local firms are already facing intense foreign competition. In particular, developing countries must have the flexibility to choose the paradigm of competition and competition policy/law that is deemed to be more suitable to their level of development and their development interests. B. TOWARDS A DEVELOPMENT FRAMEWORK ON COMPETITION FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES The developed countries’ conceptual and negotiating framework can be challenged through a different framework that looks at competition through the lens of development. Developing countries can argue that only if local firms and agencies are given certain advantages can they remain viable. If these smaller enterprises are treated on par with the huge foreign conglomerates, most of them would not be able to survive. Perhaps some would remain because over the years (or generations) they have built up distribution systems based on their intimate knowledge of the local scene that give them an edge over the better-endowed foreign firms. But the operation of such local distribution channels could also come under attack from a competition policy in the WTO ort the FTAs as the developed countries are likely to pressure the local firms to also open their marketing channels to their foreign competitors. At present, many developing countries would argue that giving favourable treatment to locals is in fact pro-competitive, in that the smaller local firms are given some advantages to withstand the might of foreign giants, which otherwise would monopolise the local market. Providing the giant international firms equal rights would overwhelm the local enterprises which are small- and medium-sized in global terms. However, such arguments will not be accepted by the developed countries, which will insist that their giant firms be provided a “level playing field” to compete “equally” with the smaller local firms. They would like their interpretation of “competition” (which, ironically, would likely lead to foreign monopolisation of developing-country markets) to be enshrined in WTO law or in the FTAs. Competition can be viewed from many perspectives. From the developing countries' perspective, it is important to curb the mega-mergers and acquisitions taking place which threaten the competitive position of local firms in developing countries. Also, the abuse of anti-dumping actions in the developed countries is anti-competitive against developing countries' products. The restrictive business practices of large firms also hinders competition. However these issues are unlikely to find favour with the major countries, especially the US, which wants to continue its use of antidumping actions as a protectionist device. In the FTA, the need for foreign firms to have national treatment and a free competition environment in the host country, could well prevail, especially given the unequal negotiating strength which works against the developing countries. The likely result is that developing countries would have to establish national competition laws and policies that are inappropriate for their conditions. This would curb the right of governments to provide advantages to local 65 firms, and local firms themselves may be restricted from practices which are to their advantage. What is required is a conceptual framework or paradigm to view competition from a development perspective. Competition law/policy should complement other national objectives and policies (such as industrial policy) and the need for local firms and sectors to be able to successfully compete, including in the context of increased liberalisation. From a development perspective, a competition and development framework should have the following elements: An understanding that local industrial and services firms and agricultural farms must build up the capacity to become more and more capable of competing successfully, starting with the local market, and then if possible internationally. This requires a long time frame, and cannot be done in a short while. A vital role for the state is required, to play the role of nurturing, subsidising, encouraging the local firms. The build up of local capacity to remain competitive and become more competitive also requires protection from the "free" and full force of the world market for the time it takes for the local capacity to build up. This means that development strategy has to be at the centre, and competition as well as competition policy has to be formulated as a means to meet the central development needs and strategy. Therefore some of the conventional models of competition may not be appropriate for a developing country. On the other hand other models may be more appropriate, but their adoption may be hindered or prohibited by a WTO agreement on competition that is based on the "core principles of WTO." For example, the Cambridge University Professor of Economics, Ajit Singh, has pointed out that: (1) The US and European models of competition law and policy are inappropriate and can cause harm to the development efforts of developing countries; (2) More suitable is the Japanese model of the 1950s and 1960s, when Japan was at its developmental stage. The Japanese government enacted competition law which was a tool to prevent the intrusion of large foreign firms and their products, whilst at the same time used industrial policy to nurture and strengthen Japanese firms so that they could develop and eventually successfully compete with the foreign giant companies. The kind of model represented by the Japanese example, in which competition policy is complemented and indeed subsumed under industrial policy, would not be allowed in the kind of competition agreement being propounded in the FTAs. Indeed, they would precisely seek to outlaw the kind of Japanese-style model that developing countries may find consistent with their development needs. There is no convincing case for competition policy to be a subject of an FTA (which should be about trade). If it is in an FTA, then the FTA would create a 66 set of binding rules to govern the competition policies and laws of developing countries. Given the “market access” and “national treatment” principles in the FTA, a competition chapter in the FTA is likely to be skewed in a way that is inappropriate for the development interests of developing countries. If there is to be a discussion on “competition” in trade talks, including in FTAs, developing countries could give their own interpretation of this issue and put forward their own ideas for the discussion (in an attempt not to have a competition chapter in the FTA). The trade expert, B.L. Das has suggested that the following issues could be put forward: -- Obligations of the foreign firms to the host country. -- Obligation of the home government to ensure the foreign firms fulfil their obligations. -- Competitiveness of domestic firms: to consider measures to be undertaken by domestic firms, government and a possible multilateral framework to enable local firms (especially small firms) to remain or to be competitive and to grow. -- Competition impeded by government action (for example, antidumping action). -- Competition impeded by IPR protection --Global monopolies and oligopolies and their effect on local firms in developing countries. --Big mergers and acquisitions (by transnational companies) and their effects on developing countries. C. What the US Proposes on Competition in its FTA: Anti-Competitive Business Conduct, Designated Monopolies and Government Enterprises A typical competition chapter in a US FTA can be seen in the FTA with Singapore. The chapter comprises three subjects: (1) Anticompetitive business conduct, (2) Designated Monopolies, and (3) government enterprises. These topics give an idea already of the disciplines the FTA seeks to impose on the operation of national companies. The objective of the chapter states: “Recognizing that the conduct subject to this Chapter has the potential to restrict bilateral trade and investment, the Parties believe proscribing such conduct, implementing economically sound competition policies, and engaging in cooperation will help secure the benefits of this Agreement.” The point being put forward is that the subject (i.e. anti-competitive business conduct, monopolies designated by government, and government-linked companies or GLCs) can restrict the benefits of trade and investment sought by the FTA, and thus both countries have to proscribe or discipline such conduct and have “economically cound” competition policies. 67 On ANTICOMPETITIVE BUSINESS CONDUCT, the countries commit: (a) To having measures to proscribe anticompetitive business conduct and to take action on such conduct. This is taken to mean that the country will introduce a competition law; a footnote in the Singapore-US FTA says Singapore shall enact general competition legislation by January 2005 (just a year after the FTA was signed). (b) To establish an authority to enforce its measures to proscribe anticompetitive business conduct. (c) That the enforcement policy of the national authority includes not discriminating on the basis of the nationality of the subjects of their proceedings. (d) That a court will give opportunity to a person charged to be heard and to review the sanction. On DESIGNATED MONOPOLIES The countries commit that: (a) Where a country designates a monopoly that may affect the other country’s interests, the country shall: introduce such conditions on the operation of the monopoly as will minimize or eliminate any nullification or impairment of benefits; and (ii) provide written notification to the other Party of the designation and any such conditions. (b) A general competition law will be enacted by a certain date and it shall not exclude government enterprises. (c) They ensure that any privately-owned monopoly that it designates after the agreement is signed and any designated government monopoly: (i) acts in a manner that is not inconsistent with the Party’s obligations under this Agreement wherever such a monopoly exercises any regulatory, administrative, or other governmental authority that the Party has delegated to it, such as the power to grant import or export licenses, approve commercial transactions, or impose quotas, fees or other charges; (ii) acts solely in accordance with commercial considerations in its purchase or sale of the monopoly good or service in the relevant market, including with regard to price, quality, availability, marketability, transportation, etc. (iii) provides non-discriminatory treatment to covered investments, to goods of the other Party, and to service suppliers of the other Party in its purchase or sale of the monopoly good or service in the relevant market; and (iv) does not use its monopoly position to engage directly or indirectly including through its dealings with its parent, subsidiaries, or other enterprises with common 68 ownership, in anticompetitive practices in a non-monopolized market in its territory that adversely affect covered investments. On GOVERNMENT ENTERPRISES, the commitments in the Singapore-US FTA are that: (a) Each Party shall ensure that any government enterprise acts in a manner consistent with the Party’s obligations under this Agreement wherever such enterprise exercises any regulatory, administrative, or other governmental authority that the Party has delegated to it, such as the power to expropriate, grant licenses, approve commercial transactions, or impose quotas, fees, or other charges. (b) The United States shall ensure that any government enterprise accords nondiscriminatory treatment in the sale of its goods or services to covered investments. (c) Singapore shall ensure that any government enterprise: (i) acts solely in accordance with commercial considerations in its purchase or sale of goods or services, such as with regard to price, quality, availability, marketability, transportation, and other terms and conditions of purchase or sale, and provides nondiscriminatory treatment to covered investments, to goods of the United States, and to service suppliers of the United States, including with respect to its purchases or sales; (ii) does not, either directly or indirectly, including through its dealings with its parent, subsidiaries, or other enterprises with common ownership: (a) enter into agreements among competitors that restrain competition on price or output or allocate customers for which there is no plausible efficiency justification, or (b) engage in exclusionary practices that substantially lessen competition in a market in Singapore to the detriment of consumers. (d) Singapore shall take no action or attempt in any way, directly or indirectly, to influence or direct decisions of its government enterprises, including through the exercise of any rights or interests conferring effective influence over such enterprises, except in a manner consistent with this Agreement. However, Singapore may exercise its voting rights in government enterprises. (e) Singapore shall continue reducing, with a goal of substantially eliminating, its aggregate ownership and other interests that confer effective influence in entities. (f) Singapore shall at least annually, make public a consolidated report that details for each covered entity: (A) the percentage of shares and the percentage of voting rights that Singapore and its government enterprises cumulatively own; (B) a description of any special shares or special voting or other rights that Singapore or its government enterprises hold; (C) the name and government title(s) of any government official serving as an officer or member of the board of directors; and (D) its annual revenue or total assets, or both, depending on the basis on which the enterprise qualifies as a covered entity. (g) Singapore shall also, on receipt from the US of a request regarding a specific enterprise, provide to the US the information listed above, for any enterprise that is 69 not a covered entity or an excluded enterprise, with the understanding that the information may be made public. There are also provisions on TRANSPARENCY AND INFORMATION REQUESTS. Each Party, at the request of the other Party shall make available public information concerning (a) the enforcement of its measures proscribing anticompetitive business conduct; (b) government enterprises, and designated monopolies, public or private. The requests shall indicate the entities involved, specify the particular products and markets concerned, and include some indicia that these entities may be engaging in practices that may hinder trade or investment between the Parties. (c) exemptions to its measures proscribing anticompetitive business conduct. Requests for such information shall specify the particular products and markets of concern and include some indicia that the exemption might hinder trade or investment between the Parties. An article on CONSULTATIONS states that to address specific matters that arise under this Chapter, the parties shall enter into consultations regarding representations made by a Party. In its request, the Party shall indicate how the matter affects trade or investment between the Parties. D. COMPETITION POLICY: IMPLICATIONS FOR MALAYSIA OF MUFTA Acceptance of the “competition” chapter would have serious implications for Malaysia in restricting the policy space that now exists in the operations and management of companies, both in the private and public sectors. Among the implications are the following. 1. Given the template of US FTAs, the competition chapter will contain disciplines on (1) Anticompetitive business conduct, (2) Designated Monopolies, and (3) government enterprises. These are very important areas affecting the structure of Malaysian companies in both private and public sectors. The FTA will thus have important effects on the structure and operations of Malaysian enterprises. There is a similar aim in these three topics: to mould the structure and behaviour and influence of local enterprises so that they do not block the full benefits of the FTA to be reaped by American companies. 2. Malaysia would have to enact a competition law within a short span of time. (Singapore committed to have a general legislation on competition just over a year after the FTA was completed). In itself having a competition law is not negative and can have positive effects, if it is properly formulated. However it is a complex exercise to formulate a competition law that is appropriate for development, in that it assists rather than undermines a national industrial policy, and that it does not hamper the expansion of domestic enterprises. Malaysia has been grappling with the dilemmas of establishing such an appropriate competition policy and law, and the law has yet to be finalized. However the FTA will commit Malaysia to enact a competition law and in a short period, i.e. it will fast track the process. Rushing into such a law is not wise; it should be introduced only when the appropriate elements are found. 70 3. The importance placed by the US on Malaysia’s competition law (and that it is in the US interest) is highlighted by the comment in the USTR report on trade barriers 2006: “Some U.S. companies have indicated a desire for measures regarding perceived anticompetitive practices in Malaysia. For example, the Malaysian government has not provided details of its proposed competition policy to local and foreign industry and has not sought public comments, despite U.S. government and industry requests for the opportunity to provide input on this proposed policy.” With the FTA, it will be easier for the US to provide inputs on how the competition law should be shaped. 3. The competition policy and law that Malaysia may have to adopt due to the FTA is likely to be inappropriate because the objective of the competition chapter biases the law towards the narrow goal of “proscribing” anti-competitive business practices that restrict bilateral trade and investment and prevent the benefits of the FTA (i.e. that would otherwise go to the US firms). The meaning of this is that certain Malaysian business practices and certain characteristics and activities of monopolies designated by the state and of government linked companies (GLCs) may hinder the ability of US companies to reap the full benefits of market access to Malaysia that they expect fom the FTA. The aim of the competition chapter is to have rules to discipline the business practices, the monopolies and the GLCs so that their freedom and powers are curbed, and that US companies can take full advantage of market access to Malaysia. In actual fact, this turns reality upside down. Because the US companies are so large and powerful, Malaysian companies require assistance and protection to enable them to survive and compete. Ironically, by removing the assistance and protection, the competition policy in the FTA will facilitate greater monopolization by the large foreign companies, thus eventually resulting in less competition and the weakening of the competitive position of local companies. 4. The competition law to be introduced by Malaysia will also be constrained by the conditions in the FTA that (a) government enterprises cannot be exempted; and (b) enforcement policy cannot discriminate on the basis of nationality. This has serious implications because (a) certain activities of government enterprises may be seen as “anti-competitive” from one angle but may be useful for development or social purposes from another angle, yet this “policy space” to have such activities or policies will now be eroded; (b) It may be beneficial to national policy and domestic enterprise growth to have a distinction between local and foreign firms in certain aspects of competition policy; this may now be difficult due to the FTA. 5. Regarding Designated Monopolies, Malaysia will be obliged to introduce conditions on the operation of the monopolies so as to minimize or eliminate “any nullification or impairment of benefits”. Another section of the FTA (on administration and dispute settlement) explains this phrase in context, that a Party can take the other Party to a dispute case if “a benefit the Party could reasonably have expected to accrue to it” under the Chapters on National Treatment and Market Access for Goods, on Rules of Origin, on Services or on Intellectual Property Rights is “being nullified or impaired as a result of a measure that is not inconsistent with this Agreement.” This is a provision with serious implications: it means that even if the government maintains a policy 71 measure that is consistent with (i.e. does not violate) the rules of the FTA, that measure could also be challenged in a dispute case by the US if that measure nullifies or impairs the benefits of the FTA expected to be gained by an American company. Malaysia would have to impose conditions on the designated monopolies so that their operations do not “nullify or impair” the benefits that would accrue to American companies. 6. Private or government monopolies designated by the government would also have to abide by many disciplines. The government will have to ensure these monopolies (a) act in ways that are not inconsistent with the FTA obligations when the monopoly exercises regulatory and administrative authority such as granting import or export licenses, approving commercial transactions, or imposing quotas, fees or other charges; (b) act solely in accordance with commercial considerations in its purchase or sale of the monopoly good or service in the relevant market, including with regard to price, quality, availability, marketability, transportation, etc. (c) provide non-discriminatory treatment to covered investments, to goods of the other Party, and to service suppliers of the other Party in its purchase or sale of the monopoly good or service in the relevant market; and (iv) do not use its monopoly position to engage directly or indirectly in anticompetitive practices in a non-monopolized market in its territory that adversely affect covered investments. 7. Malaysia would also have to adopt disciplines on government enterprises or Government Linked Companies (GLCs). The government would have to ensure that government enterprises: (a) act in a manner consistent with its FTA obligations when they exercise any governmental authority such as the power to expropriate, grant licenses, approve commercial transactions, or impose quotas, fees, or other charges; (b) act solely in accordance with commercial considerations in their purchase or sale of goods or services, such as with regard to price, quality, availability, marketability, transportation, and other terms and conditions of purchase or sale, and provides non-discriminatory treatment to covered investments, to goods of the United States, and to service suppliers of the United States, including with respect to its purchases or sales; (c) do not, either directly or indirectly, including through its dealings with its parent, subsidiaries, or other enterprises with common ownership enter into agreements among competitors that restrain competition on price or output or allocate customers; or engage in exclusionary practices that substantially lessen competition in a local market. 8. If the competition chapter is similar to the one in the Singapore-US FTA, the Malaysia would also be obliged to take no action or attempt in any way to influence or direct decisions of its government enterprises, including through the exercise of any rights or interests conferring effective influence over such enterprises. Malaysia would also be asked to commit to reducing, with a goal of substantially eliminating, its aggregate ownership and other interests that confer effective influence in entities. 9. Malaysia can also expect to be asked to make an annual report of details of each covered entity including: (a) the percentage of shares and the percentage of 72 voting rights that Malaysia and its government enterprises cumulatively own; (b) a description of any special shares or special voting or other rights that Malaysia or its government enterprises hold; (c) the name and government title(s) of any government official serving as an officer or member of the board of directors; and (d) its annual revenue or total assets, or both. On top of this, Malaysia shall also Singapore shall also provide to the US (on request) the information listed above, for any enterprise that is not a covered entity or an excluded enterprise, and the information may be made public. 10. All these obligations will place heavy obligations on Malaysia and its enterprises. It is beneficial for companies, especially monopolies and GLCs to be more efficient, transparent and accountable. However this should be a nationally initiated and based process, to meet national goals. The obligations placed in the FTA have the goal of ensuring that American companies can reap the full benefits promised by the formal opening of market access, by (a) disciplining the business practices of Malaysian companies, (b) ensuring the monopolies and GLCs give “non-discriminatory treatment” (i.e. national treatment) to American investments, goods and service suppliers; (c) preventing GLCs from having relationships or agreements with their parent companies or subsidiaries that restrain competition or engage in “exclusionary practices.” Although in an ideal situation Malaysian companies would be able to withstand and thrive in a totally free global environment, in reality the time for this is not yet ripe, as Malaysian companies are too small and not yet advanced in technology, management and marketing that can take on the full might of American companies. The companies receive certain advantages and preferential treatment from government, and government in return has some influence over the companies. The competition chapter’s provisions, if implemented, would cause many problems to private as well as governmentlinked companies. 11. This is not an argument for complacency, as there is a great need for greater efficiency, transparency and accountability of Malaysian companies, whether in the private or public sector. However this process of corporate reform should be a national exercise with the aim of benefiting consumers, the public welfare as well as the companies themselves which should operate more efficiently and competitively, while expanding their social functions and responsibilities as well. However it would be a mistake to place such a comprehensive “competition policy” within an FTA where the main objective is to benefit the American companies that want to enjoy the advantages of market access and national treatment. Placing competition policy in this context would skew this policy in the wrong direction, and in ways that are likely to undermine rather than enhance the growth of Malaysian enterprises and to foster greater competitiveness. 12. The manifestation of the US approach to competition can be seen in the FTA chapter on telecommunications, which spells out how American firms should be granted not only market access but telecom facilities, and rules on the relationship between GLCs and government authorities. 73 14. ENVIRONMENT, BIOSAFETY AND FOOD SAFETY A. BIOSAFETY AND LABELLING OF GENETICALLY MODIFIED ORGANISMS Malaysia can expect demands from the US in the MUFTA negotiations that it prohibit policies or laws that food and other products containing genetically modified organisms (GMOs) be labelled as such. This demand has been made in some other FTAs. Such a demand would affect at least two laws/regulations that Malaysia is enacting – the Biosafety Bill and the Food Act that require mandatory labelling for GMO products. Malaysia has a Biosafety Bill that has been presented to Parliament, which regulates activities related to genetically modified organisms (GMOs) and their products, given their potential environmental as well as health impacts. It is underpinned by a precautionary approach, in keeping with Malaysia’s obligations under the Cartagena Protocol on Biosafety. Malaysia has also been active in the international discussions under the Cartagena Protocol, including the on-going negotiations for an international regime on liability and redress for damage resulting from GMOs. The US is not a party to the Cartagena Protocol. The Biosafety Bill has an enabling clause that provides for the identification and labeling of GMOs and items containing GMOs. The Ministry of Health has also drafted regulations under the Food Act 1983 requiring the labelling of genetically modified foods. The proposed regulations are intended to give consumers proper information via labelling, as to whether a package contains genetically modified food or ingredients where the GM content is more than 3% of the total. There are several reasons why such labelling is important: 1) Labelling is important for consumer choice, so that consumers can choose whether or not they want to eat GM food. 2) There may be unintended effects of GMOs, such as potential allergenic effects (i.e. they can cause certain people to have allergies). Labelling would let consumers know of the GMO content of the food, and would serve to warn those who have legitimate health concerns. For example, a gene from a nut may be used in a GMO; since many people have potentially fatal nut allergies, they need to know the content of the food and labelling could meet this need. 3) Labelling informs consumers about GMO content, particularly those who may have religious, ethical or moral concerns. For example, if a pig gene was used in the making of a GM food, Muslim consumers could be informed by an appropriate label. 74 Likewise, if there are fish genes in GM tomatoes, vegetarians would need a label informing them that a food has a non-vegetarian GM gene. 4) Labelling would also push GMO exporting countries to segregate their GM and non-GM crops, shifting the burden to exporter countries, rather than to importing countries like Malaysia to detect and identify GMO shipments. More than 40 countries around the world, including China, Japan, Australia and most European nations, already require mandatory labelling of GM foods. Under the Codex Alimentarius Commission, the joint WHO/FAO body regulating international food standards, the Committee on Food Labelling has been discussing a global standard for mandatory GM food labelling. The draft standard on GM labelling has support from a majority of the Committee, including Malaysia. The US Bipartisan Trade Promotion Authority Act 2002 which grants the US Trade Representative negotiating authority (ie the fast track legislation) in Section 2102 ‘Trade Negotiation Objectives’ clearly states that “The principal negotiating objective of the United States with respect to agriculture is to obtain competitive opportunities for United States exports of agricultural commodities…. by—(viii) developing, strengthening, and clarifying rules and effective dispute settlement mechanisms to eliminate practices that unfairly decrease United States market access opportunities or distort agricultural markets to the detriment of the United States, particularly with respect to importsensitive products, including— (II) unjustified trade restrictions or commercial requirements, such as labeling, that affect new technologies, including biotechnology;’ (emphasis added). Besides the above law which mandates the USTR to oppose GMO labeling, US companies have also urged the USTR to use the FTA against the Malaysian measures. The Biotechnology Industry Organization (BIO) and the AMCHAM Malaysia/US Chamber of Commerce, in their public submissions to the USTR are against the mandatory labelling for genetically modified (GM) products or foods. They urge the USTR to take advantage of the FTA negotiations to forward their position against labelling of GM products or foods. The US biotech industry says that “…labelling of biotech foods will often mislead consumers by implying biotech foods are either different from conventional foods or present a potential risk.” (see Amcham Malaysia/US.Chamber of Commerce submission on MUFTA, pg 95, May 19,2006). Consequently, the US biotech industry has asked the US government to oppose such labelling in the MUFTA. The paper also make inappropriate comments on Malaysia’s national positions at the negotiations of the Cartagena Protocol on Biosafety. Given that some BIO members are also members of the USTR’s Advisory Committees, which are explicitly tasked to ensure that US trade policy and trade negotiation objectives adequately reflect US commercial and economic interests, there are grave concerns that the BIO industry interests will be reflected in the USTR’s FTA demands. 75 Malaysian consumer and other public health interested groups have supported the Malaysian government in having GM mandatory labelling provisions in the interest of consumer welfare and public health. Indeed, it is well established among concerned scientists that GM foods are not the same as conventional foods and are not devoid of risks to health and safety. Consumers have a right to know both for ethical and health reasons and must be given a choice as to whether they want to consume GM foods or not. It should be noted that Australia has signed an FTA with the US, yet it still has a mandatory labelling law in place. Thus Malaysia can demand that it be allowed to maintain its policies and laws on GM labeling (i.e. in the Biosafety Bill and the Food Act) and its position in international fora such as the Cartegna Protocol and the Convention on Biological Diversity. B. OTHER ENVIRONMENT ISSUES The MUFTA presents several other concerns in relation to the environment. Below are some of these concerns. 1. Convention on Biological Diversity Malaysia is a party to the Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD) and is a megadiverse country. The US is not a party to the CBD. Malaysia has been a strong advocate of international measures to counter bio-piracy and to ensure fair benefits to countries possessing biodiversity and traditional knowledge. To ensure that Malaysia’s biological resources are not taken, commericalised and patented outside of Malaysia, and to ensure that equitable benefits flow back to the country and to the indigenous people and local communities, Malaysia’s position has been that a strong international regime on access and benefit sharing is required. This is currently being negotiated under the CBD. Countries such as Peru and Colombia (which are megadiverse countries that were strongly in favour of an international legal framework to regulate access to genetic resources and ensure equitable benefit sharing) have had to sign a side letter as part of their USFTAs which reverses their position and agrees that mere contracts (instead of a global treaty) are sufficient to address access and benefit sharing concerns. Contracts between unequal parties have not proven to be sufficient to stop biopiracy or ensure equitable benefit sharing, and Malaysia should not change its stance on this issue because of a similar potential side letter in MUFTA. 76 2. Environmental implications in relation to the Investment chapter All US FTAs have certain provisions in the investment chapter which have serious implications for environmental policy and measures. These provisions and their implications will also apply to MUFTA. As a result, environmental measures taken by the Malaysian government to protect the environment may be challenged as “expropriation”, which is defined broadly, leading to an obligation to compensate US investors and/or change Malaysian laws, regulations, measures etc. US companies will be given the right to sue the Malaysian government directly, and if the Malaysian government does not pay the compensation due, then the US government can impose tariffs on any Malaysian export. Many cases involving environmental measures have been taken against Canada, mexico and the US under their North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). Cases such as these can be expected against countries like Malaysia signing on to FTAs with the US. Among the environment-related cases under NAFTA are the following: The United States has been sued by Methanex, a Canadian corporation, as the state of California had phased out a chemical additive that contaminates the ground water. The company is seeking damages of USD 970 million. (Methanex case) Canada’s environmental regulation that banned a chemical that causes global warming and is a neurotoxin was challenged by US corporation Ethyl, which sought compensation of USD 250 million. The case was settled and Ethyl was paid USD 13 million. (Ethyl case) US chemical company Crompton has challenged a voluntary agreement established by Canada to restrict production of the chemical lindane (a pesticide that is a possible carcinogen). Crompton is seeking damages of USD 100 million. (Crompton case) Canadian company Galmis Gold is seeking compensation of USD 50 million from the United States for a California regulation that requires backfilling and restoration of open pit mines that would damage Native American sacred sites. (Glamis Gold case) US firm Metalcald sued Mexico for USD 90 million, challenging a Mexican municipality’s refusal to grant a construction permit for a toxic waste dump and the governor’s declaration of an ecological preserve surrounding the site. Metalclad won and USD 15.6 million was paid in compensation (Metalclad case) A Canadian temporary ban on hazardous PCB exports was challenged by US waste treatment company, S.D. Myers. The temporary ban was put in place while Canada was considering its obligations under the Basel Convention on the Control of Transboundary Movements of Hazardous Wastes and Their Disposal. S.D. Myers sued for USD 20 million, won the case and was paid USD 4.8 million. (Myers case) 77 Not all these cases have been decided in favour of the foreign investor yet, but it indicates the possible ways that companies may use the investment chapter to challenge environmental measures. Even if the company does not sue, the mere threat of legal action may be enough to prevent governments from carrying out policies that are put in place to protect the environment. When investors have such strong rights, we are concerned about Malaysia’s ability to fulfill its obligations under multilateral environment agreements (MEAs) such as the CBD, the Cartagena Protocol on Biosafety, the Kyoto Protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change and the Basel Convention on the Control of Transboundary Movements of Hazardous Wastes and Their Disposal, none of which the US is a Party to. If Malaysia’s obligation under an MEA constitutes expropriation, Malaysia will face the invidious choice of violating its MEA obligation or having to pay compensation at fair market value, including interest at a commercially reasonable rate. Nothing in existing USFTAs allays these fears because USFTA provisions still require environmental measures to be consistent with the investment chapter. 3. Government procurement and implications for the environment There are also legitimate concerns about the restrictions the government procurement chapter of USFTAs puts on the ability to specify environmentally-friendly products or processes. For example it may prevent Malaysia from being able to specify that: food for Malaysian Government canteens, hospitals or schools comes from local farmers (to reduce transport miles, the amount of preservatives and the amount of packaging) food procured by the Malaysian Government is not genetically modified, notwithstanding any Malaysian biosafety laws or decisions made under them products supplied to the Malaysian Government should be made of recycled materials, e.g. paper, or materials that are less ozone-depleting. 15. INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS (IPRS) A. BACKGROUND 1. WTO’s TRIPS Agreement The introduction of IPRs as an issue with binding rules within a trade agreement was very controversial, and remains so, after the TRIPS Agreement was incorporated within the WTO. Since then, many economists ranging from Joseph Stiglitz to Jagdish Bhagwati have decried the inclusion of IPRs and TRIPS in the WTO. 78 There is a growing realisation that high IPR standards, promoted by TRIPS to developing countries, are inappropriate to the development needs of developing countries. In particular, the former head of the World Bank’s trade research department, Michael Finger, estimated that the cost to developing countries of implementing their TRIPS obligations amounts to US$60 billion annually, and that this more than offsets the gains they may expect to benefit from expanded market access in agriculture and textiles in the Uruguay Round. (Khor 2005). There is now a movement by developing countries to clarify some aspects of TRIPS or to amend them, to reduce the more developmentally-negative aspects. For instance the Doha Declaration on TRIPS and Public Health has clarified that developing countries can make use of “flexibilities” such as compulsory licenses to offset the monopoly privileges of patent holders. Developing countries are also trying to have TRIPS amended to deal with the problem of “biopiracy”, by requiring that patent applications involving biological resources be accompanied by disclosure of the countries of origin and evidence of benefit-sharing arrangements with these countries. Moreover, TRIPS requires some life forms to be patented (microorganisms and micro-biological processes) but allows the prohibition of patenting of other lifeforms (plants and animals), and gives countries the leeway to define what is an invention and thus what is patentable. The TRIPS agreement requires that IP protection be granted to plant breeders for plant varieties, while previously this was an issue for each country to decide on. However, TRIPS allows countries flexibility to define their own “sui generis” system of protection for plant varieties. Countries can provide for farmers’ rights to save and use seeds. 2. IPR negotiations shift to FTAs As WTO negotiators have become more aware of the development dimensions of IPRs, the developed countries have tried to introduce even higher standards of IP globally through the WIPO. However, many developing countries have now started a movement to establish a “development agenda” within WIPO. They have also resisted attempts at harmonizing patent and copyright laws at even higher standards. Thus, there is now an attempt by the developed countries to seek the forum of the FTA to: (a) remove or reduce the flexibilities in the TRIPS agreement and (b) establish even higher standards of IPRs in developing countries. IP is thus a major item in bilateral FTAs, and countries like the US and Japan are keen to have their interests furthered, beyond what is in the WTO-TRIPS agreement. The FTAs threaten the use of TRIPS flexibilities in relation to (a) patents and access to medicines; (b) IP protection of plant varieties with respect to the sui generis system, and the rights of farmers; biodiversity; (c) the ability to ban patenting of some lifeforms. There may also be a potential for FTAs to make it more difficult for countries to have disclosure requirements with respect to patent applications involving biological resources. Some FTAs also oblige developing countries to have tighter 79 copyright legislation, with adverse effects on technology transfer or access to information and information technology. Prior to TRIPS, countries were able to tailor their level of IP protection to suit their level of development. Many of today’s industrialised countries such as the USA, Europe,5 Japan, South Korea and Taiwan did not have high levels of IP protection until it suited them. For example Switzerland did not allow patents on chemicals until 1978; Italy, Sweden and Switzerland did not allow patents on medicines until 19786 and Spain did not allow patents on chemicals or medicines until 1992 because it said it could not afford the higher medicine prices as a result of patents. According to the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, ‘development objectives need to be integrated into the making of policy on intellectual property rights’7 and there should be wide-ranging consultations before any changes to IP laws are made to ensure they are in line with development objectives in agriculture, health and industry.8 In addition, it emphasizes that ‘developing countries will incur significant costs if they rush to establish an IP regime that is inappropriate to their level of development.’9 According to the 9th Malaysia Plan, in 2005 there was already estimated to be a net outflow of royalties of RM5.7billion.10 This is not surprising given that 98% of patents granted in Malaysia are to foreigners (see below). This is not unusual, ‘almost without exception, developing countries are net importers of technology.’11 Even in an industrialized country like Australia 90% of patents are granted to foreigners according to government statistics.12 Most countries in the world are net intellectual property importers, except those such as the USA and European Union. If Malaysia broadens and lengthens its intellectual property protection while it still has less capacity to generate its own intellectual property, it can expect to see the royalty outflow increase. 5 Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, Study Paper 1a, Intellectual Property and Economic Development: Lessons from American and European History, B Zorina Khan. 6 Human Development Report 2001, United Nations Development Programme. 77 Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page i. 8 ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 161. 9 ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 162. 10 Page 264. 11 ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm. 12 http://www.ipaustralia.gov.au/about/statistics.shtml 80 While the US insists that the intellectual property (IP) chapter of the MUFTA negotiations, like all chapters, is kept secret, it is possible to ascertain the likely US demands based on existing USFTAs. The USA is a net IP exporter13 and so if it can obtain broader and longer periods of IP protection, the profits of its companies will increase. Apart from the costs to users of IP listed below, implementing and enforcing an IP regime is ‘costly’.14 ‘In developing countries, where human and financial resources are scarce, and legal systems not well developed, the opportunity costs of operating the system effectively are high. Those costs include the costs of scrutinising the validity of claims to patent rights (both at the application stage and in the courts) and adjudicating upon actions for infringement. Considerable costs are generated by the inherent uncertainties of litigation.’15 3. Industry influence The USTR has long promoted the interests of its industries that have heavy IP protection such as pharmaceuticals, software and films and television. The USTR is advised by these private sector industries via committees whose role according to the USTR is ‘to ensure that U.S. trade policy and trade negotiation objectives adequately reflect U.S. commercial and economic interests.’16 These committees include the pharmaceutical companies, chemical companies, Biotechnology Industry Organization, copyright owners such as Time Warner, International Intellectual Property Alliance, Recording Industry Association of America, Intellectual Property Owners Association, Motion Picture Association of America.17 The pharmaceutical industry spent US$91.4million on 675 lobbyists to engage members of the US Congress and Administration.18 This is seven lobbyists per US ‘Between 1991 and 2001, the net US surplus of royalties and fees (which mainly relate to IP transactions) increased from $14 billion to over $22 billion. In 1999, figures from the World Bank indicate a deficit for developing countries for which figures are available of $7.5 billion on royalties and licence fees.’ Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 21 14 Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 15. 15 Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 15. 16 http://www.ustr.gov/Who_We_Are/Mission_of_the_USTR.html 13 17 http://www.ustr.gov/assets/Who_We_Are/Advisory_Committee_Lists/asset_upload_file936_5742.pdf and http://www.ustr.gov/assets/Who_We_Are/Advisory_Committee_Lists/asset_upload_file232_5754.pdf 18 Third World Resurgence 167/168, page 17. 81 Senator.19 It also makes contributions to US election campaigns. For example the top 25 pharmaceutical firms donated US$48.6million from 1997-2002.20 By contrast, the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights states that the imperative ‘is for developed countries to ensure that their policy objectives for IP standards in regional/bilateral trade agreements are demonstrably consistent with their broader objectives for promoting international development and poverty reduction… Negotiators for developed countries need to take account of the costs to developing countries of higher IP standards, as well as the benefits to their own industries.’21 Given development objectives, it goes on to say that ‘it would be unwise to let IP policy be influenced by domestic industrial and commercial interest groups in developed countries.’22 B. MUFTA WILL OBLIGE MALAYSIA TO SIGN UP TO MANY INTERNATIONAL IP TREATIES One of the key aspects of the IPR chapter in US FTAs is that the parties have to sign up to many international intellectual property treaties, some of them under the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO). Malaysia is a member of WIPO, but it has signed only some of the treaties. In the MUFTA negotiations, the US will most likely insist that Malaysia join many treaties which are beneficial to the US but may not be for Malaysia. These treaties include: The Patent Cooperation Treaty (WIPO). The WIPO Copyright Treaty (WIPO) The WIPO Performances and Phonograms Treaty International Union for the Protection of New Varieties of Plants (UPOV 1991). Budapest Treaty on the International Recognition of the Deposit of Microorganisms for the Purposes of Patent Procedure Malaysia is a member of the Patent Cooperation Treaty but not of the other four. There are good reasons for Malaysia’s reluctance to join many of the treaties located in or administered by WIPO. For example, the Commission on Intellectual Property 19 Third World Resurgence 167/168, page 17. Third World Resurgence 167/168, page 17. 21 ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 162-3. 22 ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 163. 20 82 Rights in its report stated: ‘Developing countries should think very carefully before joining the WIPO Copyright Treaty.’23 WIPO is ‘a firm advocate of stronger IP protection in developing countries. Indeed, the analyses in WIPO’s various published policy documents pay little attention to the possible adverse consequences of such protection.’24 Furthermore, depending on the year, about 90% of its funding comes from patent applicants. 25 According to the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, ‘WIPO has always been responsive to the needs of the industrial sectors which make intensive use of IP. We are less persuaded that it is as responsive to the interests of consumers or users of IP-protected products.’26 Due to a perceived bias towards stronger intellectual property protection in a way that undermined the work of other United Nations agencies such as the World Health Organization and the United Nations Development Programme, developing country governments are trying to reform WIPO to make it more development oriented via a ‘Development Agenda’. This has been echoed by the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government. Given the concerns above about the impact of stronger IP protection on development, including access to knowledge, Malaysia should be very cautious about entering any treaties that require stronger IP protection and cross-sectoral consultations and detailed cost-benefit analyses should be conducted before any decision is made. Analysis of the nature and effects of the above treaties are made in this report in various sections below. C. IMPACT OF MUFTA ON ACCESS TO MEDICINES Before the WTO’s TRIPS Agreement, countries were allowed to exempt medicines from being granted patents. This made it easier for these countries to make or import generic drugs (i.e. drugs made by generic producers rather than the brand-name drugs made by “originator” companies) that are usually much cheaper. After the TRIPS agreement, it was compulsory to allow for patents for medicines. This made it more difficult to promote the generics. But there are many “flexibilities” in TRIPS which countries can use (such as compulsory license). However the FTAs with the US erodes or removes many of these flexibilities. ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 109 24 ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 157. 25 ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 157. 26 ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 159. 23 83 Generic medicines are chemically the same as branded medicines. For example the branded version of paracetamol is called ‘Panadol’ and is made by GlaxoSmithKline (who once had a patent on it) but the generic version of paracetamol could be made by a Malaysian generic medicine company such as Hovid Berhad. Generic medicines have been tested by the Malaysian Government to ensure they are just as safe and effective as the branded version. Malaysian academics found that patented medicines can be 1,044% more expensive than their generic equivalents in Malaysia.27 Malaysia has generic medicine manufacturers that can manufacture more than 80% of the product categories in the National Essential Drugs List of Malaysia.28 Based on previous US FTAs which are all very similar, if the Malaysia-US free trade agreement (MUFTA) is signed, Malaysia will have to make a number of changes to its laws including to allow: patents on more medicines, the patents to last for longer and monopolies for a number of years even when there are no patents via ‘data exclusivity’, none of which are required by TRIPS. In the WTO Doha Ministerial, developing countries had their rights under the WTO’s TRIPS agreement reconfirmed that they are able to offset patents through compulsory licences, government use and parallel importing, including for medicines. The flexibilities available for policy measures to promote access to cheap medicines were spelt out. However, US bilateral FTAs with several countries or groupings are limiting the flexibilities or measures that are permitted in WTO. The result is that the developing country in the FTA would now find it more difficult or impossible to undertake measures such as compulsory licensing or “government use” to provide cheaper generic drugs to patients. Examples of this include the following (the first four listed below are from the Médecins Sans Frontières paper, “Access to Medicines at Risk Across the Globe”) include: (a) Data exclusivity. The WTO does not require “data exclusivity”, i.e. that data submitted by a patent holder to drug regulatory authorities (to obtain marketing approval for safety) cannot be made use of as part of the drug regulatory approval process undertaken by other applicants. Thus, a generic producer (which is given permission, for example under a compulsory license, to sell or produce a generic version of a patented drug) can make use of that data when it seeks safety approval from the drug regulatory authority. However, in bilateral FTAs the US seeks to establish or expand “exclusive rights” over test data provided by the originator companies to prevent generic companies from registering an equivalent generic version of the drug, thus preventing or making it difficult for a compulsory licence to take effect, and effectively curbing the supply of generic drugs. It should be noted that this “data exclusivity” applies even to generic versions of drugs that are not ‘TRIPS, Patents, Technology Transfer, Foreign Direct Investment and the Pharmaceutical Industry in Malaysia’, Ida Madieha Azmi and Rokiah Alavi, Journal of World Intellectual Property, Vol 4 No. 6, November 2001. 28 http://www.mopi.org.my/home.html 27 84 patented. If this provision is adopted in MUFTA, it would seriously harm the Malaysian generic drug industry; and also severely affect the Malaysian consumers’ ability to make use of imported generic drugs. [This limitation is in the US-Singapore agreement and all other recent US FTAs]. (b) Extending patent life span. Patents on drugs last 20 years from date of filing in most countries. This is the WTO requirement; before the TRIPS agreement, many countries granted drug patents for fewer years Through the FTA, the US is seeking extend the life of the patent beyond the 20 year period. It says that drug companies need to be “compensates” for any “unreasonable” time a national drug authority or patent office takes to examine or approve an application. The life of the patent would be extended by the “unreasonable time” taken. This extension measure is in all the US FTAs since NAFTA. (c) Evergreening the patent. Drug companies try to renew patents after they expire by applying for new patents for “new uses” of the same product. This practice has ben descriobed as “evergreening” the patent. Under WTO, members are not obliged to grant patents on new uses of existing substances. The US wants provisions in FTAs to allow companies to apply for new patents for each “new use” of a product, thus allowing the patent protection to continue beyond the expiry date of the patent. Patents on new uses are required by several USFTAs. (d) Limitation to conditions for compulsory license. TRIPS allows countries to issue compulsory licenses (to companies or government agencies to produce or import generic versions of a drug that has been patented) and does not restrict conditions for their use. The Doha Declaration on TRIPs and Public Health confirms that countries have “the freedom to determine the ground upon which such licenses are granted.” However, the United States’ FTAs seek to limit the circumstances under which compulsory licenses on drugs are issued. For example, the US-Singapore FTA allows compulsory licenses only for remedying anti-competitive practice by the patent holder; for public non-commercial use; and in the case of national emergency or circumstances of extreme urgency. Such limitations erodes the “policy space” available to the government to issue compulsory licenses. Limitations on compulsory licensing grounds are required by several USFTAs. (e) “Linkage” or making the drug regulatory authority play the role of a “patent police”. Before medicines can be sold, they need “marketing approval” from the Health Ministry’s drug regulatory authority to confirm that the drug is safe and beneficial. The drug authority does not normally have jurisdiction over patents or the patent status of the drug. However, many FTAs with the US have changed the role of the drug authority by making them part of the “patent police.” Some FTAs require that the DRA “shall not grant marketing approval to any third party prior to the expiration of the patent term unless by consent of the patent owner”. This is not required by TRIPS. This effectively prevents generic products from being available through the whole patent term. This means any compulsory licence or government use order would be ineffective for the whole patent term as any generic medicine produced or imported under such a licence/order could not be registered and so could not reach patients. 85 This drastically curtails the ability of governments to ensure the health of their citizens, particularly in emergencies such as bird flu or SARS. Furthermore, these provisions significantly alter the role of the DRA by requiring the DRA on receiving a registration application for a generic version, to enquire: (1) whether there is a patent claimed in the developing country for that generic product, (2) whether that the developing country patent is in force (ie the fees have been paid), (3) whether the patent actually covers the generic medicine as generic manufacturers usually change their version enough to avoid infringing the patent. Ascertaining this can take the courts up to 10 years, expert witnesses, thousands of documents and millions of dollars. It is not an easy question which the DRA with no patent expertise can determine; and (4) whether consent has been granted by the patent owner if all of the above occur. Historically, the duty of the DRA has been to ensure that a drug is safe, effective and of sufficient quality before it registers the drug. It is the patent office’s task to ensure that patents meet the criteria of patentability and ultimately the courts are the only authority that can determine if a patent is valid and has been infringed by a generic product. This linkage of marketing approval to the patent term has been so controversial that countries such as the Philippines,i the European Union and Australia have explicitly refused to do it. Australia was eventually pressured to do it in the FTA it signed with the USA. The European Union’s DRA argues that it does not have the training, skills, expertise or capacity to determine such questions of patent status. In fact the US Food and Drug Administration, which is required by law to do linkage, has also admitted that it does not have the capacity to do it. [This linkage is required by all recent USFTAs]. (f) Effective prevention of parallel importation. Parallel importation is one of the key methods of keeping medicines affordable. It involves legitimately importing the branded product from another country where it is sold more cheaply (for example because of price controls in that other country). TRIPS allows parallel importation as developing countries fought to retain that right. Some US FTAs have effectively prevented parallel importation by requiring countries to prevent it if the patent holder has not consented to it. Since patent holders in practice will never consent, parallel importation will be made impossible. However, the US Congress has recently refused to fund the inclusion in any new FTAs of the provisions restricting parallel importation that are found in some existing US FTAs. This decision by Congress should allow Malaysia to reject any proposed restrictions on parallel importation in US FTA negotiations. The Effects The above FTA provisions result in the government taking on IPR obligations more than what the WTO requires, which are often termed “TRIP-Plus.” The World Health Organization has an economic model of the impact of these ‘TRIPS-Plus’ provisions 86 on medicine consumption and a country’s generic medicine manufacturers. The model predicts that the full impact of medicine price rises will not be felt until about 15 years after the USFTA begins because the stronger IP protection only applies to each new medicine so it will not affect all medicines in a country and the overall medicine price until about 15 years has passed. The extension to patent terms has been calculated by the Korean National Health Insurance Corporation to cost 504.5 billion won (US$529 million) for having to extend drug patents for 3 years and 722.5 billion won (US$757 million) if it has to agree to a four year extension in its USFTA negotiations.29 It was recently estimated that eight years of data exclusivity alone in Canada would have added $600 million to prescription medicine costs alone in the last five years.30 Malaysia was considered a world leader when it issued a type of compulsory licence to import the cheaper generic version of patented medicines for people with AIDS. It reduced the average cost of treatment per patient per month by 81% and more than doubled the number of patients who could be treated.31 Many other countries saw Malaysia as a role model. If this USFTA is signed, there will be significant restrictions on Malaysia’s ability to issue compulsory licences in future. The Thai Government recently issued compulsory licences for 3 types of medicines and estimates that it could save it up to US$24million each year.32 Many have expressed their concerns about the way the intellectual property provisions found in USFTAs make medicines more expensive, including the United Nations Special Rapporteur on the Right to Health,33 the World Health Assembly,34 the WHO’s Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, Innovation and Public Health,35 Ministers of Health from ten Latin American countries,36 the Ministers of Health37 of the African Union, the African Union’s Ministers of Trade38, the UK 29 http://english.hani.co.kr/arti/english_edition/e_business/165065.html http://www.canadiangenerics.ca/en/news/nov_14_06.shtml 31 ‘Malaysia’s experience in increasing access to antiretroviral drugs: exercising the ‘government use’ option’, Chee Yoke Ling, Intellectual Property Rights Series No. 9, Third World Network, 2006. Earlier version available from http://www.twnside.org.sg/title2/FTAs/Intellectual_Property/IP_and_Access_to_Medicines/Malaysia's ExperienceInIncreasingAccessToAntiretroviralDrugs-CheeYokeLing%5BOct05%5D.docs 32 http://www.bangkokpost.net/breaking_news/breakingnews.php?id=116803 33 Press Release, 5 July 2004, http://www.unhchr.ch/huricane/huricane.nsf/view01/35C240E546171AC1C1256EC800308A37?opend ocument 34 WHA56.27, May 2003, http://www.who.int/gb/ebwha/pdf_files/WHA56/ea56r27.pdf 35 ‘Public health, Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights’, World Health Organization, April 2006. For example recommendation 4.21. 36 Declaration of Ministers of South America over Intellectual Property, Access to Medicines and Public Health, Geneva, 23 May 2006. The Ministers of Health were from Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay and Venezuela, http://lists.essential.org/pipermail/ip-health/2006-May/009594.html. 37 Gaborone Declaration, 2nd Ordinary Session of the Conference of African Ministers of Health, Gaborone, Botswana, 10-14 October 2005, CAMH/Decl.1(II), http://lists.essential.org/pipermail/iphealth/2005-October/008440.html. 30 87 Government’s Commission on Intellectual Property Rights 39 and Nobel Peace Prize winning Doctors Without Borders40. There have also been many expressions of concern by Malaysians, including the Malaysian generic drug industry, Malaysians living with HIV/AIDS, consumer organisations and health organisations. The government of the state of Western Australia was concerned about the impact of the Australia-USFTA on medicine prices in Australia. They noted that ‘PBS data indicates that the prices of brand name (patented) drugs fall by an average of more than 30 per cent after patent expiration and the entry of generic medicines. Delays to the availability of generic pharmaceuticals will therefore significantly increase pharmaceutical expenditures in Australia over time particularly in hospitals where generic brands are used extensively… A rise in medicine costs through the PBS and any delays in the availability of generic equivalent medicines will have a direct impact upon the cost of medicines purchased by the public sector. Medicines are the second most expensive item after salaries in the health budget and a small increase in costs in addition to the implementation of new medicines in the market will have a significant impact upon the health budget.’41 Significant damage to the local generic medicine industry from USFTAs has also been predicted. For example Korean Health and Welfare Minister Yoo Si-min said, ‘Under free trade talks, the damage to the South Korean pharmaceutical industry may total between 600 billion won to 1 trillion won (US$629 million-1.05 billion) if the U.S. proposal is accepted.’42 The World Health Organization’s model predicted that the Colombia-USFTA would cause the Colombian generic industry to lose 71% of its market share. If Malaysia wishes to encourage more research and development and innovation, the evidence is not clear that stronger intellectual property protection will achieve this. If Malaysia wants more foreign direct investment, again the evidence does not indicate that weak IP protection discourages investment.43 Indeed International Trade and Industry Minister Datuk Seri Rafidah Aziz said that Malaysia’s existing regulations on intellectual property protection provide adequate protection for US investors to encourage them to come to Malaysia.44 The Federation of Malaysian Manufacturers has also taken the position that Malaysia’s current level of intellectual AU’s Ministerial Declaration on EPA Negotiations, AU Conference of Ministers of Trade, 3rd Ordinary Session, 5-9 June 2005, Cairo, Egypt, AU/TI/MIN//DECL.(III), www.twnside.org.sg/title2/FTAs/General/AFRICAN_UNION.Cairo_Decl.doc. 39 ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy: Report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights’, Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, London, 2002. For example, pages 39, 49, 113. 40 ‘Access to Medicines at Risk Across the Globe’, Briefing Note, MSF Campaign for Access to Essential Medicines, May 2004, www.accessmed-msf.org/documents/ftabriefingenglish.pdf. 41 Western Australian Government Submission to Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America 42 http://english.hani.co.kr/arti/english_edition/e_business/165065.html 43 Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 23. 44 Business Times 21 July 2006 38 88 property protection is strong enough and should not be increased in MUFTA negotiations.45 In conclusion, the following can be expected to be the results of MUFTA on access to medicines: 1. There will be severe curtailment on the supply and availability of cheaper generic medicines. The biggest victims will be Malaysian patients suffering from a wide range of ailments, who will have to pay much more. If the prices are too high, this has a tremendous effect on access to medicine and to the people’s health. 2. The Malaysian generic industry will be affected by the clauses on “data exclusivity” and “linkage” (rejecting the generic drugs’ marketing approval if the drugs are patented). At least one company has announced shifting its operations to India because of the damaging effects that an FTA with the US would entail. 3. The Ministry of Health will have to pay for the higher costs of medicines as a result of the FTA. 4. As 98% of the patents granted in Malaysia belong to foreign firms, there are already tremendous amounts of royalty that flow out of the country. According to the 9th Malaysia Plan, in 2005 there was already estimated to be a net outflow of royalties of RM5.7billion.46 This is not surprising given that 98% of patents granted in Malaysia are to foreigners (see below). If Malaysia broadens and lengthens its intellectual property protection while it still has less capacity to generate its own intellectual property, it can expect to see the royalty outflow increase. D. EFFECTS ON PATENTING OF LIFE, BIODIVERSITY, GENETIC RESOURCES, AGRICULTURE AND FARMERS 1. Background The FTA will have serious effects on an inter-related set of issues: patenting of lifeforms (especially micro-organisms), biodiversity and traditional knowledge, agriculture and the income and interests of farmers (especially the saving, control and use of seeds). This is because: 1. At present, the WTO’s TRIPS agreement allows countries to exclude the patenting of plants and animals. However some US FTAs (for example with Chile) oblige the country to make available “patent protection for plants that are new, involve an inventive step and are capable of industrial application.” 2. The TRIPS agreement makes it mandatory for WTO members to patent microorganisms and certain microbiological processes. However it is left to members to 45 See its position paper available from http://www.fmm.org.my/p_ne_it.asp?NewsID=986&ThemeID=300&From=ThemeNews 46 Page 264. 89 determine what types of micro-organisms to allow for patenting. For example, some countries do not allow patenting of naturally-occurring micro-oragnisms. Malaysia’s Patent Act only allows for the patenting of “man-made microorganisms”. Malaysia, like many developing countries, interprets this to exclude naturally-occurring microorganisms. The US FTAs usually require the parties to sign up to the Budapest Treaty on the International Recognition of the Deposit of Microorganisms for the Purposes of Patent Procedure, which increases patenting of micro-organisms. 3. The TRIPS agreement allows WTO members the choice of patenting plant varieties or establishing a “sui generis” system of intellectual protection for plant varieties. This gives countries the freedom to chose their own system, and some countries have stressed the right of farmers to save and re-use their seed. However the US FTAs oblige countries to be members of the UPOV 1991 treaty, which provides a lot of rights to plant breeders and companies, while the rights of farmers to save and re-use seeds are very limited. Malaysia has been a leading part of developing countries’ striving to use international conventions such as the Biodiversity Convention (CBD) to establish the sovereign right of countries to their genetic resources and to prevent the misappropriation of their biological resources (bio-piracy) through patenting. However, the FTA will eliminate or greatly reduce the ability of the country to protect its rights. 2. UPOV 1991, Plant Varieties protection and Effect on Farmers’ Rights The US FTA obligation to protect new plant varieties (NPV) also raises concerns. The WTO TRIPS Agreement leaves it to Members to protect NPV by patents or a sui generis system or a combination of both. Exercising that right, Malaysia enacted in 2004 a sui generis law to protect NPV that balances the protection of commercial plant breeders with the protection of traditional farmers who also breed NPV. Biosafety concerns are also incorporated in the Malaysian law. On the other hand, the US is a party to the International Convention for the Protection of New Varieties of Plants which set up the International Union for the Protection of New Varieties of Plants (UPOV). Adopted in 1961, and revised in 1972, 1978 and 1991 each revision of this agreement has led to more benefits for institutional/commercial plant breeders by according them higher and higher IP protection. The majority of developing countries have chosen not to be a party to UPOV and so of the current 63 UPOV Members, only a few are from developing countries and most of these are members of UPOV 1978. New members can only adopt UPOV 1991 which would disadvantage small farmers, which constitute the vast majority of farmers in developing countries. Pressures are increasing via bilateral FTAs with the US to join UPOV 1991. All the US FTAs since NAFTA (including the one with Singapore) oblige the parties to be members of UPOV 1991. Plant varieties are types of the same plant, for example D24 is a durian variety. Plant varieties are often developed by multinational agriculture companies such as Monsanto. These ‘plant breeders’ in laboratories want to maximize their profits by restricting what farmers can do with the plant varieties they develop. This means that like any other intellectual property (IP) legislation, plant variety protection has to find 90 the appropriate balance between the user (in this case the farmer) and the ‘creator’ (plant breeder) of the IP. Even among plant breeders, there is a need to balance between public researchers in developing countries such as Malaysia and foreign researchers in order to ensure that the fruits of research and the use of materials from those developing countries will primarily benefit the countries concerned. The strongest type of IP protection would be a patent on the plant and/or plant variety as this would stop or restrict the farmer from being able to save seed from one crop to re-plant or exchange it with another farmer, as well as prevent or restrict the use of the patented materials for further research by others. TRIPS does not require WTO member countries to allow patents on: plants, animals or plant varieties. However some FTAs with the US (e.g. Chile) require the parties to allow patenting of plants. The second strongest form of intellectual property protection for plant varieties is via a 1991 version of a treaty on plant variety protection called the International Convention for the Protection of New Varieties of Plants (UPOV). TRIPS does not require countries to join UPOV 1991. UPOV was ‘designed with the commercialised farming systems of the developed countries in mind.’47 UPOV 1991 favours formal plant breeders (in laboratories) and does not sufficiently safeguard the right of small farmers to breed and develop new plant varieties. The balance between farmers and formal plant breeders is more in favour of farmers in UPOV 1978, but Malaysia can no longer join UPOV 1978. As it is allowed to by TRIPS, Malaysia has a sui generis law to protect new plant varieties called the Protection of New Plant Varieties Act 2004. So far Malaysia has decided against joining UPOV 1991 and this is appropriate because at Malaysia’s current stage of research and development in agriculture, in practice UPOV 1991 would allow breeders’ rights to be claimed by foreign researchers rather than local farmers or researchers. Malaysia’s sui generis law has been regarded as a model for other countries because of the protection it offers farmers and its better balance that could build local research capacity. However every country signing a USFTA since the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) in 1994 has had to sign UPOV 1991. Malaysia is not a party to UPOV 1991, but the USA is. If Malaysia has to join UPOV 1991, some of the changes it would have to make to its tailor-made sui generis regime would be: a) To remove the protection Malaysia’s law currently gives to farmers and indigenous people who have developed varieties themselves over the millennia in the field. This 15 years of protection helps to prevent biopiracy (where others take their plant resources and make profits without their prior informed consent or providing them with a fair and equitable share of the benefits). UPOV 1991 essentially only gives legal protection to formal laboratory techniques. b) The deletion of the Malaysian law’s provisions that allow: small farmers to exchange seeds amongst themselves and to sell the farmer’s farm-saved ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 61. 47 91 seeds if the farmer cannot make use of them because of natural disaster, emergency or other factors beyond the farmer’s control. UPOV 1991 would instead require a compulsory licence to be applied for if farmers wanted to sell their farm-saved seed in this situation. This is more difficult, time consuming and not an automatic right the way Malaysia’s Act allows. c) To reduce the situations in which a compulsory licence can be issued (to overcome plant variety protection). d) The deletion of Malaysia’s right to prohibit the registration of plant varieties that may cause a negative impact on the environment. e) The deletion of Malaysia’s protections against biopiracy. (Malaysia’s Act requires applications for plant variety protection to include items such as the source of the genetic resource, prior written consent of the indigenous people or local community if they developed it from traditional varieties and evidence that it has complied with any law regulating genetically modified organisms if the plant variety was developed via genetic engineering). f) The deletion of Malaysia’s safeguards to ensure plant varieties developed from Malaysian samples are available in Malaysia for example for local researchers to work on. 3. Budapest Treaty on the International Recognition of the Deposit of Microorganisms for the Purposes of Patent Procedure The Budapest Treaty on the International Recognition of the Deposit of Microorganisms for the Purposes of Patent Procedure (Budapest Treaty) is about microorganisms. Microorganisms are not defined in TRIPS and so could be bacteria, cells, enzymes, proteins, genes etc. TRIPS does not require countries to join the Budapest Treaty. Malaysia is not currently a party to the Budapest Treaty, but the USA is. Almost all USFTAs have required the countries signing them to join the Budapest Treaty. The Budapest Treaty aims to make it easier for people to get patents in multiple countries, in this case for microorganisms. Countries may want to require people who apply for patents on microorganisms to deposit a sample of the microorganism with them. This is because microorganisms can be difficult to adequately describe on a paper patent application.48 Part of the quid pro quo underlying the patent system is that a monopoly is granted (for 20 years for WTO members) to the inventor in return for the inventor disclosing how to make the invention so that at the end of 20 years, anyone can make the invention.49 This disclosure occurs in the patent application. To ensure there is adequate disclosure to justify getting a patent, countries can require the patent applicant to deposit a sample of the microorganism at a storage facility in the country. 48 UNCTAD-ICTSD Resource Book (2005), available online at http://www.iprsonline.org/unctadictsd/ResourceBookIndex_update.htm 49 UNCTAD-ICTSD Resource Book (2005), available online at http://www.iprsonline.org/unctadictsd/ResourceBookIndex_update.htm 92 Patent applicants say the cost and effort of posting microorganism samples to each country they want a patent in makes it procedurally more difficult for them to get patents in multiple countries. If countries have signed the Budapest Treaty, people seeking to get a patent in those countries only have to give a microorganism sample to an ‘international depositary authority’. As of March 2006 there were 37 such authorities: seven in the United Kingdom, three in the Russian Federation and in the Republic of Korea, two each in China, Italy, Japan, Poland, Spain and the United States of America, and one each in Australia, Belgium, Bulgaria, Canada, the Czech Republic, France, Germany, Hungary, Latvia, India, the Netherlands and Slovakia. The majority of the depositories are in developed countries and these hold the bulk of the deposits. Implications for Malaysia If Malaysia signs the Budapest Treaty, as most USFTAs have required, it is likely to receive more microorganism patent applications due to the easier application procedure and if these are granted at the same rate, more microorganisms will be patented in Malaysia. This is likely to raise the cost of inputs for the food, medical and agricultural industries50 in Malaysia, including the biotechnology industry. For example Thai industries rely on imported micro-organisms costing an average of RM5.2billion-RM6.2billion per year.51 In the context of the Japan-Thailand Economic Partnership Agreement ‘Khao-Kwan Foundation chairman Day-cha Siripatra said the country would lose several hundred billion baht a year if the government allowed Japan to patent micro-organisms, because Thailand relied on Effective Microorganism (EM) imports from Japan to support many industries and solve the environment problem.’52 As 98% of patents in Malaysia are granted to foreigners and this has been constant for the last five years (see above), it is likely to increase the outflow of royalties, contributing to greater foreign exchange losses. There are also concerns that international depositary authorities may not be properly managed so it would be difficult for the country of origin or providing country to safeguard its interests and rights over the samples. Malaysia has significant biodiversity, including in microorganisms and this may lead to biopiracy. Furthermore, the international depositary authority may deal with the sample in a way the country does not desire. For example Indonesia freely gave samples of its bird flu virus to the World Health Organization who then passed it onto an Australian company who developed a vaccine and would not give it free to Indonesia but insisted on Indonesia paying commercially for it.53 50 http://nationmultimedia.com/2007/02/17/business/business_30027112.php http://nationmultimedia.com/2007/02/17/business/business_30027112.php 52 http://nationmultimedia.com/2007/02/17/business/business_30027112.php 53 http://www.thejakartapost.com/detailheadlines.asp?fileid=20070212.A07&irec=6 51 93 4. Data exclusivity and farmers The “data exclusivity” requirements in USFTAs also apply to agricultural chemicals. This prevents suppliers of generic versions of these chemicals from being able to make use of the test data of the companies that first received registration of the chemicals in order to get the safety approval to market their generic products.Data exclusivity is not required by TRIPS.54 Based on other USFTAs, this would mean that no generic version of a herbicide or pesticide can be registered and therefore used in Malaysia for ten years. When ten years of data exclusivity for agricultural chemicals was introduced in Australia as part of the Australia-USFTA, Australian farmers said ‘These changes will have a devastating effect on the independent generic chemical companies which provide competitively priced chemicals to farmers… In the context of this submission we ask that the Senate Committee to consider taking the important issue of data protection out of the FTA agreement or set aside Chapter 17 [on intellectual property] of the FTA from the broader agreement. This will allow Australia to set our own laws which best serve our market and stakeholders.’55 Generic versions of agricultural chemicals are two to three times cheaper than their counterparts that are patented or have data exclusivity and the agricultural chemicals make up 10%-14% of total input costs for Australian farmers.56 Therefore the Australian farmers concluded that ‘Australian farmers have no subsidies to aid payment for input costs like chemicals, they survive in a distorted world market by keeping their input costs minimal. The competitive generic chemical market has evolved to meet the Australian farmers requirements and needs to remain for Australian farmers to stay internationally competitive… these laws if implemented in Australia, they have the potential destroy the generic companies that exist in Australia and the beneficial competition that goes along with their presence in the market.’57 The farmers asked that ‘data protection be taken out of the Intellectual Property Chapter or the entire Chapter be set aside for re-negotiation.’58 54 Protection of Data Submitted for the Registration of Pharmaceuticals: Implementing the Standards of the TRIPS Agreement, Carlos Correa, South Centre (from: www.southcentre.org/publications/ protection/protection.pdf). 55 Submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America by the Pastoralists and Graziers Association of W.A. (Inc) And Generic Agricultural Chemical Association. (The members of the Pastoralists Association grow 2 million tonnes of wheat). 56 Submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America by the Pastoralists and Graziers Association of W.A. (Inc) And Generic Agricultural Chemical Association. 57 Submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America by the Pastoralists and Graziers Association of W.A. (Inc) And Generic Agricultural Chemical Association. 58 Submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America by the Pastoralists and Graziers Association of W.A. (Inc) And Generic Agricultural Chemical Association. 94 Some pertinent questions arise. Has the Malaysian Government calculated whether data exclusivity on agricultural chemicals will also lead to a rise in input costs for Malaysian farmers of 10%-20% from data exclusivity alone? If so, will the farmers be compensated for the duration of MUFTA? The increase in costs will add to the other problems facing the farmers as a result of MUFTA, such as higher competition from (often subsidized) imports as tariffs are reduced or eliminated, and higher costs of seeds due to the strict IP to be introduced for plant varieties. E. PATENT COOPERATION TREATY TRIPS does not require countries to join the Patent Cooperation Treaty (PCT). However, all recent US Free Trade Agreements have required the countries signing them to join the PCT.59 Patents are national. It is not possible to apply for a worldwide patent. The PCT is designed to enable people to apply for a patent in multiple countries more easily. It does this by standardizing the application procedures and requiring Parties to the PCT to accept the standardised procedure. Applications can then be sent to multiple countries by basically ‘ticking a box’. The PCT is more beneficial for countries with inventors who wish to apply for patents in other countries. 98% of patents granted in Malaysia are to foreigners and this has been constant for the last five years according to Malaysian Government statistics.60 Malaysia became a party to the PCT last year. As this makes it easier for foreigners to apply for patents in Malaysia by lowering the procedural hurdles, Malaysia can expect more patent applications. This was the experience of all other countries joining the PCT except one according to WIPO’s data. For example China’s patent applications increased five-fold, Iceland’s increased 12-fold and Vietnam’s increased 15-fold.61 61 countries62 are still not PCT members. Some of the countries that are not yet PCT Members are fellow ASEAN members (Brunei, Cambodia, Myanmar and Thailand), and/or those with higher incomes per capita than Malaysia (such as Saudi Arabia, Kuwait, Lebanon and Malta). If it turns out that the PCT has caused a flood of patent applications causing the Intellectual Property Corporation to fall behind in its examinations, or causing more medicines to be under patent monopolies, it is possible for Malaysia to unilaterally withdraw from the PCT,63 without penalty, if the Malaysia-USFTA has not been signed. Countries have reversed their levels of intellectual property protection in the 59 www.ustr.gov. http://www.mipc.gov.my/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=3&Itemid=10 61 The other countries registering significant increases in patent applications were Canada, Croatia, Israel, Mexico, New Zealand, Serbia and Montenegro and Turkey. Of the countries with sufficient data, only Algeria did not register a significant increase in patent applications when it joined the PCT. 62 United Nations has 191 Members and PCT has 130 Members (from http://www.wipo.int/treaties/en/ShowResults.jsp?lang=en&treaty_id=6 accessed on 28 April 2006). 63 Art 66. 60 95 past, e.g. the Netherlands used to allow patents, then it abolished its patent law (before later reinstating it).64 However, Malaysia is likely to have to commit to remaining in the PCT if it signs a MUFTA because all recent USFTAs have had this obligation. This (and other provisions such as non-violation complaints and the investment chapter) may make it harder to withdraw from the PCT or other WIPO treaties. The rapid increase in patents in Malaysia will have several effects. examples are given below. A few Effects on the 9th Malaysia Plan Health/quality of life The 9th Malaysia Plan emphasizes the importance of improving quality of life including achieving better health in Chapter 20. As a greater proportion of medicines in Malaysia will be patented if it signs the PCT, this means Malaysians will have to pay the higher monopoly price for all these patented medicines. For example, a World Health Organization funded study found that for a family of 3 with some minor health problems, it would take the lowest level Malaysian government official 2 months of salary to afford one month of medicines if generics were not available.65 Moving up the value chain According to Thrust One of the 9th Malaysia Plan, Malaysia should move up the value chain. However in higher technology industries, the inputs are also technology. If a greater proportion of machinery etc is patented in Malaysia because it joins the PCT, this will increase the cost of inputs (as more royalties will have to be paid) and make it harder for Malaysia to move up the value chain. (This would be exacerbated under a USFTA which, based on existing USFTAs, would require all Malaysia’s tariffs to be bound at 0% making it very difficult to start new industries higher up the value chain as they are exposed to competition from day 1). Biotechnology Biotechnology is a focus of Chapter 6 of the 9th Malaysia Plan. As explained above, to foster a biotechnology industry in Malaysia, Malaysia actually needs to grant as few patents as possible in Malaysia. The main thing is that patents continue to be granted in the main markets for the products of a Malaysian biotechnology industry, i.e. the USA and European Union. Malaysia’s economic growth is affected if Malaysians are sicker The World Health Organization’s Commission on Macroeconomics and Health found that a 10% increase in life expectancy at birth is associated with a rise in economic growth of at least 0.3-0.4% of economic growth per year (all else being held Schiff, E. (1971) “Industrialisation Without National Patents: The Netherlands 1869-1919, Switzerland, 1850– 1907”, Princeton University Press, Princeton. 65 A survey of medicine prices, availability, affordability and price components in Malaysia using the WHO/HAI methodology, Research Report, University College Sedaya International & University Sains Malaysia in collaboration with the World Health Organization, October 2005. 64 96 constant).66 Conversely, a high malaria prevalence is associated with a reduction in economic growth of more than 1% per year.67 F. SCOPE OF PATENTABILITY TRIPS allows countries to decide not to give patents on: plants, animals or diagnostic, therapeutic and surgical methods.68 There can be ethical and cultural objections to patenting life.69 Furthermore, medicines such as the last remaining effective malaria treatment in some areas are plants. Allowing patents on plants would grant monopolies on them and so make these medicines unaffordable. However, US FTAs can require countries to allow patents on some or all of these things. One reason for this is that US national patent law already allows for patents for some of these things. For example: (1) There were 600 patents relating to rice issued in the US in 2000 and the rate of patenting is rapidly rising.70 (2) The US has introduced patents for surgical procedures. When the introduction was made, ‘a blizzard of lawsuits followed. This unhealthy circumstance was halted in 1996 by the American Medical Association and Congress, which decided that doctors couldn't sue other doctors for using patented surgical procedures.’71 (3) USFTAs can also require countries to give patents for new uses of old medicines.72 This is dangerous because not many brand new medicines are being invented. Instead, computerized testing now allows pharmaceutical companies who have thousands of existing medicines on the shelf to test them against different diseases very quickly. This is cheaper and faster than building a new medicine from scratch so is preferred by pharmaceutical companies. If patents on new uses are allowed, a medicine such as AZT which was used to treat cancer and received a 20 year patent for that, would get a second, consecutive, 20 year patent when it was found to be effective for HIV/AIDS. This delays generic competition and keeps medicine prices high. 66 www.cmhealth.org. www.cmhealth.org 68 Art 27.3. 69 ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 59. 70 ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 64. 67 71 http://www.nytimes.com/2006/03/19/opinion/19crichton.html?ex=1172379600&en=66dcde5df677af77 &ei=5070. Congress added subsection (C) to 35 USC 287 to fix the problem. 72 For example Art 15.8.1 (b) Oman-USFTA. 97 The Commission on IPR recommends that ‘maximum use be made of the possibilities under TRIPS of excluding such inventions from patent protection.’73 Software patents TRIPS does not require patents on software either74 and many countries do not allow patents on software. However the USA allows patents on software and some information technology lawyers are concerned that certain provisions in USFTAs could eventually lead to software patents.75 For a table that details the many provisions in the Australia-USFTA that affect software, see http://linux.org.au/projects/fta/fta_comparison_table_040322.pdf. As for the effect on the vibrant open source software community in Malaysia, the possible implications can be seen by how it is playing out in the USA. ‘A single patent can ruin an Open Source project… With the USPTO granting an estimated 45,000 software patents in 2003 and rising, it is not possible to audit software against the hundreds of thousands of patents.’76 Alleged infringement of one software patent alone resulted in the US court awarding damages of US$521million.77 G. COPYRIGHT 1. .Background USFTAs require stronger copyright protection than TRIPS in several ways, some of which are discussed below. The text of several insightful remarks on copyright and FTAs are given below. According to a UNESCO report: ‘Copyright has emerged as one of the most important means of regulating the international flow of ideas and knowledge-based products, and will be a central instrument for the knowledge industries of the twentyfirst century. Those who control copyright have a significant advantage in the emerging, knowledge-based global economy. The fact is that copyright ownership is largely in ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 66 74 UNCTAD-ICTSD Resource Book (2005), available online at http://www.iprsonline.org/unctadictsd/ResourceBookIndex_update.htm 75 http://www.ilaw.com.au/public/softwarepatents.html citing Art 17.9.14 of the Australia-USFTA ‘Each Party shall endeavour to reduce differences in law and practice between their respective systems, including in respect of differences in determining the rights to an invention, the prior art effect of applications for patents, and the division of an application containing multiple inventions. In addition, each Party shall endeavour to participate in international patent harmonisation efforts, including the WIPO fora addressing reform and development of the international patent system’ as something that could lead to harmonization with the US and therefore allowing software patents in Australia. 76 Submission to Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America from http://www.aph.gov.au/Senate/committee/freetrade_ctte/submissions/sub164.pdf 77 http://www.imakenews.com/bakerbotts/index000036038.cfm 73 98 the hands of the major industrialized nations and of the major multimedia corporations placing low per capita income countries as well as smaller economies at a significant disadvantage.’78 Copyright-based industries including publishing, film, television, radio, music and computer software ‘supply the intellectual “raw material” for science and innovation, as well as for education and instruction in general, and they have helped bring about dramatic increases in productivity through aiding the creation of information-based products like desk-top publishing software, electronic mail or sophisticated scientific computer databases.’79 Access to computer software is a ‘pre-requisite for access to information and for competitiveness in the global economy. . . In the knowledge-based global economy, computer technologies are an essential requirement for accessing and using information, accelerating technology transfer and boosting the growth of productivity’ according to the Commission.80 ‘Software, textbooks, and academic journals are key items where copyright is a determining factor in pricing and access, and which are also essential ingredients in education and other spheres crucial to the development process. For instance, a reasonable selection of academic journals is far beyond the purchasing budgets of university libraries in most developing countries, and increasingly in developed countries as well.’81 As a result of the successful lobbying of powerful US copyright markets, ‘the U.S. copyright regime sets one of the highest standards of copyright protection in the world but one which is not recognised as providing a balance between the interests of users and copyright owners… It is apparent however that many of the FTA provisions closely mirror those provisions already in the U.S. Digital Millenium Copyright Act 1998 (DMCA) so that harmonisation equates to unilateral action to amend Australian copyright legislation to U.S. legislation.’82 The IP chapter (Chapter 17) of the AUSFTA ‘creates obligations to amend the Australian copyright regime in ways that will reduce access to materials, increase costs for institutions which provide public access to knowledge, and ultimately curb innovation. This neglect is disturbing and unsatisfactory given that a balanced intellectual property regime forms the research and resource base upon which our UNESCO (1998) “World Information Report 1997/98”, UNESCO, Paris, p.320. Source: http://www.unesco.org/webworld/com_inf_reports/wirenglish/chap23.pdf 79 ‘Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 95. 80 Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 100 and 104. 81 Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 17 82 Australian Digital Alliance (a coalition of IT companies, scientific and research organizations, schools, universities, consumer groups, cultural institutions, libraries and individuals) submission from http://www.aph.gov.au/Senate/committee/freetrade_ctte/submissions/sublist.htm. 78 99 knowledge and creative industries depend. Overall, the provisions in Chapter 17 fail to provide a satisfactory level of balance. The ADA does not believe that the provisions pertaining to copyright serve the interests of Australians and does not support the ratification of the FTA on that basis.’83 Most developing countries are net importers of copyrighted material (and technology).84 75% of global book exports were from the US (20%), UK (17%), other European countries, Canada and Singapore.85 If Malaysia is seeking to encourage innovation, it should be noted that countries such as Benin and Chad which joined the Berne Convention many years ago ‘have not seen significant increases in their national copyright-based industries or in the level of copyright-protected works being created by their people.’86 An Australian legal academic K. Weatherall found that the IP provisions of the AUSFTA would mean that Increased costs to users As a net IP importer, more royalties will flow overseas. No recognition of moral rights in the USA for creations by Aboriginal Australians. Some new works not created because of the increased costs to Australian creators and researchers of using older material. Transaction costs of searching for the author to ask permission to use the material Lost opportunities to create archives or digital collections of older works such as Project Gutenberg. Orphaned works where the author cannot be found to get permission and so it is not available.87 The Australian Libraries’ Copyright Committee (ALCC) is the cross-sectoral body acting on behalf of Australian libraries and archives on copyright and related matters. It seeks to have the interests of users of libraries and archives recognised and reflected in copyright legislation, and in so doing, help build and sustain a copyright regime 83 Australian Digital Alliance (a coalition of IT companies, scientific and research organizations, schools, universities, consumer groups, cultural institutions, libraries and individuals) submission from http://www.aph.gov.au/Senate/committee/freetrade_ctte/submissions/sublist.htm. 84 Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 17 85 Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 97 86 Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 98 87 Kimberlee Weatherall’s submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America 100 which promotes learning, culture and the free flow of information and ideas in the interests of all Australians.88 In their Submission on the Australian-US FTA, they state that: The ALCC does not support the ratification of the FTA on the basis that the provisions of Chapter 17 [intellectual property] will result in substantial damage to our creative and innovative potential by restricting access to and increasing the costs of access to knowledge. It is ALCC’s submission that overall, the obligations created by the FTA will require change to Australia’s copyright regime that will fundamentally alter the current balance in Australian law with detrimental impacts on our cultural, educational and information environments… The extension of copyright term will place a significant burden on libraries which will ultimately be borne by users and the Australian public… The ALCC is disappointed to note that the importance of maintaining a balanced copyright regime is not properly reflected in the draft text of Chapter 17 of the FTA. Chapter 17 creates obligations to amend the Australian copyright regime in ways that will reduce access to materials, increase costs for libraries and archives which provide public access to knowledge and ultimately impede the flow of information. This neglect is disturbing given that a balanced copyright law forms the necessary foundation for fulfilling Australian government policy goals in building a ‘clever country’. Overall, the provisions in Chapter 17 fail to provide a satisfactory level of balance. The ALCC does not believe that the provisions pertaining to copyright serve the interests of Australians and does not support the ratification of the FTA on that basis… As stated repeatedly by negotiators from Australia and the U.S., the overall effect of Chapter 17 is the ‘harmonisation’ of our respective copyright regimes. It is apparent however that many of the FTA provisions closely mirror those provisions already in the U.S. Digital Millennium Copyright Act 1998 (DMCA) so that harmonisation equates to unilateral action to amend Australian copyright legislation to match U.S. legislation. The alignment of our copyright legislation to meet obligations created by the FTA has dangerous potential to create severe distortions within our domestic regime. Although Australia and United States share a common law tradition, some divergence has developed in recent years, marked by the emergence of powerful U.S. copyright markets which have been extremely successful at legislative lobbying. As a result, the U.S. copyright regime sets one of the highest standards of copyright protection in the world but one which has not been recognised as providing a balance between the interests of users and 88 Australian Libraries Copyright Committee submission to Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America 101 copyright owners. This consequently leads to a great deal of expensive litigation.’89 2. Copyright term extensions TRIPS requires copyright protection for a period of at least 50 years from publication or making (when it is not calculated on the basis of the life of a natural person).90 By contrast, US free trade agreements (USFTAs) require copyright to last for 70, 95 or 120 years.91 Malaysia’s copyright law provides protection for literary, musical or artistic works during the author’s lifetime plus a period of 50 years after the death of the author. For protection for sound recordings, broadcasts, films, performers’ rights, the period covered is 50 years after the recording or broadcast was first made. It is likely that Malaysia will have to agree to copyright protection of at least 70 years (after the death of author; or of date of recording etc.) if it signs MUFTA. This 40% increase in copyright duration is likely to have significant effects on Malaysia’s ability to increase its knowledge and innovation capacity. Former Assistant Commissioner at the Australian Productivity Commission and trade expert, now at the Australian National University in a report that was commissioned by the Senate Committee, looking at the AUSFTA found that ‘Australia’s net royalty payments could be up to $88 million higher per year as a result of extending the term of copyright’ [from 50 years to 70 years].92 In addition to the increased royalty payments, much of which flows overseas, there are economic costs of seeking permission to reproduce a work when it is still copyrighted. For example the Carnegie-Mellon study by US universities found that the cost of seeking permission to copy an out-of-print or commercially unavailable work is US$150-200, without guarantee of a response.93 In the context of the USA’s decision to extend copyright from 50 to 70 years, US Justice Breyer said ‘the costs of obtaining permission, now perhaps ranging in the millions of dollars, will multiply’.94 To get clearance for one work, ‘consumed approximately a dozen man-hours per work. The College Art Association says that the costs of obtaining permission for use of single images, short excerpts, and other 89 Australian Libraries Copyright Committee submission to Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America 90 Article 12 TRIPS. 91 The North American Free Trade Agreement was signed before TRIPS and it has a copyright term of 50 years. Jordan’s USFTA does not specify a copyright period as it is a different style of FTA. The other USFTAs all have 70 years except for Oman’s which requires 70, 95 or 120 years of copyright protection depending on which measurement system is used. 92 It is also in her ‘The Australia-US Free Trade Agreement: An Assessment’, Pacific Economic Papers No. 345, 2005, Australian National University. 93 ALIA Submission to Senate Committee. 94 Dr Rimmer’s Submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America 102 short works can become prohibitively high.’ 95 Justice Breyer went on to state that the ‘economic effect of the Copyright Term Extension Act 1998 (US) is to make the copyright term ‘virtually perpetual.’ He observes that the legislation creates a copyright term worth 99.8% of the value of a perpetual copyright: The economic effect of this 20-year extension - the longest blanket extension since the Nation’s founding - is to make the copyright term not limited, but virtually perpetual. Its primary legal effect is to grant the extended term not to authors, but to their heirs, estates, or corporate successors. And most importantly, its practical effect is not to promote, but to inhibit, the progress of ‘Science’ - by which word the Framers meant learning or knowledge.’96 Universities were also concerned about the impact of extending copyright term in Australia. For example, the executive director of the Australian Vice-Chancellors Committee, John Mullarvey, said that ‘Australian universities now paid $20 million a year in copyright fees and adding 20 years to the period of copyright protection would add to that sum. How much I couldn’t even guess’. For people in remote areas who would have been able to rely on electronic versions of books via the internet such as via the free Project Gutenberg which uploads them once they are out of copyright, this means waiting another 20 years before they can access them. Furthermore, copyright term extensions are unlikely to promote creativity, the basic objective of copyright law because ‘Milton Friedman and 17 other economists (including 5 Nobel Prize winners) found that the economic benefit of 20 extra years to copyright owners was less than US$0.01 per year per work and so was unsustainable as an economic argument for extension.’97 Expressions of concern in Australia about the extension of copyright duration to 70 years Australian Federal Government concerns The Australian Federal Government negotiated and signed the Australia-USFTA which contained an extension of the copyright period to 70 years, despite earlier having concluded that such an extension would not be advisable, for example in the reports below. ‘The Minister for Communications, Information Technology and the Arts, The Hon Darryl Williams, [informed the Media Entertainment and Arts Alliance] that the Government would make no concessions to the US regarding extension of copyright term. The Minister explained it was Government policy that copyright term not be extended because of the negative financial impact doing so would have on Australia. The Minister advised that his department, DCITA, had undertaken work on extension Dr Rimmer’s Submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America 96 Dr Rimmer’s Submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America 97 ALIA Submission to Senate Committee. 95 103 of term and had concluded the cost to Australia would be so considerable that reviewing Government policy could not be contemplated.’98 Similarly, the Office of Regulation Review which is part of the Productivity Commission which is the ‘Australian Government’s principal review and advisory body on microeconomic policy and regulation’99 made a submission to a Committee’s review of the Copyright Act and recommended against an extension of copyright term saying that ‘The ORR considers that a general extension of copyright protection’ would have few (if any) tangible benefits and holds the risk of substantial costs: it represents an unjustifiable redirection of funds (i.e. economic rents) from Australian consumers and secondary producers without commensurate benefits; it would be likely to cause an increase in net royalty flows to overseas authors and publishers; there is no evidence that it would provide a significant incentive to produce works not already being produced’100 State Government concerns ‘The NSW Government is concerned… that the proposed extension of the period of copyright protection from 50 to 70 years from the death of the author, will have a significant financial impact on libraries, universities and schools… The extension of the copyright term would delay the entry of works into the public domain and restrict the flow of creativity and knowledge into the public domain. It will impose greater limits on access to information, which is a fundamental principle of library services.’101 Similarly, the ‘The Queensland Government is concerned that this change would have serious implications for large scale users of copyright material who will have to pay significantly more in copyright fees, particularly government, libraries, universities TAFEs and other education institutions. There are also significant concerns from industry that the extension of copyright protection represents a barrier to innovation by restricting access to intellectual property for longer periods.’102 The Queensland Government thought consideration should be given to a ‘funding mechanism to allow educational and research institutions to accommodate the extra 20 years of copyright protection.’103 98 Media Entertainment and Arts Alliance Supplementary Submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America 99 http://www.pc.gov.au/commission/index.html 100 Media Entertainment and Arts Alliance Supplementary Submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America 101 NSW Government Submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America. 102 Queensland Government Submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America. 103 Queensland Government Submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America. 104 Librarians’ concerns ‘Librarians warn a free trade deal with the US may result in a massive transfer of wealth from the Australian public and performers to US monopoly copyright holders. Negotiations for the US Free Trade Agreement…may result in a tenfold increase in licence fees for Australians performing original works by US artists, if overseas experience is a guide. Australian Library and Information Association copyright adviser Colette Ormonde says in a recent case an Australian performer touring the US was denied the chance to perform the works of Hungarian composer Bela Bartok because an extension to the US copyright term had clawed Bartok's work back from the public domain. Bartok died in 1945 and his works entered the public domain - where they could be performed without paying licence royalties - in 1995. But under new US laws, the Bartok estate retains control over his works until 2015. ‘Extension of the copyright term in the US benefited the publishing conglomerates and film and record producers but disadvantaged copyright users. Amateur musicians, for example, found that the licensed cost of a music score for a one-night performance increased from $100 to $1000. The worst result for copyright users was that authors and composers whose work was out of copyright became protected again… Ormonde says the cost to Australia - a net importer of copyrighted works [104] such as films, music and books - will continue to grow as copyright terms are extended and won't be compensated by the greater returns to Australian publishers of original works. ‘The rewards to Australian copyright owners in extending the term of protection are minimal because they don't have the huge product of major European and US publishers and never will have.’… Project Gutenberg Australia, an online repository of works in the public domain, will be among the first to feel the impact of any extension to copyright terms. Named after the famous bible first printed by Johannes Gutenberg in 1454 with the then newly invented printing press, Project Gutenberg was started by volunteers in the US 32 years ago to make available to the public works of cultural significance that are in the public domain. Downloads are free. Project Gutenberg Australia's maintainer, Col Choate, says if a new deal was to extend the term of copyright it would ‘just about wipe us out’. He says works by authors such as Virginia Wolfe, D.H. Lawrence and George Orwell now in the public domain would be taken back into the hands of private copyright holders. Copyright term extension undermines the foundation for creation of copyright. The legal and economic basis for copyright is that creators should be protected and rewarded for a set period in order to stimulate further creativity and innovation. Apart from financial reward, the stimulation of creativity and further works depends on the eventual entry of works into the public domain so that others can freely learn from and draw from a collective pool of knowledge and creativity. The extension of 104 The Victorian Government agrees with this in its submission to the Senate Select Committee. 105 copyright term prejudices a generation of creators and users by denying access to a rich public domain. Term extension has generated fierce debate within the U.S. where numerous successive extensions of copyright have effectively locked works out of the public domain and displaced the intended cycle of creation and contribution upon which copyright was originally justified. In the recent challenge posed to the U.S. Copyright Term Extension Act 1998 (CTEA) in Eldred v Ashcroft, the strong arguments made to the court for repealing the CTEA, such as the added costs to users, the minimal long term awards to owners and the speculative nature of predictions on creative incentives arising from extended monopoly were not disputed… The available reports on the topic such as the Allens report, Copyright Term Extension: Australian Benefits and Costs (July 2003) provides no clear evidence of any short or long term economic benefits of extension. No claims have been made that the economic benefits of harmonisation with the U.S. is any more than marginal and no data has been presented to substantiate even this weak assertion. Although the benefits of harmonisation are theoretically plausible, the reality is that the beneficiaries of harmonisation will be multinational companies, who are based mostly in the U.S. and European Union… No proponent of term extension has relied on an argument that an extra 20 years of protection after the death of the author will have any impact on the incentive of authors to produce more work. In addition, Australia is a net importer of copyright materials from the U.S. by a substantial margin; an extension of copyright term will, other things being equal, lead to a reallocation of resources and adversely affect our balance of trade. An extension of copyright term has serious consequences for libraries, cultural and educational institutions in relation to raised costs of maintaining access to information and increased costs associated with the already formidable and resource-intensive task of tracing copyright owners and requesting permissions. The groups of people who will be ultimately affected by the added burden of term extension include historians, scholars, teachers, writers, artists and researchers of all kinds. … Overall the copyright provisions in Chapter 17 create obligations that will erode public access to works and diminish the power of libraries and archives to carry out their mandate to preserve and provide access to cultural, intellectual and creative works. The obligations imposed by the FTA unilaterally raises the standard of protection of copyright owners in Australia by adopting DMCA-like measures which would fundamentally alter the balance struck in the Copyright Act.’105 And again, ‘This submission, expresses the serious concern of those responsible for Australia’s research and academic information services at the copyright changes identified in Chapter 17 of the Free Trade Agreement with the USA… CAUL is cognisant of the fact that Australia has developed a Copyright Act which, while meeting Australia’s obligations to the WIPO treaties, also balances the needs of the copyright creators and the users. The Act has received worldwide recognition as a model of best practice. 105 Australian Libraries Copyright Committee submission to Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America 106 US copyright legislation is significantly different to that in Australia. These differences are due to a very different history and the fact that in the US copyright is driven by sustained lobbying from large corporations and powerful industry associations, especially the entertainment and media industries. The ‘balance’ of the Digital Millennium Copyright Act (DMCA) is tipped firmly in favour of copyright owners, as demonstrated by the extension yet again of the term of copyright, and continues to attract criticism as it is considered to be cumbersome, punitive and highly supportive of big corporations in opposition to individual creators, researchers, students and the general public. In proposing to ‘harmonise’ the well respected Australian copyright legislation with that of the problematic US legislation under Chapter 17 of the FTA, the carefully developed balance between the interest of copyright owners and users apparent in the Australian legislation, will be destroyed and tipped firmly in favour of the owners. This outcome will be to the disadvantage of writers, artists and filmmakers, as well as the general public, who all depend on using copyright materials to create, to learn and to participate in community life. Specifically, the impact on higher education in Australia will be to raise the cost of compliance on an annual basis. In addition, researchers, who - in Newton’s words stand on the shoulders of giants., will be required to pay for information which would under current Australian law have come into the public domain.’106 The Australian Library and Information Association (ALIA) in its submissions to Senate Committees pointed out that the ‘ALIA represents 900 library and information organizations and the interests of 10.7million users of library and information services. It is opposed to the copyright extension in the AUSFTA… Australia is and will be for the foreseeable future a net consumer of information… Extensions of the copyright term benefit producers and publishers of massive amounts of content. They do not benefit the estates of individual creators or promote further creativity, the basic objective of copyright law…’ According to them, ‘The extension of copyright terms is an extension of corporate monopoly. It has no place in a free trade agreement, is anti-competitive and burdens information consumers with escalating and unpredictable costs and legal obligations.’ Australia’s largest reference library, the National Library of Australia stated that moves to increase the copyright term to 70 years ‘would not be supported by the National Library. We submit that this would have adverse consequences for the public interest. The purpose of copyright is dual: to advance learning as well as to recompense creators. The public domain is an integral part of the creative process and allows the public access to the fruits of an artist’s labours after the expiry of the 106 Council of Australian University Librarians (CAUL) submission to Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America. According to their Submission, ‘The Council of Australian University Librarians (CAUL) represents all Australian university libraries… CAUL members operate in an educational environment which produces a significant amount of copyright material, while their core business is the provision of access to information. Consequently, copyright is integral to the work of university libraries and CAUL has an abiding interest in the development of balanced and effective copyright legislation.’ 107 copyright term. This is particularly true for creators of works such as reference books, CD-ROMs, multimedia material, and documentary and educational films, all of which draw heavily on public domain material. Because the copyright regime exists to serve everyone, not just specialist interest groups, the National Library would regard any extension of the copyright term, and the consequent reduced access to a large portion of our common heritage, as detrimental to creativity and against the public benefit.’ Application of Agreement to Existing Subject Matter The AUSFTA specifically requires the copyright extensions to apply to material that is currently under copyright.107 3. Anti-circumvention provisions A technological protection measure (TPM) is a digital lock on digital material to stop access or copying. This can prevent even legal copying, for example if the copyright has already expired on a movie or book, a TPM could stop a digital copy of the book from being able to be copied.108 This is therefore an extra, potentially infinite, monopoly in addition to copyright. Other examples of legal copying could include a blind person using the software to read aloud a computer file,109 making a back-up copy of legitimate software in case the computer breaks down and the software has to be re-loaded, ‘region coding for DVDs, anti-copying music CDs that will not play in a PC, encrypted software requiring entry of a registration code before being installable, passwords and encryption used to prevent unauthorised access to online databases’110 TPMs can significantly restrict access to knowledge. ‘For developing countries, where Internet connectivity is limited and subscriptions to on-line resources unaffordable, it may exclude access to these materials altogether and impose a heavy burden that will delay the participation of those countries in the global knowledge-based society [and] could be very harmful to the interests of developing countries in accessing information and knowledge they require for their development. . . [therefore] it is premature at the present time for developing countries to be required to go beyond TRIPS standards in this area.’111 107 Article 17.1.9. There is an exception for things whose copyright have already expired (Article 17.1.10), for example if a book’s copyright expired in 2000 and the AUSFTA came into force on 1/1/2005, that book would not go back into copyright until 2020 because of the copyright extension to 70 years. 108 Although the US Government says that TPMs are only supposed to protect copyrighted material, things have not worked out this way in practice. For example, in 2003 when an exception was sought to circumvent movies that were already out of copyright protection on a DVD, the exception was not granted because it was joined to something that could be copyrighted such as a new introduction to the old movie. 109 In the US, the publishing industry considers providing such software to be a violation of the anticircumvention provisions. 110 Australian Parliamentary Library Current Issues Brief No. 3 2004-5, http://www.aph.gov.au/library/pubs/CIB/2004-05/05cib03.pdf 111 Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy, report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights established by the British Government, http://www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm, page 106 and 108 108 A concrete example is that some scientific databases protected by TPMs can only be accessed from one dedicated terminal in the library. This prevents students and researchers who live long distances away and could otherwise use it online from being able to access the information in that database. Similarly, if a Malaysian Government Ministry bought a CD with a database on it that was not protected by copyright, a TPM could nevertheless stop the Ministry from making legal copies to educate its staff. Circumvention devices can get around TPMs. Circumvention devices are allowed under TRIPS. The WIPO Copyright Treaty (see above) has an anti-circumvention provision112 but it allows room for national copyright exceptions, but USFTAs go further than the WIPO Copyright Treaty.113 Malaysia is currently not even a party to the WIPO Copyright Treaty. All USFTAs since NAFTA have required countries to ban the act of circumventing a TPM (i.e. penalizing the user, see below) and the manufacture, importation and distribution of circumvention devices, even if they would be legal under national copyright law for non-copyright-infringing uses, like the examples given above. Because USFTAs require a ban on circumvention by consumers, the end users of a circumvention device may be liable even when s/he did not know they were circumventing a TPM, for example when playing a DVD on a DVD player that can play DVDs from multiple parts of the world.114 This is because if the person had reasonable grounds to know that they were circumventing a TPM, they can be liable.115 The AUSFTA also makes distributors of circumvention devices liable even if they did not know it was a circumvention device. Since circumvention devices can be physical or computer programs, this was stated as being inappropriate for Australians who do not understand the technology so cannot be expected to know when they are circumventing a TPM.116 If this is the case for Australian consumers, it should be even more true for a developing country such as Malaysia. Although there is a provision which says that additional exceptions to the ban on the act of circumvention may be allowed for users if they can credibly demonstrate in an administrative/parliamentary review at least every four years that there is an adverse 112 Art 11 for copyright and Art 18 of the WIPO Performances and Phonograms Treaty for related rights. 113 Assistant Secretary of Commerce and Commissioner of Patents and Trademarks, Bruce A. Lehman, Electronic Frontier Foundation Briefing Paper On Technological Protection Measures Prepared For The WIPO Inter-Sessional Intergovernmental Meeting On The Development Agenda Proposal & Fourth Session Of The Permanent Committee On Cooperation Related To Intellectual Property Development, April 2005. This is because the WIPO Treaty would still allow fair use exceptions. 114 http://www.eff.org/IP/FTAA/?f=tpm_implementation.html. Most films released on DVD now can only be played in one region of the world, http://www.eff.org/IP/DMCA/copyrightoffice/DMCA_rulemaking_broken.pdf 115 The Chile-USFTA at least limits the liability to when the user actually knew that s/he was circumventing a TPM. 116 Kimberlee Weatherall’s submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America. 109 impact on their non-infringing use,117 a similar system in the USA has been problematic.118 The problems include: The process only exempts the act of circumventing a technological measure, but does not legalize the circumvention tools necessary to do so, so it only applies to the limited number of technologically-savvy users who can make their own circumvention tools. This means the blind would each have to write their own computer programs to read things aloud as no one else can make or distribute them, nor can anyone (including the blind person) import them or share them to their blind colleagues or associations.119 Consumers without lawyers to represent them find they cannot use the process because it is so complex It is a costly and time consuming process, so it makes it particularly difficult for the non-profit sector who are most likely to need such exceptions It is very difficult to credibly prove harm from copyright. For example of the 392 comments in one batch and 5 days of hearings in the 2003 inquiry, only two exemptions were granted. See http://www.eff.org/IP/DMCA/copyrightoffice/DMCA_rulemaking_broken.pdf for more details of the very difficult things which are requested to prove to obtain one of these exceptions. If these provisions were in a Malaysia-USFTA (MUFTA) and the Malaysian Ministry of Education distributed software to schools for the blind so it could read aloud technologically protected electronic books, the Ministry of Education may be liable under the laws implementing MUFTA. Similarly, if the schools or libraries bought electronic books, these books may have technological protection measures which limit the number of times it can be viewed (unlike a normal book which can be borrowed from the library many times until it falls apart). This limitation on the number of times it can be viewed is not required by copyright law. If the library disabled the limitation on the number of times it can be viewed so that it could be ‘borrowed’ like an ordinary book by all the library members, this would be a violation of the anti-circumvention laws required under MUFTA because it is not allowed by one of the seven exceptions in the AUSFTA.120 One of the seven exceptions is for reverse-engineering a computer program to make it interoperable with another one. Unfortunately this does not necessarily cover situations where data needs to be compatible with a program. For example for the open source Open Office program’s word processor to be able to read a Microsoft 117 For example Article 17.4.7(e)(viii) of the AUSFTA. Kimberlee Weatherall’s submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America and http://www.eff.org/IP/DMCA/copyrightoffice/DMCA_rulemaking_broken.pdf. 119 The American Foundation for the Blind’s request for an exemption can be found at http://www.copyright.gov/1201/2006/comments/discipio_afb.pdf and the testimony transcript at http://www.copyright.gov/1201/2006/hearings/transcript-mar29.pdf and the limited exception for blind users that was obtained in 2003: http://www.copyright.gov/1201/2003/index.html 120 The exception for libraries is merely so they can choose whether to buy the e-book, not to allow its members to read it once they have bought it, Art 17.4.7(e)(vii) AUSFTA. 118 110 Word file, it has to be able to interact with the data file, not with the computer program Microsoft Word. Furthermore, the interoperability exception does not cover device-program interoperability where the machine and the program need to be able to work together. The narrowness of the seven exceptions can be seen from their operation in the USA where no one has ever successfully defended themselves because they used one of the equivalent seven exceptions in a case where they have been sued for circumventing a TPM. These seven exceptions are further limited by Article 17.4.10 of the AUSFTA which says that a) the exceptions have to be confined to special cases that do not conflict with the normal exploitation of the copyrighted product and do not prejudice the legitimate interests of the copyright owner; b) the exceptions cannot allow the retransmission of TV on the internet for any reason; c) the rights under the TRIPS+ WIPO Treaties still apply. When circumvention is needed Those seeking to prohibit circumvention devices want a monopoly beyond copyright. Circumvention is needed to: Make lawful uses under existing exceptions and limitations in Malaysian copyright law ensure that different computer programs can operate together121 Overcome artificial geographic market segmentation, for example to allow material such as DVDs that is bought in one geographical region of the world to be played in another. [Companies segregate the markets via region coding of DVDs to allow differential pricing]. The Australian Government had a policy to allow the parallel importation of some copyrighted items (i.e. buying a legal copyrighted version in another country where it is cheaper and bringing it to Australia) to avoid the price-inflating effects of market segmentation.122 This was done to ensure that Australian consumers could access copyrighted material more cheaply and was strongly supported by the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (the independent statutory authority which protects consumers).123 The AUSFTA makes this type of parallel importation impossible.124 There is an exception in the AUSFTA for this, but this exception mirrors that in the USA’s Digital Millennium Copyright Act which has still stopped the development of interoperable products, Kimberlee Weatherall’s submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America. 122 Kimberlee Weatherall’s submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America. 123 Kimberlee Weatherall’s submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America. 124 Kimberlee Weatherall’s submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America. 121 111 To allow material to be made accessible for the blind American rights holders have argued that ‘circumvention device’ can include someone pointing out a security flaw in software in an academic paper To avoid being locked into buying the consumable parts, such as printer cartridges from the maker of the machine (the printer). Because of its potentially severe impact on the 54,000 blind and 464,000 people with low vision in Malaysia,125 the effect of the anti-circumvention provisions of the Malaysia-USFTA should be carefully studied including via detailed consultations with the blind community, before anything is agreed to. The possible impact on Malaysia can be seen from the cases that have occurred under the US provision. Threats to ability to make flaws public An industry group (SDMI) in the US issued a public challenge for experts to try and defeat certain digital watermarking technologies. Professor Felten from Princeton was one of those who participated in the challenge and when he succeeded he tried to present his results at an academic conference. SDMI threatened to sue Professor Felten claiming that presenting an academic paper could be a circumvention device. Sony-BMG: Sony had put software on its CDs that installed itself on computers and left computers vulnerable to malicious third parties. When a student discovered this, he consulted lawyers for two weeks about whether publicly revealing the security flaw would be illegal circumvention. Similarly, a Russian programmer who visited the US to speak at a conference was jailed and kept in the USA for five months for working on a program that others might use to illegally copy products. Skylarov was ultimately acquitted. Impeding innovation and competition When RealNetworks developed technology designed to allow interoperability of their music on Apple iPods, the threats of legal action from Apple made Real give up. A company that reverse engineered a way to allow refilled ink cartridges to run in Lexmark Printers was sued by Lexmark. Lexmark eventually lost but not because it was an allowed circumvention. 4. MUFTA obliges Malaysia to join WIPO 1996 Internet Treaties Many of the Free Trade Agreements signed between the US and other countries require the ratification of the WIPO Internet Treaties (i.e the WIPO Copyright Treaty (WCT) and the WIPO Performers and Phonograms Treaty (WPPT)) that came about 125 Prevalence of blindness and low vision in Malaysian population: results from the National Eye Survey 1996, British Journal of Ophthalmology 2002; 86: 951-956, conducted by the Malaysian Ministry of Health et al. 112 as a result of a Diplomatic Conference on Certain Copyright and Neighbouring Rights Questions, proposed by the US and held in December 1996. [A Diplomatic Conference launches negotiations.] The treaties that entered into force in 1996 draw their texts upon studies submitted by national governments, in particular the US, European Community and Japan, thus reflecting the lobbies in those countries. It has been suggested by some critics that the treaties came about as a way to overcome domestic opposition in the US against strengthening the copyright law domestically. With the existence of the internet treaties, there was then justification for the US government to implement standards as part of their multilateral obligations. It would also in addition ensure the worldwide implementation of strong IP standards preferred by certain individuals and organizations in the US. The US, in response to the WCT, legislated the Digital Millennium Copyright Act, which goes beyond the WCT.126 The US-based digital civil rights organisation, Electronic Frontier Foundation, documents how the anti-circumvention provisions of the DMCA have been used to stifle a wide array of legitimate activities, rather than to stop copyright infringements. It illustrates how they are being invoked against consumers, scientists, and legitimate competitors, rather than pirates.127 Of these two treaties, WCT has been very strongly criticised as it goes beyond what is required under TRIPS and the Berne Convention for the Protection of Literary and Artistic Works. It provides copyright holders exclusive rights over material in the online environment and specifically calls for countries to provide effective legal remedies against the circumvention of the technological protection measures (TPMs). Some of the concerns raised by the Electronic Information for Libraries (eIFL) is as follows: (i) TPMs cannot distinguish between legitimate and infringing uses. The same copycontrol mechanism which prevents a person from making infringing copies of a copyright work, may also prevent a student or a visually impaired person from making legitimate copies under fair use/fair dealing or a legal copyright exception. (ii) Long-term preservation and archiving, essential to preserving cultural identities and maintaining diversity of peoples, languages and cultures, must not be jeopardised by TPMs/DRMs. The average life of a DRM is said to be between three and five years. Obsolescent DRMs will distort the public record of the future, unless the library has a circumvention right. Musungu, S, Dutfield, G., “TRIPS plus Multilateral agreements and a TRIPS-plus world: The World Intellectual Property Organisation (WIPO) available at http://www.quno.org/geneva/pdf/economic/Issues/Multilateral-Agreements-in-TRIPS-plus-English.pdf 127127 Digital Rights Management: A failure in the developed world, a danger to the developing world, Cory Doctorow http://www.eff.org/IP/DRM/drm_paper.php Electronic Frontier Foundation, Unintended Consequences: Seven Years under the DMCA April 2006 http://www.eff.org/IP/DMCA/unintended_consequences.php 126 113 (iii) The public domain must be protected. TPMs do not cease to exist upon expiry of the copyright term, so content will remain locked away even when no rights subsist, thereby shrinking the public domain. The UK Commission Report on IP and Development, in its report states that “more analysis needs to be undertaken about the best means of protecting digital content and the interests of right holders whilst at the same time honouring the principles that ensure adequate access and “fair use” for consumers. More specifically policy makers need to gain a better understanding of the impacts of the trend towards on-line distribution and technological protection of content on developing countries”. The report adds that it is “not clear how reasonable requirements of “fair use” will be guaranteed in such an environment”. It goes on to caution “Developing countries should think carefully before joining the WIPO Copyright Treaty and should not follow the lead of US and the EU by implementing legislation on the lines of the DMCA”. Some may argue that the Malaysian Copyright Act already includes standards found on in WCT such as TPMs, thus one need not worry about ratifying the WCT. However it should be noted that standards that are implemented in the national law, can at anytime be amended, if a negative impact on access to knowledge or public interests is shown. When a country signs on to an international treaty such as WCT and WPPT, it is bound by those minimum obligations and it becomes difficult to take a step backwards. More analysis needs to be done with the engagement of the various stakeholders, such as libraries, open source initiatives, industry, internet service providers and other relevant NGOs to have a discussion to understand better the costs and benefits of signing on to the WIPO internet treaties. However, given the US template in their FTAs, Malaysia would be obliged by MUFTA to join these two WIPO treaties. 5. Some implications of Copyright section for Malaysian society The following are some implications for Malaysian society: 1. MUFTA will oblige Malaysia to change its laws and policies on copyright in many ways. Malaysia would have to: (a) Extend the length of copyright from 50 to 70 years. (b) “Lock in” technological protection measures through the FTA (c) Join the WIPO “internet treaties” (copyright and performers/phonograms) which would in turn lock the country into the treaties’ obligations. (d) The balance between the privileges of the copyright holder and the public interest would shift significantly away from the public interest. An important 114 point is that users of libraries will be much more constrained. There would be a negative effect on access to knowledge. (e) Implications for the 9th Malaysia Plan Thrust Two of the Ninth Malaysia Plan is ‘To raise the capacity for knowledge and innovation and nurture ‘first class mentality’’. In particular, Chapter 11 is entirely about ‘enhancing human capital’. Furthermore, Chapter 5 of the Ninth Malaysia Plan focuses on ‘mainstreaming technology and communications technology’. In addition, Chapters 4, 6, 8, 20 in the other Thrusts all place high priority on human resource development. Human resource development is heavily dependent on access to information and USFTAs restrict access to knowledge in the ways outlined above. (f) Human rights impact Malaysia is a party to the United Nations Convention on the Rights of the Child (CRC) and so is legally bound to implement its provisions. MUFTA could impact the rights of the child in a number of ways. The CRC contains a right to education.128 Textbooks are key to students and the copyright term extension likely to be part of any MUFTA (see above) will extend the monopoly on textbooks and other educational materials to 70 or 95 years before they can be copied. This makes them expensive for longer and potentially reduces the access of children to the materials necessary for their education because parents (or the Malaysian Government through the Textbook Loan Scheme129) can no longer afford to provide them. H. TRADEMARKS The AUSFTA chapter requires the countries to allow trademarks on sounds and scents.130 The development implications of this need to be studied further. The provisions relating to common names not being able to impair the effectiveness of trademarks131 may reduce the ability of countries to require the international nonproprietary name of a medicine (e.g. paracetamol) to be placed in large letters on all medicine packaging so consumers can more readily see that the different brands are all the same chemical and so they can choose on the basis of price (i.e. the generic) more easily. 128 Article 28 CRC. Malaysian Government Report to the Committee, Document CRC/C/MYS/1, 22 December 2006. 130 Art 17.2.2 131 Art17.2.3. 129 115 I. ENFORCEMENT 1. General The enforcement part of TRIPS very clearly states that ‘It is understood that this Part does not create any obligation to put in place a judicial system for the enforcement of intellectual property rights distinct from that for the enforcement of law in general, nor does it affect the capacity of Members to enforce their law in general. Nothing in this Part creates any obligation with respect to the distribution of resources as between enforcement of intellectual property rights and the enforcement of law in general.’132 This was added to TRIPS to address the concerns of developing countries.133 However, the enforcement chapter of USFTAs can specify that a decision that a USFTA country makes on the distribution of enforcement resources shall not excuse that Party from complying with the IP chapter.134 USFTAs can have 11 pages of detailed enforcement prescriptions.135 Some of these specify how a TRIPS level of enforcement should be carried out, others involve much stronger levels of enforcement than TRIPs. The enforcement part of USFTA IP chapters are particularly detailed about internet service provider liability. 2. Internet service provider liability Internet service providers (ISPs) do various things. Some ISPs merely provide access to the internet. Others provide people with space online to host their webpages. One ISP (such as TM Net136) could host millions of webpages. People put things on these webpages without getting permission from the ISP. So the webpages may contain things that infringe copyright such as copyrighted books, articles, music or movies. In many countries, ISPs are not liable for the copyright infringing material that people have posted on the websites they host. However, in the USA, there were conflicting court decisions about whether ISPs were liable for copyright infringing behaviour by their end-users, including having copyright-infringing items on the websites they host.137 For this reason, ISPs wanted legislation to give them ‘safe harbours’ so that they could carry out their normal business activities with only limited liability, if they complied with certain conditions.138 These safe harbours have been criticized as being too narrow and procedurally burdensome to use.139 132 Art 41.5 UNCTAD-ICTSD Resource Book (2005), available online at http://www.iprsonline.org/unctadictsd/ResourceBookIndex_update.htm 134 For example Art 16.9.4 Singapore-USFTA. 135 Such as the Australia-USFTA. 136 According to http://www.tm.com.my/business/small_medium/internet/smi_net_CASP.htm, TM Net offers web hosting, domain hosting, server hosting, online storage service, media hosting and tmnet ebrowse. 137 Via two doctrines only used in the USA: vicarious copyright liability and contributory copyright liability. In addition, a US report found that the temporary reproductions made by a computer in its memory also infringed copyright and so ISPs could be liable for caching material. 138 http://www.eff.org/IP/FTAA/ISP_june05.pdf 139 For example http://www.eff.org/IP/FTAA/ISP_june05.pdf 133 116 TRIPS does not require internet service providers to be liable for copyright infringing material put on websites they host by others.140 USFTAs contain these ISP safe harbours. USFTAs may create ISP liability in countries where none previously existed because: Recent USFTAs require temporary reproductions (for example in the memory of the computer while accessing a webpage), to be a copyright infringement.141 Since digital communication involves serial reproduction and distribution of temporary reproductions of digital works, ISPs may face increased liability if temporary reproductions are considered infringing and there is no corresponding limitation on copyright. In addition, the existence of safe harbours may imply the existence of liability where none previously existed in domestic law, and has been used to create a de facto liability standard in the USA, where copyright owners have sued ISPs for failure to comply with safe harbour conditions as evidence in itself of copyright infringement (even though under US law failure to comply with safe harbour conditions only means that infringement still has to be proven on general principles). The non-violation provision in the dispute settlement chapter of all USFTAs applies to the intellectual property chapter and so may mean that even if the USFTA does not require ISP liability to be created, if the USA reasonably expected it to be and the country (M) which signed the USFTA does not make ISPs liable, M may be sued at the international tribunal by the US Government. If the USA wins the case and M does not change its law to make ISPs liable, the US can raise tariffs on M’s exports to the USA. How ISP liability works in USFTAs To benefit from the safe harbour, in the Australia-USFTA, the person or company must fall within the definition of ‘internet service provider’, must be involved in one of the four activities listed below and the ISP has to comply with the conditions attached to each activity. 140 This is because TRIPS does not require secondary liability or temporary reproductions to be copyrightable. The only provision of TRIPS that could possibly be used to require secondary liability is Art 41.1 ‘effective action against any act of infringement’. However this does not require secondary liability laws and major WTO members do not allow secondary liability (http://www.eff.org/IP/P2P/MGM_v_Grokster/20050301_sharman.pdf ) and yet have not been sued by the USA for failure to comply with TRIPS as you would expect the US to do if it really were required by TRIPS (http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/analytic_index_e/trips_03_e.htm#article41). That TRIPS does not require temporary reproductions can also be seen in the fact that many countries fail to allow temporary reproductions to be copyrightable and yet are not sued by the USA for noncompliance with TRIPS. 141 This is the case in all USFTAs since NAFTA, for example Art 16.4.1 of the Singapore-USFTA which says ‘Each Party shall provide that authors, performers, and producers of phonograms and their successors in interest have the right to authorize or prohibit all reproductions, in any manner or form, permanent or temporary (including temporary storage in electronic form).’ 117 If the ISP meets all of these requirements, courts cannot fine them for authorizing copyright infringements on their networks in that category of activity. Courts can still do things like order the ISP to remove or disable access to the copyright infringing material or terminate the user’s account. \ For Category A activities, courts can only order the ISP to terminate specified accounts or take reasonable steps to block access to a specific online location that is not in the ISP’s country. For activities in other Categories, the court can only order: access to the copyright infringing material to be removed or disabled, specified accounts to be terminated and other remedies the court finds necessary as long as they are the least burdensome to the ISP compared to other forms of relief. Courts can basically only order these things if the ISP has received notice and a chance to appear before the court. Definition of ISP The definition of ISP in the Australia-USFTA is broad enough142 to cause even universities to be concerned that they will be considered to be ISPs, see below. Activities143 Category A activities are known as ‘conduits’ where the ISP transmits, routes or provides connections: i.e. a transitory communication. Category B activities, automatic ‘caching’, i.e. where ISPs store material automatically, for example to make it faster to retrieve rather than the user having to connect to the overseas site again. Category C activities, ‘hosting/storing’, is where material is stored on the ISP network/system at the user’s direction. Category D activities, ‘directing’, is where users are directed to copyrighted material, for example via links. Conditions ISPs must comply with to get safe harbour protection As Category A and B activities are seen as more passive, they gain almost automatic safe harbour status with minimal conditions attached.144 However for Categories C and D where ISPs exercise greater control, there are more rigorous conditions to qualify for safe harbour protection such as ‘take-down notice’ procedures.145 The main conditions to qualify for the safe harbour protection are: All Categories must have adopted and reasonably implemented a termination policy for accounts of repeat infringers Category A: o ISPs must not have initiated transmission of copyrighted material and 142 Art 17.11.29(b)(xii). Lawyer Leaellyn Rich writing in the March 2005 New South Wales Society For Computers and the Law Journal, Issue 59, http://www.nswscl.org.au/journal/59/Rich.html 144 Lawyer Leaellyn Rich writing in the March 2005 New South Wales Society For Computers and the Law Journal, Issue 59, http://www.nswscl.org.au/journal/59/Rich.html 145 Lawyer Leaellyn Rich writing in the March 2005 New South Wales Society For Computers and the Law Journal, Issue 59, http://www.nswscl.org.au/journal/59/Rich.html 143 118 o ISPs cannot have made substantive modifications to the content of the transmitted material (it is ok to make technical modifications such as format shifting) Category B: o ISPs must not have initiated transmission of copyrighted material and o ISPs cannot have modified the original user access conditions for significant parts of the cached material and o ISPs must have expeditiously removed or disabled cached copyright material when it has been removed or disabled at the originating site and a notice of claimed infringement has been received o ISPs cannot have made substantive modifications to the content of the transmitted material (it is ok to make technical modifications such as format shifting) Category C: o ISPs must not have initiated transmission of copyrighted material and o The ISP cannot have received any directly attributable financial benefit from the copyright infringing activity o The ISP must have expeditiously removed/disabled material if it gets actual knowledge of the infringement or becomes aware of circumstances which make the infringement apparent such as a takedown notice claiming infringement. o The ISP must publicly designate a representative to receive take-down notices. Category D: o The ISP cannot have received any directly attributable financial benefit from the copyright infringing activity o The ISP must have expeditiously removed/disabled material if it gets actual knowledge of the infringement or becomes aware of circumstances which make the infringement apparent such as a takedown notice claiming infringement. o The ISP must publicly designate a representative to receive take-down notices. Steps in a take-down procedure 1. Copyright owner (C) notifies the ISP that C thinks there is infringing material on one of the websites the ISP hosts 2. ISP ‘takes down’ the allegedly infringing material 3. ISP sends notice to person whose material was removed (D) (otherwise the ISP could be sued by D) 4. D sends ISP counter-notification that not infringing 5. ISP promptly sends counter-notification to C and tells C will restore the material unless C starts court case within 10 days to get injunction 119 6. ISP restores the material unless C gets injunction 7. ISP also has to provide identification of D to C C usually does not have to have waited for the court to decide that D’s material is infringing C’s copyright. Problems with take-down procedure If this procedure is required, then to minimize the burden on the ISP, the copyright owner’s notice should identify all the copyright work(s) alleged to have been infringed so the ISP can more easily find them and remove them. Furthermore, to prevent abuse of the system by copyright owners, the notice should be accompanied by a statutory declaration – that is, a statement made on oath by someone with direct knowledge of the facts of the matter [that it believes the material is infringing]. Otherwise many notices can be sent when the material is not infringing. However the combination of the side letter and non-violation complaint in the AUSFTA may mean these safeguards are not allowed. The cost of ISP liability According to the lawyer who is the Associate Director of the Intellectual Property Research Institute of Australia, the ISP liability provisions in the AUSFTA ‘will impose significant costs on Australian ISPs.’146 The impact on Malaysian ISPs (e.g. TM) of a standard USFTA can be seen from the effect of this system in the USA. The enforcement agent of one copyright industry association sent one ISP over 16,700 arguably invalid takedown notices. 147 One small U.S. ISP had received over 20,000 notices in 2003 and all were invalid.148 Another US ISP received over 30,000 notices from January to April 2004 alone, only two of which were legitimate takedown notices.149 In the previous 12 months, the same ISP received over 90,000 invalid peer-to-peer notices.150 As the Vice President and Associate General Counsel of Verizon Communications, Inc., Sarah Deutsch noted, copyright owners can use automated programs to send out notices with no due diligence, but each notice received requires human intervention by the ISP to see if they are valid or not.151 More detailed information including about the subpoena system in the US and its cost to ISPs can be found at http://www.eff.org/IP/FTAA/ISP_june05.pdf and more examples of invalid takedown notices at http://www.eff.org/IP/P2P/20030926_unsafe_harbors.php. Kimberlee Weatherall’s submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America. 147 Pacific Bell Internet Services v. Recording Industry Association of America, Inc et al, (U.S. District Court, Northern District of California, San Francisco Division, Case No. C 03-3560 SI). 148 http://www.eff.org/IP/FTAA/ISP_june05.pdf 149 http://www.eff.org/IP/FTAA/ISP_june05.pdf 150 http://www.eff.org/IP/FTAA/ISP_june05.pdf 151 http://www.eff.org/IP/FTAA/ISP_june05.pdf 146 120 This abuse of the take-down notices in the USA led a US Congressman to call for a Congressional investigation into the practice.152 Given the concerns of all of the Vice-Chancellors of the universities in Australia about the effect of the internet service provider provisions on them as they may be considered to be ISPs,153 has the Malaysian Government consulted all Malaysian Universities as to their ability to comply with any internet service provider provisions in MUFTA? Australia’s obligations under the AUSFTA with respect to internet service providers closely parallel those in the USA’s Digital Millennium Copyright Act 154 which has been widely criticized and challenged. Submissions to the Australian Senate Inquiry into the Australia-USFTA reiterated that ‘recognition must be given to the realities of resource limitations in managing networks’155 J. IMPLEMENTATION If countries think that they can sign a USFTA and then use loopholes during implementation to mitigate the FTA’s effects, they should be aware that the USTR continues to press for stronger IP protection than the USFTA requires during implementation, including during the drafting of implementing legislation.156 For example after Guatemala finalized its USFTA, the USTR gave it four pages of detailed comments and demands which can be seen here http://www.cptech.org/ip/health/trade/cafta/ustr11162005.pdf. K. IPRS: SUMMARY ON EFFECTS OF MUFTA The provisions in the intellectual property (IP) chapter of a Malaysia-US free trade agreement (MUFTA) may have far-reaching consequences for a wide range of areas: Malaysia’s culture; farmers; government-linked companies; students; the blind; businesses; actors, directors, producers and all those involved in the Malaysian audiovisual industry and any Malaysian who gets sick and needs medicine. The IP provisions in USFTAs require much stronger levels of IP protection than Malaysia is currently required to provide under the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) at the World Trade Organization (WTO). 152 http://www.eff.org/IP/FTAA/ISP_june05.pdf. Australian Vice-Chancellors’ Committee Submission to the Senate Select Committee on the Free Trade Agreement between Australia and the United States of America 154 ‘Protecting the messenger: carriage service providers’ liability for third party copyright infringement’, Jan Charbonneau, https://elaw.murdoch.edu.au/issues/2006/2/elaw_Protecting%20the%20Messenger%20for%20Carriage %20Service%20Providers.pdf 155 Australian Digital Alliance (a coalition of IT companies, scientific and research organizations, schools, universities, consumer groups, cultural institutions, libraries and individuals) submission from http://www.aph.gov.au/Senate/committee/freetrade_ctte/submissions/sublist.htm. 156 Letter by some US Congress representatives to the USTR, available at http://www.cptech.org/ip/health/trade/cafta/representatives04072006.pdf 153 121 The TRIPS agreement has already been widely criticised as obliging developing counties to adopt standards of IP higher than appropriate for their level of development. There are negative effects such as higher medicine prices, obstacles to industries to upgrade their technology, compulsory patenting of some life forms, introducing IP to farm seeds (which in many countries were exempted before), and facilitating bio-piracy (misappropriation by multinational companies of genetic resources and traditional knowledge belonging to developing countries). The developing countries increasingly realise that higher standards of IP can be detrimental to development in many ways. There must be a balance between the IP monopoly given to private individuals and companies, and the public interest. They have thus initiated a movement inside WIPO to institute a Development Agenda, to orientate IPR policies towards development needs and the public interest. The FTA imposes even stricter standards of IP than even the TRIPS and thus makes the present imbalance even worse. Malaysia’s farmers will be affected by making their inputs (such as seeds and agricultural chemicals) more expensive, and as they lose significant control over the saving of their seeds. The data exclusivity clause for agricultural chemicals will also make these more expensive and raise production costs. Malaysia’s national goal to promote biodiversity and traditional knowledge and the fair sharing of benefits from their use will be affected by the probable demands of the MUFTA that the country join the UPOV 1991 treaty, and the Budapest Treaty relating to microorganisms. Malaysian businesses may also face higher input costs from the IP chapter of a MUFTA. In specific sectors such as Malaysia’s generic medicine manufacturing, one of Malaysia’s largest generic companies, Hovid Berhad is already setting up manufacturing in India because ‘Once the FTA takes effect, many local pharmaceutical companies such as Hovid would stand to lose out to US-based multinational pharmaceutical companies.’ Another sector that may be significantly affected is internet service providers. There are Malaysian government-linked companies that make generic medicines (e.g. Pharmaniaga) and provide internet services (e.g. TM Net). The prospect of stronger intellectual property protection under a USFTA has also caused many to fear increases in medicine prices in Malaysia. Malaysia’s patent law will most likely have to change in many areas to accommodate the American FTA demands. They potentially include: having a data exclusivity clause; extending the term of drug patents; linkage between patents and marketing approval by the drug regulatory authority; restricting the ground for compulsory licensing; and a possible restriction on parallel importation. Access to information and knowledge will be another major area to be affected, as copyright laws will tighten, with extension of copyright term by 20 years, and with the “locking in” of technological protection measures. Not only academics, students, 122 and scientists but also the blind may also be particularly disadvantaged by the stronger copyright provisions. The possible negative impacts due to the intellectual property chapter can be exacerbated by other chapters in a USFTA such as the preamble and the investment and dispute settlement chapters. As the eminent Commission on Intellectual Property Rights states ‘there are no circumstances in which the most fundamental human rights should be subordinated to the requirements of IP protection. IP rights are granted by states for limited times (at least in the case of patents and copyrights) whereas human rights are inalienable and universal… Developing countries should not have to accept IP rights imposed by the developed world, outside their existing commitments to international agreements.’ 16. NEED FOR POLICY FRAMEWORK AND ASSESSMENT OF COSTS AND BENEFITS Negotiating an FTA is a serious exercise as the outcome can have major implications for development policy and for social, economic and development outcomes. While it can result in some export gains, it can also: (a) result in increases in imports, with implications for the trade balance and the debt position; (b) facilitate import surges as tariffs decline or are eliminated, and this can adversely affect the local industries and farms; (c) reduce tariff revenue, with consequences for the government budget; (d) restrict and in some cases remove “policy space,” or the options and instruments available to a country to institute certain social, economic and development policies. Thus, before negotiating an FTA, the country needs to have three things in place. Firstly, a national development policy framework comprising an overall development strategy, with sectoral national plans (for agriculture, industry and services) and issuebased plans (policy towards foreign investment, local participation in the economy, intellectual property, etc). The proposals put forward by the FTA partner or potential partner can then be assessed within the context of such a framework. Similarly, the positions of the country in the FTA negotiations can be formulated in light of the framework. In the absence of such a framework, it would be difficult to determine the objectives of entering an FTA negotiation, or of the advantages or otherwise of the proposed FTA. Secondly, there should be a framework to assess the benefits and costs of the FTA, in terms of its various components and of the various proposals and provisions, and the overall balance. The benefits and costs can be assessed in terms of: (a) gains and losses in trade terms: eg. increase in exports, imports; (b) gains and losses in terms of jobs; (c) effects on the degree of policy space and flexibilities available to the country as a result of the FTA; (d) social effects: on access to health, to knowledge, food security etc; (e) effects on technology transfer. Other items can be added. 123 The costs and benefits can be applied to the various aspects of the FTA, including market access (to the other country, and the partner country’s access to one’s own market) in goods; services; intellectual property; investment, competition and government procurement; and labour and environment standards. The cross-cutting social and environmental costs can also be assessed. In general, a developing country can expect (or hope) to benefit from some market access in goods from an FTA with a developed country. This has to be weighed against the market access to be gained by the partner to its own home market. If the country lacks production and export capacity, or if the partner does not offer significant concessions, then it is possible that there may be a net cost rather than benefit, especially if the FTA is on a reciprocal basis (with no SDT for the developing country). The developing country can be expected to suffer costs in additional IPR obligations beyond the already onerous obligations in TRIPS. These costs are losses to the nation since most patents, copyright and other forms of IP are owned by foreigners. The costs can be in terms of increased royalty and IP licence payments (with resulting loss in foreign exchange) or higher prices of the protected products, and in terms of the social costs of decreased access to medicines, decreased access to knowledge, decrease in farmers’ rights to seeds and other resources, and decrease in food security possibilities. Regarding investment, there can be expected to be major costs to the developing country in terms of loss of policy space and the use of policy instruments such as regulation of entry of foreign investment, performance requirements, regulation of the flow of funds, etc. The threat of expropriation cases being taken by investors can also have a real or chilling effect on national policies. The ability to use investment policy as a means to increase local participation in the economy, or to nurture local firms and farms, will also be severely restricted. Regarding government procurement, the loss of policy space will be immense as procurement policy is a major social and economic instrument for boosting the domestic economy and to redress social imbalances. The requirement to give national treatment for foreign goods, services and firms, can also result in loss of market share of local firms, and loss of foreign exchange. There can be loss of effect of fiscal policy, eg an increase in government spending to boost economic growth will have reduced effect if there is higher “leakage” through increased imports of goods and services procured by government. There can also be considerable loss of policy space and options with regard to the other non-trade issues such as competition policy, labour and environmental standards, as well as in terms of effects on the competitive position of local enterprises. An example of a simple cost-benefit chart is given below. It can be made more complex, reflecting the realities of the particular country concerned. 124 Example of FTA Cost-benefit Framework Possible benefits 1. Market access in goods: a. Agriculture b. Industrial 2. Market access in services: a. commercial services b. labour 3. Possible concessions on SPS and TBT? 4. Possible aid mechanisms? 5. Possible technology flows investment Possible costs 1. Market access into country: a. industrial goods b. agriculture 2. Market access into country Services 3. Intellectual property (a)Access to medicines (b) Lifeforms (c) Plant varieties (d) Biodiversity and disclosure and requirements (e) Copyright and access to information (f) Broadcasting 4., Singapore Issues (a) Investment (b) Government procurement (c) Competition policy 5 Labour, environment standards 6. Environmental costs Thirdly, the country should establish or organize the resources and institutional base for assessing whether or not to enter negotiations for the FTA; and if so, to organize the negotiating teams, objectives, and conduct of the negotiations. As part of the process, different agencies of the government should be consulted and should be part of the process of the formulation of policy and positions. It is equally important to involve stakeholders, such as local firms, trade unions, farmers, consumers, groups representing patients and involved in health provision and environmental protection. This is especially because the FTA can have such wide-ranging effect on society. Eventually, national decisions have to be taken as to: (1) whether in principle to enter negotiations in the FTA; (2) how to conduct the negotiations; (3) what issues to include and exclude from the FTA; (4) putting positions forward; (5) assessing the other party’s position. (6) continuously assessing the costs and benefits of proposals and provisions; (7) whether or not to conclude the negotiations, if there are many sticking points and outstanding issues. 125 References AMCHAM Malaysia (2006). Public submission for the proposed US-Malaysia Free Trade Agreement. By AMCHAM Malaysia and US Chamber of Commerce. Carlsen, Laura (2003). The Mexican experience and Lessons for WTO negotiations on the agreement on agriculture. (Speech to European Parliament). Americas Program, Interhemispheric Resource Centre. Khor, Martin (2003). The WTO Singapore Issues: What’s at stake and why it matters. (TWN briefing paper 16). Khor, Martin (2005). Intellectual Property, Competition and Development. Paper presented at the WTO symposium on intellectual property and development, May 2005. Koh, Tommy and Chang Li Lin (editors) (2004). The United States Singapore Free Trade Agreement: Highlights and Insights. Singapore Médecins Sans Frontières (2004). “Access to Medicines at Risk Across the Globe” Oxfam International (2005). Kicking down the door. Briefing paper no. 72. Smith, Sanya (2007). Intellectual property chapter in United States FTAs. Smith, Sanya (2005). Market access: where’s the beef? (Draft paper). United States (2002). Trade Promotion Authority Act of 2002. United States Trade Representative (2006). Foreign Trade Barriers. United States Department of Agriculture (2007). Rice Outlook, 12 Feb. 2007. U.S. Singapore Free Trade Agreement: Text of the Agreement World Trade Organisation (1994). The results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations: The Legal Texts. World Trade Organisation (2005). Trade Policy Review Malaysia: Report by the Secretariat. 126