1 The economics of hope: Trust, trade and human progress A proposal for a book By Matt Ridley 2 ``On what principle is it that, when we see nothing but improvement behind us, we are to expect nothing but deterioration before us?’’ Thomas Babington Macaulay, 1830 Synopsis In ten thousand years the human race has expanded from less than ten million to nearly ten billion people. Some of those ten billion live in misery and want even worse than the worst experienced in the stone age. But the vast majority do not: probably 99% of people are much better fed, much better sheltered, much better entertained, much better protected against disease and much more likely to live to old age. The availability of almost everything a person could want or need has been going rapidly upwards for 200 years and erratically upwards for 10,000 years before that: calories, vitamins, clean water, machines, privacy, means of travelling faster than you can run, ways of communicating over longer distances than you can shout. There are exceptions, where things are getting worse on average. There is less emptiness, more of some forms of pollution, more terrorism, more obesity, perhaps more unhappiness (but then, as any Buddhist would tell you, happiness is relative, not absolute, so it’s bound to recede forever into the distance). And there are plenty of people who tell us that the good times are all coming to a disastrous end some day soon, that we are like the man falling past the second floor of the skyscraper who says `So far, so good!’ I think they are wrong and future material progress for all is not only possible but likely. In this book I want to ask how it can be that we six billion are, on average, far more prosperous than people have ever been before. I think I have a surprising and universal answer, namely that prosperity consists of having access to the effort and ingenuity of others through trade, trust and technology – and that progress consists of increasing that access. It’s not so much the division of labour; it’s the multiplication of talent. 3 This notion explains more than purely economic facts. Power is the confiscation of others’ efforts. Politics is the diversion or monopolisation of their efforts. Property is the purchase of their efforts. Energy, in the form of oil or electricity, is the amplification of effort. Technology is the capture and embodiment of a craftsman’s effort in machines, bringing together the talents of people across centuries and countries. Trade is the about the exchange of effort – bringing together to best advantage the fruits of different people’s talents across the globe. Progress in short IS the multiplication of talent. And here lies a central paradox. As consumers, we have become more and more diversified people: we experience more and more activities and use more and more things. The richer you get, the less restricted your consumption. But to achieve that, we have to become more and more specialised as producers. An airline pilot or an insurance salesman produces only one thing; but consumes many. This is not of course an entirely new idea. The Anglo-Irish economist Sir William Petty first spotted the importance of the division of labour in Cromwell’s time, and Adam Smith brilliantly developed the notion a century later. David Ricardo, Emil Durkheim, Karl Marx and many others added to the thought. The central role of mutually beneficial exchange was explored by Robert Wright, in `Non-Zero’, and myself in `The Origins of Virtue’. But never till now has anybody tried to make the case that all human progress can be seen through the lens of this idea, and exploring how far it will take us to understanding the human enterprise. I am not a trained economist but then I was not a trained geneticist either when I wrote `Genome’. In 20 years as a reporter and as a columnist, I frequently wrote about economic issues and today, as non-executive chairman of a mortgage bank, I grapple daily with issues of markets, interest rates, credit and growth. I know enough formal economics to understand what the experts mean; but I am sufficiently outside the subject to see the forest for the trees. As with all my books, the writing will be an exploration, 4 and will take me to ideas I do not yet see. When writing a book, I do not know exactly where it will lead. In three of my previous books (`The Red Queen’, `The Origins of Virtue’ and `Nature via Nurture’) I have explored how far human behaviour is the expression of an invariant, innate nature. Yet, though in some ways we are condemned to repeat the attitudes and aspirations of our ancestors, life is dramatically different for each new generation. This book starts where the others leave off. It tries to explain why human beings, uniquely among animals, steadily improve the conditions of their lives, generation by generation. It is about the things that do change, and why they change: how a fixed human nature cumulatively and progressively alters and is altered by the world in which it is expressed. The book will go back into the distant stone-age past and forward to the latest neuroscientific future in search of explanations of the human capacity to progress. It will be 80,000 – 100,000 words long and will take two years to research and write, to be delivered in early 2009. -------------------------------------- 5 Contents Chapter 1 Are we really better off? Chapter 2 The first division of labour Chapter 3 Trade: the exchange of effort Chapter 4 Technology: the amplification of effort Chapter 5 Social technologies and trust Chapter 6 The taming of religion and violence Chapter 7 Sensibility and Nostalgia Chapter 8 Environmental progress Chapter 9 The future -------------------------------------- 6 Chapter 1 Are we really better off? It appears that material prosperity is greater today than at any time. Even allowing for the millions who live in abject poverty, disease and want, this generation of human beings has access to more calories, watts, gigabytes, megahertz, miles per gallon, dollars, vitamins, medicines, machines, shoes, singers, soap operas, sexual partners and anything else one can covet. That fact is a source of almost universal disgust among the intelligentsia, who, steeped in the puritan traditions of Christianity and filled with the evolved instinct of jealousy, despise material wealth. Their claim is that affluence has come at a profound spiritual cost. They may be right: my aim is not to moralise, at least not yet. My aim is to explain this fact of increasing material wealth. Of course, a modern dollar buys less than it did, so perhaps our greater prosperity is an illusion caused by inflation. But for most things that is irrelevant. Take Thomas Babington – Lord – Macaulay, the historian who 160 years ago in 1845 celebrated the progress that had happened in the preceding 160 years and boasted of the wealth and comforts of his own age while lambasting those who looked back to an illusory golden past. Macaulay was – once he rebuilt the fortunes of his family by taking a lucrative position in India – rich by the standards of the day. He had footmen at his beck and call. Compare him to the average citizen of Britain today, say a woman working in a banking call centre on £15,000 a year. She is, in relative terms, immeasurably poorer than he was. Where he was among the richest of the rich in what was then one of the world’s richest cities, she is now on the median income. She has no servants, where he had scores. She lives in a modest house, where he lived in a mansion. She uses public transport where he had a coach and four at his beck and call. And yet consider this. She may have no servants, but she can go to an Indian restaurant and have an excellent meal cooked for her by a very good cook. She employs no tailor, but she can easily afford excellent cotton clothes made up for her in a Vietnamese 7 factory. She has no coach, but she can buy a ticket which will summon the services of a skilled pilot of a budget airline to fly her for a week in Spain. She has no pocket borough, but she employs the operators of a gas rig in the North Sea to bring her comparatively cheap central heating. She has no wick-trimming footman, but her light switch gives her the instant and brilliant produce of hard-working people at a distant power station. She has no runner to send messages, but she has a mobile phone instead, designed by anonymous genii in distant lands and using a network maintained by diligent experts. She has no retained apothecary, but her dentist uses local anaesthetic and durable amalgam invented by some scientist. She does not hear unreliable gossip in the tavern about the disappearance of Franklin, but at the flick of a switch she can get a television newsreader to tell her about a film star’s divorce in California. The point is that she is richer than he was, not because she has more money, or more property, or more resources, but because she has more services. Despite having no servants, she has more people working for her. She does not employ them directly, and she shares them with many others, but they work for her as surely as Macaulay’s butler did for him. It is as if she employs these people directly. And she employs not only the newsreader and oil-rig worker; she employs people long dead or thousands of miles away: John Logie Baird and Alexander Graham Bell and Sir Tim Berners Lee and Thomas Crapper and Jonas Salk and myriad assorted other inventors. She gets the benefit of their labours, too, whether they are dead or alive. Their labour has been embodied in their inventions to continue serving her indefinitely. It is the simple proposition of this book that wealth is getting other people to work for you and progress is expanding the number of them. -------------------------------------- 8 Chapter 2 The first division of labour In the evolution of life, too, progress depends on multiplying the access of individual units to each others’ talents. Lichens are joint ventures between structural fungi and photosynthesising algae. Indeed, all animals and plants are collaborative ventures between oxygen-using bacteria called mitochondria and larger cells. You can make a case that evolutionary `progress’ – the invention, for example, of multi-cellular forms, the emergence of bigger brains in social animals – consists of new steps in dividing labour and exchanging talent. Ants are probably the most spectacular example of divided labour among individuals of a species – workers, soldiers and queens, though genetically very similar, come to look completely different. The immense success of the ants has much to do with this invention, a neat parallel with human industry. But even ants have a very limited range of castes. Note, by the way, that human beings have never divided reproductive labour as ants do. Even in Britain, we do not expect Queen Elizabeth to do our breeding for us. In human beings, the oldest division of labour of all is probably the sexual one. Mammals divide reproductive skills between the sexes, almost by definition. Females gestate and lactate, while males…don’t. Sometimes the bargain is relatively egalitarian: in pygmy marmosets, the male looks after the baby all day while the female forages to get enough calories to feed the baby with milk at night. A million years ago our ancestors were just typical animals in every sense. They occupied an ecological niche, killing, scavenging or gathering rodents, antelope calves, fruits and tubers; living in wide home ranges on grassy plains or wooded lake shores; breeding at a certain age, one young at a time, maturing slowly. I can’t know the details for sure and nor can anybody, but from around this time onwards they had one thing going for them that nearby baboons and warthogs did not: a rudimentary division of labour between the sexes. 9 Males had started pursuing and eating meat much more than females. This is highly unusual among animals, but it is by no means unknown. It is generally explained by something called a niche-separation hypothesis. If males eat different things from females, they compete less with them and both sexes benefit. New Zealand’s extinct huia bird had this strategy, with the male and female even having different shaped beaks. You can see this niche-separation today in many modern women’s much lesser fascination with meat. You can also see it in the fact that among hunter-gatherers it is an almost inviolable rule that men hunt and women gather. But the hunter-gatherers also show something different: at some point male and female began sharing their food. Now no longer was the different foraging strategy a matter of niche separation. It was a multiplication of talent. Men brought scarce, unreliable and valuable protein to the feast; women supplied regular, staple carbohydrate. Each was better off for the other’s contribution. Men probably could not afford to spend days on a hunting expedition that might be fruitless unless they knew that women could feed them if they failed. Women could not rear big-brained babies on roots and seeds unless they knew that men were bringing protein. It’s a classic gain from trade, a non-zero sum, and it was the first. By becoming more specialised in their production, each sex became more diversified in its consumption. The invention of the sexual division of labour benefited both genders. It made the species more competitive and allowed it to occupy new niches and habitats. According to one recent study, it almost certainly was not shared by the Neanderthals and thus helps to explain their displacement by African immigrants. But it was only the first division of labour. -------------------------------------- 10 Chapter 3 Trade: the exchange of effort The next step in human progress was to multiply access to the talents of other individuals and groups. The evidence suggests that specialisation in human skills came very early. By 30,000 years ago people were talented specialists: some were good hunters, some good makers of tools and some good leaders. To get to this point, people had had to accept sharing arrangements. Two commodities in particular may have encouraged sharing: big game and fire. A dead mammoth, or a good fire, is not worth keeping to yourself. You can share it at little cost. Agriculture brought a new dilemma, the so-called `husbandry problem’. To rear a goat or a wheat plant, keeping it safe and healthy, takes much time and work. To go out and kill a wild goat, or harvest a wild wheat plant, takes just a few hours. So why waste time on the former activity? Some believe that the invention of agriculture was not progress, but regress, a desperate response to near starvation: although populations increased, health declined. But it was made possible by further specialisation. The farmer growing wheat could trade his surplus grain for a hunter’s meat. By the time William Petty coined the phrase `the division of labour’ in the seventeenth century – after watching the efficient Dutch shipmakers building a ship in modules that were then assembled – specialisation was a central fact of economic life. So ancient is this peculiar human trait that it has left its mark on our psyches. From about the age of ten, children start to identify their own and each other’s particular skills and to reinforce them by doing much more of what they are good at, and much less of what they are bad at. Trade is uniquely human. For most other features of human existence, there is at least a rudimentary animal analogue. Dolphins have language, crows make tools, chimpanzees have cultural traditions, elephants have a sense of self, bower birds make art. But for trade there is nothing: in no other species does one group of animals generate a surplus of some good and swap it for another group’s surplus of a different good. 11 And trade is, without doubt, the source of most human prosperity. It enables people to have things they cannot grow or produce at their home, but far more than that, it allows specialisation, division of labour and almost incredibly greater productivity for those at both ends of each trade. How ancient is trade? Burial goods from 30,000 years ago show items of jewellery, made from sea shells, travelling long distances inland. Obsidian glass blades and yellow ochre body paint were moving long distances perhaps ten times as long ago as that. Australian aborigines, when still hunter-gatherers, were trading extensively. The experimental study of trade has only just begun. This chapter will recount the first faltering attempts by Vernon Smith and his colleagues to recreate in a game on a computer network the problems that face international traders, revealing just how the psychology of the trader develops. It was traders who built the prosperity on which empires were built: the Phoenicians first straddled the Mediterranean. The Hansa merchants united Northern Europe. The Fujian Chinese knitted together east Asia. The Gujarati Indians made the Indian Ocean one. In China, in India, the British empire, even in Inca Peru, it was trade that came first and that generated the surpluses for kings and tyrants to confiscate. The great leaps of progress and civilisation were made by traders. The Phoenicians, the Mayans, the Greeks, the Chinese, the Florentines, Venetians and Genoans, the Dutch, the British and the Americans all built empires from trade networks rather than vice versa. Concentrated imperial wealth and military power – in ancient Egypt, classical Rome, Inca Peru, imperial Spain or modern Baghdad – depends entirely on monopolising or taxing the gains from trade. Political power is essentially parasitic on trade. -------------------------------------- 12 Chapter 4 Technology: the amplification of effort Human beings are condemned to rebuild their natures in every generation. But each generation grows up amid quite new technology. Born in 1750 and you would probably never travel faster than the speed of a galloping horse, and nor would your letters; born fifty years later and you would happily find yourself going like the wind in trains, and getting messages by telegraph almost instantaneously. When I was born the idea of sending a letter from a blackberry while sitting in a train was unimaginable and unimagined (seers of the 1950s expected transport, not communication to innovate fast). Why does progress in technology result in progress in prosperity? There is of course nothing valuable about the machines themselves. A spinning jenny is not an asset except in what it can do – enable a man to make more cloth, sell it and live off the proceeds. But even that has it backwards. It is not the producer that counts, but the consumer. The person who buys a cloth made by a machine has been served more cheaply. It is his wellbeing that has been increased. Technology serves progress to the extent that it allows people to draw on the services of others. The most obvious examples are in the field of energy. The discovery of fire, of coal, of oil, of nuclear power and the invention of steam engines, turbines, electricity are useful precisely because they amplify the effort that people can draw upon. (So did the domestication of horses and oxen.) Technology is progress to the extent that it amplifies the amount of work a person can call upon. Innovation in technology is crucial to progress. In the 1200s, for example, medieval Christendom enjoyed unprecedented peace, prosperity and – for abbots and lords – growing wealth. But because there was virtually no innovation, especially in agriculture, the average peasant ended the century poorer than his grandfather – thanks to deflation, another word for regress. Innovation, in a world where most people mistrust change, is a tender plant that withers easily. Philosophers like to think they create it, technology being 13 a spin-off from scientific discovery. But this is only occasionally the case. Discovery usually follows invention rather than the other way around. And there is only one reliable engine of invention: competition. All forms of monopoly suppress innovation; all forms of competition encourage it. That is why governments did not invent mobile phones, but firms did. That is why unified, bureaucratised Ming China fell suddenly behind fragmented Renaissance Europe, where cities and states competed for the talents of inventors. The great boon of the free market is not that it drives down costs, though it often does, but that it drives up the rate of innovation. Innovation comes from people tinkering with their tools and their services to gain incremental gains over each other. Does new technology drive new prosperity? Was the growth of recent decades down to the computer, the mobile phone and the internet, as the growth of the 1820s was down to weaving and spinning machines, or the growth of the 1920s was down to cars and production lines? In a sense yes, but not in the determinist way that `endogenous theory’ would have you believe. Possessing a gadget does not make you richer and producing one certainly does not. Using a gadget does not automatically make you richer either. Only using that gadget to draw upon the services offered by other people does. Once again progress is down to getting access to others’ efforts. The consumer, not the producer, is who counts. That is why the internet is only as good as the things you can do with it. What is valuable is not the network and the processors, but the work that has gone into Google, Wikipedia, Amazon, Ebay and their ilk: the incredible shrinkage of time and effort it now takes to check a fact, track down a friend, order a CD, book a ticket or find a provider of an obscure good. The services you can draw on, not the money you use to buy them, are your wealth. -------------------------------------- 14 Chapter 5 Social technologies and trust So where and how do trade, technology and exchange deliver their magic? There is nothing inevitable about it. Countries, regions and whole empires have stagnated or even rotted as trade has failed to flourish. The standard of living in the Mediterranean region probably regressed between 1500 BC and 500 BC and in China between 1500 AD and 1980. The spectacular surges in prosperity on which progress depends happen all too rarely and in unexpected places. There is no particular correlation with political regime. Some democracies like America experience rapid progress; others like Haiti don’t. Communism in North Korea kills prosperity; slightly relaxed in Vietnam it delivers excellent material improvement. Autocrats like Mao are disastrous; others like Peter the Great may not be so bad. Nor is access to resources much use: countries like Congo or Russia with ample metals, oil or diamonds often suffer from the corruption and stagnation that goes by the name of the `curse of resources’. Even the industrious Netherlands was sunk into lethargy by an abundance of North Sea Gas in the 1980s. Britain is sometimes said to have built its nineteenth century prosperity on coal, but France, Germany and China had just as much coal. It was the means of expanding trade they lacked. No, the thing that defines a nation’s capacity for progress is much more intangible. It is the building of institutions that foster human exchange – markets, firms, clubs and coffee houses; the rule of law, secure property rights, sound money; credit. Why do these `social technologies’ matter so much? Because they create trust and with trust people begin to take risks and venture enterprises. The cost of credit, for example, is directly related to the degree of trust. Credit borrows the cost of today’s investment from the wealthy future. Trust is the central psychological ingredient of progress. Merchants in a market must trust each other to deliver deals. Traders must risk their money on trust. From a Hanseatic merchant to a modern bond dealer, there is an extraordinary need for and reliance upon 15 trust. The great success of the Fujian Chinese in the East Indies, the Jews in medieval Europe and the Parsis in India came from their networks of trust within kith and kin. A Fujian trader could carry the risks of sending a cargo home was because he (often she) was sending it to family relatives he could trust. Trust builds slowly and incrementally within a merchant society; it cannot be created in an instant. But once created it spills over into civic virtue generally. That is why it is merchant societies, in Greek city states, Italian Renaissance republics or Manhattan skyscrapers who have pioneered the development of art, of thought and of charity. You can measure trust and test it. International surveys reveal how some countries have it more than others. The frequency with which a wallet left in the street will be returned to its owner is symptomatic of a society’s level of trust. Trust is like money: you must invest it to grow it. Societies that have been devastated by war but are left with good levels of trust will soon recover; others that are luxuriating in sudden prosperity but lack trust will soon stagnate. Indeed, it is now possible not just to study trust inside the brain, but to induce it, too. In a remarkable series of experiments, people like Paul Zak and Ernst Fehr have shown that they can make people more trustworthy in computer games, by squirting puffs of the brain hormone oxytocin up their noses. Oxytocin is the hormone that causes a ewe to build a bond with her lamb, or causes a monogamous prairie vole to become mentally addicted to her mate. It is also the hormone that enables people to build bonds with strangers. So what is it that triggers the release of oxytocin inside a person’s brain? This chapter will explore the latest research, as yet unpublished. The author will himself attempt to alter his behaviour using oxytocin. -------------------------------------- 16 Chapter 6 The Taming of Religion and Violence If I am right and trade, technology and trust lie at the heart of human progress, why do so many people spend so little of their time admiring commerce? That is to say, why have most of the world’s idealists been set on either religious or political careers? And why is the universal view of trade, shared equally by a modern socialist anticapitalist and a Victorian earl, so dismissive of trade? Why is the intelligentsia so virulently anticonsumerist? Exchange is usually a mere footnote in the telling of history. You can tell the story of, say, the sixteenth century while barely mentioning trade – you would mention people like Luther and Charles V; even if you did mention Cortez and Vasco da Gama it would be their vicious conquering, not their legacy of trade, that caught your attention. Drake the pirate outshines every London merchant of his time. The truth is that trade just is not good box office, at least not alongside burnt heretics and besieged cities. To this day, even modern business news consists mainly of boardroom battles, corporate crimes or tales of heroic leadership. This is partly because the instinct to exchange is such a recent feature of human life that it often struggles to be heard among the older instincts of ambition, violence, treachery and superstition. So every time we get the progress engine turning, some fool hijacks its output to pursue political ambitions. The Phoenicians and Greeks unite the Mediterranean with trade only to have their efforts subsumed within the empires of Carthage and Rome, so that we read about Hannibal and Scipio rather than the merchants that made their feats possible. The pre-Ming Chinese created a ferment of invention and exchange only to enrich an emperor who preferred to retreat into bureaucracy and luxury. Clive of India embodied, in his career, the very problem: sent to trade with Madrassi merchants, he ended up conquering and exacting tributes from Bengali princes instead. 17 Of course, in a society divided into specialist producers exchanging their products, there is a place for warriors and priests. Fighting and praying are themselves farmed out to specialists, just as weaving and tanning are. A society that neglects to provide its defence will be conquered. But it is quite wrong to see either violence or religion as playing any role in progress. Even the old Max Weber notion of the `Protestant work ethic’, which saw the Reformation as preparing the way for the Industrial Revolution, reads history backwards. It was the invention of, especially, printing that made the Reformation possible. (The notion that progress only reached benighted savages because of military conquest or religious missions will be easily despatched.) None the less, history suggests that we have grown gradually better at solving the problem of human violence by handing a monopoly on violence to a government and tying it down with constitutional strings to prevent it using that violence against any but the criminal. The beast of human violence, thus tamed, becomes ever more implicit – the blue light on a policeman’s car is all you need to see to know who has a monopoly of force. The trouble is, the beast keeps escaping, to invade Poland, launch a cultural revolution, or crash an airliner into a building. Religion, likewise, can be domesticated. In this case, it is a matter of gradually taking its grip off the windpipe of commerce – abolish its monasteries, nationalise its tithes – and then gradually redirecting its efforts into charity. All religions have made astonishing progress over the millennia, from blood-letting cults to conscientious philanthropies, and – violent reformations and vengeful ayatollahs notwithstanding – the three great monotheisms have done so in remarkable parallel. Progress indeed. -------------------------------------- 18 Chapter 7 Sensibility and Nostalgia Religious progress reminds us that progress is not just an economic phenomenon. As well as becoming wealthier, we are also becoming nicer. Why so? The intelligentsia would have us believe that the more time we spend in markets and the richer we grow, the coarser and more selfish our morals become. The evidence suggests otherwise. Not only have people become steadily less tolerant of cruelty and injustice as their prosperity has grown, but they have done so most rapidly in the most capitalist, market dominated societies. Progress in sensibility is superficially surprising since human nature is plainly a universal fact owing much to inherited instinct. Generation after generation people are born with the same tendencies, from hunger and thirst to ambition, sexual jealousy and parental affection. The romantic idea shared by Rousseau, Hobbes and most monotheists that we laboriously invented our morals has long since been exploded. But if so, how does sensibility progress? How is it possible for one generation to be intolerant of the casual cruelties of its predecessors? Romans enjoyed the torture of wild beasts in the forum. Under the Tudors, vagabonds were ordered by law to be branded, forced into slavery and hanged if disobedient. Georgians sugared their coffee with the produce of slaves. Victorians sent the indigent poor to workhouses. In the 1920s casual racism and anti-Semitism were quite acceptable. Corporal punishment was normal for children when I was young. How many of the things we take for granted today will be considered disgraceful a century hence? Already a concern for the planet has become a universal virtue in the capitalist rich countries, something unimaginable even a generation ago. Environmental sensibility is the latest step in this inevitable progress from cruelty and intolerance to intolerance of cruelty. Even economists have recently rediscovered that people are motivated by softer incentives than merely profit or self interest. Businesses, rapidly learning to boast of their fine carbon footprints, are making the same discovery. 19 Whence comes this progress in sensibility? A clue lies buried in the environmental debate. Last Valentine’s Day, I ordered flowers for my wife. This was, presumably, a planetary sin: the flowers had been flown from either a fossil-heated greenhouse in Holland or from a farm in Kenya’s Rift Valley in a fossil-powered jet. Either way, the carbon footprint of my little romantic gesture was awful. Yet ironically, the people who would criticise such wasteful luxuries are the very same ones who would accuse economics of being a heartless science concerned only with utility maximisation and not recognising the softer motives of life. In other words, just as economics is discovering its softer side, environmentalism is discovering puritan utility. In this paradox lies the solution to progress in sensibility. My wife did not need flowers. The further people progress from need and from desperation, the more their exchanging will take the form of luxury. And concern for child chimney sweeps, or for the climate, are themselves luxuries unaffordable before. So if the past was nastier why are we so nostalgic? Much of the environmental movement taps into the feeling that there was a golden age, when we all lived in flower-strewn meadows, rather than concrete streets, and woke to larks not sirens. In practice, life in even the poshest iron-age settlement was dominated not just by toil, hunger, smoke, lice, mud, sewage and toothache, but by the threat of violence, too. Nostalgia is progress’s implacable enemy, and pessimism’s eager ally. -------------------------------------- 20 Chapter 8 Environmental Optimism Human progress since the stone age has resulted in ever greater average wealth, despite more and more people using the same small planet. Surely this must cease? Surely we will run out of room, or resources, or luck, soon? Not necessarily. Environmental constraints keep appearing, but expanding human knowledge keeps making them go away. As Julian Simon spotted, resources can substitute for each other and are limited by human ingenuity In 1900 we were going to run out of land to grow food on, but tractors (which don’t need feeding from fields as horses do) and fertilisers solved that problem so we ended the twentieth century comfortably feeding five times as many people as nearly starved in 1900. Then in the 1960s we worried that population growth would accelerate indefinitely, but lowered infant mortality paradoxically lowered the birth rate and we will reach 2050 with a stable world population for the first time in 50,000 years. In the 1970s, we thought we would soon run out of oil, or copper, but the fears proved groundless: ingenuity will keep uncovering new resources till the price chokes off demand and alternatives replace them. In the 1980s we worried about acid rain killing forests, but sulphur trading soon evaporated the problem. In the 1990s it was the ozone layer. Now it is global warming, a problem with plenty of potential solutions, from reforestation and carbon capture to nuclear power, though none of them are painless. The special feature this time is massively political: how to internalise the costs of global warming to every nation so that the magic of exchange and innovation can get to work on it, rather than blunder into a future where everybody waits for another to solve the problem and nobody does. But the idea that we cannot harness the ingenuity of the market, backed by the immense wealth that even the pessimists admit is inexorably coming our grandchildren’s way, to defeating a human-induced two degrees of warming – this idea beggars belief. The next century of progress almost certainly includes continuing a steady 21 shift from burnt carbon to burnt hydrogen as our main source of energy, and it includes unimaginable new wealth to spend on mitigating carbon emissions. All too often environmental problems are presented as insuperable. The truth is, progress can solve them and in solving them can make a better world not just for us but for wilderness and the planet, too. Imagine, for instance, that you could suddenly travel back 1,000 years. The land then grew everything you needed. Not just your food, but your fertiliser (legumes), your fuel (wood), your clothing (wool and flax), your transport (horses), your lighting (tallow candles), your building and roofing (wood and thatch), your medicines (herbs). Even your power came from dispersed sources across the land – water mills and wind mills. Only your metal tools came from point sources. The story of the past thousand years has been how much LESS land-hungry all of those things have become – how concentrated. A car factory released a million acres of oats and hay. A coal mine substituted for ten thousand acres of forest. A synthetic fleece started life in an oil well, whereas a wool jumper needed half an acre of land. Food farming is going the same way. Consider this statistic, calculated by the economist Indur Goklany. If we were to feed the world’s current population of 6.5 billion as generously as we do now, using the yields of 1961, we would need to cultivate 82% of the world’s land surface area. At the moment we cultivate 38%. The intensification of agriculture has therefore not only saved untold numbers of human beings from starvation, it has also saved the rain forest, the desert, the wetlands and the tundras of the world. The worship of self sufficiency is therefore terribly misguided. Wealth is the opposite of self sufficiency: to get a Kansas farmer to supply you with the wherewithal for a loaf of bread whenever you need it, or a Vietnamese factory worker to sew your shirt for you -that is wealth. It is service from multiplied talent, not property or money. It is also vital for the planet that we don’t seek self sufficiency: if 6.5 billion people went back to nature, nature would be devastated. -------------------------------------- 22 Chapter 9 The future In a modern economy, nobody seems to be making anything. Two centuries ago, most people were growing wheat, tending cattle, milling grain, forging horseshoes, weaving cloth or supplying some similarly obvious necessities. A century ago, they were also building railways, manning ships and digging coal. The switch from the farm to the factory was well under way, but it was not difficult to see where prosperity originated: people went to work to supply the needs of others. Today, however, most of us will know hardly anybody who does anything useful. Who’s doing the work? The truth is that there is nothing special about growing food or digging coal. Both are simply means to the end of getting others to serve you. Wealth is calling on the efforts and talents and knowledge of others, especially if those efforts are amplified by mechanical and electrical ingenuity. An economy works just as well if all the food and coal come from somewhere else and people are grooming each other’s poodles, or ogling each other’s websites. What adds value is not some material, hard, utilitarian stuff – and certainly not money – but the services of others, efficiently supplied. And therein lies the paradox. It is the free-marketeer, praising the credit-derivatives trader and the poodle groomer, who has managed at last to free economics from physiocratic materialism. It is the anticapitalist, anti-globalising green who is still stuck in puritanical worship of utility. Global warming is only the latest excuse for pessimism, but pessimism about the future is everywhere and always has been. The future was always going to be terrible and has always proved wonderful. Why will it be different this time? In 1845, when Thomas Babington Macaulay wrote his famous passage on life in London in 1685, 160 years before, he also hazarded wildly optimistic predictions of life in the twentieth century. Now, 160 years later, his prognostications seem laughably cautious 23 (medical discoveries may add `several more years’ to life expectancy!). But his observations about people’s implacable nostalgia reverberate with truth: ``It is now the fashion to place the golden age of England in times when noblemen were destitute of comforts the want of which would be intolerable to a modern footman, when farmers and shopkeepers breakfasted on loaves the very sight of which would raise a riot in a modern workhouse, when to have a clean shirt once a week was a privilege reserved for the higher class of gentry, when men died faster in the purest country air than they now die in the most pestilential lanes of our towns, and when men died faster in the lanes of our towns than they now die on the coast of Guiana. We too shall, in our turn, be outstripped, and in our turn be envied. It may well be, in the twentieth century, that the peasant of Dorsetshire may think himself miserably paid with twenty shillings a week; that the carpenter at Greenwich may receive ten shillings a day; that labouring men may be as little used to dine without meat as they now are to eat rye bread; that sanitary police and medical discoveries may have added several more years to the average length of human life; that numerous comforts and luxuries which are now unknown, or confined to a few, may be within the reach of every diligent and thrifty working man. And yet it may then be the mode to assert that the increase of wealth and the progress of science have benefited the few at the expense of the many, and to talk of the reign of Queen Victoria as the time when England was truly merry England, when all classes were bound together by brotherly sympathy, when the rich did not grind the faces of the poor, and when the poor did not envy the splendour of the rich.’’ 24 About the author Matt Ridley is the author of six highly acclaimed books, including the cult favourite `The Red Queen’, the controversial `The Origins of Virtue’, the enormous best-seller `Genome’ and the prize-winning `Nature via Nurture’. His most recent book was a biography of the scientist Francis Crick. His books are published in 26 languages and have been short-listed for six literary awards. Ridley has always combined his writing with work in the business world and in 2004 he was elected part-time chairman of Britain’s seventh largest bank, Northern Rock plc. He has long wished to bring his writing talent to bear on his everyday experience of economic and commercial life as he has done on the life sciences. In `The Economics of Hope’ he realises this dream and articulates for the first time his original ideas about economic progress. Comments on Ridley’s previous books The Red Queen A bold and fascinating book' – Edward Chancellor 'A terrific book to have a damn good argument with' – Marek Kohn 'Displays a dazzling knowledge of the habits of insects, fish, bird and mammals' – Anthony Daniels 'A vivid introduction to the most exciting of thinking available on the evolution of sex' – Robert Trivers The Origins of Virtue 'Dashing, apophthegmatic, ingenious in argument and beautifully constructed'—Galen Strawson 'Enthralling and provocative'— Penelope Lively 'It has done it brilliantly' – A.S.Byatt 'Bracing, informative, amusing and infuriating by turns' – Maggie Gee 'I was enthralled by it all' – Ruth Rendell Genome 'A lucid and exhilarating romp through our 23 human chromosomes' – James Watson 'The 23 chapters brim with Ridley’s customary stylish wit and cool insouciance' – Richard Dawkins 25 'As elegant, as unpatronising and lucid as a layman could desire' – Miranda Seymour 'An altogether spellbinding read' – Sarah Blaffer Hrdy Nature via Nurture 'Written with insight, wisdom, and style throughout' – Steven Pinker 'Bracingly intelligent, lucid, balanced—witty, too' – Oliver Sacks 'Sets the modern terms for an ancient debate' – Ian McEwan 'Profoundly intelligent and persuasive' – John Cornwell 'Ridley’s enthusiasm for his subject is contagious' – Los Angeles Times Francis Crick `This is a wonderful book--deeply substantive, lucid, trenchant, and witty. It tells the biggest story in modern biology.’ — David Quammen `Ridley’s thoughtful book aims less to unearth new facts than to highlight undervalued ones. He has found some new material...’ — The New York Times end