Розділ 1 Економіка природокористування і еколого-економічні проблеми ЧАСТИНА 1 МЕТОДОЛОГІЧНІ ПРОБЛЕМИ СУЧАСНОЇ ЕКОНОМІКИ Розділ 1 Економіка природокористування і еколого-економічні проблеми УДК 330.34 Peter J. Stauvermann1 How to operationalize Economic, Ecological and Social “Sustainability” for Policy-Making with the help of National/Regional Accounting Matrices including Environmental Accounts In this paper we have derived some minimal conditions for economic, social and environmental sustainability. In general our assumption is that an economy can only be sustainable regarding all three dimensions, if the unemployment rate is zero, if the quantity of emissions is decreasing from year to year and if the production measured in physical units is not decreasing. Combining the different aspects of sustainability, we are able to derive one minimal necessary condition of sustainability (MNCS), which is nothing else than one inequality. 1. Introduction In the report “Our Common Future” of the Brundtland commission (1987), sustainable development was defined, as “… a development that meets the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs”. The problem with this definition is, that it is impossible to operationalize the definition in a satisfactory manner. Because of the missing operationalization of sustainability hundreds of different concepts of sustainability has been developed in the last twenty years. In this time period many definitions have been formulated and many attempts have been made to operationalise the concept in varying forms: with collections of seperate indicators, weighted indices of indicators, dealing explicity with or without economic valuation and monetarization methods and applied on Peter Josef Stauvermann, PhD, Telos, University of Tilburg; Department of Economics, University of Twente, Netherlands. © Peter J. Stauvermann, 2007 1 I thank Bert Steenge, Paul Safonov, Tanya Filatova, Frans Hermans, Ruben Smeets and the partcipiants of the 16th Internationl Conference of the Russian Society of Ecological Economics 2007 in Sochi for helpful suggestions and comments. All remaining errors are mine. Механізм регулювання економіки, 2007, № 3 11 Peter J. Stauvermann. How to operationalize Economic, Ecological and Social “Sustainability” for PolicyMaking with the help of National/Regional Accounting Matrices including Environmental Accounts varying scales: from urban to regional levels up to national and international levels. The list of attempts seems to be endless.2 However, all these definitions have the disadvantage, that they are more or less based on subjective value judgements, which of course could be criticized. Because of this unsatisfactory situation, we discuss another approach, which is partly based on Spangenberg, Omann & Hinterberger (2002). The main idea is to develop a system of minimal necessary conditions, which guarantee that we are not on an unsustainable growth path and which are not based on value judgements. Of course, these conditions can not guarantee that we are on a sustainable growth path. The reason is that we do not have enough knowledge about the physical and biological capacity of our earth. E.g. no scientist knows the sustainable quantity of CO2 emissions in general, however in principle we are able to calculate the natural absorption capacity of the environment (e.g. absorption capacity of forests and other plants with respect to green house gases). Here we want derive minimal necessary conditions for sustainability, which are based on very well accepted sustainability norms. The paper is organized as follows, in part II we derive the minimal necessary conditions for social, economic and ecological sustainability. In the third section we will introduce the concepts of the NAMEA (National Accounting Matrix including environmental accounts) and RAMEA (Regional Accounting Matrix including environmental accounts). In the forth section we will ckeck in how far the Netherlands and the Dutch region Noord-Brabant have fulfilled the sustainability conditions in the time period 2001-2003. In the last section we will conclude our results. II The Minimal Necessary Conditions for Sustainability The starting point of economic sustainability was the notion of sustainable income expressed by Hicks (1946): “…income is the maximum amount an individual can consume during a period and remain as well off at the end of the period as at the beginning.” The sustainable income of Hicks (1946) is interpreted as the amount of income that can be spent without depleting the wealth which generates the income. Hence, sustainability requires non-decreasing levels of capital stock over time, or, at the level of the individual, nondecreasing per capita capital stock. The indicators of sustainability could be based on either the value of total assets every period, or by the change in wealth, depreciation of capital in the conventional national accounts. Consequently, for a proper measure of sustainability, all assets should be included in such an indicator. The main accepted economic indicator is the gross national product (GDP) measured in monetary units. It can be argued that the growth rate of production or GDP should be zero or bigger than zero to fulfill Hicks’ (1946) definition.3 Here we improve and extend the approach of Spangenberg, Omann & Hinterberger (2002). To take the social dimension into account, it is clear that the unemployment rate should be as low as possible, or in other words the number of employees should increase from period to 2 See for a rough overview http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Sustainability Because of the fact that the propulation growth rate is nearly zero in the Netherlands, we do not differentiate between GDP per capita and GDP. However, in general the per capita growth rate of the GDP should be zero or bigger than zero. Additionally, it should be clear from a world-wide view that the population growth rate should be zero to become sustainable. 3 12 Механізм регулювання економіки, 2007, № 3 Розділ 1 Економіка природокористування і еколого-економічні проблеми period as long as unemployment is a permanent problem. We assume that unemployment is obviously the main social problem in the world. Social sustainability is never been reached if unemployment exists.4 Regarding ecological sustainability, we have the problem with respect to question what kind of emissions are important and environmental damages are relevant for ecological sustainability. Here we restrict ourselves to the substances and ecological themes which were proposed by the Dutch national environmental agency (RIVM) and approved by the Dutch government. Of course the quantity of emissions should decrease from period to period In this paper we assume a population growth rate of zero, because this assumption coincides with the development of population in mostly all European countries. Now we will use these assumptions to derive the minimal conditions for sustainability. A. Minimal conditions to reach ecological sustainability: Let us define the amount of emissions as E and the growth rate of this quantity as e. The variable Y represents the output and y the growth rate of output. A necessary condition for ecological sustainability is e 0 , because it is well known from the IPCC reports that humans produce too much emissions. (It might make the statement stronger if you for example cite IPCC report where they tell that human emissions affect global climate processes and caused climate change). This condition is only met, if the growth rate of production y is Y . That means E Y y y e . E lower than the growth rate of eco-productivity (1) The reasoning is that the inverse of eco-productivity is nothing else than eco-efficiency (defined by emissions per unit of output), and it is obvious that the relative increase of ecoefficiency must exceed the relative increase of output, otherwise the total quantity of emissions will increase. To make this point more clear we take the CO2 emissions from traffic into consideration. If we look at each single car or truck it is easy to recognize that the CO2 emissions per km has dramatically decreased the last 20 years in Europe, however the relative increase of driven km exceeded the relative increase of eco-efficiency of cars and trucks a lot in the same period. As a result, the quantity of CO2 emissions from traffic has increased the last 20 years in Europe and everywhere in the world. B. The minimal condition to reach social sustainability: The minimal condition for social sustainability means that the number of employed people is increasing l 0 , where l represents the growth rate of full-time employed people and L the total stock of full-time jobs. The reason for this condition is that mostly in all countries unemployment is omnipresent. Of course, unemployment is not the only social problem, but the most important one regarding inequality of income distribution. As long as the national income is not distributed equally, it is clear that the access to universities, health care system etc. is also not distributed equally. 4 It is clear that it is not sufficient for social sustainability to reach a unemployment rate of zero, also health, eduducation and other variables must be taken into account to measure social sustainability. Here we only argue, that it is a necessary condition for social sustainability that unemployment must be zero. Механізм регулювання економіки, 2007, № 3 13 Peter J. Stauvermann. How to operationalize Economic, Ecological and Social “Sustainability” for PolicyMaking with the help of National/Regional Accounting Matrices including Environmental Accounts We define the labor productivity as Y , than we get the following necessary condition. L Y y y l , L (2) the growth rate of production exceeds the growth rate of labor-productivity, otherwise the rate of unemployment will increase. Please note, that this condition requires that the number of full-time jobs must increase, not the number of employees as a criterion for itself. Obviously, a reduction of the obligatory number of official working hours will lead to an increase of full-time jobs. Or in other words, a reduction of the obligatory number of official working hours of a fulltime worker is a mean to decrease the growth rate of labor productivity per employed person. C. The minimal condition to reach economic sustainability: Following Hicks (1946) a minimal condition for economic sustainability is given by (Growth of output (y>=0) means the growth of supply. That is very often considered as a panacea to achieve sustainability. Do you think that the decrease of demand (change of consumption pattern) could also be considered as an option? Certainly complimentary to the increase of eco-efficiency of production) y 0. (3) If this condition will be violated, future generations will be harmed, because of the reduced consumption possibilities. Or in other words, economic sustainability is only be reached as long as all following generations would have at minimum the same consumption possibilities as our generation. Now we are able to write down the following proposition. Proposition I: A minimal necessary condition to reach social, economic and ecological sustainability requires that the growth rate of labor productivity is lower than the growth rate of output and this former growth rate must be lower than the growth rate of eco-productivity. Proof: Combining inequalities (1), (2) and (3) leads to From this we get easily y l 0 y y e (4) l y 0e. (5) q.e.d. Proposition II: The minimal necessary condition to reach sustainability (MNCS) is l y 0 e . The growth rate of employment must exceed the growth rate of output, which is equal or bigger than zero and the growth rate of emissions is negative. 14 Механізм регулювання економіки, 2007, № 3 Розділ 1 Економіка природокористування і еколого-економічні проблеми It should be noted, that the condition MNCS is necessary but not sufficient to reach sustainability, because it is possible that the speed of the decrease of emissions is too slow to avoid a breakdown of the whole ecological system. To make this more clear take a look at the folling figure 1. Emissions A S B Time Figure 1 – Two development paths In figure 1 we see two development paths A and B, the line marked with the S is the sustainable level of emissions. If a region is on a path like the one marked with A, than the society will be never sustainable, because the emissions are always higher than the sustainable level, although the emissions will decrease from period to period and in so far the environemtal sustainability criterion is fulfilled. The only sustainable path is the path which is marked with the B. A more general formulation of the MNCS where we take all different environmental substances and natural resources into account and population growth would be l y n 0 max e1 ,....em , (6) where the subscripts 1 until m denote the different environmental substances or natural resources. Additionally, we are able to take additional social indicators like income distribution into account. E.g. the relation between the average and the median income. As long as this indicator of inequality is bigger than one the distribution of income is in any case not equal or in other words the poorest 50 percent of the inhabitants earn less than 50% of the national income. To extend inequality (6) we take the aggregate production Y and the aggregate production of 50% quantile then given by Y median . An indicator for the distribution of income is Механізм регулювання економіки, 2007, № 3 15 Peter J. Stauvermann. How to operationalize Economic, Ecological and Social “Sustainability” for PolicyMaking with the help of National/Regional Accounting Matrices including Environmental Accounts d Y Y median , If income inequality shall be reduced, the following inequality must hold: (7) y y median , median where y is the growth rate of the 50% low-income employees.5 If we add this condition to inequality (6), we get the new condition: min l , y median y n 0 max e1 ,....em . (8) It is clear, that we could add some additional conditions, but than the MNCS will become more and more complex and it will become more complicate to fulfill the MNCS, because of an increasing number of trade-offs between the different variables. However, it is easy to find out with the help of the most simple MNCS if a region of country is not on a sustainable growth path. It is much more difficult to say something about if a region is on a sustainable growth path, because we may not ancicipate and take into account all environmental problems. Certainly, the biggest challenge is to bring analytical formalizations to the operational level to make them applicable to and useful in policy making. The section below illustrates how MNCS can be estimated using NAMEA. III The Usefulness of Regional and National Accounting Matrices including Environmental Accounts Here we want to give a short description of the NAMEA/RAMEA system as in use in the Netherlands. We abstain from explaining the details and how the numbers of the NAMEA are compiled. We only want to give a brief overview about the NAMEA, so that it should be possible to understand, what kind of information the NAMEA can provide for policy-makers and economists and how it can be used to estimate MNCS. The NAMEA is a statistical information system to combine national accounts and environmental accounts in a single matrix. It is a so-called satellite accounting matrix (SAM), as it is described in the SNA 1993 (Chapter XXI). 6 The conception of the NAMEA system is based on the work of Keuning (1992) de Haan & Keuning (1996) and de Boo, Bosch, Gorter & Keuning (1991, 1993). The origin of their work is the input-output approach7 of Leontief (1970).8 The NAMEA system is only a descriptive system in which the economy is divided into its economic sectors and the contributions of these sectors to economic and environmental indicators. It maintains a strict borderline between the economic and the environmental 5 This indicator of inequality is explained in detail in Stauvermann (1997), in principle it is a simplified Ginicoefficient. As long as the average income exceeds the median income, it is obvious that the aggregate national income is ditributed in an inequal way. 6 The original idea behind the SAM's (Satellite Accounting Matrix) was to incorporate concerns of inequality and poverty within the national accounts and input-output tables. An introduction to the SAM approach is given in Keuning & de Ruijter (1988), Pyatt & Thorbecke (1976) and Pyatt & Round (1986). 7 Duchin & Steenge (1999) give a technical overview about input-output analysis with respect to environmental problems. Additionally, Duchin (1998) has presented a structural approach of different I-O models. See also Duchin & Lange (1994). 8 Leontief´s (1970) analysis of the physical economy "can be regarded as the first prototype NAMEA since both systems are characterized by a hybrid structure including both physical as well monetary data" (de Haan (2001), p.5). 16 Механізм регулювання економіки, 2007, № 3 Розділ 1 Економіка природокористування і еколого-економічні проблеми aspects. It is represented in monetary units on the one hand and in physical units on the other hand, that is the reason why it is called a hybrid accounting system. To get a clear understanding of the interrelationships between the natural environment and the economy, we must use a physical representation. (Otherwise, we are not able to understand these relations.) If the NAMEA system would contain monetary values about environmental problems, two problems would occur. Firstly, the environmental services, such as CO2 absorption, must be valued in monetary units. If we would like to monetarize environmental damages, it is very delicate task to differentiate between prize changes, quantity changes and the resulting effects on disposal income. Therefore, the resulting indicators are measured in physical units. The interrelationship between the economy and the environment has two perspectives, an economic one and an environmental one. The economic perspective contains the physical requirements in the economic processes, like energy and material and spatial requirements. The environmental perspective puts forward the consequences of these requirements with respect to the availability of the natural environment, which produce resources and absorbs wastes. Consequently, the optimal allocation of natural resources requires the consideration of both perspectives. The fundamental idea of the NAMEA is to extend the conventional national accounting matrix with two additional accounts. One additional account is the account for environmental problems like the greenhouse effect or the ozone layer depletion.9 The selected environmental themes are partly global environmental problems and partly national and local environmental problems. The selected themes are:10 1. Greenhouse effect 2. Ozone layer depletion 3. Acidification 4. Eutrophication 5. Waste 6. Waste water 7. Fossil fuels The second additional account is for environmental substances, like carbon dioxide or sulfur dioxide, where these substances are expressed in physical quantities, like kilogram, tons et cetera. The selected environmental substances are: 11 1. CO2 N 2O 3. CH 4 4. CFC's and halons 5. NO x 2. 9 The numbers for the environmental themes are aggregated with the help of the IPCC conventions. This means e.g. that one kg of CO2 emissions equals one global warming potential, one kg of global warming potentials, and one kg of N 2O emissions equals 270 CH4 equals 11 global warming potentials. 10 See for example the NAMEA table in Keuning, van Dalen & de Haan (1999, p.18-22). 11 See e.g. the NAMEA table in Keuning, van Dalen & de Haan (1999, p.18-22). Механізм регулювання економіки, 2007, № 3 17 Peter J. Stauvermann. How to operationalize Economic, Ecological and Social “Sustainability” for PolicyMaking with the help of National/Regional Accounting Matrices including Environmental Accounts SO2 7. NH 3 6. 8. P 9. N The selection of themes and substances follows those environmental themes which were most important in the view of the Netherlands Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment (1989, 1990, 1992, 1993)12 and with an approval of the Dutch parliament (Tweede Kamer (1996)). The ministry had designed a single indicator each of the environmental themes, by weighing together the emissions that contributed to each theme. 13 It can be said, that the NAMEA generates consistent summary indicators for those environmental problems, which are considered to be most pressing at the political level in the Netherlands. A stylized NAMEA/RAMEA has in general the following form: Table 1 – Table of origins of Noord-Brabant and the Netherlands year labor input labor input of employed GHG theme GHG theme of employed Output NL Output NB perso in full NL in NB in persons NL in EUR in EUR time millions of millions of in full time equivalents kg kg equivalents ns NB Agriculture Industry Services Given this table for two periods of time we have all information which is needed to check if a country or region has fulfilled the minimal condition for sustainability between the periods. All these numbers of table 2 could be found in Stauvermann (2007). We get the following results then. Relative changes of output, employment and emissions in Noord-Brabant and the Netherlands 2001-2003: Applying inequality (6) we get the following results by using the data from table 2. For the Netherlands we get -1.3441>0.07 0>16.147 (7) Obviously, the Netherlands were in the period 2001-2003 not on a sustainable growth path, because of the decline of employed persons and the increase of N2O emissions. Only the criterion for economic sustainability was fulfilled. That means that the national income has increased, however also the emissions of N2O has increased at the same time. We know from the considerations above that the economic growth must be equal or bigger than zero and that 12 The pilot NAMEA in 1993 benefited much from the work done on environmental indicators at the Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment (Adriaanse (1993)). 13 The indicators refer to Adriaanse (1993). An extended discussion of the aggregation of different environmental substances is given in the Annex B of de Haan, Keuning & Bosch (1994). 18 Механізм регулювання економіки, 2007, № 3 Розділ 1 Економіка природокористування і еколого-економічні проблеми the growth of emissions must be negative to become sustainable. This of course can only be realized if the productivity of environmental inputs (emissions) is growing faster than the economic output. Table 2 – Growth Rates14 Economic activities Output (based on volume change) NL Output (based on volume change) NB Labour input of employed persons NL (fte) Labor input of employed persons NB (fte) CO2 NL CO2 NB N2O NL N2O NB CH4 NL CH4 NB CFC halons NL CFC halons NB NOx NL NOx NB SO2 NL SO2 NB NH3 NL NH3 NB P NL P NB N NL N NB waste NL waste NB GHG theme NL GHG theme NB Acidification NL Acidification NB Eutropohication NL Eutrophication NB change % 0.07 -0.07 -1,3441 -1,3947 -4,27138 -1,51431 16,14713 12,24129 -12,7041 -4,1218 -17,0984 -18,391 -17,9221 -23,1789 -36,1664 -59,2095 -11,6793 -16,9747 5,261836 0,438652 -7,26911 -10,9469 -13,0653 -11,2354 -3,42827 -0,57484 -19,9871 -26,3497 -1,18628 -5,18657 Now we take a look at the Dutch region Noord-Brabant, where we get -1.3947>-0.07 0>12.241 (8) In some sense it can be argued that the situation in Noord-Brabant has develped more worse, because all objectives were not reached (I think the idea to use a single line inequation 14 NB represents the Dutch province Noord-Brabant and NL the Netherlands. Механізм регулювання економіки, 2007, № 3 19 Peter J. Stauvermann. How to operationalize Economic, Ecological and Social “Sustainability” for PolicyMaking with the help of National/Regional Accounting Matrices including Environmental Accounts such as MNCS is a bright one. It gives a quick snapshot for the policy maker who is interested in easy-to-use and quick decision support measures and tools . I like it! At the same time by comparing rates of change you can indeed consider social, econ and ecological aspects all together!). IV Conclusions and further Research Until now we have only developed a system how to monitor the state of an society, where we propose to take social, economic and ecological indicators in an equal way into account. One good starting point regarding the measurement of ecological, social and economic indicators is the so-called Dutch NAMEA (national Accounting matrix including Environmental Accounts) approach, which will be available for all European countries in the following years. What we did not do until now is to analyse each sector from the NAMEA15 regarding the MNCS. This will infrom us which econmic sectors are responsible for the violation of the MNCS. Additionally, this system could be also extended to social accounts, the so-called SESAME16 (System for economic, environmental and social statistics). This approach has the advantage that all countries make use of the accounting rules of the SNA 1993 and SEEA 2003 and in so far international and intertemporal comparisons would be possible. Unfortunately, it is impossible to state that a country or region is on a sustainable growth path, because at least we do not know the sufficient conditions for sustainability. Here we have developed conditions which allow us to state, that a region or country is not on a sustainable path, if the MNCS are violated . If the minimal necessary conditions are fulfilled, we are not able to say that we are on a sustainable path. Consequently, we are only able to differentiate between appearently unsustainable growth paths from growth paths which could be sustainable. Of course, this analysis is only a small step to get a better insight what sustainability means. 1. Adriaanse, A. 1993: Environmental Policy Performance Indicators, Netherlands Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment. 2. Brundtland, G.H. et al. 1987: Our Common Future, World Commission on Environment and Development, Oxford, Oxford University Press. 3. De Boo, A., Bosch P., Gorter, C.N. & Keuning, S.J. 1991: An Environmental Module and the Complete System of National Accounts, Occasional Papers of the CBS, No. NA-046, Voorburg. 4. De Boo, A., Bosch P., Gorter, C.N. & Keuning, S.J. 1993: An Environmental Module and the Complete System of National Accounts, in: Franz, A. & Stahmer, C. (eds): Approaches to Environmental Accounting, Heidelberg, Physica Verlag. 5. De Haan M., Keuning, S.J. & Bosch., P.R. 1994: Integrating indicators in a National Accounting Matrix including Environmental Accounts (NAMEA); an application to the Netherlands. National accounts and the environment; papers and proceedings from a conference, London, 16–18 March, Statistics Canada, Ottawa. 6. De Haan, M. & Keuning, S.J. 1996: Taking the environment into account: the NAMEA approach, Review of Income and Wealth 42, 131-148. 7. De Haan, M. 2001: A Structural Decomposition Analysis of Pollution in the Netherlands, Economic Systems Research 13, 2001. 8. Duchin, F. & Lange, G.-L. 1995: The Future of the Environment: Ecological Economics and Technological Change, Oxford University Press. 15 At the moment the Dutch NAMEA consists of 38 industrial sectors, emissions from consumption and emissions from private traffic. 16 See e.g. Keuning & Timmerman (1995). or Keuning (1997). 20 Механізм регулювання економіки, 2007, № 3 Розділ 1 Економіка природокористування і еколого-економічні проблеми 9. Duchin, F. & Steenge, A.E. 1999: Input-Output Analysis, Technology and the Environment, in: J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (ed.): Handbook of Environmental and Resource Economics, Northampton, MA, Edgar Elgar, 1037-1059. 10. Duchin, F. 1998: Structural Economics: Measuring Change in Technology, Lifestyles, and the Environment, Island Press. 11. Hicks, J.R. 1946. Value and Capital, Oxford, Clarendon Press. 12. Keuning, S.J. & de Ruijter, W.A. 1988: Guidelines to the Construction of a National Accounting Matrix, Review of Income and Wealth 34, 71-101. 13. Keuning, S.J. & Timmerman, J.G. 1995: An information system for economic, environmental and social statistics: integrating environmental data into the SESAME. Conference papers from the second meeting of the London group on natural resources and environmental accounting, US Bureau of Census. 14. Keuning, S.J. 1992: National accounts and the environment. The case for a system’s approach, occasional paper NA-053, Statistics Netherlands (CBS) 15. Keuning, S.J. 1997: SESAME: an Integrated Economic and Social Accounting System, International Statistical Review 65 16. Keuning, S.J., Dalen, van J. & Haan, de M. 1999: The Netherlands’ NAMEA; Presentation, Usage and Future Extensions, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 10, 15-37 17. Leontief, W. 1970: Environmental Repercussions and the Economic Structure: An Input-Output Analysis, Review of Economics and Statistics 52, 262-271 18. Netherlands Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment (VROM) 1992: ThemaIndicatoren voor het milieubeleid nr. 1992/9, (Theme related Indicators Supporting Environmental Policy (in Dutch)), The Hague 19. Netherlands Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment (VROM) 1989: National Milieubeleidsplan, (National environmental Policy Plan (in Dutch)), The Hague. 20. Netherlands Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment (VROM) 1990: National Milieubeleidsplan-plus, (Extended National environmental Policy Plan (in Dutch)), The Hague. 21. Netherlands Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment (VROM) 1993: Tweede National Milieubeleidsplan, (Second National environmental Policy Plan (in Dutch)), The Hague 22. Pyatt, G. & Round, J. 1986: Social Accounting Matrices: A Basis for Planning, World Bank, Washington, D.C. 23. Pyatt, G. & Thorbecke, E. 1976: Planning Techniques for a Better Future, International Labour Office, Geneva. 24. Spangenberg, J.H., Omann, I. & Hinterberger, F. 2002: Sustainable Growth Criteria: Minimum Benchmarke and Scenarios for Employment and the Environment, Ecological Economics 42, 429443. 25. Stauvermann, P.J. 2007: The Regionalized nAMEA-type Matrix (RAMEA/ Regionalized national Accounting Matrix including Environmental Accounts): Methodology, Application and Interpretation: A Dutch Pilot Study. 26. Tweede Kamer 1996: Action Plan for Green National Accounting: Letter of the Minister of Economic Affairs to the President of the Lower House of the States-General of the Netherlands, Ministry of Economic Affairs, The Hague. Received 11.09.2007 Петер Дж. Стауверманн Застосування економічної, екологічної та соціальної «сталості» при прийнятті рішень із використання матриць аналізу національної/регіональної господарської діяльності, що включають рахунки екологічних ресурсів В статті розглядається декілька важливих мінімальних умов економічної, соціальної та екологічної сталості. На думку автора економіка може бути сталою, якщо врахувати усі три сфери, якщо рівень безробіття дорівнює нулю, кількість викидів з роками зменшується, а Механізм регулювання економіки, 2007, № 3 21 Peter J. Stauvermann. How to operationalize Economic, Ecological and Social “Sustainability” for PolicyMaking with the help of National/Regional Accounting Matrices including Environmental Accounts кількість вироблених товарів не зменшується. Поєднуючи різні аспекти сталого розвитку, можна визначити необхідну мінімальну умову сталого розвитку (НМУСР). Автор аналізує мінімальний набір умов сталого економічного, соціального та екологічного розвитку, а також пропонує матриці аналізу національної та регіональної господарської діяльності, до яких включені екологічні рахунки (МАНГДЕР та МАРГДЕР (NAMEA/RAMEA)). В якості прикладу автор пропонує розглянути практичне застосування даного підходу в Нідерландах і аналізує виконання НМУСР у період із 2001 до 2003 року. Автор визначає мінімальні умови, які дають змогу досягти екологічної, соціальної та економічної сталості. Позначивши обсяг викидів через Е, а темпи зростання викидів через е, необхідною умовою екологічної сталості маємо e 0 . Цієї умови можна досягти, якщо темп росту виробництва нижчий за темп росту екопродуктивності Y . E Це означає, що Y y y e , E (1) де Y – обсяг виробленої продукції, а у – темп зростання виробітку. Мінімальною умовою сталого соціального розвитку є збільшення кількості зайнятих – l 0 , де l – темп росту повністю зайнятого населення, а L – загальна кількість робочих місць. Y Продуктивність праці визначається як , а необхідна обов’язкова умова визначається як: L Y y y l . (2) L По Хіксу (1946) мінімальна умова економічної сталості виконується при y>=0 (зростання виробітку продукції означає збільшення пропозиції). Відтак, автор припускає, що y l 0 y y e (3) і мінімальною необхідною умовою економічної сталості є l y0e (4) Отже, автор пропонує враховувати і соціальні, і економічні, і екологічні індикатори, при розробці системи моніторингу стану суспільного розвитку. Досвід Нідерландів, а саме практичне застосування МАНГДЕР та МАРГДЕР є тим прикладом, який згодом зможуть наслідувати усі європейські країни. Аналіз кожної сфери за допомогою МАНГДЕР та МАРГДЕР на предмет мінімальної необхідної умови сталого розвитку дасть змогу виявити, де дана умова не виконується. Нажаль, неможливо остаточно визначити, чи йде країна шляхом сталого розвитку, оскільки необхідно визначити ще велику кількість умов, які забезпечують сталий розвиток країни. Навіть, якщо виконуються мінімальні умови, це ще не означає, що ми на шляху сталого розвитку. Підготувала: І.Б. Дегтярьова 22 Механізм регулювання економіки, 2007, № 3