Contracts Intro Contracts generally R1: Contract is a promise or set of promises for the breach of which the law gives a remedy, or the performance of which the law in some way recognizes as a duty. R2: A promise is a manifestation of intention to act or refrain from acting in a specified way, so made as to justify a promisee in understanding that a commitment has been made. The person manifesting the intention is the promisor. The person to whom the manifestation is addressed is the promisee. Where performance will benefit a person other than the promisee, that person is a beneficiary. Shaheen v. Knight: Failed vasectomy. Court recognizes a contract for a particular outcome but refuses to award damages (healthy child not considered harm). “The beautiful idea of contracts”: Each party gives something up in exchange for something they value more. Assumes that people know what they want. Why enforcement, then? If no simultaneous performance, you need some way to ensure that the benefit both parties expect is actually coming. In a very small community, reputational effects could help enforce. 3 ques.: (1) What is injury? (2) What remedy is most effective? (3) Do any policies limit D’s liability? Damage Interests R347 (p.78): Subject to limitations, injured party has a right to damages based on his expectation interest as measured by the loss in value to him of the other party’s performance caused by its failure or deficiency, plus any other loss, including incidental or consequential loss caused by the breach, less any cost or other loss avoided by not having to perform. 1. Expectation: Benefit to P of what was promised less costs avoided (R347). 2. Reliance: Amount P is set back bc entered into the contract. 3. Restitution: Party in breach has to disgorge benefits received. Expectation damages are the rule. Hawkins v. McGee (p.69): Hairy hand. Expectation damages: court fixes; jury instruction had awarded only reliance, but award should be for difference between hand after the operation and hand as it was expected to be after operation. Note that value of hand is determined by reference to the plaintiff (R347). 1 Nurse v. Barnes (p.79): Expectation dmgs inc. reliance. J.O. Hooker & Sons v. Roberts Cabinet Co. (p.81): Cabinets. P can’t recover costs not actually incurred bc contract—rental of warehouse space would have happened anyway. UCC doesn’t apply bc even though sale of goods—the cabinets—is involved, main purpose of contract is services. Tongish v. Thomas (p.90): Sale of seeds. Disagreement between which provision of UCC (applicable here bc sale of goods) is applicable: 1-106 says damages should put injured party in position they would have been in (expectation damages), but 2-713 says difference between K price and market price; court goes with latter because it’s the more specific statute. Result probably actually better serves policy ends, anyway—just doing 1-106 damages would essentially have awarded breaching seller a windfall for having breached. UCC 1-106 (p.97): Remedies provided by UCC shall be liberally administered to the end that the aggrieved party may be put in as good a position as if the other party had fully performed but neither consequential nor special nor penal damages may be had except as specifically provided in the UCC or by other rule of law. UCC 2-711: Buyer may cover or recover damages under 2-713 at its election. UCC 2-712 (p.97): Buyer may “cover” (“by making in good faith and without unreasonable delay any reasonable purchase of or contract to purchase goods in substitution for those due from the seller”), and may recover as damages difference between cost of cover and K price plus other damages, but less expenses saved as consequence of breach. Failure of buyer to cover doesn’t bar from any other remedy. UCC 2-713 (p.97): Measure of damages for non-delivery or repudiation by seller is difference between market price at time when buyer learned of breach and contract price, etc., but less expenses saved bc breach. Efficient breach: If a party is better off by breaching, and the other party isn’t made worse off, what’s the incentive to keep people from breaching? Limitations on Damages 1. Remoteness: party in breach must have been able to foresee damages in question. General rule (from Hadley) is that there are two types of “foreseeable” damages: general damages, which “arise naturally,” and “special damages”: the breaching party has been notified of the possibility of such damages. R351 (p.120): (1) Damages not recoverable for loss that party in breach did not have reason to foresee as a probable result of breach when contract was made. (2) Loss may 2 be foreseeable because it follows from breach (a) in the ordinary course of events, or (b) as a result of special circumstances, beyond the ordinary course of events, that the party in breach had reason to know. (3) A court may limit damages for foreseeable loss of profit by allowing recovery only for loss incurred in reliance, or otherwise if it concludes that in the circumstances justice so requires in order to avoid disproportionate compensation. Hadley v. Baxendale (p.102): Shaft for mill. Rule is that damages are foreseeable when they “arise naturally”—in the “normal course of events” (general damages), or when breaching party has been notified of the possibility of such damages (special damages). Hector Martinez and Co. v. Southern Pacific Transportation Co. (p.116): Dragline. “ … it was obvious that the dragline is a machine which of itself has a use value.” “The general rule does not require the plaintiff to show that the actual harm suffered was the most foreseeable of possible harms. He need only demonstrate that his harm was not so remote as to make it unforeseeable to a reasonable man at the time of contracting.” Morrow v. First National Bank of Hot Springs (p.121): Coin collection, bank vault. Stricter (Arkansas) test applied; under Hadley/Martinez test, notice given to bank would have been enough to hold it liable. Stricter test: they would have had to (tacitly) agree to be held liable. Almost no one ever passes “tacit agreement” test. 2. Certainty: how certain parties are from moment of making K that those damages could eventuate R346 (p.139): Injured party has right to damages … if there’s no loss or amount of loss is not proved, a small sum fixed without regard to amount of loss will be awarded as nominal damages. R349 (p.139): Reliance damages = expenditures made in preparation for performance or in performance, less any avoided costs/losses. No word on opportunity costs. R352 (p.140): Damages are not recoverable for loss beyond an amount that the evidence permits to be established with reasonable certainty. Chicago Coliseum Club v. Dempsey (p.125): Court awards reliance damages because lost profits are too uncertain as a basis for damages (“The profits from a boxing contest of this character, open to the public, is dependent on so many different circumstances that they are not susceptible of definite legal determination.”) Expenses incurred prior to the execution of the agreement not recoverable. Winston Cigarette Machine Co. v. Wells-Whitehead Tobacco Co. (p.137): “It is clear that whenever profits are rejected as an item in the calculation of damages, it is because they are subject to too many contingencies and are too dependent upon the fluctuations of markets and the chances of business to constitute a safe criterion for an estimate of damages.” 3 Anglia Television Ltd. v. Reed (p.140): Court awards lost opportunity costs as part of reliance damages. In general courts don’t do this. Argument also to be made that court was actually awarding expectation damages: court decided that show would have broken even, and in order to put them in a break-even position—expectation damages—reliance damages are the appropriate award. Mistletoe Express Service v. Locke (p.143): If no breach, net loss. P should get reliance damages less any lost profit that would have happened had K not been breached, idea being to put the woman in the position she would have been in had K been performed (though here no losses deducted because other party didn’t prove what they would have been). 3. Avoidability: damages avoidable? R350 (p.163): (1) Except as in (2), damages are not recoverable for loss that injured party could have avoided without undue risk, burden or humiliation. (2) The injured party is not precluded from recovery by the rule stated in (1) to the extent that he has made reasonable but unsuccessful efforts to avoid loss. Rockingham County v. Luten Bridge Co. (p. 147): Luten kept building bridge after told not to, and then sued for whole amount of K. No luck, bc duty to mitigate damages. In any case, Luten isn’t even made better off by completing construction: the profit is the same, they just incur and get reimbursed more costs. Deadweight loss, from an economic point of view. Shirley Maclaine Parker v. Twentieth Century-Fox Film Corp. (p. 152): Facts analogous to bridge case, but court finds no duty for Maclaine to accept substitute employment, even for same money: argument is that there was value to her in making first movie over and above $, and so waste if she’s forced to take another role. Employer would have had to show that the other employment offered was comparable or substantially similar to the original employment; court finds second film offer to be different and inferior. Cooter and Ulen article: (a) An efficient contract will not cover every contingency, meaning that a lot of remedies situations get left up to courts; (b) efficient breach is where a breach of contract is more efficient than the performance of a contract. If no transaction costs, party who values a good most will end up with it, no matter where entitlements are allocated. If no doctrine of avoidability, Luten has right to build bridge, and county has to pay … however, they’d negotiate so that the county would pay Luten a little over their profit—in fact, up to $69—and the net cost savings work out to everyone’s benefit. Different distribution, but end result is the same. Problem 1: Transaction costs do exist. 2: goals besides efficiency—fairness, etc. Friedmann article: Why not make rules about theft and conversion via efficient breach model, too? 4 UCC 2-718 (3)(a) (p.170): Buyer’s right to restitution offset if seller establishes right to recover damages under other provisions. UCC 2-708: (1) Measure of damages for non-acceptance or repudiation by buyer is difference between contract price and market price plus incidental damages, but less expenses saved because of breach. (2) If measure of damages in (1) is inadequate, then the measure of damages is profit which the seller would have made from full performance by the buyer. Neri v. Retail Marine Corp. (p.163): Boat sales. Avoidability doesn’t work for volume situations. If seller can find a second buyer for a good, that means he would have had two sales instead of one. Important to note that this only works for completely identical goods—cars, boats, etc.—sold at high volumes. Doesn’t work for unique goods. A. Contracting Around Default Rules 1. Express limitations 2. Liquidated damages v. penalty clauses: General rule on penalty clauses is that if contracting parties attempt to deal with problems associated with damages by articulating their own penalties, they cannot do so by meting out punishment to the party in breach – any clause they adopt must be a way of estimating what the party’s actual damages would have been – it must be a liquidated damages clause and not a penalty clause. This rule cannot be contracted around. R355 (p.185): Punitive damages are not recoverable for a breach of contract unless the conduct constituting the breach is also a tort for which punitive damages are recoverable. R356 (p.185): (1) Damages for breach by either party may be liquidated in the agreement but only at an amount that is reasonable in the light of the anticipated or actual loss caused by the breach and the difficulties of proof of loss. A term fixing unreasonably large liquidated damages is unenforceable on grounds of public policy as a penalty. (2) (deals with bonds). UCC 2-718 (p.169): (1) Damages for breach may be liquidated but only at an amount reasonable in the light of the anticipated or actual harm caused by the breach, the difficulties of proof of loss, and the inconvenience or nonfeasibility of otherwise obtaining an adequate remedy. A term fixing unreasonably large liquidated damages is void as a penalty. Kemble v. Farren (p.174): Liquidated damages clauses usually only work where damages are unclear. Here, the problem is that the clause applies to any breach, and there could be a huge disconnect between amount of actual damages and amount of damages under the clause—if P breached by not paying D 4 pounds one day, D would suddenly owe 1000 pounds. Damages for not paying would have been clear—4 pounds—so it’s odd to do a damages clause. Courts will consider all the circumstances in which the clause might be imposed. 5 Lake River Corp. v. Carborundum Co. (p.186): Posner: Penalty clauses discourage efficient breach. However, (1) Parties wouldn’t have entered into certain contracts in the first place if they couldn’t have the penalty clause – and not having these contracts in the first place involves a loss; (2) Rational economic actors will only include a penalty clause if the benefits of the clause exceed the costs (including those of having efficient breach discouraged). So if the contract wouldn’t be made without the penalty clause, and we assume that the actors are able to assess the damages in advance, why not let people contract for what they will and enforce penalty clauses? Ways to get around penalty clause issue: Offer a “reward” for, say, on-time completion and artificially lower the price. Wassenaar v. Towne Hotel (p.176): Court looks at three factors in determining whether clause is reasonable (i) intention: did parties intend to provide for damages or a penalty?; (ii) is injury caused by the breach one that is difficult or incapable of accurate estimation at the time of contract; (iii) are the stipulated damages a reasonable forecast of the harm caused by the breach? Court holds that a valid liquidated damages clause makes duty to mitigate damages go away. Non-economic reasons for disallowing penalty clauses: penalty clauses could basically cause people to act under threat: theoretically a power reserved to the state. A court wouldn’t uphold a contract with a clause stipulating that if completion didn’t happen on time contractor gets imprisoned. 3. Punitive damages/arbitration Generally speaking, judicial hostility toward punitive/exemplary damages for simple breach of contract. Garrity v. Lyle Stuart, Inc. (p.188): Arbitrator shouldn’t have power to award punitive damages bc that kind of coercive power should be wielded by the state. Willoughby Roofing & Supply Co. v. Kajima International, Inc. (p.197): Federal Arbitration Act does not prohibit punitive damages by arbitrators. States shouldn’t be striking down arbitral awards. B. Other Remedies 1. Specific performance: general rule is that damages are preferable. a. Land: general rule = specific performance for land. Loveless v. Diehl (p.217): Rental of land with option to buy. Court initially just awards damages because buyer was just going to resell anyway, but on rehearing court reverses and says that for land, specific performance is a matter of course. Doesn’t matter what sellers were going to do afterwards. b. Goods 6 UCC 2-716 (p.233): (1) Specific performance may be ordered where the goods are unique or in other proper circumstances. (2) Judgment for specific performance may include such terms and conditions as to payment of price, damages, or other relief as court may deem just. (3) Buyer has a right of replevin for goods identified to the contract if after reasonable effort he is unable to effect cover or if circumstances reasonably indicate that such effort will be unavailing or if the goods have been shipped under reservation and satisfaction of the security interest in them has been made or tendered. Scholl v. Hartzell (p.226): A 1962 Corvette, while a collector’s item, is not a unique good to the point where it can be replevied. Sedmak v. Charlie’s Chevrolet, Inc. (p. 229): A new car ‘could not be obtained elsewhere except at considerable expense, trouble or loss, which cannot be estimated in advance and under such circumstances [plaintiff] did not have an adequate remedy at law.’” Car in question was a specially modified Corvette “pace car.” Generally: With a market good, we have several reasons to transform the value of that good into $: the market gives us an average, kind of, as to what people across society value the item at, and the person being willing to pay that market price tells us something about how much they value it. Second, a disappointed buyer can always cover, and therefore recreate the position she would have been in under the contract. In case of unique goods, or where circumstances make it hard to cover, specific performance is the only way to make sure disappointed buyer gets same utility she would have under contract. c. Personal service Even if damages are not an adequate remedy, the constitutional bar on involuntary servitude precludes a court from ordering specific performance of a contract for personal services. (E&E, p.623) Lumley v. Wagner (p.240): General rule against compelling specific performance, but here court indirectly does—by enforcing a negative covenant against performing in theaters besides P’s—what it can’t directly do. Ford v. Jermon (p.245): They won’t grant specific performance on either half: “ … a contract for personal services thus enforced would be but a mitigated form of slavery, in which the party would have lost the right to dispose of himself as a free agent, and be, for a greater or less length of time, subject to the control of another …” Also, serious monitoring problem: you’d have to send a court agent down to the performance; how would you know if the performer is actually living up to the spirit of the contract and so on? That said, it’s not hard to monitor an order not to sing at another theater. Duff v. Russell (p.247): Court actually implies a negative covenant to get same result as Lumley. 7 Bailey v. State of Alabama (p.265): AL had set up law that made breach of labor contract a crime. Violation of 13th Amendment: state statute sets up involuntary servitude. Court doesn’t like end-run that law allows Alabama to do: state doesn’t have power to force him to work if he doesn’t want to, because that’s clearly involuntary servitude, but since the state made it a crime to breach a personal services contract, they can essentially force him to work … basically they’re trying to do indirectly what they can’t do directly. Holmes dissent here emphasizes freedom of contract: why shouldn’t state “throw its weight on the side of performance” as long as the contract is fair and proper? Lochner v. New York (p.272): state of NY attempted to address lamentable labor conditions for bakers who were working long days … set up a statute whereby bakers couldn’t work more than 60 hours a week. Constitutionality challenged on the grounds because it interferes with the parties’ freedom of contract and so violates the 14th amdmt.: surely they could enter into a contract for anything they wanted to contract for; court thought this statute unduly burdened freedom of contract/property under 14th. Holmes dissent: states regulate lots of things under the heading of police powers – they’re allowed to decide health conditions and things left and right, so to wave freedom of contract around and say that imposes an undue restriction on people is disingenuous. This (Holmes dissent) is the modern position: modern regulatory state is all about … well, regulation. Holmes: just taking a broad view of state police powers? In Bailey, he thought state was within its rights to enforce contracts; here, he thinks state can regulate bakers’ hours. A constant tension; background principle under 14th A. – freedom of contract – that we want to promote (beautiful idea of contract law, etc.; general freedom of movement – we want people to be able to do what they want unless they’re harming third parties). 2. Restitution: where party in breach is the one who has been enriched – has gotten some benefit from the victim – and victim is suing to get that benefit back. Or, where victim of breach is enriched, and party in breach is the one who is suing to get the benefit back. a. To party in breach R371 (p.287): Measure of restitution interest: If a sum of money is awarded to protect a party’s restitution interest, it may as justice requires be measured by either (a) the reasonable value to the other party of what he received in terms of what it would have cost him to obtain it from a person in the claimant’s position, or (b) the extent to which the other party’s property has been increased in value or his other interests advanced. R373 (p.287): Restitution when other party is in breach: (1) Subject to (2), on a breach by nonperformance that gives rise to a claim for damages for total breach or on a repudiation, the injured party is entitled to restitution for any benefit that he has conferred on the other party by way of part performance or reliance. (2) The injured party has no right to restitution if he has performed all of his duties under the contract and no performance by the other party remains due other than payment of a definite sum of money for that performance. 8 R374 (p.298): Restitution in favor of party in breach: Subject to (2), if a party justifiably refuses to perform on the ground that his remaining duties have been discharged by other party’s breach, party in breach is entitled to restitution for any benefit conferred by way of part performance or reliance in excess of the loss that he has caused by his own breach. (2) To the extent that, under the manifested assent of the parties, a party’s performance is to be retained in the case of breach, that party is not entitled to restitution if the value of the performance as liquidated damages is reasonable in the light of the anticipated or actual loss caused by the breach and the difficulties of proof of loss. Britton v. Turner (p.288): NH. No recovery under K bc breach, but can recover sum for the service actually performed, because it was accepted (“where the contract is to labor from day to day, for certain period, the party for whom the labor is done in truth stipulates to receive it from day to day, as it is performed, and although the other may not eventually do all he has contracted to do, there has been necessarily, an acceptance of what has been done in pursuance of the contract, and the party must have understood when he made the contract that there was to be such acceptance.”) b. Restitution and “quasi-contract” When a benefit has been conferred on a recipient under circumstances in which it is unfair to permit him to retain it without payment, the cause of action of unjust enrichment is available to the person who conferred the benefit. Using this cause of action, the conferrer can claim the remedy of restitution, under which the court will restore the benefit or its value to her. In order to fit this newly recognized cause of action into existing legal forms, earlier common law courts used various fictions. (E&E, p.217) Cotnam v. Wisdom (p.298): We do impute consent to a person who needs medical care, because otherwise emergency medical personnel could be sued for battery. Custom might, in fact, be for both parties to contemplate financial condition of the patient when services were rendered and accepted, but even if this is so, evidence of this custom would only be admitted if there were, in fact, contemplation; court says that an unconscious patient could not, in fact or in law, be held to have contemplated the charges a physician might bring. Again: this would be different if this were a real contract, but given that this is merely a fiction of law, all that is required is a reasonable compensation for the services rendered. II. Mutual Assent A. Offer and acceptance R17 (p.331): (1) Except as in 2, the formation of a contract requires a bargain in which there is a manifestation of mutual assent to the exchange and a consideration. (2) Might be a contract without a bargain under special rules applicable to formal contracts. R18 (p.331): Manifestation of mutual assent to an exchange requires that each party either make a promise or begin or render a performance. 9 R22 (p.331): (1) Manifestation of mutual assent to an exchange ordinarily takes the form of an offer or proposal by one party followed by an acceptance by the other party or parties. (2) A manifestation of mutual assent may be made even though neither offer nor acceptance can be identified and even though the moment of formation cannot be determined. R24 (p.331): An offer is the manifestation of willingness to enter into a bargain, so made as to justify another person in understanding that his assent to that bargain is invited and will conclude it. R25 (p.331): Option contracts: An option contract is a promise which meets the requirements for the formation of a contract and limits the promisor’s power to revoke an offer. R35 (p.332): (1) An offer gives to the offeree a continuing power to complete the manifestation of mutual assent by acceptance of the offer. (2) A contract cannot be created by acceptance of an offer after the power of acceptance has been terminated in one of the ways listed in R36. R36 (p.332): (1) An offeree’s power of acceptance may be terminated by (a) rejection or counter-offer; (b) lapse of time; (c) revocation by offeror; (d) death or incapacity of either. (2) In addition, power of acceptance terminated by non-occurrence of any condition of acceptance under the terms of the offer. R37 (p.332): Power of acceptance under an option contract not terminated by any of that except lapse of time unless requirements are met for discharge of a contractual duty. R42 (p.332): Revocation by communication: An offeree’s power of acceptance is terminated when the offeree receives from the offeror a manifestation of an intention not to enter into the proposed contract. R43 (p.332): Indirect communication of revocation: An offeree’s power of acceptance is terminated when the offeror takes definite action inconsistent with an intention to enter into the proposed contract and the offeree acquires reliable information to that effect. UCC 2-206 (p.333): Unless otherwise specified, an offer shall be construed as inviting acceptance in any manner and by any medium reasonable to the circumstances; (2) Where the beginning of a requested performance is a reasonable mode of acceptance an offeror who is not notified of acceptance within a reasonable time may treat the offer as having lapsed before acceptance. Standard method for forming a contract: (1) One party makes an offer to another party; and (2) That offer is subsequently accepted. 10 You might think of an offer as creating a power in another person to accept it. A makes an offer to B; B then has a power which A has conferred on him to create a binding contract between A and B by accepting the offer. Dickinson v. Dodds (p.325): P tried to accept offer knowing full well land had been sold to someone else; court thinks it doesn’t matter how the offeree found out about other transaction. This is actually the conventional wisdom: offeree need not have been informed by offeror; he just needs to hear about it. It does have to be reliable word of revocation, though. Court compares this to a case in which offeror dies. [“meeting of the minds”] B. Objective theory of assent R17 (comment on p.351): Comment c: clear that a mental reservation of a party to a bargain does not impair the obligation he purports to undertake. R19 (p.351): Conduct as manifestation of assent: (1) Manifestation of assent may be made wholly or partly by written or spoken words or by other acts or by failure to act. (2) Conduct of a party is not effective as a manifestation of assent unless he intends to engage in the conduct and knows or has reason to know that the other party may infer from his conduct that he assents. (3) The conduct of a party may manifest assent even though he does not in fact assent. In such cases a resulting contract may be voidable because of fraud, duress, mistake, or other invalidating cause. Embry v. Hargadine, McKittrick Dry Goods Co. (p.334): Embry thinks he had a valid contract. The offer was “Hire me now or I quit”; response, he thinks, was “don’t worry about quitting, we’ll proceed.” He understood he had a valid renewal of his contract of employment. What matters was outward manifestation, not what boss was thinking. Texaco v. Pennzoil (p.341): Only manifestations matter. Intention manifested towards each other, not third parties, necessarily. Lucy v. Zehmer (p.342): (“high as a Georgia pine”) objective manifestations were sufficiently serious to indicate to a reasonable person that a contract was being made. “Mirror image” rule: a response is not an acceptance if the offeree imposes conditions on the acceptance or seeks to change or qualify the terms of the offer. Contemporary approach is to tolerate minor discrepancies and apply only where response makes material changes. (E&E, p.64) US v. Braunstein (p.352): Raisins. Acceptance must be unequivocal, unambiguous, and must comply with requirements of the offer. C. Offer? 1. Negotiations 11 R26 (p.359): Preliminary negotiations: Manifestation of willingness to enter into a bargain is not an offer if the person to whom it is addressed knows or has reason to know that the person making it does not intend to conclude a bargain until he has made a further manifestation of assent. R29 (p.359): To whom an offer is addressed: (1) Manifested intention of offeror determines person or persons in whom is created a power of acceptance. (2) An offer may create a power of acceptance in a specified person or in one of more of a specified group or class, acting separately or together, or in anyone or everyone who makes a specified promise or renders a specified performance. R33 (p.359): Certainty: (1) Even though a manifestation of intention is intended to be understood as an offer, it cannot be accepted so as to form a contract unless the terms of the contract are reasonably certain. (2) Terms of a contract are reasonably certain if they provide a basis for determining existence of breach and for giving appropriate remedy. (3) Fact that one or more terms of a proposed bargain are left open or uncertain may show that a manifestation of intention is not intended to be understood as an offer or as an acceptance. UCC 2-204 (p.360): (1) Contract for sale of goods may be made in any way sufficient to show agreement, including conduct that recognizes the existence of such a contract. (2) Agreement may constitute a contract even if moment of making is undetermined. (3) Even though one or more terms are left open, contract for sale doesn’t fail for indefiniteness if the parties have intended to make a contract and there’s a reasonably certain basis for giving an appropriate remedy. UCC 2-305 (p.360): Open price term: (1) Parties can conclude a sale contract even if price isn’t settled. Price in that case is a reasonable price at time of delivery if (a) nothing is said re: price; (b) price is left to be agreed and there’s failure to agree; (c) price is to be fixed in terms of some agreed market or other standard as set or recorded by third party and it’s not. (2) Price to be fixed by seller or buyer means a price to be fixed in good faith. (3) When price left to be fixed otherwise than by agreement of parties fails to be fixed through the fault of one party, the other may treat the contract as cancelled or fix a reasonable price. UCC 2-308 (p.361): Fixes place for delivery in absence of one set by agreement—place of business or residence, or if parties know that goods are in some other place, that place. UCC 3-309 (p.361): Absence of specific time provisions; notice of termination: (1) Time if not agreed upon shall be reasonable time. (2) If contract is indefinite in duration it is valid for a reasonable time but may be terminated at any time by either party. (2) Termination by one party except on happening of an agreed event requires that reasonable notification be received by other party and an agreement dispensing with notification is invalid if its operation would be unconscionable. 12 Nebraska Seed Co. v. Harsh (p.356): Sending out sample seeds and indicating approximate number you have doesn’t constitute an offer to be accepted, but an invitation for offers. 2. Written memorial contemplated R27 (p.365): Manifestations of intent that are in themselves sufficient to conclude a contract will not be prevented from so operating by the fact that the parties also manifest an intention to prepare and adopt a written memorial thereof; but the circumstances may show that the agreements are preliminary negotiations. Empro (p.362): Letter of intent not binding because Empro left itself so many outs; language used is very non-binding. Texaco (p.366): Similar facts to Empro, but court finds other way. Why? Intent to formalize an agreement is some evidence of an intent not to be bound before signing a writing, it’s not conclusive: the issue of when the parties intended to be bound is a fact question to be decided from acts and communications. If there is no understanding that a signed writing is necessary, and all substantial terms are agreed upon, an informal agreement can be binding, even if parties contemplate later putting things into a formal doc. D. Acceptance? 1. Mailbox rule R63 (p.381): Unless offer provides otherwise, (a) an acceptance made in the right way is operative and completes manifestation of mutual assent as soon as put out of offeree’s possession; (b) an acceptance under an option contract is not operative until received by the offeror. (why the latter? Offeror has given offeree an option that binds the offeror, making it impossible for the offeror to re-offer to someone else; since the offeror is bound, slightly more stringent rule on acceptance.) Problems? If offeror never receives letter, still counts; mailbox rule doesn’t apply to revocation: you have to actually communicate; under an option K, not formed until acceptance actually received by offeror. R65 (p.381): Medium of acceptance: a medium of acceptance is reasonable if it is the one used by the offeror or one customary in similar transactions at the time and place the offer is received. That is, if there’s a customary way, and the offeree accepts in that manner, that’s valid even though different from what offeror has provided, or if offeror hasn’t provided a manner of acceptance, you use the customary way. Custom can override terms of an offer. 2. Silence 13 R69 (p.383): Acceptance by silence or exercise of dominion: (1)(a): If you take the benefit of offered services, assuming you had a chance to reject them and knew that there was the expectation that you would pay for them, your silence could operate as acceptance. (b): If offeror has said or given offeree reason to understand that silence might mean assent, and the offeree intends, by remaining silent and inactive, to assent, silence could mean acceptance. (c): If it’s reasonable for offeree to notify offeror that he doesn’t intend to accept, then silence could mean acceptance. Hobbs v. Massasoit Whip Co. (p.382): (eelskins) Silence can’t be generally construed as an acceptance unless a given course of dealing established a pattern which gave buyer reason to believe seller would see silence as acceptance. E. Acceptance by performance/Unilateral contracts R30 (p.405): (1) An offer may invite or require acceptance to be made by an affirmative answer in words, or by performing or refraining from performing a specified act, or may empower the offeree to make a selection of terms in his acceptance. (2) Unless otherwise indicated by the language or the circumstances, an offer invites acceptance in any manner and by any medium reasonable in the circumstances. R37 (see above) R45 (p.422): (1) Where acceptance by performance is invited and not promissory acceptance, an option contract is created when the offeree tenders or begins the invited performance or tenders a beginning of it. (2) The offeror’s duty of performance under any option contract so created is conditional on completion or tender of the invited performance in accordance with the terms of the offer. R50 (p.422): Acceptance: (1) Acceptance or an offer is a manifestation of assent to the terms thereof made by the offeree in a manner invited or required by the offer. (2) Acceptance by performance requires that at least part of what the offer requests be performed or tendered and includes acceptance by a performance which operates as a return promise. [In a situation, then, in which offeree can accept by either performance or promise, performance operates as a return promise, and thus in that situation and that situation only the offeree is bound to complete performance; otherwise, offeree is not bound.] (3) Acceptance by a promise requires that the offeree complete every act essential to the making of the promise. Bilateral contract: where acceptance is via promise. Promise is exchanged for promise. Unilateral contract: where acceptance is via performance. Promise is exchanged for performance. Offeror controls. Carlill v. Carbolic Smoke Ball Co. (p.385): It’s a unilateral contract: offeror set terms, and in this case acceptance was not intended to be a promise from the user of the product, but just performance: using the thing as offer set out. P did that, so performance itself constitutes acceptance. Concurrence compares this to cases in which you post signs 14 offering a reward to whoever finds your lost dog: if you hang up a sign offering a reward, no one’s going to call you and accept and then go find the dog; the manner of acceptance is understood to be finding the dog and bringing it to you. Petterson v. Pattberg (p.412): Debt on land in Brooklyn. Court finds that this is a unilateral contract: promise made; mode of acceptance was to be performance – condition was to pay the money. Why didn’t Petterson do just that? Pattberg revoked before he could: Petterson tried to tender money after Pattberg told him the mortgage had been sold. Petersen v. Ray-Hof Agencies, Inc. (p.418): Court holds that contract is formed when the offer is accepted. Thus our need to know where the offer was accepted, exactly. Employee wants rule that acceptance takes place when performance is initiated (not rule that acceptance takes place when performance is completed). If we consider the entire performance in Petterson case to be showing up and offering payment and turning money over, then rule would be that offer is not accepted until performance is complete. Anyway, Petersen court says that K was formed as soon as the guy left Miami: i.e., offer was accepted when performance was initiated. Overruled by SC of FL (because, one would assume, while an offeror is bound not to revoke an offer once acceptance by performance has begun—an option contract is created—since the offeree is not bound to complete performance, and the offeror is not actually bound to perform, the contract is not actually created in this situation until performance is completed). III. Interpreting Assent A. Filling gaps 1. Agreements to agree Courts generally do not enforce agreements to agree. That said, as indicated by R204, courts are willing to supply terms to an agreement that is sufficiently defined so as to be considered a contract. R34 (p.433): (1) Terms of a contract may be reasonably certain even though it empowers one or more parties to make a selection of terms in the course of performance. (2) Part performance may remove uncertainty and establish that a contract enforceable as a bargain has been formed. (3) Action in reliance on an agreement may make a contractual remedy appropriate even though uncertainty is not removed. R204 (p.434): When parties to a bargain sufficiently defined to be a contract have not agreed with respect to a term which is essential to a determination of their rights and duties, a term which is reasonable in the circumstances is supplied by the court. UCC 2-204, 2-305, 2-309, above Sun Printing & Publishing Assn. v. Remington Paper & Power Co. (p.427): No valid contract bc of terms left open. Price and time left open; there was at least a provision as 15 to price, but no specification of how long that provision would apply for. Provision as to price was that max. price would be Canadian price if no other price agreed on. “beautiful idea”: parties might intend to be bound, but if there’s a huge gap in what they intend to be bound to and the court ends up supplying the terms, the court is binding the parties to an agreement: if we’re interested in defending freedom of contract we wouldn’t make up terms but require parties to be clearer about what they’re agreeing to. Ultimately the Cardozo dec’n does support contractual rights. Something to be said for idea of making off-the-rack terms that parties universally hate: encourages them to come up with their own. Texaco v. Pennzoil (2) (p.434): Court suggested that there was a contract bc terms were sufficiently definite to identify a breach and the damages that resulted from the breach. 2. Illusory promises When consideration consists of the exchange of mutual promises, the undertakings on both sides must be real and meaningful. If the promise of one party has qualifications or limitations so strong that they negate it, it is really no commitment at all. Because it does not bind that party, this lack of consideration voids the apparent contract, so neither party is bound. Such a promise is said to be illusory. In situations where one party can prevent fulfillment of a condition simply by failing to try to fulfill, courts tend to imply conditions—like obligations to use best efforts—to validate contracts. Wood v. Lucy (p.441): Cardozo supplies “good faith” obligation to perform to an otherwise complete contract which D had tried to get out of because of lack of express requirement on P to actually place D’s endorsements and market her designs. B. Interpreting assent: subjective v. objective R200 (p.465): Interpretation of a promise or agreement or a term thereof is the ascertainment of its meaning. R201 (p.465): Whose meaning prevails? Where parties have attached same meaning to term, that meaning prevails. Where parties have attached different meanings, interpreted according to meaning attached by one of them if (a) that party didn’t know the other party meant something else, and the second party knew what the first party understood; or (b) that party had no reason to know of any different meaning attached by the other, and the other had reason to know the meaning attached by the first party. If none of that applies (Peerless), neither party is bound, even if that means mutual assent fails. UCC 1-205 (p.467): (4) Express terms of an agreement and an applicable course of dealing or usage of trade shall be construed wherever reasonable as consistent with each other; but when such construction is unreasonable express terms control both course of dealing and usage of trade and course of dealing controls usage of trade. 16 UCC 2-208 (p.467): (1) Where contract involves repeated occasions for performance by either party with knowledge of the nature of the performance and opportunity for objection to it by the other, any course of performance accepted or acquiesced in without objection shall be relevant to determine the meaning of the agreement. Raffles v. Wichelhaus (p.451): not enough basis for deciding objectively between ship 1 and ship 2, so no contract: neither person is more reasonable than the other Party whose beliefs are most reasonable should govern result. Party who is aware is in best position to avoid costs of relying on other party’s behavior. If disagreement on a term, if one party was aware or should have been aware of the other’s understanding of that term, the contract should be on the terms of the other party. Oswald v. Allen (p.463): Peerless, only about Swiss coin collections. Neither party knew nor had reason to know what the other meant, and so failure. Weinberg v. Edelstein (p.469): Question as to what constitutes a dress. There was no agreement on the term—just didn’t come up—so court goes to industry practice to figure out whose interpretation more reasonable. Why industry standard? Both to figure out what they meant and what they reasonably should have had in mind. Burden of proof is on party seeking enforcement. Frigaliment (p.473): Disagreement as to meaning of “chicken.” No agreement, and trade usage unclear. Comes down to burden of proof on buyer—initiated dispute, after all—to prove that chicken had narrow meaning, and they haven’t met that burden. IV. Written manifestations A. Interpreting parol evidence R209 (p.487): (1) Integrated agreement = writing or writings constituting final expression of one or more terms of an agreement. (2) Whether there is an integrated agreement is to be determined by court prior to question of interpretation or application of parol evidence rule. (3) Where parties reduce an agreement to a writing which in view of its completeness and specificity reasonably appears to be a complete agreement, it is taken to be integrated unless it is established by other evidence that the writing did not constitute a final expression. R210 (p.487): (1) A completely integrated agreement is an integrated agreement adopted as a complete and exclusive statement of terms. (2) Partially integrated is integrated, but not completely. (3) Integration to be determined by court prior to interpretation/parol evidence rule. R213 (p.487): (1) A binding integrated (completely or partially) agreement discharges prior agreements to the extent that it’s inconsistent with them. (2) A binding completely integrated agreement discharges prior agreements to the extent they’re in its scope. (3) 17 An integrated agreement that isn’t binding or is voidable and avoided does not discharge a prior agreement. Even so, it might be enough to render inoperative a term which would have been part of the agreement had it not been integrated. R214 (p.488): Agreements and negotiations prior to the adoption of a writing are admissible to show (a) that a writing is integrated or not; (b) complete or partial integration; (c) meaning of the writing, integrated or not; (d) illegality, fraud, duress, mistake, lack of consideration, or other invalidating cause; (e) ground for granting or denying rescission, reformation, specific performance, or other remedy. R216 (p.488): (1) Evidence of a consistent additional term is admissible to supplement an integrated agreement unless the court finds that the agreement was completely integrated. (2) An agreement isn’t completely integrated if the writing omits a consistent additional term which is (a) agreed to for separate consideration, or (b) such a term as in the circumstances might naturally be omitted from the writing. UCC 2-202 (p.488): Final agreement can’t be contradicted by evidence of a prior agreement, but may be explained or supplemented (a) by course of dealing or usage of trade or course of performance, or (b) by evidence of consistent additional terms unless court finds writing to have been intended as a complete and exclusive statement of the terms of the agreement. Parol evidence rule says, basically: if everything the parties intended to contract for is covered by the written contract, you may not turn to extrinsic evidence to supplement our understanding of the written contract. Two different ways in which parties would intend for everything to be covered by K. (1) Parties could intend that everything they agreed to is in the K, but that not every part of the agreement is explained in that contract. “Partial integration.” No part of the agreement not represented in K, but expectation that you might look to outside evidence to explain parts of K. (2) Complete integration: parties intend that everything needed to understand their agreement is contained in the agreement itself. (3) (Also possible that a K isn’t integrated at all—parties might enter into a written agreement but have side agreements that aren’t represented in any form in the written agreement). Thompson v. Libbey (p.482): No implied warranty of quality of logs. Lower court erred in admitting extrinsic evidence: initial agreement was complete enough that no add’l evidence should be allowed. Their statement of the rule: “where the parties have deliberately put their engagements into writing in such terms as to import a legal obligation, without any uncertainty as to the object or extent of such engagement, it is conclusively presumed that the whole engagement of the parties, and the manner and extent of their undertaking, was reduced to writing.” Two separate inquiries: (1) 18 Integration. If contract not completely integrated, was there an agreement on the side that would lead us to conclude something besides what contract says on its face? (2) Interpretation. Brown v. Oliver (p.484): Contract is silent on issue of furniture. Why isn’t that enough? P says there was another agreement—an oral one—re: sale of furniture. Fact that we didn’t say anything doesn’t mean that wasn’t our understanding. Seller wants question to be limited by four corners; buyer argues that you have to look outside contract to determine if it’s completely integrated and if not then you can introduce oral evidence. Court: contract is partially integrated re: transaction—“did not by itself conclusively establish whether the parties intended it should exclude every subject of sale except real estate.” Wigmore: (1) Whether a particular subject is embodied by writing is determined by intent of parties; (2) intent must be sought in conduct and language of parties and surrounding circumstances … document itself will not suffice. Must compare writing and negotiations before we can determine whether they were in fact covered. Pacific Gas and Electric Co. v. G.W. Thomas Drayage & Rigging Co. (p.489): Traynor agrees with Wigmore: you need to consider extrinsic evidence. Words do not have absolute and constant referents. The meaning of words varies; a word has no meaning apart from context. “[R]ational interpretation requires at least a preliminary consideration of all credible evidence offered to prove the intention of the parties.” If court decides, after looking at this evidence, that language is susceptible to either of the interpretations being offered, extrinsic evidence is admissible. Trident Center v. Connecticut General Life Insurance Co. (p.493): Thinks PacGas is patently ridiculous—“Under Pacific Gas, it matters not how clearly a contract is written, nor how completely it is integrated, nor how carefully it is negotiated … the contract cannot be rendered impervious to attack by parol evidence.” B. Statute of Frauds: R110 (p.520): (1) Classes of contract subject to statute of frauds, which forbids enforcement unless a written memorandum or applicable exception: (a) contract of an executor or administrator to answer for duty of deceased (“executor-administrator”); (b) contract to answer for duty of another (“suretyship”); (c) contract made on consideration of marriage (“marriage”); (d) contract for land sale (“land contract”); (e) contract not to be performed within a year of making (“one year”). Certain contracts which used to be subject to the Statute of Frauds are now governed by Statute of Frauds provisions of the UCC: contract for sale of goods, contract for sale of securities, contract for sale of personal property somehow worth more than $5000. 19 UCC also requires writing signed by debtor for an agreement which creates or provides for a security interest in personal property or fixtures not in the possession of the secured party. In most states, statutes provide that no acknowledgment or promise is enough evidence of a new or continuing contract to take a case out of the operation of a statute of limitations unless made in a writing by the party to be charged, but that statute doesn’t alter the effect of any payment of principal or interest. States might make other classes of contract subject to a writing requirement. 1. And its exceptions R125 (p.524): Land contracts in writing, except in most states short-term leases and contracts to lease of less than one year. R129 (p.524): Action in reliance: A contract for land transfer may be specifically enforced even if failure under statute of frauds if established that the party seeking enforcement, in reasonable reliance on the contract, has so changed position that injustice can be avoided only by specific performance. R130 (p.525): Where any promise can’t be fully performed in a year, statute of frauds applies. UCC 2-201 (p.531): (1) Contract for sale of goods for more than $500 not enforceable unless in writing sufficient to indicate a contract signed by party against whom enforcement is brought. (3) However, that said, a contract is enforceable (a) if the goods are to be specially manufactured for the buyer and are not suitable for sale to others in the ordinary course of the seller’s business and the seller, before notice of repudiation is received and under circumstances which reasonably indicate that the goods are for the buyer, has made either a substantial beginning of their manufacture or commitments for their procurement; (b) if the part against whom enforcement is sought admits in court that there’s a contract; (c) with respect to goods for which payment has been made or accepted or which have been received or accepted. Boone v. Coe (p.521): LAND CONTRACTS IN WRITING. Might have been decided differently under R129. 2. Satisfying its requirements R131 (p.538): A contract within statute of frauds is enforceable if it’s evidenced by a writing signed by party to be charged; that writing has to identify the subject matter of the contract, indicate that there’s a contract, and state the essential terms of promises left to be performed. 20 R133 (p.539): writing doesn’t have to particularly be a memorandum of the K so long as it’s signed. Schwedes (p.533): Contract for sale of land not in writing. Good consideration, the whole bit, but no writing. Ps try to argue that there should be a contract based on their part performance—they lined up financing—but court finds that there’s a distinction between preparation for performance and part performance. Parma Tile (p.540): Court finds that letterhead on fax is enough to satisfy signature requirement. [Some discussion of how what you end up seeing in statute of frauds cases are contracts, essentially, that someone is trying to wriggle out of—there’s nothing lacking except compliance with this statute of frauds.] V. Enforceability 1. Deontological approach: An approach based on moral principles. Court would ask itself what the morally required/fair thing to do was. Might be different versions of this kind of approach. i. When you exchange promises, you’re morally bound to make good on that promise, bc promise is a morally binding commitment you make. Moral obligation for parties themselves to stick to their agreements. Court ought to enforce all or nearly all agreements because it’s forcing the parties to behave morally. ii. Fairness: what is the fair result in this case, regardless of whether or not there’s a general moral obligation to stick to agreements? “Fairness in results” approach. [Note that this would give a different answer from (i) in Baby M.] 2. Utilitarian: [Market in babies.] Idea might be that the court should adopt that rule which would maximize society’s utility (court should pick rules that maximizes total utility of everyone in a society). In Baby M, say Sterns get 100 units of utility out of the baby; if they don’t get it, they get 20 … if surrogate gets baby taken away, she’s at 0 utility; otherwise she gets 200. So the argument would be that max. utility would be on side of surrogate keeping baby. A caricature, but you get the idea. Also note that there’s no actual way to quantify any of this. No such thing as measuring interpersonal utility … can’t really compare on some kind of absolute scale how much utility people get from something. We should, argument is, come up with rules, though … what kind of rule would legal economists suggest to come up with a maximization of utility here? i. Beautiful Idea: in general, a utilitarian would be in favor of the enforcement of contracts: people know what they’re doing, and will bargain for agreements that make both of them better off. 3. Contractarian: if parties were to agree to rules behind a (partial) veil of ignorance, they’d come up with legal rules that you’d imagine would 21 satisfy their preferences but not knowing what their preferences would be under the circumstances. VI. Consideration Bargained-for exchange. A. History “Considerations” were factors which promisor considered when he promised and which moved or motivated his promising. “Motive” is about the best you’re going to get as far as a synonym. What’s the “motive” for an agreement? Reason for entering into an agreement … Simpson says that consideration is the thing the person was trying to get by entering into the agreement. Makes sense: a bargained-for exchange—the thing you’re bargaining over—is the reason you have for entering into the contract in the first place. B. Bargain theory Restatement approach: A contract is an enforceable promise (R1 and 2). With some exceptions (17(2)), to be enforceable a promise must be supported by consideration (17(1)). A promise is supported by consideration if it is bargained for (71(1)). A promise is bargained for “if it is sought by the promisor in exchange for his promise and is given by the promisee in exchange for that promise.” (71(2)). “It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker, that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest.” R17 (p.331): the formation of a contract requires a bargain in which there is a manifestation of mutual assent to the exchange and a consideration. 1. Bargain v. gratuitous promise R71 (p.666): (1) To constitute consideration, a performance or a return promise must be bargained for [read: for something to be consideration, it must be a bargained-for performance or a return promise]; (2) a performance or returned promise is “bargained for” if it is sought by the promisor in exchange for his promise and is given by the promisee in exchange for that promise. (3): Performance may consist of an act, forbearance, or the creation, modification or destruction of a legal relation. Comment B: “ … the consideration induces the making of the promise and the promise induces the furnishing of the consideration.” Johnson v. Otterbein University (p.655): Conditional gift (to university), rather than bargained-for exchange; no consideration. 22 Hamer v. Sidway (p.658): Nephew restricted his actions per uncle’s request, and therefore a binding K—nephew giving up drinking, smoking, etc. counts as forbearance and thus is consideration. Argument against: just another conditional promise. 2. Past consideration If the promisee suffered the detriment before the promise was made, it cannot be said that the detriment was exchanged for the promise. If a person makes a promise to compensate another for some prior performance, that prior detriment cannot be consideration for the promise. The promise is seen as gratuitous and non-binding. (E&E, pp.161-162) Moore (p.669): Psychic predicts death. The past consideration was the reading … the original bargain wasn’t the reading for the mortgage. Could have been set up that way, but there was no evidence that that was the case. No contract if past consideration. 3. Moral consideration Taken together, Webb and Mills obviously suggest that moral obligation may support a promise in the absence of traditional consideration, but only if the promisor has been personally benefited or enriched by the promisee’s sacrifice and there is, as a consequence, a just and reasonable claim for compensation. (Chirelstein, p.31) R86 (p.686): (1) A promise made in recognition of a benefit previously received by the promisor from the promisee is binding to the extent necessary to prevent injustice: unjust enrichment idea. (2) Promise not binding if the benefit was conferred as a gift or promisor was generally not unjustly enriched, or if the value of the promise was disproportionate to the value of the benefit. Mills v. Wyman (p.671): Even though person did take care of the son, by the time the father wrote letter, expenses had been incurred, and there was no suggestion that Mills ought to care for son in exchange for promised money. Fact that father had a moral duty to pay for medical service for his sick son doesn’t make a legal duty. So moral duty not good enough to be consideration. “What a man ought to do, generally he ought to be made to do, whether he promise or refuse. But the law of society has left most of such obligations to the interior forum, as the tribunal of conscience has been aptly called.” Webb v. McGowin (p.681): Consideration? Which theory? Moral duty: unjust enrichment theory. Promise to pay is an enforceable contract only because of the prior moral duty. Court goes with this. Difference between this and Cotnam, incidentally: not just a quasi-contract, but a real K, says court, because there was an actual promise. Supreme court opinion: really important thing was the massive material benefit: they stress the unjust-enrichment side of it. C. Contract modifications/pre-existing duty rule The performance or, or promise to perform, a pre-existing duty is not consideration. (E&E, p.156) 23 R89 (p.697): Promise modifying a contract is binding if fair and equitable in view of new, unforeseen circumstances; or if ok bc statute or bc justice requires enforcement in view of material change in position in reliance [someone, say, makes a commitment to buy something they otherwise wouldn’t have bc they think they have the money bc modified contract]. UCC 2-209 (p. 697): Modifications don’t need consideration to be binding. Doesn’t really agree with R89. Only applies for sales of goods. Stilk v. Myrick (p.687): Is modified contract made at sea enforceable? No. No consideration: P was already under contract, and he wasn’t doing anything extra (arguably), so how could there be consideration for a new agreement? Captain’s promise was gratuitous. Point: if captain had fired them capriciously, it would have been different, but two sailors leaving is like two sailors dying; original contract was enough to cover contingencies like this. Alaska Packers’ Assn. v. Domenico (p.689): Sailors under contract to fish for salmon; they demanded a hike in the K price, company wouldn’t pay when they got back, court said no new K: no consideration. They were already under obligation. [Note: nets found not to be defective.] No consideration here; even more of a pure holdup than Stilk, where at least there was a change in circumstances (i.e., increase in work). There is an argument to be made that the old contract was breached and a new one was negotiated, but it wasn’t made and wouldn’t fly anyway because those in the company with authority to do that kind of thing weren’t aware of goings-on. Brian Construction and Development Co. v. Brighenti (p.692): D subcontractor wants extra money—over and above initial agreement—to excavate, given that they found extra crap down there. [A fact pattern to keep one’s eye on.] General contractor agreed to pay costs plus 10%, D started work again, but then stopped. Contractor sues subcontractor for breach. General contractor is suing on modified contract. Subcontractor, in defense, is saying that the modification isn’t binding: that there was no new consideration, that that was stuff he was supposed to be doing anyway. If court had tried to decide case entirely on first contract? Per original contract, there had to be written authorization for additional work. Sub still has an argument. They met with unforeseen condition; couldn’t proceed without authorization; never got authorization; therefore contractor in breach and they had the right to walk off the job. US v. Stump Home (p.698): Function of requiring consideration in modification of a contract: preventing coercive modifications. Idea is to head off duress-type situations. Argument: law doesn’t require adequate consideration. Consideration can be as small as you want it to be; seems like a funny way to get at the concern about exploitation. You can have these nominal consideration recitals; surely that’s not doing much work against Alaska Packers style issues. Prefers to entirely rely on duress or something like it: go at the issue we’re worried about directly. 24 D. Adequacy R79 (p.704): If requirement of consideration met, no add’l reqs of gain, advantage, benefit, equivalence, mutuality, etc. That said, “Disparity in value … sometimes indicates that the purported consideration was not in fact bargained for but was a mere formality or pretense. Such a sham or “nominal” consideration does not satisfy the requirement of 71.” R364 (p.705): Specific performance or an injunction will be refused if such relief would be unfair because (c) the exchange is grossly inadequate or the terms of the contract are otherwise unfair. Newman & Snell’s State Bank v. Hunter (p.702): Transfer of worthless paper isn’t consideration. Note is worthless; bank’s transfer is sham consideration and thus no binding contract. Dyer v. National By-Products, Inc. (p.705): Dyer injured on job; goes back to work, but eventually is laid off. He sues: says K for lifetime employment with his forbearance from suing about injury as consideration. Workman in Dyer actually believed his claim was worth something; very unlikely that bank believed that its note from dead husband was worth something—can be squared by saying that there is real consideration if party tendering thinks they’re giving up something of value. VII. Intention to be bound R21 (p.712): “ … but a manifestation of intention that a promise shall not affect legal relations may prevent the formation of a contract.” Thus, if there’s some objective manifestation of intent not to be bound, no contract. Formalities: formality was the seal … to make a binding K, you’d seal an agreement with wax. Rule was that no K was binding unless under seal. Notion of a seal on a document took the place of and predated the notion of consideration. Only agreements that were made under seal would be legally binding. Purpose of requirement of seal? Given that it’s a weird, difficult ritual, you’re not going to slip into legal relations accidentally: it ensures that parties really intended to make a binding agreement … advantage of seal is that other people can later see. You can use it to provide evidence of intention on part of both parties to be legally bound. Function of seal is served pretty well by signature. Why not just always use signatures? Most people couldn’t write. So same function. Seal has been deprived of effectiveness by statute. A. Nominal consideration Pretense of a bargain does not satisfy the exchange element, so that a false consideration which does not in fact induce the return promise (or, at least, cannot reasonably be conceived as doing so), should not be treated as sufficient. (E&E p.162) 25 Schnell v. Nell (p.726): Wife dies … husband agrees to pay $600 to ppl in consideration of one cent bc wife had no property to will to these ppl (and will had said that each person would get $200). Almost certainly intent to be bound—otherwise unlikely you’d go through the ritual of providing one cent’s worth of consideration. Court says no consideration, though: obvious disparity in value. Option Contracts: Purported consideration (i.e., nominal consideration) ok. Why is this different from substantive contracts? “The fact that the option is an appropriate preliminary step in the conclusion of a socially useful transaction provides a sufficient substantive basis for enforcement …” That is, options facilitate transactions; transactions are good bc increase utility. Options make it easier to enter into real contracts (all of this, then, supports “beautiful idea.”) R87 (p.730): Option contracts just require purported consideration (and signed writing). B. Recitals For option contracts, even recited consideration is ok. (R87) Smith v. Wheeler (p.731): Option contract to buy land; recital of $1 consideration, but $1 never actually paid. Wheeler revokes option before consideration actually paid. Court reverses lower court decision in favor of seller … even if dollar wasn’t paid, contract not voided: there was an implied promise to pay which can be enforced by the other party. Wheeler, in theory, could have sued for $1. Jolles v. Wittenberg (p.732): Nominal consideration recited in a sealed instrument sufficient as a matter of law. VIII. Promissory Estoppel R90 (p.811): (1) A promise which the promisor should reasonably expect to induce action or forbearance on the part of the promisee or a third person and which does induce such action or forbearance is binding if injustice can be avoided only by enforcement of the promise. The remedy granted for breach may be limited as justice requires. (1) A charitable subscription … is binding under (1) without proof that the promise induced action or forbearance. [Changes from the previous R90 expanded the reach of the doctrine, bringing it even closer to being a tort action.] A. As substitute for consideration 1. Family Promises Ricketts v. Scothorn (p.760): No contract: money was given as a gift, not in exchange for girl quitting her job. They’re not saying there is consideration, but again, that you can’t 26 use the argument that there’s no consideration because promisee relied. Important to be clear on this: reliance theory of enforcement, but generates expectation measure of damages. That’s a way of making the point that if this is really a contractual animal, then it’s not necessary for her to have suffered some kind of detriment in order to recover. We’re just taking the fact that she relied on this promise as a basis for finding an enforceable promise here. Tip-off: business about estoppel. Grandfather is estopped from claiming lack of consideration because reliance suggests that what’s going on here is that the court is treating this as a contract. 2. Land Greiner v. Greiner (p.766): No consideration; guy moving back near his mother is like person crossing the street to get money. No exchange, etc. However, reliance, and reasonably expected reliance, too, therefore PE. 3. Charitable Subscriptions Allegheny (p.770): Virtually same facts as Johnson v. Otterbein University. Cardozo makes up consideration here because he hates PE. 4. Pensions Feinberg (p.777): Poster child for R90. Court held PE bc company had induced reliance: she gave up a good job in reliance on promised pension. Wouldn’t work if she had been otherwise employable, or had gotten a better job, etc.: she really relied to her detriment. 5. Construction bids Baird (p.784): No contract because offer was withdrawn before accepted; L. Hand declines to apply PE because this is a business transaction. No option contract bc no consideration; no conditional offer; no evidence of a unilateral contract. Drennan (p.788): Same scenario, more or less, but court implies a subsidiary promise … business practice: acceptance via inclusion in main bid. B. As alternative to breach Goodman (p.798): P wanted an Emerson Radio franchise; D assured them they had it, even though that decision wasn’t in their power. No actual K. P incurred costs, ultimately didn’t get the franchise, and sued. Promissory estoppel used as a consideration alternative here, but only reliance damages awarded; ultimately, this seems like a torts opinion. Hoffman v. Red Owl (p.800): P wanted to open a franchise; D, for some time, led him to believe that that would happen, causing P to incur significant costs, only to ultimately cause P to abandon the deal by hiking amount of capital necessary to get in. P sues, but 27 no contract—not even anything that looks like a contract. Court awards damages on promissory estoppel basis, but this comes out looking like a tort case: PE not used as a consideration substitute, only reliance damages granted, damages even granted to Hoffman’s wife, which clearly wouldn’t have happened in a contracts action, but fits in a torts framework: damage to her was foreseeable. Death of Contracts? Barnett suggests that what Red Owl and cases like it have created is a new tort of negligent promissory misrepresentation: wouldn’t work under existing torts bc D wasn’t actually lying at the time. Grant Gilmore suggested that contract law, via promissory estoppel and quasi-contract, was being reabsorbed into the “mainstream” of tort law. In a sense, though, Red Owl actually protects contract law: no contract damages granted when no contract. Hillman study seems to indicate, in any case, that plaintiffs aren’t actually winning on promissory estoppel claims very often. C. Some Modern Applications and Limits of Promissory Estoppel 1. Promise Blatt v. USC (p.822): PE as consideration substitute. No Order of the Coif. Not an actual Hamer-style contract, bc performance (working hard and getting good grades) not sought by promisor (school) in exchange for its promise (eligibility for honor). Decided under Old R90, which required action of a definite and substantial character on part of promisee; that language not in new R90, but likely that case would go the same way under sentence allowing limitation of remedy as justice requires. Spooner (p.826): Insurance salesmen sue for bonus despite clause in letter stating that bonus may be withheld pretty much at will. PE theory would be that letter induced reliance, but letter wasn’t really to be relied upon: promise was optional by its own terms. Ypsilanti (p.830): Township seeks an injunction to keep GM from moving operations elsewhere. GM had, they claim, promised to stay in Ypsilanti in exchange for tax abatements. Lower court grants injunction, says fundamental element of a promise is “an expression of intention by the promisor that his future conduct shall be in accordance with his present expression, irrespective of what his will may be when the time for performance arrives.” Problematic: that definition of promise does not include an intent by the promisor to be bound by his promise. Township clearly relied, and lower court, at least, thinks that not enforcing this “promise” would cause terrible injustice. On appeal, reversal: GM didn’t make a promise. Things GM said were a statutory prerequisite, were just hyperbole and puffery, etc.: GM hoped that these things were true, and intended to stay, but wasn’t promising anything. Court of Appeals analysis might have been motivated by a sense that there wasn’t so much injustice here. 2. Reasonable Reliance 28 Presley (p.846): When P filed for divorce the second time, she had notice that the estate wasn’t going to pay; her reliance, therefore, wasn’t justified (she could have changed the settlement agreement). Analogous to mitigation of damages, in a sense: once you know other party intends to withdraw promise, you shouldn’t go ahead and rack up damages. Fictional third-Restatement 90: Loosens consideration and broadens scope of contractual liability, but shrinks promissory estoppel. Suggestion that (1) formalities should make a contract enforceable; (2) in the absence of consideration a contract is binding if with knowledge of promisor, promise induces reliance by the promisee that is so substantial that it would be unlikely in the absence of a manifested intention by the promisor to be legally bound; (3) a promisor should be able to avoid liability by announcing lack of intent to be bound—i.e., calling a halt to reliance. 3. Injustice of Nonenforcement Cohen v. Cowles: No contract between “confidential” source and reporters to keep source’s identity confidential. MN court declines to apply promissory estoppel, largely because they’re not clear that what happened (publication of source’s name) was unjust, and in any case justice concerns are swamped by First Amt. worries: “The court must balance the constitutional rights of a free press against the common law interest in protecting a promise of anonymity.” USSC makes a distinction between two kinds of laws for First Amt. purposes: generally applicable laws and laws that target the press specifically. The press shouldn’t be any less subject to the former than anyone else just because they might have an incidental impact on press’s operation. Blackmun dissent thinks that if the operation of any law has a direct impact on speech (as, arguably, promissory estoppel does here), you can’t just say that’s an incidental impact and ignore. On remand, MN court finishes its promissory estoppel analysis (they’d not done the injustice part) by weighing need of paper to publish news against source’s need for confidentiality (similar analysis to First Amt. one above) and decides that justice would be best served by using promissory estoppel here. Performance A. Implied duty of good faith performance Contracts generally contain an implied duty to perform in good faith (Wood v. Lucy, Lady Duff-Gordon). Acting in bad faith has nothing to do with bad motives. Possibly a problematic concept: are courts reading in this covenant bc they think parties meant it to be there, or are courts reading it in because they think it should be there? Should courts be reading in these clauses, or should they let agreements be illusory and make parties draw up better agreement? Position depends on whether you think these clauses are somehow inherent in the Ks, or you think the courts are just making things up where parties didn’t intend to include best efforts. Possibly an issue to imply that one party should have the interests of the other in mind. 29 UCC 1-203: Every contract or duty within [the UCC] imposes an obligation of good faith in its performance or enforcement. R205: Every contract imposes upon each party a duty of good faith and fair dealing in its performance and enforcement. Goldberg v. Levy (p.877): Receipts fell below $101K and D wants out; P alleges that D was diverting business so that he could break the lease. Claim is that D brought his gross receipts down that low on purpose. Court found for plaintiff. Court appears to be saying it’s finding this implied covenant of good faith in the promise to pay percentage rent (as in Wood v. Lucy). You might argue that in order to find real consideration here and make sure this isn’t an illusory promise, you have to read in such a provision. Mutual Life Insurance Co. of NY v. Tailored Woman (p.879): Court finds that it was ok for D to move furs to portion of store with flat-rent lease (lower section involved percentage rent), thus avoiding a significant chunk of percentage rent: no bad faith there. Goldberg court would likely have found bad faith here. B. Warranties 1. Implied UCC 2-314 (p.899): Implied warranty of merchantability in contracts for sales of goods. (1) Warranty implied; (2) Goods to be merchantable must (a) pass without objection in the trade; (b) if fungible goods, be of fair average quality; (c) be fit for ordinary purposes for which such goods are used; (d) run of even kind, quality and quantity; (e) be adequately contained/packaged; (f) conform to promises or affirmations of fact made on label (if any). UCC 2-315 (p.899): Implied warranty of fitness: If seller at time of contracting has reason to know any particular purpose for which goods are required and that buyer is relying on seller’s skill or judgment to select/furnish suitable goods, there’s an implied warranty of fitness for a particular purpose. Step-Saver Data Systems, Inc. v. Wyse Technology (p.896): Step-Saver rented computer systems to professionals; they used Wyse terminals. Problems develop and consumers sue Step-Saver, Step-Saver sues Wyse for problems with terminals, claiming breach of an implied warranty of merchantability. Here, buyer failed to show that seller knew or had reason to know the precise purpose for which buyer was purchasing goods. 2. Express Warranties UCC 2-313 (p.906): (1) Express warranties created: (a) any affirmation of fact or promise made by seller which relates to goods and becomes a basis of the bargain creates an express warranty that goods shall conform to the description; (b) any description of goods which is made part of basis of bargain creates express warranty that goods shall conform 30 to description; (c) any sample or model made part of basis of bargain creates express warranty that goods shall conform to sample or model; (2) Not necessary that seller use formal words such as “warrant” or “guarantee” or even intend to make a warranty, but an affirmation of the value of the goods or a statement of opinion or commendation doesn’t create a warranty. Royal Business Machines, Inc. v. Lorraine Corp. (p.900): Seller said that (1) copiers were of high quality; (2) copiers didn’t break down often; (3) replacement parts were readily available; (4) cost of maintenance and cost of supplies would remain low, no more than ½ cent/copy; (5) copiers had been tested and were ready to be marketed; (6) experience and projections showed that purchase and leasing of these copiers would lead to substantial profits; (7) machines were safe and wouldn’t cause fires; and (8) service calls would be required on average of every 7K copies or so. Court found (in accordance with UCC 2-313) that 1, 2, 3, 6 and the cost-of-supplies portion of 4 weren’t warranties: 1 is pure opinion, 2 lacks specificity (opinion), 3 doesn’t relate to the good being sold, 4 re: supplies doesn’t relate to good being sold, 6 is vague and opinion; the rest are fact. Case is remanded on fact ones, though: if buyer knows that an affirmation of fact is untrue (bc more experience, as possibly here: deal took place over long period), that affirmation can’t form a basis of the bargain. Breach A. Anticipatory Repudiation Distinction between breach and repudiation (E&E p.542): repudiation = party makes it clear by words or actions that it will breach when performance falls due. Basic approach: a clear, unequivocal and voluntary repudiation is recognized as the equivalent of a material and total breach if the threatened action or failure to act would be a material and total breach if it happened at the time due for performance. A mere request for a chance in the terms or a request for cancellation of a contract is not in itself enough to constitute a repudiation (Corbin via Harrell, p.961). Rationale: Allowing parties to sue for anticipatory breach helps them minimize damages; if one party knows the other is going to breach, it may be able to minimize damages by going for a quick remedy rather than waiting for performance that might never happen. Problem is that you don’t know if a party is really going to breach until they do. UCC 2-610 (p.963): Anticipatory repudiation: When either party repudiates contract with respect to performance not yet due the loss of which will substantially impair the value of the contract to the other, the aggrieved party may: (a) wait for performance by repudiating party for a commercially reasonable time; or (b) resort to any remedy for breach; and (c) in either case suspend its own performance. UCC 2-611 (p.963): Retraction of anticipatory repudiation: (1) Until repudiating party’s next performance is due it can retract its repudiation unless aggrieved party has, since the repudiation, cancelled or materially changed its position or otherwise indicated that it 31 considers the repudiation final. (2) Retraction may be by any method which clearly indicates to the aggrieved party that the repudiating party intends to perform. (3) Retraction reinstates repudiating party’s rights under the contract with due excuse and allowance to aggrieved party for any delay occasioned by repudiation. Harrell v. Sea Colony, Inc. (p.947): Harrell offers to mutually rescind contract; Sea Colony (seller) possibly anticipatorily repudiates by selling condo to someone else. Damages? If mutual rescission, Harrell would simply get deposit back; if seller anticipatorily repudiated, Harrell would get expectation damages (here, difference between market price and contract price). B. Constructive Conditions and Material Breach 1. Constructive Conditions A court will imply a condition as a matter of law if the circumstances and nature of the contract compel the conclusion that the condition should exist as a matter of policy, or that if the parties had addressed the issue, they reasonably would have intended it to be part of their contract. (E&E p.473) In an exchange transaction, unless the language of the contract or its surrounding circumstances clearly indicate a contrary intent, the parties must almost always be taken to have expected that the principal promises exchanged would be dependent on each other—that they would be what are known as constructive conditions of exchange. If they were not, this would lead to the bizarre situation in which a party could be forced to perform even when the other has failed or refused to do so. R224 (in Selections for Contracts): Condition is an event, not certain to occur, which must occur, unless non-occurrence is excused, before performance under a contract becomes due. If a condition has not been satisfied (which conditions other party’s performance), you don’t have to perform. Jacob & Youngs v. Kent (p.974): Cardozo essentially finds that contractor substantially performed on construction of mansion: they used the wrong brand of pipe, but he finds that they did so by (good faith) mistake, and that the pipe is of equal quality and generally the same as the requested pipe except for the name stamped on it. Distinction between two kinds of promises: dependent and independent promises. Could rephrase in terms of conditions: Independent promise: if promise to put Reading pipe in is independent, then promise on part of other party is not dependent on it (promise on part of other party being promise to pay). So if independent promise, no condition—promise to pay not conditional on Reading pipe. If, however, dependent promise, creates a condition that promise to pay is conditional upon satisfaction of that condition. Could say here that J&Y substantially performed (i.e., did not materially breach), and thus measure of damages is difference in value between house as it is and house as it would have been with Reading pipe (here, zero) and not cost of replacement of pipe. 32 Note that substantial performance doesn’t work where a party intentionally, say, uses the wrong brand of pipe. 2. Material Breach If the other party has failed to live up to the contract in some way, and that failure constitutes a material breach, then you do not have to perform your part of the contract. Note that not every failure on the other party’s part constitutes a material breach. The opposite of material breach is known as substantial performance; if party to contract fails to live up to condition of contract which is really minor, court may find that failure to live up to contract did not constitute material breach bc substantial performance. Parties are free to expressly empower the victim of any breach—however small—to cancel the contract. But, in the absence of an expressed or constructive condition to the contrary, only if a breach is material does it relieve the nonbreaching party of its duty of performance under the contract. (Barnett, p.984) A breach is material if the failure or deficiency in performance is so central to the contract that is substantially impairs its value and deeply disappoints the reasonable expectations of the promisee. (E&E, p.529). Substantial performance: if party’s performance is short of that promised in the contract, but sufficient to qualify as substantial performance, the other party is not entitled to withhold return performance due but has the right to claim damages for the breach. Usual measure of damages is amount to correct the shortfall in performance; however, if that’s disproportionate, court may instead choose to use difference in value. (E&E, pp.531-532) 3. Perfect Tender Rule: Cure and Rescission Substantial performance not applicable to a sale of goods. Buyer is entitled to perfect tender of the goods ordered and has the right to reject goods that fail to conform exactly to what was called for by the contract. UCC 2-106 (p.1006): Cancellation occurs when either party puts end to K for breach by other; effect is same as that of termination. (2) Goods or conduct including any part of a performance are “conforming” when in accordance with obligations under K. UCC 2-601 (p.1007): … if goods or tender of delivery fail to conform to K, buyer may reject whole, accept whole, or accept part (unit) and reject the rest. UCC 2-508 (p.1006): Where any tender rejected because non-conforming, and time for performance not yet expired, seller may seasonably notify of intention to cure and within K time make conforming delivery. (2) Where buyer rejects nonconforming that seller thought would be acceptable—say at the K time—seller gets reasonable time to substitute a conforming tender. 33 Ramirez (p.999): Autosport supplied a nonconforming van. They did supply it, but substantial performance doesn’t apply to sales of goods. 4. Cost of completion v. diminution in value If no substantial performance, or that that doesn’t apply, then higher measure of damages is correct: then we see the promises in the contract as conditional on each other, meaning that Ps can hold Ds to the contract, and thus Ps could hold D to specific performance or the monetary equivalent thereof. So this court is with the Jacob & Youngs dissent: if contractor acted in bad faith, doctrine of substantial performance doesn’t apply and P gets (normal) damages. Groves v. John Wunder Co. (p.1011): Contractor removes gravel and fails to restore land to level grade. Aggrieved landowner sues and only gets difference in value at trial; higher court remands, but strongly suggests that cost of completion be awarded: “ … where the contractor willfully and fraudulently varies from the terms of a construction contract, he cannot sue thereon and have the benefit of the equitable doctrine of substantial performance.” R346: (comments): “Sometimes defects in a completed structure cannot be physically remedied without tearing down … The law does not require damages to be measured by a method requiring such economic waste. If no such waste is involved, the cost of remedying the defect is the amount awarded as compensation for failure to render the promised performance.” Restatement is concerned with economic waste, but bear in mind that economic waste is iffy: depends on value to contracting parties (i.e., might look like waste to award $60K completion cost when diminution in value was only $12K, but in theory contract might still be efficient because P might never have entered into it were it not for the assurance that their land would be restored after gravel was taken out). Peevyhouse (p.1017): Measure of damages ordinarily = reasonable cost of performance of the work. But where K provision breached was incidental, and where econ. benefit of full performance is grossly disproportionate to the cost of performance, damages are limited to diminution in value bc nonperformance. Jury award here was less than cost of completion but more than diminution in value; court says (as above) that that’s inappropriate: that the main purpose of the lease was not the restoration of the land afterwards. Damages reduced to diminution in value ($300). Defenses to contracts A. Unconscionability UCC 2-302 (p.1137): If court finds a clause to be unconscionable, it may refuse to enforce the contract, or refuse to enforce the clause, or limit the application of the clause … when unconscionability is claimed, parties may present evidence to aid court in its determination. 34 R208 (p.1137): If a contract or term is unconscionable, court may refuse to enforce the contract, may enforce the remainder of the contract without the bad term, or may limit the application of the bad term as to avoid any unconscionable results. Comments to UCC 2-302, echoed by those to R208, suggest a two-part test for unconscionability: for relief to be granted, transaction must exhibit both bargaining unfairness (“procedural unconscionability”) and resulting unfair or oppressive terms (“substantive unconscionability”). In most cases both are present, at least to some degree, but there is some balance, so that if one is strongly shown court is likely to be less finicky in finding the other. There are cases in which relief has been granted when only one of the elements has been established, but very rare: only happens when an element (usually unfair terms) is so outrageous that the other can be assumed to have been present as a matter of course. (E&E, p.367) Williams v. Walker-Thomas Furniture Co.: Appellants purchased household items from appellee under contract that kept a balance due on every item purchased until the balance due on all items was liquidated; debt incurred at the time of purchase of each item was secured by the right to repossess all the items previously purchased by the same purchaser. Question of first impression for the court; they discuss both formal/procedural unconscionability and substantive issues, citing UCC 2-302. A. Failure of a basic assumption 1. Mistake The doctrine of mistake applies when the contract is based on an erroneous belief at the time of contracting that certain facts are true. Confined to errors of fact: i.e., errors about some thing or event that actually occurred or existed and can be ascertained by objective evidence. Doesn’t cover bad judgment, incorrect predictions of future events, or mistaken understandings between parties (the third item is an interpretation question). (E&E, pp. 424-426) Sherwood v. Walker (p.1166): Both parties made a mistake; question is whether when both parties make a mistake about a term in a contract, that’s a reason to void the contract. Trial court found for P: mistake didn’t vitiate the contract. This court reverses and says K is unenforceable because whether or not the cow was pregnant was a material fact—the subject matter of the sale. Court says that a mistake as to a mere quality of the thing being sold wouldn’t void. R151 (p.1189): A mistake is a belief that is not in accord with the facts. R152 (p.1190): Restatement’s requirements for avoidance on ground of mistake: (1) mistake goes to a basic assumption on which K was made; (2) mistake has a material effect on the agreed exchange of performances; and (3) the mistake is not one of which that party bears the risk. 35 36