“Virtual compliance to Kyoto by non-state actors and through domestic climatechange policies: A rationalist appraisal of the US’s untenable unilateralism” IPS 204: Theories and Concepts in International Relations Final Paper Andrew Nutter Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper The Bush administration’s withdrawal from the process of Kyoto ratification on grounds that they had “no interest”1 in pursuing such policy prompted many to claim Kyoto dead. Instead, the protocol has been characterised by significant resilience and while its future existence or success is by no means certain, there are now clear commitments by governments, international organisations and firms, backed by a strengthening consensus within the scientific community, to reduce the growth rate and eventually stabilise the emissions of Green House Gases (GHG) at a non-threatening level. What is particularly surprising about this picture is not that the US has decided to part ways with the international effort, given the uncertainties and the looming costs it would have faced in ratifying Kyoto. But both that there is a prevailing perception that the US acted “wrongly”, and that international cooperation on the issue might be able to survive the loss of the single largest emitter of GHGs. The first observation testifies to the rapid social construction of global warming as an anthropogenic2 and controllable evil ever since the policy seed of the issue was “internationally” planted at the Rio summit just ten years ago (Liberatore 1995, Jones 2002). The latter tendency must be coupled with the observation that much of the effort to combat global warming is being driven by non-state actors and through domestic politics. Taking a speculative step, this paper argues that independently of whether or not it was justifiable for the Bush government to withdraw from the protocol, the US’s chosen unilateralism may be undermined by the deepening interdependence between and within countries and the efforts of firms and foreign countries with regard to climate change. The interdependence of modern society now prevents states from acting in their own interests. Environmental Protection Agency Administrator Christine Whitman, March 27th 2001: “we have no interest in implementing that treaty [Kyoto protocol]” 2 Anthropogenic: caused by human activity 1 2 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper From an academic standpoint, the focus of international relations theories has been adept at shifting with the times and trailing evolving areas of policy interest closely. As environmental issues have grown in prominence after the end of the Cold War, so has the intent of international relations scholars to explain and understand new environmental security threats, international regimes that could coordinate international behaviour or the genderisation of environmental politics, for example. This paper’s aim is to put two dominant rationalist paradigms of International Relations to the test, namely neorealism and neoliberalism, first on the need for international coordination to manage Global Climate Change (GCC), and second, to reason the US’s peculiar behaviour. Although Neoliberalism, and in particular regime theory, has emerged as the de-facto theoretical framework for explaining the international response GCC, Neorealism has also evolved to allow for cooperation and may be better suited to explain the US’s apparent unilateralism. The second part of this paper will come to look at the nonstate forces that may undermine the intentions of the state, and in particular, how there may be some form of “virtual compliance” to the Kyoto protocol. Rationalist perspectives, notably liberal institutionalism, can help explain why there was the creation of an international regime, why the US refused to consider ratification of the Kyoto protocol and perhaps even the consequence for Kyoto. They struggle however to explain what some of the events that are occurring now: notably the pressures on US firms to change their practices despite US government reluctance to support these international regimes. Before delving into the theory, it is worth having an overview of the historical and scientific context for global warming. Global Warming, Regime Building and Kyoto: History and Context 3 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper Ten years ago, few environmental concerns were as contentious within the scientific and political communities as that of climate change. In a short space of time, consensus was reached that climate change was occurring and that some of the change was anthropogenic. The consequences of climate change are, however, still unclear given the complexity of climate modelling and the interplay between natural “cyclical” and anthropogenic global warming (See appendix). A rationalist appraisal of the GCC problem nevertheless requires us to take a brief look at the science behind global warming and the historical process of international regime building, ultimately leading up to the Kyoto protocol, to support the necessary calculations of relative and absolute gains to states and the international community. Although the science dates as far back as the early 60s (Andresen 2002), the date widely attributed to climate change becoming a significant political issue is 1988, with the Toronto Conference of the Atmosphere, along with a statement to the US congress by NASA scientist James Hansen that “it is time to stop waffling so much. We should say that the evidence is pretty strong that the greenhouse effect is here” (quoted from Patterson). The claim was made even more plausible by the freak weather patterns that were occurring at the time, with the biggest drought in the US since the 1930s, and the six hottest years on record being in that decade. What was perhaps more pivotal was that a void being left by the end of the Cold War was being filled by environmental issues; the depletion of the stratospheric ozone layer, tropical deforestation, loss of biological diversity and pollution of the oceans to name but a few. The confirmation that the ozone hole was being created by the emission of chlorofluorocarbons (CFCs), “dramatically demonstrated that human activities can indeed affect the global atmosphere […]. Initially, public concern about global warming rode on the coattails of the ozone issue.” (Bodansky p27 in Lutterbacher 2001). Institution building 4 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper Governments reacted to the tide of rising concern with three main initiatives3. First, the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) was established in late 1988 to provide a clear statement of scientific consensus about climate change and its possible impacts, as well as suggestions to counter the problem (Boehmer-Christiansen 1996). Second, a series of international conferences created an arena for politicians to convene and issue pronouncements and policy ideas. Third was a series of unilateral targets that some countries set themselves to stabilise emissions of CO2 by the year 2000. With a great deal of momentum, this political agenda led to the signing in Rio of the 1992 UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) with the explicit goal of “stabilising the concentrations of greenhouse gases (GHGs) in the atmosphere at a level that would prevent dangerous anthropogenic interference with the climate system”. There were no binding targets, a condition negotiated by the US doubtful of the nature of scientific knowledge and aware of costly compliance, only a commitment to voluntarily reduce CO2 emission to 1990 emission levels by 2000 for Annex I countries4. Although the convention was only a procedural framework with only very general and diplomatically palatable obligations (to all except the oil producing nations), it is important to note that it was a first step in concretising the climate change regime by establishing a legal and institutional framework for future meetings of the parties and the addition of more forceful protocols. Indeed, representatives from over 160 countries met in Kyoto in December 1997 to negotiate individual binding limits on emissions of six greenhouse gases. The protocol has already been ratified by 97 countries and assuming Canada and Russia ratify early next year, it will come into force and commit countries to target ranges of anything between a 3 See Bodansky 1995 for a complete review of the emerging climate change regime Annex I countries are mainly industrialized countries. The argument being that developing countries could not afford to reduce their emissions and that the vast majority of GHGs had been emitted by industrialized countries over the previous fifty years. 4 5 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper reduction of 8-percent for Europe to a 10-increase allowed for Iceland, to be achieved between 2008 and 2012 and relative to emission levels in 1990. Kyoto protocol mechanisms Understanding the difficulty of meeting the emission proposals, the US insisted on including a series of flexibility mechanisms into the protocol, the contention being that market based mechanisms could increase economic efficiency in meeting targets and allow for emission reductions to happen in the cheapest country. Briefly, the three mechanisms are the International Emissions Trading (IET), Joint Implementation (JI) and the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM). The IET is what is commonly known as the “carbon market”, an arrangement for countries to sell and buy carbon permits to meet targets at minimum cost and promote efficiency. JI and CDM are project-based mechanisms, whereby Annex I countries can take credits for projects that reduce emissions in non-Annex I countries (anything from planting forests to investing in renewable sources of energy). The international relations of global warming With such titles as “the Greening of Machiavelli” by Brenton (1994), the majority of international relations studies on global environmental politics reflect the discipline’s legacy of taking a state-centric approach (Paterson 1996, Saurin 1996). It is also assumed that the environmental problem can be retrofitted to existing paradigms of international relations, rather than the paradigms changed to reflect new circumstances. The standard approach being that global environmental protection is immensely difficult in a world where the main political actors continue to be sovereign states. International regimes are needed to coordinate state behaviour in the management of these “global commons” dilemmas; 6 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper the atmosphere being the perfect model of an anarchic system in which coordination is deemed essential. The difficulty for neorealism to explaining the existing global warming institutional setup has left the approach being outmoded by neoliberalism, with its explicit focus on institutional regimes (Newell, Saurin 1996). However, the Kyoto protocol has made the costs and benefits of action or inaction more explicit and given the choice of the Bush government not to ratify Kyoto, recent turns in events appear to have a realist slant to them. Can neorealism make a contribution to our understanding of international cooperation on global climate change? Neorealism Classical realists consider cooperative outcomes to be elusive, an exception being the transitory alliances that would serve to balance power among opposing blocs of states (Morgenthau 1972). Neorealists maintain the assumptions of sovereign states, acting as unitary actors in an anarchic world where the distribution of power in the system is the only concern of states. As opposed to neoliberalists, neorealists are thus only concerned with gains in relative power. Compared to classical realism, cooperation within the neorealist literature is more likely and has revolved around “hegemonic stability theory” (Kindleberger 1973). This approach argues that cooperation is possible when a single actor with a preponderance of power, or hegemon, is willing to use this power to coordinate behaviour. A hegemon is distinguished from states which merely dominate by the recognition of its power on those it controls, and the level of coordination is proportionate to the perception of hegemonic power exerted on other states. Cooperation will thus be more probable when one state is “powerful enough to maintain the essential rules governing interstate relations, and willing to do so” (Keohane and Nye, 1977: 44). 7 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper How does this translate to the climate change issue and what measure of power should we be looking at? Rowlands (2001: p45) argues that above military and economic power is the ability of actors to change global climate. Porter and Brown (1996: p14) argue that “in every global environmental issue there is one state or a group of states whose cooperation is so essential to a successful agreement for coping with the problem that it has the potential to block strong international action”. This is an indirect way of suggesting that the hegemon would aim to satisfy his interests, at least through the power of veto, and that a cooperative regime is simply an “epiphenomenon” of these interests. Examples of this are given by Mitchell (1994) with regard to the nations appearing likely to phase out ozonedepleting substances even before required by the Montreal protocol, or the International Whaling Commission being labelled a “whaling club” in which “violations were rare because the commission never set quotas below the levels of harvest desired by the whaling nations”. By all accounts, the US was the dominant hegemon on the climate change issue. It clearly had and still has military and economic primacy. It was responsible for over a quarter of worldwide emissions (or 36-percent of Annex 1 country emissions5) and had a large number of interests on the issue of climate change, be it through the effect of action or inaction, with regard to agriculture, industry restructuring, energy dependency, and its coastline amongst many. Furthermore, it was generally recognised by those involved in climate negotiations that US participation was crucial (Patterson 1996). Rowland (2001) thus labels the US “climate hegemon”, suggesting the prospects for cooperation were high. However, according to neorealist theory, this also suggests that the US’s interests in cooperation would be met and would result in gains of relative power if cooperation was deemed successful, a fact not answered by the literature. 5 www.unfccc.com website 8 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper One convenient means to simplify our analysis of the climate change negotiations is to look at the alliances that demarcate the issue. Alliances are understood as being transitory within the classical realist literature, as groups of states form blocs to balance power within the negotiations. Five main alliances emerged. The Alliance of Small Island States (AOSIS), those most threatened by global climate change calling for the most drastic action, the Organisation of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), highlighting the immediate economic cost of action and resisting controls on GHGs, the EU, although with notable divisions amongst its rank, calling for large cuts in GHG emissions, the G77 of “least developed countries” arguing for fair treatment in policy making, and finally the US. It is argued that the OPEC block used a strategy of using a negotiating “veto” to block action on climate change, a point going counter to the idea that only a hegemon could veto proceedings. As it turns out, the OPEC block was informally told at one of the Conference of the Parties meetings that this strategy would be subsequently ignored and that action would be taken to combat climate change. AOSIS had little negotiating power and was content with any attempt to reduce GHG emissions. EU and US interests clashed on a number of occasions. A first clash that has been highlighted a number of times in the literature was during the negations building up to the UNFCCC, the convention that underpins all subsequent international climate change negotiations. The US opposed the demands of mainly European states for a timetable for greenhouse gas emission reductions, and strongly objected to demands for binding targets. The desire to have US participation in the subsequent regime caused the EU to backtrack on their demands and resulted in a non-binding policy for industrialised nations to not exceed 1990 emission levels in 2000. A second example of US demands filtering through into policy came from its demands that flexibility mechanisms and that the basket of targeted emissions be raised to six, despite strong EU objections to their inclusion. Such incidents do indeed suggest that the US was acting as a climate hegemon. However, as Rowlands (2001) 9 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper points out, these Kyoto flexibility mechanisms are only to be used to meet specific targets, the idea of binding targets having gone against the grain of US preferences during the negotiations and thus putting into question hegemonic stability theory. I would argue that this only happened because of changing state interests. Indeed, although the US was against targets under the Bush senior administration, the tables were turned under the Clinton administration and Bill Clinton, in the run-up to Kyoto expressed his desire that “the Unites States […] commit to the binding and realistic target of returning to emissions of 1990 levels between 2008 and 2012”. When state interests changed a second time as Bush junior took the helm, the targets were binding and the US effectively judged it in its best interests to pull out of Kyoto, threatening the stability of the regime. Furthermore, given the US’s belief that the Kyoto commitments would be costly to any state entering the agreements, by ejecting itself from the regime and assuming Kyoto survives (something neorealism allows for given mutual interests of the parties involved 6), the US would be free-riding on the costly collective action of other states, thus guaranteeing an immediate gain in absolute and relative power, exactly the premise of neorealism. Finally, should the Kyoto protocol collapse (as it still might do if 55-percent of Annex 1 countries’ emissions are not accounted for in the ratification process), hegemonic stability theory would come to stand on higher ground. However, the more solid criticisms of neorealism and hegemonic stability theory with regard to global climate change are more structural than anecdotal in nature. The above argument for example defies the standard assumption that states interests are defined and constant, unless the measure of power changes (Keohane 1989), to which there is no strong evidence that they did. More critical yet are Paterson’s 6 Works if understand that absence of hegemon only means success more unlikely. More strained relations. Hegemon now Europe? P94 Paterson (1996) states “This is not to suggest that international cooperation cannot continue as a hegemon’s power declines, since congruent interests of major powers may make it possible for existing regimes to continues. It does, however, suggest that such continued cooperation will become more strained”. 10 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper (1996) arguments7 that creating a single measure of power resources is problematic (a point also raised in Luterbacher 2001), that state interests with climate change are fundamentally ambiguous and that the state is the sole actor, despite evidence that the agenda setting stage of the international regime was solidly set by non-state actors (pp 98113). Much of the above analysis is anecdotal evidence, fishing for facts to validate a hypothesis. Since neorealism is rooted in a neopositivist epistemological approach, with successive proponents aspiring to Waltz’s “philosophy of science values”, the theory necessarily generates hypotheses which can be tested, but rarely strictly falsified. The hypothesis even risks creating a line of enquiry that will create the facts needed to validate or disprove the theory (Paterson 1996a), the process not being devoid of normative influence. For example, my argument that the US could make absolute and even relative gains if Kyoto proceeded without it, thus substantiating a neorealist hypothesis to reason its actions, was based on one normative view of the state’s discount factor, or what scholars more eloquently refer to as “the shadow of the future”. Had we made the assumption that the US’s shadow was cast at dawn, the absolute and relative gain would turn to at least a relative loss, as competing countries would be far better prepared, by shifting to renewable forms of energy, to cope with the inevitable fall in supply of petroleum as natural reserves are depleted, and the inevitably large rise in demand from developing nations. Whilst this paper concludes that hegemonic stability theory is only weekly supported by the evidence of global cooperation on climate change, I take the liberty of making a 7 He also makes reference to the feasibility of cooperation without a clear hegemon in a neorealist paradigm. This “cooperation under anarchy” developed by Snidal (1985) is a response to the apparent failure of hegemonic stability theory, but as Patterson mentions, this approach “straddles neorealism and neoliberal institutionalism” and is outside the scope of this essay. Besides, he makes a convincing series of arguments that the theory is irrelevant to the question of global climate cooperation. 11 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper perhaps normative claim that, at least at the systemic level of analysis, the more recent event of the US dropping out of the Kyoto ratification process bodes well with neorealist predictions. Moreover, should Kyoto collapse within the next year, the evidence would shift to being more supportive of hegemonic stability theory. Neoliberal institutionalism This approach is still founded on the basis of states being the most important actors operating in a fundamentally anarchic framework. In contrast to neorealism however, institutions now matter and are not merely epiphenomena of balance of power struggles. Thus while neorealism has been generally dismissed with regards to the study of global environmental issues, institutionalist theories of IR have been a very important line of thought in not only understanding the importance of institutions, but also prescribing policy advice for international responses to environmental coordination problems and studying regime efficacy. The argument is put forward that we are not solely considering formal intergovernmental or cross national nongovernmental organisations in the traditional sense (bureaucratic organisations with explicit rules), but also regimes as “sets of implicit or explicit principles, norms, rules, and decision-making procedures around which actors’ expectations converge in a given area of international relations” (Krasner, 1983:2)8. Keohane (1989) makes a succinct synopsis of institutionalist thought by conceding to neorealists that the condition of anarchy still holds, but that institutionalists start from the premise that international agreements prevail and can have an effect on government behaviour. Crucially, Keohane posits the assumption that states are still acting within a Oran Young goes yet further in broadening the definition of institutions by stating that they are “social practices consisting of easily recognized roles coupled with clusters of rules or conventions governing relations between occupants of these roles” (Young, 1989:32). The delineation with constructivist thought becomes blurred if we consider the possibility that Young’s picture of international relations becomes one of states maximizing utility according to sets of rules. Outcomes then need to be analyzed purely in terms of the evolving norms and ideas that affect these rules. 8 12 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper rationalist framework, but to maximise absolute gains, not relative gains. This is indeed acknowledged by game-theorists to make cooperation more likely. In the context of global climate change, states are not concerned with military threats, solely absolute gains. To summarise, Keohane defines institutions as “persistent and connected sets of rules (formal or informal) that prescribe behavioural roles, constrain activity and shape expectations”. They can affect state behaviour by affecting the flow of information, creating an environment conducive to negotiation, having an ability to monitor compliance, make commitments credible and alter the perceptions of international agreements. With respect to global climate change, what was the role of institutions as organisations? The cognitive development and agenda setting for climate change can be traced back to the activities of the World Meteorological Organisation (WMO) and the United Nations Environment Program (UNEP). The WMO was primarily an arena for transnational scientific networks to pursue climate research, in existence for over a century. In addition to this function, the WMO can be credited for the implementation of continuous atmospheric CO2 measurements and the organisation of data that disproved theories of global cooling at the Norwich meeting of 1975, the same data that later came to underpin theories of global warming over the following 20 years. Andresen and Agrawala (2002) point to UNEP as not having the scientific ties that the WMO benefited from, but can be credited for “sharpening the policy relevance of climate research by focusing on societal impacts of climate variability”. The result of the Villach meeting where the WMO and the UNEP presented a five year assessment of climate change prompted the creation of the more politicised IPCC in 1987-8 and created a “machinery to set the ball rolling in the direction of coordinated international policy responses to climate change” (Andresen and Agrawala 2002: 43). It is clear that international organisations were central to altering 13 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper states perceptions of interest; that global warming was a political issue in need of an international response. This, as pointed out by Paterson (1996b), is not the same as suggesting state behaviour had been fundamentally changed, just that their information sets had been altered. The Toronto Conference of the Atmosphere in 1988, indirectly organised by the WMO, UNEP and a series of other groups, called for industrialised countries to cut their CO2 emissions by 20-percent relative to 1988 levels by 2005, a target “borrowed” from the ozone regime. As US State Department negotiator Daniel Reifsnyder noted, the idea of “targets and timetables captured and riveted the public’s imagination. It provided a simple litmus test of a country’s environmental commitment. It required no painstaking feasibility analysis. It was political genius” (quoted from Andresen and Agrawala 2001). International organisations had created a cognitive base, galvanised public opinion and begun the act of agenda setting before states had even begun to join the discussions and negotiate. From 1988 onwards, national governments took up the initiative of forging political consensus on the issue of global warming and the voice and influence of international organisations was somewhat lost. Negotiations nevertheless took place under the auspices of the UN, in a framework that states knew well and which facilitated and arguably accelerated the process of agreeing on a convention. Cooperation was not easy, but institutions created an environment that eased the process. As for institutions as norms and rules, a number of examples of unilateral policy action, starting with Norway in 1990 adopting a stabilisation target for CO2 emissions by the year 2000, then Germany, the Netherlands and Denmark adopting goals of CO2 reductions, begun to resonate through the international system. Differing interpretations exist for this, the most salient being that of Patterson (1996b: p128). In this analysis, he suggests states “were in a process of redefining” the purpose of policy action. Not a scientifically reasoned target of CO2 abatement, but the process of abatement as a collective good. There was 14 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper thus a dynamic of attempting to understand what “norms concerning global warming mean”. There was also a strong sense of states gaining an identity as good global citizens by pursuing emission reduction policies. Up till the formal interstate negotiations begun in 1991, it can thus be stated that norms and institutions played a part in influencing state behaviour and generating subsequent negotiations. From 1991 to the creation of Kyoto in 1997, institutions played a less substantial although by no means negligible role of streamlining negotiations by increasing the flow of information. I would also argue institutions had a looming presence over the negotiations, especially from the norms that had emerged from other successful institutions such as the ozone one, as an assurance that a framework for compliance was feasible. Can neoliberal institutionalism account for the US’s Houdiniesque escape from the Kyoto protocol process, despite the strong norms suggesting it should act multilaterally, and can it explain the apparently unforeseen survival of the protocol despite the loss of its most important member? To answer the first question, we should remind ourselves of Keohane’s (1989) assumption that states in an institutionalist paradigm act to maximise absolute gains. Given the dependency of the American economy on energy, the debated scientific basis for action, coupled with the balance of evidence suggesting that global warming may not have such a terrible impact on the US economy9, the decision may no longer seem so careless. In fact, the US policy has been one that ties in very well to institutionalist thinking, notably that it has adopted a “no-regrets position, whereby only action which has benefits for problems other than the greenhouse effect alone is considered” (Newell 2000). This is clearly compatible with Keohane’s assumption of rational behaviour aiming to maximise absolute gains. In fact, a more accurate description 9 The US is in the desirable position of being relatively immune to many of the potentially disastrous consequences of global warming. As an example, a study in Nature in1990 by Adams et al. suggests crop yields in the US may increase by 9% http://www.gcrio.org/USGCRP/sustain/wolfe.html 15 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper is that the US government was minimising costs, preferring to break norms of multilateralism and incite a potential international backlash than suffer the costs estimated at up to 2.5-percent of gross domestic product for reducing CO2 emissions within the Kyoto framework10 (and despite the existence of flexibility mechanisms). The second question as to why the Kyoto protocol is as resilient as an institution is also addressed in the neoliberal institutionalist model. Keohane and Nye (1977) suggest that the networks of organisation in a state of interdependence will be “difficult either to eradicate or drastically to rearrange”. Young corroborates this belief by stating that “existing regimes or institutional arrangements often prove highly resistant even to assaults spearheaded by one or more of the great powers”; The US is still a member of the climate convention and has not made any explicit efforts to undermine Kyoto other than by its lack of support. Besides, the international norms of environmental action and the loss of US ratification may improve the chances of cooperation, especially given the fact that Russia, should it ratify and in the absence of its American customer, will reduce the cost of meeting the Kyoto requirements for all by flooding the emissions market with so-called “hot-air”11. The punch of the climate change regime may be dented, but its survival potentially guaranteed until the next round of emissions reductions around 2010. Hence we can conclude that neoliberal institutionalism holds more explanatory power than neorealism in understanding and explaining the international reaction to climate change. Whilst the neorealist perspective struggled to accommodate the institution forming and 10 The loss in GDP, plus the funds used to purchase permits internationally, represents the total cost to the economy. Over the period 2008 to 2012, the annual average total cost ranges from $77 billion (1992 dollars) to $338 billion, depending on the level of carbon reductions and the recycling assumptions. This cost is relative to a total economy of $7 trillion in 1996, growing to about $9.5 trillion in 2010, and about $11 trillion in 2020 (1992 dollars). From Energy Information Administration study “Impacts of the Kyoto Protocol on U.S. Energy Markets and Economic Activity” 11 the cost of carbon permits is expected to be far lower than initially estimated in the absence of the US, allowing countries to cheaply “buy” themselves out of their commitments 16 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper strong level of cooperation that was apparent, it does offer an alternative if not incompatible answer to the US apparent unilateralism. Nevertheless, a number of objections can be levelled over the deceptive comprehensiveness of the neoliberalist model. The first of these is that there is no treatment of the influence of domestic politics and nonstate actors. The accusation of deficiency can equally be aimed at neorealism and I will argue that the two rationalist paradigms share these same weaknesses, but focus on neoliberalism for parsimonious reasons. Furthermore, there is a strong and generally accepted assumption, found in all the academic literature I have come across that I would like to address. Since climate change is a global phenomenon, it is commonly argued that the problem cannot be solved by one country alone; some form of international cooperation is essential. What of the possibility of countries acting individually to fight climate change, without coordinating their actions? What of the possibility that international cooperation may be at a level other than a systemic one? For example, a constructivist line of thought might propose the argument that international institutions have indeed promulgated norms and ideas of behavior with regard to climate action not only to states but to all levels of society. Similar to the idea that recycling household waste occurs at the household level and addresses the global problem of resource depletion, we can likewise argue that since households account for anything between 10 and 40-percent of a country’s CO2 emission12, a culture of energy saving would reduce emissions significantly without imposing any binding costs on the country. A number of countries already have implemented stringent domestic climate change policies, despite international efforts to spread the practice. The UK for example is phasing in a country wide carbon permit trading market that already includes 6,000 large companies and is well on its way to meeting its Kyoto target of reducing emissions by 8% by 2010 (the UK’s domestic policy is International Energy Agency paper (2000) “Co2 Emission Trends And Reduction Opportunities In Transport, Households And Commercial Sectors” by Lew Fulton, Fridtjof Unander, Lee Schipper and Carmen Difiglio 12 17 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper aiming for a 20% reduction); an impressive and by no means solitary effort to combat climate change at the domestic level. As a generalization, theorising about international environmental politics begins with an environmental threat framed as a collective action problem. Institutionalist theory and market failure literature then attempt to find the optimal cooperative or institutional mechanisms to overcome the problem, without referring to the viability of the political process underlying the arrangement. Putnam offers a convincing two-level metaphor to describe the relationship between domestic and international politics “At the national level, domestic groups pursue their interests by pressuring the government to adopt favourable policies, and politicians seek power by constructing coalitions among those groups. At the international level, national governments seek to maximise their own ability to satisfy domestic pressures while minimising the adverse consequences of foreign developments. Neither of the two games can be ignored by central decision-makers, so long as their countries remain independent, yet sovereign” (Putnam 1988, 434). Sprinz and Weiß (2001) point out with regard to the climate change regime and FCCC negotiations that countries may not be willing to enter into agreements (voluntary defection) or may be trapped in involuntary defection as domestic politics interfere with international aims. Negotiators thus have “double edged diplomacy” as they can play the domestic and international arenas off against one another and use these arenas to expand or reduce their “win sets”; the range of domestically feasible international agreements. This was particularly true of the climate change negotiations with the US sometimes accused of legitimising its demands by playing the domestic politics card. Later, despite the Clinton administration’s attempts to agree to the Kyoto protocol, the Byrd-Hagel Resolution was unanimously passed through the Senate in 1997. It called for the US to mandate new commitments for developing nations to limit or reduce GHG emissions, and not to accept a 18 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper protocol that would result in serious harm to the economy. It effectively reduced the US win-set to a negligible point, made it clear the Senate was unlikely to ratify Kyoto and coincided well with the subsequent US withdrawal from the protocol. The second element that falls outside the sphere neoliberal analysis of is that of non-state actors. It is clear that there was a strong presence of Non-Governmental Organisations (NGOs) throughout the climate change regime, but it is one thing to say they were there and another to suggest they matter in a world of sovereign states. An NGO generally refers to “any organisation that does not have a formal or legal status as a state or agent of a state, or as a constituent sub-unit of a state such as a province or municipality” (Raustiala 2001). Alongside NGOs, we must also concern ourselves with epistemic communities of scientific experts, a fundamental piece of the climate change regime. It is accepted that the main actors were environmental NGO are particularly influential, a statement supported by the evidence surrounding the issue of ozone depletion. Friends of the Earth and the Sierra Club started campaigns in the US that mobilised public opinion, lobbying international conferences that were being organised by epistemic communities, who themselves went on to directly influence government policy. For the climate change regime, non-state actors were the main agenda setters for five years up until the interstate negotiations begun in 1991, arguably creating the norms and diffusing the information within the regime structure and outside to the domestic environment. The former UN Secretary-General Boutros Boutros-Ghali commented to a gathering of NGOs in 1994 “I want you to consider this [the UN] your home. […] Non-governmental organisations are now considered full participants in international life”. And at the birthplace meeting of Kyoto in 1997, there were an astounding 4000 NGO delegates, 19 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper outnumbering the representatives of countries that were taking part. Answering the question as to whether non-state actors are capable of changing state behaviour, Keck and Sikkink (1998) demonstrate the efficacy of human rights activist networks in Argentina and Mexico, and extend their claims to the power of non-state actors as a whole. Nonstate actors, they argue, are capable of influencing state behaviour on a number of levels and do not just diffuse norms; they create them. Keck and Sikkink go as far as stating that “nonstate actors undermine absolute claims to sovereignty”. The conclusion that non-state actors have affected the outcomes of the climate change regime is reiterated by Raustiala (2001) and Newell (2000). To what extent do the phenomenon I have addressed above undermine the rationalist predictions advanced by neorealism and neoliberalism? Can we imagine a scenario whereby nonstate actors and other forces that transcend the traditional lines of state frontiers compel a country to act in ways that are disjointed from the state’s control and interests? I am ready to tentatively argue that the climate change institution, in the broad sense of the term, as well as general shifts in corporate perception towards satiating stakeholder value is already creating undercurrents that run counter to the policy directions of certain states. In particular, this paper contends that the US position of unilateralism is fragile, if not untenable. The three interrelated mechanisms that I identify as sources of these undercurrents are domestic politics, firms and the potential framework of Kyoto. At the domestic level, it is clear that until recently, the fuel and energy lobbies yielded a great deal of power. The largest was the Global Climate Coalition (GCC) which grouped many of the world’s largest corporations and a majority of US energy companies. The GCC launched a negative 20 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper advertising campaign in August 1997, just months before the Kyoto Conference, to prevent the US from endorsing any agreement on climate change. Since then, however, the GMC has lost it clout as a number of companies broke rank in quick succession (Ford, BP, Royal Dutch Shell, Dupont, GM, Texaco, Daimler Chrysler…). Also at the domestic level, US states are relatively free to pursue independent climate change policies13 and 19 states have developed “action plans” to combat GHG emissions14. Despite attempts to rule the effort unconstitutional, California has been leading the pack with regulations imposing a mandate for 10% of all light-duty vehicles offered for sale in 2003 to be zero-emission. A federal plan to report GHGs voluntarily at first will be made mandatory if less than 60% of emissions are unaccounted, and a number of bills are working their way through the senate calling for legislature that supports engagement in the international negotiations on climate change. At the firm level, many of the companies that walked out of the GMC are now part of an environmental lobby group called the Business Environmental Leadership Council and have launched aggressive corporate climate change strategies. BP Amoco, for example, plans to bring its carbon emissions to 10 percent below its 1990 level by 2010, exceeding the Kyoto goal of roughly 5 percent for industrial countries. Dupont has one of the most ambitious goals of any company, going far beyond that of Kyoto. It has already cut its 1990 greenhouse gas emissions by 45 percent and plans to reduce them by a total of 65 percent by 2010. On the supply side, BP Amoco and Shell are investing heavily in renewable sources of energy. BP Amoco is now a leading manufacturer of solar cells. Shell, already a major player in both wind and solar cells, is also investing heavily in hydrogen and will likely open the world’s first chain of hydrogen stations in Iceland. If these 13 See http://www.energy.ca.gov/global_climate_change/summary.html for a summary of domestic climate action plans 14 21 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper are not just attempts to clean tarnished corporate images, why have companies made such a striking volte-face? The norms of the climate change institution seem to have seeped through to the firm level and made companies aware of the new environment they are dealing with. Thus not only is climate change now an integral part of business risk, or even the largest part of risk for the insurance industry for example 15, but companies are beginning to recognize the inevitability of some form of extra carbon cost and a gradual shift to renewables and hydrogen. Furthermore, large multinationals are being held accountable to far more scrutiny by stakeholders and shareholders (customers, employees, activist groups and the public) alike. Being “green” doesn’t even have mean lower share value, as BP found to its great surprise that considerable net savings were made by cutting on carbon emissions. We have also witnessed a growing number of corporations adopting policies of self-regulation such as corporate codes of conduct, social and environmental standards, and auditing and monitoring systems: Almost half of the Fortune 500 are now compiling and issuing annual reports that describe not only their financial performance but also details about their environmental and social behaviour. Labelled "triple-bottom line reporting", this view rests on the belief that corporations owe stakeholders an annual accounting of their environmental and social performance. These emerging norms are even being legitimised by accounting firms that independently review these non-financial reports. The UN has launched the laughter, UN Global Compact, a framework to guide such efforts of corporate responsibility. Finally, a more subtle mechanism is emerging at the international level. The restrictions on CO2 emissions being imposed in Europe will affect multinationals operating there just as much as it will local companies. Far from losing a competitive edge as claimed by the anti- 15 Franklin Nutter, president of Reinsurance Association of America, draws a direct link "The scientific community's consensus is we're in a period of warming and weather variability. Climate change will affect property and human lives." 22 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper Kyoto lobbyists, US industry may lose business in Europe if it does not normalise and accept the changing European environment. Some firms are rising to the challenge and a carbon trading exchange is being launched in Chicago next year for voluntary trading of emissions to better understand the principle and come to grips with the emerging monitoring, verification, tracking and reporting requirements. Even more profound is the potential effect of the Kyoto flexibility mechanisms. At its most potent, carbon trading requirements could require that carbon emissions be accounted for along the whole chain of supply of a good or produce. A car being sold in London may one day have to account for all the carbon emissions that entered the fabrication process, with third party certification at each step of the way. This means the entire supply chain of companies needs to account for carbon emissions, a trend that upon reaching a certain critical mass, affected companies will inevitably force all companies that wish to trade in Europe, or with companies that trade in Europe, or even with the companies that trade with the companies that trade in Europe, to account for and manage their carbon emissions to remain competitive. Hence the assertion that there could be a “virtual” compliance to Kyoto; the flexibility mechanisms first proposed by US negotiators ironically being the key to making global climate change action a concerted worldwide effort. The process being so recent, there has been scant academic attention to this hypothesis, a great deal however being devoted to the rising concepts of global governance and the focus on “global civil society” and “reconfiguration of institutions that inform corporate practices” 16 (Wapner 2001). Keohane refers to global governance as the “analyses of how networks of states, intergovernmental organisations and nongovernmental actors are responding to environmental interdependence.” Wapner refers to the CERES principles, similar in nature to the global compact, that specify “a set of guidelines for corporate practices based on a code of conduct that would minimize corporate contributions to environmental degradation” 16 23 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper To conclude, I have posited the hypothesis that firms and domestic politics should be appended to this list and that there exist elements of global governance that operate through mechanisms that cannot be captured by traditional state centric theories of international relations. This does not necessarily invalidate the evidence exposed by our analysis of global climate change using neorealist and neoliberalist paradigms. The conclusions we gathered are still valuable, notably that institutions, regimes and state interests still have a part to play in such problems of global coordination. Our analysis did nevertheless pick up on some shortfalls, the worst being the implicit assumption that interstate cooperation is the only means to solve the collective problem of global warming. Rather, a strengthening web of interdependency, linking firms, individuals, nonstate actors, institutions and states, and governed by the norms and beliefs that these actors create and disseminate, is producing forms of cooperation that can no longer be limited to being strictly in the sphere of interstate relations. In the specific case of global climate change, this paper has made that argument that structural elements of the Kyoto protocol, coupled with changing corporate practices and domestic efforts to reduce carbon emissions, may furtively undermine and even nullify the US state’s policies. Therefore, the US Kyoto targets may yet be met, despite inaction and disinterest at the federal level: Kyoto will become a “virtual reality” in the US. Lastly, neorealism and institutionalism, due to their inability to see below the state level, will be unable to capture the intricacies of the mechanisms we have described above, but we cannot rule out the possibility that they will continue to offer valuable insights into the interstate coordination of the climate change problem. 24 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper Appendix I Climate change science A growing mass of scientific evidence has accumulated over the last decade or so pointing to a rise in the global surface temperature of the Earth. Whilst our planet does undergo periodic cycles of rising and falling temperature, cycles normally steered by natural events such as volcano activity, the current consensus is that current global warming is happening at a greater rate than ever before. If no action is taken, the Inter-Governmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) and the National Research Council (NRC) predict increases in temperature in the ranges of 1-3.5C and 1.5-6C by 2100. There are two questions that need to be answered. First, how is this increase in temperature likely to affect the planet, its ecosystems and its inhabitants? Second, is human activity to blame and, especially, which type of activity is to blame for the potentially rapid change in the surface temperature? The answer to the first question is simple: the effect of a large rise in temperature would be catastrophic. Depending on the magnitude and the rate of the rise, models predict very differing scenarios, notably when coupled to the fundamentally complex structure of temperature transfers between oceans and continents. For the environment, a rapid shifting of climatic zones towards the poles may destroy species that fail to keep up with their ecosystems and the consequences on agriculture could be considerable. For the climate, a damaging disequilibrium would hit convection patterns and cause more “freak” events, which many commentators declare are already happening. The most damming effect of rising temperatures though would undoubtedly be the rising sea level. The combination of the melting ice caps and the increase in the energy content of the water would swell the oceans significantly and submerge all low level land. The IPCC predicts a rise in the mean sea level of 15-95cm, without overtly massive polar meltdowns (see figure 1, from IPCC predictions). This is enough to engulf parts of countries like the Maldives, Bangladesh, even Europe for example and do some serious flooding damage. Is human activity to blame? Scientific consensus points to an overwhelming yes in that Greenhouse Gases (GHGS) released by human activity are to blame for the warming of the planet. The earth is like a greenhouse in that the atmosphere is transparent to visible radiation from the sun and is opaque to some of the reflected infrared radiation from the earth, thus “trapping” the incident energy from the sun and raising the average temperature (hypothetically -19C without this effect). Under normal circumstances, the earth releases heat at the same rate at which it absorbs energy from the sun. However, this balance is being destabilised by the steady release of GHGS from human economic activity. While some particulates released by economic activity contribute to a cooling of the atmosphere through cloud creation, carbon dioxide, CO2, chlorofluorocarbons (CFCs), methane (CH4) and nitrous dioxide (N2O) all increase the greenhouse effect. Furthermore, CFCs damage the ozone layer, thus allowing more damaging UV radiation through the 25 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper atmosphere. With industrialisation came the need to burn fossil fuels for production and transportation, increasing the concentration of CO2 in the atmosphere by over a third since 1800. Agriculture and other human activity has also contributed to the release of other GHGS, but CO2 remains the most important of these, contributing to an estimated 60% of all human induced greenhouse effects. The figure above (The Economist November 2000) shows the changes in CO2 concentration and temperature variations in a historical perspective. Clearly, the predictions of the IPCC and the NRG do not intuitively seem inappropriate when such evidence is brought to light. Yet actions to counter global warming are difficult because the mechanisms are so complicated. Unlike the hole in the ozone, which shows a clear relationship between man-made CFC emissions and a thinning ozone layer, the costs and benefits of curbing GHGS emissions is much less clear cut. For one, global warming has a strong lag and the effects must be decomposed between natural ones and human ones. Secondly and most importantly, even with the vast quantity of scientific evidence pointing to serious consequences if nothing is done about it, there is great uncertainty in the models used and the greenhouse effect will only be detected once it has happened. 26 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper Bibliography Andresen, S., Agrawala, S. (2002), “Leaders, Pushers and Laggards in the making of the climate regime”, Global Environmental Change, 12, 41-51 Bodansky, D. (1995), “The emerging Climate change regime. Annual review of Energy and Environment, 20, 425-461 Boehmer-Christiansen, S. (1996), “The international research enterprise and global environmental change: climate-change policy as a research process”. In J. Vogler and M. Imber (eds) The Environment and International Relations, pp. 59-77 Brenton, T. (1994) “The greening of Machiavelli: The Evolution of International Environmental Politics”, London: Earthscan Royal Institute of International Affairs. Jones, S. (2002), “Social Constructivism and the environment: through the quagmire”, Global Environmental Change, 12, 247-251 Kindleberger, C. (1973) “The world in depression”, Los Angeles: University of California Press Keck, M. and Sikkink, K. (1998), "Activists Beyond Borders: Adbocacy Networks in International Politics”, Ithaca: Cornell University Press Keohane, R. and Nye, J. (1977) “Power and Interdepence: World Politics in Transition”, Boston: Little Brown and Company Keohane, R. (1989), “Neoliberal institutionalism: A perspective of world politics” Krasner, S., (1983) “International regimes”, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press Liberatore, A. (1995) “The social construction of environmental problems” in “environmental policy in an international context” Luterbacher, U., Sprinz, D. (Ed.) (2001) “International relations and global climate change”, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press Mitchell, R. (1994) “Intentional oil pollution at sea : environmental policy and treaty compliance”, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press Mitchell, R. (1992) “From paper to practice: improving environmental treaty compliance”, Thesis (Ph.D.) Harvard U., Moravcsik, Andrew (1997), Taking preferences seriously: A liberal Theory of International Politics, International organisation, 51.4, 513-553 Morgenthau (1973) “Politics Among Nations: The struggle for power and peace” New York: Knopf Newell, P. (2000), “Climate For Change: Non-State Actors And The Global Politics Of The Greenhouse”, Cambridge ; New York: Cambridge University Press Nutter, Andrew (1998) “Considerations to guide the choice of regulation instruments to achieve reductions in the emission of greenhouse gases in the UK”, unpublished Paterson , M. (1996a) “IR theory: Neo-realism, neo-institutionalism and the Climate Convention”. In J. Vogler and M. Imber (eds) The Environment and International Relations, pp. 59-77 Paterson, M. (1996b), “Global Warming and Global Politics”, New York : Routledge, 1996 Putnam, Robert (1988), Diplomacy and Domestic politics. The logic of two-level games, International organisation, 43.4, 427-460 27 Andrew Nutter IPS 204: International Relations Final Paper Raustalia, K. (2001) “Nonstate Actors in the Global Climate Regime”, in “International relations and global climate change” by Luterbacher and Sprinz, pp95-118 Saurin, J. (1996) “International relations, social ecology and the globalisation of environmental change”. In J. Vogler and M. Imber (eds) The Environment and International Relations”, pp. 77-99 Sprinz, D and Weiß, M. (2001) “Domestic politics and Global Climate Policy” in Luterbacher, U., Sprinz, D. (eds) “International relations and global climate change”Vogler, J. and Imber, M. (Eds), (1996), “The environment and international relations”, London : New York : Routledge, 1996 Waltz, K. (1979) “Theory of International Politics”, Reading MAL Addison-Wesley Wapner, P. (1997) “Governance in global civil society” in Young (1997) Wettestad, J. (1999), “Designing effective environmental regimes : the key conditions”, Northampton, Mass. : Edward Elgar Wendt, A. (1992) "Anarchy is What States Make of It: The social construction of power politics" pp. 75-82 International Organisation 46: 391-425 Young, O. (1997), “Global Governance: Drawing insights from the environmental experience”, London, MIT Press Energy Information Administration “Impacts of the Kyoto protocol on U.S. Energy Markets and Economic Activity” 28