The Impact of Canada’s Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit in Ontario By Ben Segel-Brown A research report submitted in fulfillment of the requirements for PAPM4908 as credit towards the degree of Bachelor of Public Affairs and Policy Management [Honours] Arthur Kroeger College of Public Affairs Carleton University Ottawa, Ontario Abstract This paper looks at the impact of the recently introduced Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit on care givers in Ontario. It builds a micro-economic model of the decision to provide care at home or in an institution (nursing home) and analyses data from the General Social Survey, Cycle 16, 2002 [Canada]: Ageing and Social Support. It finds that the tax credit should create efficiency and equity gains, but it is unlikely to have a substantial impact given its small size. Its findings suggest that the Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit should be made refundable and substantially increased in size. Acknowledgements Firstly, I would like to thank my supervisor, Åke Blomqvist for his time, his guidance and his support for introducing me to research and writing in the field of health economics. I would also like to thank thoughtful reviewers of this document who provided valuable substantive feedback. I would also like to thank my parents for their ongoing encouragement and support. Table of Contents Introduction .............................................................................................................. 1 Exposition .................................................................................................................. 4 Literature Review ................................................................................................... 13 Theoretical Framework ......................................................................................... 18 Data Analysis........................................................................................................... 36 Conclusion ............................................................................................................... 54 Works Consulted .................................................................................................... 55 1 Introduction This report provides an economic analysis of the impacts of Canada’s Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit introduced by the Harper Government for the 2012 tax year, which reduces the taxes of those who provide care for a dependant elderly person in their home. This report focuses on three aspects of the impact of the credit: efficiency, equity, and effectiveness. This paper shows that the Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit could theoretically lead to efficiency gains (i.e., it could make families better off at lower cost), but is unlikely to be effective (i.e., its size is not substantial relative to the costs of longterm care). The data analysis suggests that the credit is regressive at lower incomes (i.e. below $15,000) but progressive beyond the point at which positive taxes are owed. The paper has four main sections: an exposition, a literature review, a theoretical model and a data analysis. Each of these sections contributes to an understanding of the efficiency, equity, and effectiveness of the tax credit. The potential efficiency gains associated with the credit are demonstrated through a graphical analysis of the theoretical model, which shows that the tax credit could reduce the market distortion created by government provision of institutional care, and therefore create efficient substitution of home care for institutional care. However, this report also shows that these efficiency gains may be partially off-set by the inefficiencies resulting from the federal subsidization of home care through the Medical Expenditures Tax Credit and provincial provision of home care. The equity impacts of the Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit are revealed though the exposition and data analysis. The exposition shows that the tax is regressive (i.e., it 2 provides greater tax relief to high income persons as a portion of their income) up until the point where positive taxes are paid, but is progressive beyond that point. Likewise, the data analysis suggests that there are substantially higher rates of care provision above the point at which positive taxes are owed compared with below it, but that beyond this point care provision declines with income. This indicates that the tax credit is regressive up until the point at which positive taxes (more precisely $300 in taxes) are owed as in this range higher income individuals receive larger tax credits and lower income individuals are less likely to be providing care. However, beyond that point the tax credit is progressive as the credit is an increasingly small amount of higher income families’ incomes and rates of care provision decline with income. Because those with dependant relatives have a greater need for income, it is debatable whether these higher income families with relatives to care for actually have a greater ability to pay taxes, so the tax credit, while regressive, may still be equitable. This paper also explores how effective the Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit is likely to be in achieving efficiency gains (i.e., substitution of home care for institutional care) and equity gains (i.e., addressing disparities in ability to pay taxes at a particular income level related to care responsibilities). The exposition shows that the value of the credit to the caregiver ($300 on top of an existing $660.30) is not substantial compared to the costs of providing care, so little gains in efficiency or equity are likely to be achieved. The literature review provides several measures of the benefits and costs of long-term care, including impact on family income, impact on quality of life, and willingness to pay. The impact of intensive personal care responsibilities (90+ minutes per day) on income and quality of life measures is modeled as part of the data analysis. It was hoped that this would 3 provide some indication of the magnitude of the burden of care, and consequently the degree to which the credit was compensating for that burden. However, the analysis shows intensive care givers find life only slightly more stressful, and being a care provider was not significantly related to life satisfaction, EI income, or health. The highest rates of care provision were in the personal income brackets slightly below the Canadian average, but it was not possible to determine to what degree this higher rate of care provision is a result of a lower opportunity cost of their time as opposed to lost income resulting from providing care. As a result no estimate of the financial burden of care in terms of lost income can be made. Rates of care provision did not change dramatically between middle and higher income respondents, see “Household Income Distribution and Profile of Care Providers” in Table 1G. These results did not provide a means of creating a reliable estimate of the size of the Tax Credit that would be needed to fully compensate intensive care givers for the burden of care, which would in turn provide an indication of the degree to which the credit is effective in compensating for that burden. The literature review also explores the substitutability of outside care, care by relatives and care in institutions, finding variable substitutability depending on medical condition. This is relevant because, regardless of value, the tax credit will only be effective in creating substitution of home care for institutional care if it is actually practical for families to do so. 4 Exposition Importance of Topic This research is timely because the Government of Ontario is facing a shortage of places in Long-Term Care homes and at the same time pressures to reduce its deficit. With an aging population and growing debt, both of these problems can be expected to worsen in the coming decades, with Statistics Canada projecting that the number of dependent seniors will triple over the next 50 years (Grignon & Bernier, 2012). A federal subsidy compensating care givers of the elderly may offer a solution to these problems by diverting demand away from publicly funded institutions (hospitals and nursing homes). Defining Long-Term Care Recipients By definition, those with long-term care needs require assistance with the instrumental or basic activities of living (Grignon & Bernier, 2012, p. 4). To illustrate, eating is a basic activity of living, and grocery shopping is an activity instrumental to eating. An elderly person who needs help eating or shopping would be considered to have a long-term care need. Long-term care is differentiated from acute or rehabilitation care in that it is expected that care will be required for an extended period of time, often the remainder of the patient’s life. This report distinguishes between long-term care in institutions (nursing homes) and home care that takes place in the caregiver or recipient’s home. Home care can be provided free of charge by friends and family, or by paid outsiders (Grignon & Bernier, 2012, p. 5). The focus in this paper is on care recipients with severe needs, such that they are eligible for care in an institution but could still be cared for in a caregiver’s home with assistance. The data analysis section of this paper focuses on those 5 providing intensive (90+ minutes per day) personal care (bathing, toileting, care of toenails/fingernails, brushing teeth, shampooing and hair care or dressing). The focus is on personal care activities because these were most closely associated with providing care in the home (as opposed to helping with shopping or to pay the bills) and the threshold of 90 minutes per day was chosen as an indicator of the level of need that would be needed to qualify for a space in a nursing home. This threshold was validated by comparing the portion of care providers above and below the intensity who believed the government would take over if they were unable to continue providing care; those providing more than 90 minutes of care per day were almost five times as likely to believe the government would take over if they were unable to continue providing care compared with those providing 30 to 89 minutes per day (Table 4b). Government Subsidies This section outlines the current system of subsidies and the new Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit, the incremental impact of which will be the focus of this report. The subsidy system described here is that of Ontario, Canada. Long-term care, both in institutions (nursing homes) and in home care, is a peculiar part of Canada’s health care system in that it is not covered by the Canada Health Act (Health Canada, 2004). As a result, it is not subject to the strict requirements of universal public coverage that apply to other aspects of health care, enabling funding mechanisms that include private financing. In Ontario, the provincial government funds long-term care and outsider home care, while the federal government provides tax credit for those who directly provide or pay for the care of an elderly dependant in their home and to offset the costs of home care. 6 In Ontario, the medical and personal services provided in institutions (long-term care/nursing homes) are fully funded by the Ontario government, which provides homes with $152.94 per day for each resident in their care, adjusted for the needs of the home’s resident mix. In addition there are a variety of funding envelopes for particular purposes such as for the payment of registered practical nurses. Accommodation and food charges for long-term care are $55.04 per day for a basic bed and more for private and semi-private rooms, but low income seniors who cannot afford this per diem can apply for a rate reduction that leaves them with a $132 per month comfort allowance (Ontario Ministry of Health and Long-Term Care, 2012). In order to enter a long-term care home, seniors must be assessed by Community Care Access Centres which will determine their eligibility and will place them on a waiting list (Ontario Ministry of Health and Long-Term Care, 2012). There are currently 19,000 eligible seniors in Ontario who are on the waiting list, so this waiting list is a substantial rationing mechanism (Ontario Association of Non-Profit Homes and Services for Seniors, 2013). This waitlist is likely inefficient as the per diem cost of care in a hospital bed for an Alternative Level of Care (ALC) patient, i.e., a patient in a hospital who could be cared for in a long-term care institution, is more than five times higher, at $842/day, and many persons on the waiting list end up as ALC patients in acutecare hospitals (Ontario Home Care Association, 2012). There are also a variety of services available to assist seniors in their home. In Ontario, these services are delivered by family and friends, volunteers, provider organizations, commercial retailers, and community centers. These care providers are funded by the government, donations to voluntary organizations, private insurance plans, or the individual (Ontario Ministry of Health and Long-Term Care, 2012). This report only 7 distinguishes between the two most common types of home care: paid outsider home care, and unpaid care by family members. A limited amount of outsider home care is publicly provided by the province. Medical expenditures for infirm dependants (including expenditures on home care services) are subsidised through a federal Medical Expense Tax Credit (Canada Revenue Agency, 2013). Family members who are providing care do not receive any subsidy except through the non-refundable tax credit discussed below, which does not depend on the hours of care provided. Between 66% and 84% of seniors primarily receive care informally from friends and family free of charge (Grignon & Bernier, 2012). For the 2012 tax year, the Harper government introduced a non-refundable Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit at the federal level. The impact of the introduction of this tax credit is the focus of this paper. A tax credit is an amount deducted from your taxes owing. Tax credits are multiplied by 15% (the lowest income bracket’s tax rate) and this is the amount deducted from taxes owing. A non-refundable tax credit is a tax credit for which you will not get a refund from the governement if your tax credits exceed your taxes owing (Canada Revenue Agency, 2013). The Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit is $2000 (a $300 reduction in taxes), on top of an existing ‘Amount for infirm dependants age 18 or older’ of $4,402 (a $660.30 reduction in taxes) for those who provide care for a low-income relative in their home due to a physical or mental condition (Intuit, 2013). Because the credit is for a fixed amount and is non-refundable, the tax is regressive up to the point 8 where the full value of the credit can be claimed and constant beyond that point as shown in Figure 1:1 Figure 1: Absolute Value of Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit The term “regressive tax credit” has rarely been used in economic literature. A regressive tax is one that takes a larger amount, as a percentage of total income, from lowincome people than from high-income people. This can occur at the individual level; for instance, a flat tax that took the same amount of money from all people would take a larger amount from the poor as a portion of their income. It can also occur due to aggregate patters of consumption where lower income people spend a larger portion of their income on a taxed good, such as cigarettes, than higher income individuals. In addition, a tax can be more or less regressive due to the behavior response to taxation, for instance cigarette taxes are slightly less regressive than they would otherwise be because the poor have a 1 Note that the value at which the Family Caregiver Amount Tax credit becomes useful depends on the other deductions and credits available, the threshold of $14,000 used here is the approximate sum of the personal amount and the existing tax credit for care givers. 9 more elastic demand for cigarettes – their consumption and therefore tax burden decrease more in response to an equal increase in tax (Remler, 2004). It follows that a regressive tax credit is one that reduces the taxes, as a percentage of total income, of higher income individuals more than that of lower income individuals. An example of this is the income tax deduction for federal taxes paid that exists in several US states, which greatly benefits the rich because they both have a larger deduction (because they pay federal taxes on a larger income at a higher rate) and get a larger reduction in taxes owing, as a result of a given deduction (because their remaining income is taxed at a higher rate) (Citizens for Tax Justice, 2009). Figure 2 shows that, as a portion of the income of a care provider, the tax credit is regressive up to the threshold at which positive taxes of $300 would otherwise be owed (around $16,000 with only the Basic Personal Amount and the existing Caregiver Amount). Whether the tax credit is considered progressive or regressive beyond this point depends on the point of comparison. The tax credit will always be worth more (as a percentage of income) to those with higher incomes than it is for those who do not owe positive taxes (for whom it was worth nothing), but its value as a percentage of income does substantially decline with increasing income meaning it is technically progressive in this range. Figure 2 does not capture the differential tax impacts arising from the higher rate of care provision of lower income individuals still owing positive taxes. Note also that, the value technically depends on the income of the higher wage earner in a family with pooled resource, but this does not greatly affect the conclusions here given the very strong relationship between personal and family income. 10 Figure 2: The value of the Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit as a Percentage of Personal Income. The non-refundable Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit introduced for the 2012 tax year is likely to have a negligible impact in terms of substitution between institutional and home care as a $2000 tax credit ($300 per year) is not a meaningful amount relative to the costs and burdens of providing long-term care. For example, the public subsidy for each nursing home patient is about $54,000 per year over and above the private cost of around $20,000 per year (Ontario Ministry of Health and Long-Term Care, 2012). Another problem is that the tax credit is non-refundable, meaning that it is only deducted from taxes owing and not reimbursed to low income individuals whose credits exceed their taxes owing. As a result it will only influence the decisions of individuals in families with an individual who currently pays positive taxes. Further, if the family does not pool resources, it is possible the care decision maker will not receive much benefit from the tax credit (for 11 instance if their spouse counts it against their taxes owing and keeps the savings in a private account spent for their own benefit). If the tax credit was made refundable, it would impose no additional burden on families to require the credit be claimed by the caregiver, ensuring it influences their decision. Research Question This report asks: Is the Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit efficient (in the sense of reducing costs to government while improving quality of care) equitable (in the sense of redistributing the tax burden away from those with less ability to pay) and effective (in the sense of creating substantial substitution from institutional to home care or compensating care givers for the burden of care)? This reflects my interpretation of the two potential microeconomic2 purposes of the tax credit, to relieve the burden on institutional care settings, and to help relieve the burden of care. This paper suggests that there are potential efficiency improvements associated with the tax credit and that it is progressive, although not necessarily inequitable. However, the small size of the credit means it is essentially meaningless in the scale of decisions involving care for the elderly. This section more explicitly defines efficiency, equity, and effectiveness. It also outlines the results I expected my analysis to produce, i.e., the initial hypotheses. Efficiency Proposition Efficiency improvements are a micro-economic concept that refers to a net utility gain, i.e., a situation where the benefits to all actors outweigh the costs of a policy option. 2 The credit was introduced as part of Canada’s Economic Action Plan suggesting it was intended to serve the macro-economic purpose of promoting growth, but this doesn’t make much sense given we are no longer in a recession. I also exclude rationales rooted in the potential political advantage to be gained. The assigning of the name ‘Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit’ to what is effectively an increase in the ‘Amount for infirm dependents age 18 or older’ was almost certainly done for the political reasons of being able to attract publicity and gain political advantage. 12 In this case, I expected to find that the elderly are happier and less expensive to care for when cared for in a relative’s home (as opposed to an institution), but the caregiver bears greater private costs when providing care in the home. Given the existing market distortions, including free rationed institutional care and limited public funding of outsider home care, this paper’s theoretical analysis (presented later) supports the claim that the tax credit could result in an efficiency improvement, although this benefit may be partially offset by the existence of inefficiency in the home care market. Equity Proposition I had also expected that the credit would be equitable in the sense of having desirable distributional consequences. By equity, I refer to vertical equity, a principle that requires that individuals with a less ability to bear the tax burden should pay less. I expected the Tax Credit to have desirable consequences in terms of vertical equity, as I expected the policy to reduce the tax burden on the poor, women, and families with dependent elderly persons. A tax credit that provides greater benefits to the poor promotes vertical equity in that it provides an additional means of reducing the tax burden on those with the least ability to pay. In addition, I expected the poor to be more likely to substitute (and therefore benefit) as a result of the credit, as fixed sums (like the tax credit) are more significant incentives for them due to the diminishing marginal utility of consumption. I also expected that the policy would benefit women, who are generally thought to be disproportionally care givers for the elderly and care recipients in the home. Finally, I expected that the credit would promote vertical equity in that it would redistribute the tax burden away from those families with an elderly relative to care for, and thus less ability to pay, to families with a 13 greater ability to pay. The data analysis presented later shows that the tax credit is progressive above $15,000 in personal income and would disproportionately benefit women who are 4.5 times as likely to provide care (Table 4b). The general proof of utility gains resulting from insurance against risk (here the risk of an elderly relative needing care) could be applied to show the value of equity gains. Effectiveness Proposition By effectiveness, I refer to the degree to which the Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit results in substitution leading to efficiency improvements or provides substantial compensation relative to the burden of care. With a value of $300, the Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit is insubstantial relative to the cost to government and burden on care givers associated with long-term care. This is discussed in the graphical analysis and data analysis presented later in this report. Literature Review There have been cost-benefit or cost-effectiveness analyses of various programs related to long-term care including: leave to provide care for dying relatives (Negera, 2009), treatment of traumatic brain injury (Faul, 2007) and neonatal intensive care for premature infants (Walker, 1984). However, as one meta-analysis of economic studies on long-term care put it, “Few studies attempt any evaluation and those that do use varied, inconsistent and controversial methodologies” (Smith and Wright, 1994). This may be a result of the improbability of any government deciding to eliminate long-term care, moral objections to the likely conclusion under existing methodologies that long-term care is not worthwhile, or the plethora of theoretical and practical challenges involved in performing such an analysis, which are outlined in detail in the literature. Because this paper must draw 14 on a variety of research areas to address the aspects of its cost-benefit analysis, this review offers a broad overview of existing literature. There have been some limited applications of contingent valuation to estimate the marginal costs and benefits of home and institutional care for care givers and patients. Contingent valuation assigns a value to a service by directly asking people, in a survey, how much they would be willing to pay (WTP) to receive or not to have to provide it. Several studies have found that contingent valuation can be effectively applied, but there is substantial variation between individuals and studies result in estimates of marginal cost (WTP) from £9.52 euros, about $12 US, to $10.54 US per hour (denBerg et al., 2005). Interestingly, this is slightly larger than the value of care to recipients. Another study put the marginal value at a less likely value of £0.38 or about $0.60 US per hour (Mentzakis, Ryan, & McNamee, 2011). . However, all these studies looked at the marginal impact of an increase or decrease in the number of hours of care provided, not the overall value of care. Further these studies do not capture the significant psychological cost to care givers or care recipients arising from their placement in a nursing home as opposed to receiving care at home (Abel, 1990). Other relevant empirical studies have taken approaches other than contingent valuation. For instance, Fevang et al. (2012) looked at labour force participation to show that, in the years prior to their parent’s death, children are less likely to be employed (all other things being equal), with employment at 0.5 to 1% lower among sons and 4% lower among daughters. Dunham and Dietz (2003) additionally showed that in many cases women change jobs in order to receive the flexibility they need to take care of aging 15 relatives, suggesting that providing care impacts both quantity and productivity of employment. In terms of the substitutability of care by family for paid home care or institutional care, the results are mixed, suggesting that the substitutability of care depends on the care recipient’s medical condition. Brach and Jette (1962) used multiple regression to identify the factors that lead individuals to enter long-term care and how differences between populations in home care and institutional care in terms of age, need for ambulatory aids, mental disorientation, and needs for assistance with the activities of daily living, may limit the substitutability of home care. Dunham and Dietz (2003) showed that informal care is an effective substitute for long-term care as long as the needs of the elderly are low and require unskilled care. Lee and Young-Sook (2012) confirmed this result finding high substitutability for diabetics and low substitutability for patients with high blood pressure and mental illness. This severity-dependant substitutability has been picked up in the theoretical models discussed below. Another approach to determining substitutability is to look at the skills required to perform the tasks currently being performed by paid outsiders. Unregistered workers, i.e., home care providers other than registered nurses, licensed practical nurses, or social workers, represented just over 75% of formal home care providers in 2001 (Grignon & Bernier, 2012). In a study in British Columbia, only 10% of outside home care providers were registered professionals (Grignon & Bernier, 2012). Consistent with this finding, 71.2% of care (by hour) funded by the government of Ontario was for personal support/homemaking, 24.8% for nursing and 3.9% for therapy providers (Ontario Home Care Association, 2012). This suggests that there is substantial substitutability of paid home 16 care for care by relatives because unregistered care providers do not have any specialized training and their work could be done by a physically able relative. Another approach to economic valuation is the discrete choice experiment methodology which imputes preferences by asking care providers and recipients to choose between two bundles of different types of care and money. Mentzakis et al. (2011) assessed care recipient and care provider preferences for combinations of different types of care and money. While formal care and informal care generally acted as substitutes, they found that formal care complements informal supervision, and argue this finding occurred because the close emotional relationship between care givers and receivers made it difficult for them to agree to substitute away from assisting with the activities of daily living. While complementary in terms of value, this suggests there is significant inefficiency associated with outsider home care in that it necessitates more supervisory work for family care givers, despite reducing other burdens. This finding of a complementary relationship might cause one to worry that removing the subsidy for home care (and thereby increasing its price) might decrease the amount of home care provided by family. However, this relationship only existed for supervision by family which does not directly contribute to care and not for other care activities like personal care by family. Thus, while supervision would be expected to decrease with an increase in the price of home care, there is no reason to believe this decreased supervision will negatively impact care recipients. Monetary incentives were also found to be significant for younger care givers, but not for older care givers. However, the external validity of these results is questionable as Mentzakis et al.’s estimates of the value of care, about $0.60 US per hour, seems implausibly low. It also relied on a small sample with a low response rate. 17 There have also been a variety of attempts to address theoretical challenges in valuing long-term care and family decision making. Kuhn and Nuscheler (2011) developed a model of health care with two levels of care (high need and low need) and two settings (home and institution). Institutional care provides better health care, which creates greater utility gain for high needs than for low needs patients, but those in institutional care suffered a fixed disutility. This model showed that those with more severe needs will selfselect to receive long-term care in institutions. Their model further incorporates information asymmetries to conclude that care in institutions will be overprovided due to its informational superiority, i.e., because the government can easily tell care recipients actually need care. Alternately, Pestieau and Sato (2008) assumed complete information and looked at efficiency in the context of mixing provision of formal and informal care with different levels of child income. Rodrigues and Schmidt (2010) complement these mathematical models with a broader explanation of the rationale for state intervention in long-term care. This result arises from their consideration of the value of insurance and the necessity of government intervention to make insurance work due to moral hazard and adverse selection. Similarly, Wan outlines considerations for the evaluation of long-term care programs. Another interesting body of economic research looks at the political economy of long-term care. This literature is useful because it takes a more comprehensive view of the costs and benefits of long-term care, including both financial and psychological burdens, as well as how they might be measured. Roeder and Nuscheler’s model shows that public spending on long-term care reduces need related income inequality. From an empirical public-economy angle, public polling shows that self-interest is a significant factor in 18 support for medical benefits for the elderly (Day, 1993), and that support is weakest in young adults with less contact with their grandparents (Silverstein and Parrott, 1997). Theoretical Framework Introduction This research is broadly built on the theoretical framework of micro-economics because of its primary concern with efficiency, equity and effectiveness -- key concepts which are used to evaluate policy options. This paper also draws on the framework of health economics by focusing on measures such as Quality Adjusted Life Years. More specifically, this paper builds on the theoretical model of Kuhn and Nuscheler (2011), whose two-setting model of home and institutional care showed that that those with more severe needs will self-select to receive institutional care, and institutional care will be overprovided relative to home care due to its informational superiority, i.e., the government can tell the person needs care and measure that it was delivered. Incorporating Interdependent Utilities This paper looks at a caregiver maximizing a weighted sum of the utilities of family members. This approach differs somewhat from the classical microeconomics assumption of an independent self-interested decision-maker. The main reason for this adaptation is that, in the context of long-term care decision-making, it is a central and common feature of the existing models discussed above that they include altruism whereby the utility of the caregiver is partially dependent on that of the care recipient. Recipients of long-term care, particularly those in nursing homes, may also lack the mental capacity to understand what is in their best interests due to dementias, so the legal power over their assets and in health 19 care decisions (Power of Attorney) is often granted to their caregiver (Ontario Ministry of the Attorney General, 2008). Economics provides a variety of concepts that could be used to describe this relationship. For example, the model could state that care for the elderly provides a positive caring externality to their care givers (i.e., there are benefits not captured in the market transaction between care supplier and care recipient), or one could define a utility function maximized by the care giver that includes the happiness of the care recipient. This second approach is adopted by Khun and Nusheler who assume a fully altruistic3 only-child acting as a decision maker for the care of a single parent. However, they give the function for the child’s decision in a more general form that allows for multiple levels of altruism: Child’s Utility = Comfort (Own Consumption) + Altruism * Parent’s Comfort (Care) This altruistic decision maker approach is functionally equivalent to treating the family as a rational decision making unit with pooled resources4, and consistent with this, the child and family are used interchangeably as the actor in narrative descriptions of decision making by Khun and Nusheler. Another equivalent concept that could be applied is that of agency, where care givers partially act as agents for their elderly relatives. This understanding would be consistent with the expectation that care givers will speak on behalf of their parent’s interests in relations with health providers (Power of Attorney for Personal Care) and over their assets (Continuing Power of Attorney For Property). However, the only ‘enforcement’ mechanisms present are internal and social pressures (or 3 In full altruism, equal weight is given to the happiness of the parent and child. Not all families will function in this way and this could impact the efficiency impacts of the tax credit. For instance if a wife provides care, but the tax credit is counted against her employed husband’s income (perhaps because she did not reach the income threshold at which positive taxes are owed and the credit would be valuable) and they do not share resources, her decision may be less influenced by the tax credit. 4 20 inheritances) and the idea of a care giver acting as an agent for a care recipient whose interests are in competition with their own self-interested desires is inconsistent with the focus of microeconomics on financial incentives. Model Focus This report’s model assumes a family with one employed potential care provider and one care recipient where resources are pooled and the recipient’s condition is severe enough that they are eligible for care in a nursing home, but manageable enough that they still could be cared for in the provider’s home. This is the basic unit required for the tax credit to be relevant. A care recipient with no potential providers cannot claim the tax credit, regardless of whether they are purchasing care in their home or receiving care in a nursing home. The care provider would likely have to be employed in order to reach the threshold at which positive taxes are owed and non-refundable tax credits become relevant.5 It does not particularly matter whether the care provider is a child or spouse, except that a spouse is less likely to be working and therefore less likely to reach the threshold at which non-refundable tax credits become relevant. The pooling of resources (i.e., pensions and benefits of the care recipient are controlled by the care provider) is significant because it simplifies the problem to a tradeoff of time and monetary resources between the direct benefits to the provider and care for the care recipient, which is critical in the graphical analysis below. It should be noted that the Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit does not benefit care recipients with no potential care providers who are willing to look after the care recipient in their home. Where the care recipient could get by on care in 5 Alternately, the care provider could have non-employment (interest and dividend income) or could have a spouse who was employed, but in the data analysis below most care givers have employment income. 21 their own home, but instead inefficiently substitutes care in a caregiver’s home to receive the tax credit, the credit likely creates an efficiency loss. Mathematical Theoretical Model The mathematical theoretical model presented here is intended to describe the major factors in a caregiver deciding how to care for a dependent care recipient who is eligible for institutional care. The care provider maximizes a family utility function (the maximum possible W value between equations 1a and 2a), a weighted (x) sum of the care recipient’s utility (UR) and the care providers’ self-interested utility (UP), subject to the time (TP) and budget (CP) constraints. In this basic form, the model describes the choice of care options for any period up to the death of the elderly relative. The care provider’s utility is a function of their leisure (LP) and consumption (CP).6 The care recipient’s utility is a constant (URI) in institutional care, otherwise it is a function of the number of hours of care provided at home by relatives (AP) and by paid home care providers (D).7 The time function (Equations 1b and 2b) represents that the care provider’s time (TP) must be allocated between hours of work (KP), hours of leisure (LP) and hours of care for the care recipient (AP). The budget function (Equations 1c and 2c) represents that the amount left for the care giver’s consumption is the care giver’s employment income plus the government benefits and pension income of the elderly relative (BR) and the care provider (BP), less the costs of care. Employment income is the product of the hours worked (KP) and the care giver’s wage net 6 Consumption and Leisure includes any altruistic value the care provider receives from spending time or money on activities with other family members such as children or grandchildren. Their utility is also dependent on the utility of their parent, but this altruism is separately captured in the weighing of the decision making criteria, the focus of this term is on their self-interested utility. 7 Although of some relevance, consumption of the parent is excluded here for the sake of simplicity, because the primary concern of the care provider is with their health, rather than happiness, and many receiving care may be physically or mentally incapable of making consumption decisions. 22 of tax (n). The financial costs of institutional care (I)8 may depend on the care recipient’s income (BR),9 while the cost of outside home care is the product of the hours worked by paid home care providers (D) and their hourly rate net of subsidy (r). Home Care Institutional Care WHome = x * UR(AP,D) + UP(LP, CP) (1a) WInstitution = x * URI + UP(LP, CP) (2a) TP = KP+LP+AP (1b) TP = KP+LP (2b) CP = KP*n + BR + BP – D*r (2b) CP= KP*n + BR + BP – I(BR) (2c) In practice, many elderly persons receive home care for some time before moving into institutional care. The model here is thus not static, but rather dynamic as UR(AP,P) and URI change over time as the care recipient’s health declines until they reach the point modeled by Kuhn and Nuscheler where the greater medical care available in institutions tilts the balance, such that the care provider decides to rely on institutional care. However, the same factors that make home care more or less desirable as a static choice are the same factors that will delay this decision as to when to turn to institutional care, so this static model is still useful for modeling this dynamic decision. First Order Conditions Focusing on the home care system of equations, the equations can be seen as having three choice variables, hours of care provided (AP), hours of leisure (LP), and the amount of paid care purchased (D). The objective function can be written as WHome = x * UR(AP,D) + UP[LP, (TP-AP-LP)*n + BR + BP – D*r] 8 9 For the details of the cost arrangements see page 6. This may include income other than government benefits such as dividends and interest of savings. 23 The first order conditions for this equation are: Equation F1 shows that the opportunity cost of leisure is the utility gain associated with consumption that could have been achieved by working at the wage rate for the same amount of time. The application of the equi-marginal principle suggests that at the margin (in the absence of market distortion), care givers value an hour of leisure at their wage rate. Equation F2 suggests that the opportunity of cost for an hour of care by relatives is equal at the margin to the utility gain associated with consumption that could have been achieved by an hour of work at the care givers’ wage rate. The application of the equimarginal principle suggests that (in the absence of market distortion) the weighted marginal value of care to the care provider (i.e., the utility they derive from it being provided to the care recipient) is equal to the care givers’ wage rate. Equation F3 indicates that the after-subsidy opportunity cost to the care provider of an hour of care by paid care providers is the utility gain associated with consumption that could have been achieved with the hourly cost of care. The application of the equi-marginal principle suggests that (in the absence of market distortion) the weighted value of care to 24 the elderly relative is equal at the margin to the value of the money spent for consumption of the care provider. The most significant equation for this report is equation F2 as it indicates the factors that will lead a care provider to choose to provide more care. Aside from emphasizing the importance of caring for elderly relatives, there is little the government can do to affect x, the weight put on the utility of the care recipient. Sociological solutions to effect x, for instance policies that promote workforce (and therefore caregiver) migration, promote physical separation which may weaken emotional bonds (Smith, 1998). Coercive solutions could also be used, such as legally compelling children to care for their parents as is the case in some US states, British Columbia, Nova Scotia, New Brunswick and Singapore (Martin, 2010). For example, in British Columbia under the 1922 Family Relations Act “A child is liable to maintain and support a parent having regard to the other responsibilities and liabilities and the reasonable needs of the child” (Spencer, 2011). When tempered by the needs of the child in this way, these liability laws essentially mandate a minimum value of x. Government might be able to affect δUR/δA, the productivity of care in providing utility for the care recipient, for instance, by training care providers. An increase in taxes would decrease the wage net of tax (n), but increase δUR/δC, the degree to which the care provider values their income. The impact on informal care provision of these competing substitution effects (work earns less) and income effects (money is valued more) is theoretically ambiguous. A per hour subsidy for care by relatives, or removal of the subsidy for care by outsiders, would most directly create substitution towards care provision by family members. 25 These first order conditions assume that there is an internal solution, i.e., that the optimal solution to the families’ maximization problem relies on home care, rather than institutional care. Assuming substitutability between home and institutional care, even if a tax credit does not replace the subsidy for care by outsiders, it would still increase the provision of care by families because it makes informal care more appealing relative to nursing home care. Because it would only have an income, rather than substitution effect for current care providers, a fixed-rate subsidy like the tax credit would likely not substantially affect the hours of care provided by family. Graphical Analysis One could simplify the model above to a trade-off in the allocation of time and money between activities that contribute directly to the utility of the care provider (aka. Full income, a function of consumption and leisure) and activities that contribute to the utility of the care recipient (a function of the number of hours of care by family and paid providers in home care or a low constant and a minimal cost for institutional care). When framed in this way, there is a downward sloping budget constraint showing the combinations of utilities that can be achieved with care in the home (paid or provided by family) and a point that represents the option of institutional care (which as a set price and a low constant for quality of care) as shown in (Figure 3): 26 Figure 3: Illustration showing a decision to place the care recipient in institutions in a trade-off between care giver utility and care recipient utility 27 This model does not produce any unambiguous results as to the impact of the tax credit except that it makes home care more appealing relative to nursing home care, potentially creating substitution as shown in Figure 4: 28 Figure 4: Illustration showing a decision to substitute home for institutional care as a result of the tax credit in a trade-off between care giver utility and care recipient utility In this possible outcome, the credit results in a decision to care for the elderly relative in the home (saving government money) and resulting in higher quality care, but less caregiver consumption/leisure. It can be shown that this represents an efficiency improvement over the same decision without a tax credit as shown in Figure 5: 29 Full Income or UP Potential Efficiency Gains with Tax Credit Institutional Care Public Cost Avoided Cost Institutional Care Private Cost Cost of Credit Indifference Curves Old, New Home Care Budget Constraint with Tax Credit UR (a function of care setting, paid hours, and family hours) Figure 5: Potential Efficiency Gains with Tax Credit With the indifference curves assumed above, the tax credit makes this family better off (allows them to achieve a higher indifference curve), while having a net negative cost (because the cost of the credit is less than the avoided cost of care). Because the families can be made better off at lower cost, there is a potential efficiency gain associated with the tax credit. However, it is worth noting that the current tax credit represents less than 2% of the person’s income, even at its peak (see data analysis below), so very few families are likely to be close enough to the margin for this result to occur. In addition, the cost of the credit to government (as they cannot perfectly distinguish between those who will and will not substitute) will exist for many families that are not close enough to the margin for it to make a difference. From an economic perspective, ineffective credits that do not shift the balance of a decision are a neutral transfer, their cost is exactly offset by the benefits to 30 families, exempting the economic cost (inefficiency) associated with raising tax revenue. The benefits received from families at the margin substituting would have to be weighed against the costs of raising tax revenue. An additional caution is that the gain from substitution may be partially offset by the inefficiency in the home care market due to distortion between care provided by family and paid help. Both subsidization and the public provision of a limited amount can be shown to be inefficient in some circumstances (As shown in Figures 6 through 8 below). Likewise, the incentive might primarily serve to reduce the waiting list, rather than reduce the number of people receiving institutional care, which is a worthwhile activity, but would not produce cost savings in the way shown above (except where care recipients moving to home care are waiting in hospitals). Figure 6: Illustration of how the home care mix might be affected the Medical Expenditure Tax Credit (a subsidy) 31 Figure 7: Illustration of the inefficiency resulting from the subsidy in Figure 6 Figure 8: Illustration of how the home care mix might be affected the limited provincial provision of care 32 If the budget constraint is shifted to the right (from original to new) because the government provides a fixed amount of care in the home (the publically provided amount), as a result (in this example) much more care is provided by family (from F1 to F2) and a little more paid care is provided (from P1 to P2), and the family is much better off (can reach a higher indifference curve). This situation might occur if the person only required a fixed amount of paid care (ie. Has a near vertical indifference curve). Figure 9: Illustration of the inefficiency resulting from the public provision in Figure 8 This diagram compares the result that can be achieved with some public care provision to that which could be achieved with a cash grant, the theoretically optimal option. It shows that where there is a corner solution (ie. the family chooses not to purchase any paid care beyond the care that the government provides), there is inefficiency (because 33 same indifference curve could have been achieved at lower cost to government). Therefore if paid care is partially publically provided there is an inefficient distortion of behavior. Extensions There are several extensions to this model that would significantly contribute to its realism but which are not applied here. If families are able to borrow or have savings to deplete then the budget function does not have to be balanced for a particular period, but rather over a lifecycle10 within the family (l). represents the discount rate for healthy life (near-term years being more valuable than further away years) and r is the interest rate. The discounted lifecycle utility and budget functions can be expressed as: Discounted lifecycle utility ∑( ( Lifecycle budget function )) ∑( ) ( ) Where for healthy years x = 0 as both parent and child act in their own interests as consumers. Another important extension that could be made is to consider the possibility of competing interests within the family. For instance, if a tax credit is claimed by the working spouse of the caregiver and the caregiver does not fully share in the benefits of that income, but they retain control over deciding whether to provide care or not, their care decision may be less impacted by the introduction of the tax credit. Alternately, if the elderly person does not delegate Power of Attorney to a caregiver and does not want to impose a burden on 10 I use life cycle instead of lifetime because in general one can assume that the amount borrowed to take care of one generation must be paid off by the time the next generation needs to be taken care of. 34 their caregiver, they may place insufficient weight on their own well-being and enter institutional care when it is inefficient to do so. Optimal Solutions The system that would be created by making this tax credit refundable given these assumptions would be equivalent to a cash grant to a rational and full altruistic caregiver. A cash subsidy that could be adjusted for health status and was the only form of subsidization for home care could theoretically lead to the optimal level of care provision. The optimal (efficiency maximizing) cash grant would create substitution in all situations where it is efficient to do so. If institutional care provided the same quality care at the same cost as home care for the same severity of care needs, this would suggest that the combined private cost of institutional care ($55.04/day or about $20,000/year) and private opportunity cost from not receiving the tax credit should equal the total cost of institutional care ($152.94 per resident public cost, plus the marginal envelope costs that could be avoided, plus $55.04/day private cost, for a total cost of about $75,000/year). This suggests that, if home and institutional care were equally cost effective, the tax credit should offer a $55,000 benefit to caregivers (the public share of the costs of institutional care). In fact, home care has been demonstrated to provide a higher quality of care at lower cost, so the efficient subsidy would be even higher. This finding exists across all levels of care including the highest (chronic) level of care and when including caregiver out-of-pocket expenses and caregiver time valued at market wage (Hollander, 2003). Although the tax credit would have to be adjusted for the severity of the care recipient’s condition, this suggests that the efficient level of tax credit for the average person currently in institutional care who is also facing the current out-of-pocket private cost would be in in 35 the order of $55,000. Theoretically, this would result in all care recipients with a potential care provider receiving care in the home at a substantially the same cost to the government (this cost reduction would likely occur in most individual cases as well as in aggregate as the current per bed subsidy is already adjusted for the severity of care needs). However, a $55,000 tax credit would be very difficult to implement, as among other issues it would create a very strong incentive for fraud through exaggerating the severity of the care recipient’s condition or failing to report their death as has occurred in Japan (BBC, 2010). This would not be the cost-minimizing solution to government if government in unable to distinguish those individuals who would substitute from those who will not. Furthermore, the incentive would be attractive to potential care providers at much lower subsidy levels; for most Canadians, a subsidy level of $55,000 would make it more lucrative to provide care in their home than to be in paid employment. It would also be difficult to prevent the inefficient substitution of care in the care giver’s home or live in care in the care recipient’s home and it would force government to face the costs of care for all care recipients. The market distortion between home care by outsiders and family could be eliminated by replacing the current home care subsidies with a larger refundable tax credit, as shown in Appendices 5b and 5d. The limited public provision is efficient in many cases, and could be made theoretically optimal by allowing the funds set aside for home care to be used to employ family members to provide home care. Without eliminating the home care subsidy resulting from the federal Medical Expenditures Tax Credit, a per hour subsidy for family care would be needed to correct the market distortion Appendix (5d), but such a 36 system would likely face administrative challenges as it would be difficult to audit reported hours of care provided by family members. Data Analysis This section assesses the equity implications of the distribution of benefits of the Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit with reference to empirical data. It also explores the impact of care on the care provider in an attempt to suggest the order of magnitude of the burden of care on the care provider. Data was not available to explore the benefits of care to recipients, for reasons discussed below. This section addresses three questions: 1. Who, statistically, will benefit from the tax credit? How are they different from the rest of the population? This question breaks down care providers by age, gender, marital status, children in the home, level of education, province of residence, whether they are employed, their employment schedule, and their family income. To put this profile in perspective, this section also compares rates of care provision across characteristics as show in the introduction to Appendix A. 2. What is the impact of care responsibilities on the provider’s quality of life (health, happiness, stress level) and income (employment, unemployment, job schedule and personal income)? 3. What factors predict whether somebody will be a care provider? This section builds a binary logistic regression model that shows the relationship between a set of independent predictors (age, sex, marital status, and personal income) and care provision. 37 Description of Data Set The General Social Survey, Cycle 16, 2002 [Canada]: Ageing and Social Support datasets is part of a series of surveys collected to “gather information on changes in the living conditions and well-being of Canadians over time and to provide data on specific social policy issues of current or emerging interest”. They are produced by Statistics Canada and collected using Computer Assisted Telephone Interviewing (Statistics Canada, 2005). This particular data set focused on aging and social support and sampled from all persons over 45 residing in Canada’s ten provinces excluding full-time residents of institutions. The sample was selected from people who responded to the 2001 Canadian Community Health Survey, which had drawn a national geographically-stratified sample. An approximately equal number of people from each 10 year age bracket were included in the sample. The total sample was 24,855 cases with a response rate of almost 84% (Statistics Canada, 2005). The dataset included many variables which I expected to influence or be influenced by whether or not someone is a caregiver, including demographics, family structure, participation in leisure activities, health-related quality of life, whether care providers had employment income and their income bracket. Because of the overall large sample and the stratification by age, there were a large number of elderly persons receiving care within the sample. However, because the survey excluded full-time residents of institutions of nursing homes, this data did not enable comparisons of outcomes between institutional and home care. Further, because of the particular questions asked, it was difficult to identify individuals who were not providing care but had a close relative who needed care. 38 A major limitation of the main dataset file was that it did not provide an indication of the intensity of care. To distinguish between the intensity and incidence of care, the main file was integrated with the General Social Survey Care Giving by Respondent (45-64) file, which asked for the number of minutes of personal care provided per day to each care recipient. For the purposes of this analysis, I distinguish between care givers with a moderate burden (30 to 89 minutes per day) and an intensive burden (90+ minutes per day) of personal care (bathing, toileting, care of toenails/fingernails, brushing teeth, shampooing and hair care or dressing). Where a respondent provided care to multiple people, the data for the respondents’ relationship with the care recipient for whom the most personal care was provided the data in the merged data set (while the credit can be claimed for multiple elderly dependents, there were too few such providers in my sample to draw significant results). Even the moderate criterion may be too strict as the total number of people in the population represented by the intensive (221,683) and moderate (58,886) care provision groups (obtained using the person weights provided by Statistics Canada) is still less than one would expect given the government’s estimate of the number of potential claimants (over 500,000 when including all infirm dependents) (Government of Canada, 2012). However, very few care givers (5.5%) providing care provided less than 30 minutes, so the results would not be substantially different with a different grouping and 30 minutes seem like a reasonable threshold that indicates the caregiver and recipient live in the same home, a requirement for receiving the tax credit. 39 Data Analysis Procedure Because the original data was stratified so as to produce approximately equal numbers of respondents in each age group and region, and in order to minimize nonresponse bias, in this analysis the data is weighted to be representative of the general population. For example, fewer men aged 45-54 (11% of those over 45) were sampled than exist in the general population (20% of those over 45, based on the census). To avoid the underrepresentation of these younger men, their results must be assigned greater weight in order for the sample to be representative of the population. The process used to establish weights (the number of people in the population represented by a person in the sample) are outlined in the User Guide. Statistics Canada states in the User Manual for the dataset that “The survey weights must be used when producing estimates or performing analyses in order to account as much as possible for the geographic over- or under-representation and for the over- or underrepresentation of age-sex groups in the unweighted file” (Statistics Canada, 2005). However, these weighted values inflate the significance of statistical tests. Following Statistics Canada’s directions, the weights used here are adjusted (specifically, divided by the mean weight), such that the sample size does not change with weighting and statistical tests are not inflated. This paper uses these adjusted weights to compensate for under representation of certain groups without inflating the significance of statistical tests. The statistical profile of care givers (Question 1) is presented in a series of crosstabulations (Annex 1A-J). The table can be read horizontally to state the rate of care provision within a particular group or vertically to state the proportion of care providers who belong to a particular group. Beneath each cross tabulation table, the Chi-Square Test is presented. The significance of the Chi-Squared value is the probability that the observed 40 result would have occurred if there was in fact no difference between cases in care provision. Where the Chi-squared value is less than .001, there is a less than 0.1% chance the result would have occurred based on chance alone and we can conclude that there is a relationship between the categories and care provision. To identify the impacts of being a caregiver (Question 2), I compare the frequency of care provision across the various categories of the variables that the literature suggests would provide measures of the impact of the care burden, namely life stress, life satisfaction, health utility, whether they are receiving EI, their job schedule, and their personal income. There is no clear directionality of the causal relationship of any of these variables, for instance, a caregiver might provide care because they are unemployed or not provide care because their health (measured in the health utility) prevents them from doing so. Likewise, the literature and survey results suggest care providers might quit their job and suffer a decline in health as a result of the care burden. As before, Chi-Squared tests are used to compare provision between groups, with the addition of an independent means ttest for the health utility index, which is continuous. Instead of comparing those who provided care to those who did not, it is useful for the purposes of moving towards isolating the impact of the burden of care to compare those who provided care compared to those who had an elderly relative who would have benefited from care, but did not provide care to them. Running the analysis only for these cases would greatly improve internal validity, our ability to attribute the change in the dependent variable (ex. Income) to a change in an independent variable (in this case taking on the burden of care). Unfortunately, a major limitation of this data is that it does not distinguish between those who do and do not have an elderly relative who needs care, 41 making it difficult to attribute differences to care responsibilities, as opposed to merely the impact of having a relative who needs care. Future studies should include these questions to allow comparisons of those who do and do not opt to provide care. To build a comprehensive model predicting whether somebody will provide care based on their demographics (Question 3), I use binary logistic regression. Binary logistic regression builds a model that predicts which of two categories a person is likely to belong to given certain other information (Field, 2009). In this case, a variety of categorical variables representing the demographic features, such as employment income, are used to predict whether or not someone is a caregiver. Fewer variables are included here because logistic regression requires that predictors not be too highly correlated. The model was highly significant, with a less than 0.1% chance the observed results would have occurred in the absence of any relationship between the predictors and care provision. All predictors were significant at the .05 level using the significance of the Wald values based on the standard errors. This means that there is a less than 0.5% chance that the observed results would occur due to chance alone if there was no relationship between the predictor and care provision. Statistical Profile and Distinguishing Characteristics of Care Providers This section outlines some of the major characteristics of informal care givers to provide a picture of who, statistically, will benefit from the program. Care provision peaks in the 50 to 54 age range with 1.1% of people in this group providing moderate care and 3.5% providing intense care (Table 1A). Age is a statistically significant (p=0.001) predictor of care provision. This relationship likely occurs because 42 those over 55 are more likely to be physically incapable of providing care or their parents may have already passed away. Women were substantially more likely to provide care at both the moderate (1.3% provided compared with 0.3% of men) and high levels (4.8% provided compared with 1.1% of men) and just over 80% of both types of care providers were women (Table 1B). This difference in rates of care provision among caregivers aged 45 to 64 is highly significant (p<0.001). This confirms the equity hypothesis that the tax credit would help compensate women for their disproportionate burden of care and thus promote horizontal equity by moving towards an equalization of the social burden for care across genders. While most care providers aged 45 to 64 are married (66.3%), the highest rates of care provision are actually in the widowed, divorced, and separated group (Table 1C). The differences in rates of care provision by marital status are highly significant (p<.001). The higher rate of care provision among the widowed, divorced, and separated group may be explained by its association with being female (73.2% of this group is female). While the focus of this paper on the impact of the federal tax credit in Ontario, I also looked at the profile and distribution of care responsibilities by province as this provides some indication of how other policy options may affect care provision. Most care providers aged 45 to 64 lived in Ontario in Quebec, but the highest rates of intense care provision were found in New Brunswick (4.7%), Nova Scotia (4.9%), and Newfoundland and Labrador (4.5%), while the lowest rates were in Quebec (2.2%) and Alberta (2.8%)(Table 1D). These differences by province are highly significant (p<0.001). The lower rate of care provision in Quebec may reflect the greater availability of paid and public care in Quebec. The contrast between the Maritime Provinces and Alberta may 43 reflect their demographic structure or the greater tendency to provide care where the family lives in close geographic proximity, as discussed in the section above. Most care givers 45 to 64 (75-80%) are employed (Table 1E). There is no difference in provision of moderate care between those with and without employment income, but the employed were more likely to provide intensive care (3.3% provided care compared with 2.2% of those without employment income). This result is statistically significant (p<.01). This result likely reflects a mix of the association of unemployment with older age and therefore decreased physical ability to provide care and the need for employment income to offset the costs of providing care. There was a highly significant (p<.001) relationship between the respondent’s highest level of education and the rates of care provision among those aged 45 to 64 (Table 1F). Most care providers had either a college diploma/certificate (39.1%) or a university degree (20.9%). Those with only a college diploma had the highest rate of care provision (4.5%) followed by those with some university or college (3.0%) and those with a university degree (2.9%). The peak at a college level of education likely reflects competing effects of the higher opportunity costs of time associated with higher levels of education and the need for a sufficient income to be able to bear the burden of care – a similar peaked relationship is found between care and personal income (below). The very low rate of care provision among those without their high school diploma (1.8%) can likely be explained by its association with older age. Canadian born respondents aged 45 to 64 were substantially more likely to be providing both moderate (0.9% provided compared with 0.3% among immigrants) and intensive care (3.1% provided compared with 2.7% among immigrants) (Table 1G). This 44 result is statistically significant (p<.001), and may be a result of the geographical separation of first-generation immigrants and their parents. Greater frequency of religious attendance and having three generations living in the same home11 were slightly associated with greater care provision, but these effects were not significant (P>.1). The largest chunk of care providers aged 45 to 64 were providing care to their mother (35.2%), a much larger group than those providing care to their father (11.5%) or spouse (1.8%) (Table 5). A similar relationship existed with in laws where 4.5% were providing care to their mother in law while only 2.2% were providing care to their fatherin-law. These results support the equity claim that the benefits of care go disproportionately to women. The lower rate of care provision for spouse is likely a function of the requirement the care recipient be over 65 or over and care provider under 65 and few couples would fall in this range. This is much less of an issue for the other relationships shown. Impact of Care Responsibilities Measurement Challenges The literature gives examples of several strategies for valuing the benefits and costs of a health policy option (for example, see Mentzakis et al, 2011). This section explains and outlines the issues and limitations associated with the four dominant approaches: Increased Productivity, Quality Adjusted Life Years, market value, and contingent valuation. 11 The challenge with this indicator is that many families span three generation regardless of needs as a result of cultural norms and many care providers’ children will have already left home. The difference was between 2.7% of three generation families providing care compared with 2.0% of non-providers. 45 Increased Productivity/Opportunity Cost Method Cost-benefit analysis attempts to value health outcomes in monetary terms. An early approach was to value health improvements based on the increase in the patient’s productivity, as measured by their wage rate, as a result of the medical intervention. However, this measurement is not feasible for those receiving long-term care, as they do not have a wage rate. However, the logic of valuing costs and benefits by the gain or loss of productive time valued at the affected persons’ wage rate has been extended to care givers. This logic would suggest that the cost of care givers’ time should be valued at their market wage. For instance, if the burden of care means a care provider earning $50,000 per year is unable to work, the cost of care could be valued at its opportunity cost (the cost of the next best use of the time), which would be the $50,000 in lost income. Some shortcoming of this strategy are that it does not include satisfaction the caregiver receives from providing care (the value of which should be subtracted from the cost of time), nor the physical and mental health consequences of the burden of care (the value of which should be added to the cost of time). To include this measure, I compare the family incomes of those providing intensive care to those not providing care (Table 2D). The results were non-significant but suggest those incidence of providing care increased with income up to about $50,000/year (just below the average Canadian household income at the time of $68,500/year). In line with this finding, care providers also were more likely to be employed and less likely to be receiving employment insurance. 46 Quality Adjusted Life Years Cost-utility analysis is commonly applied to the evaluation of health programs. Using this method, the benefits of a program are measured in Quality-Adjusted Life-Years, a measure that considers both the increased length of life and increased quality of life for the patient associated with a medical intervention. However, because there is no compassionate/ethical alternative treatment option to long-term care, one could not ethically construct an experimental design to evaluate the benefits associated with various care options. While estimates have been made of the Quality of Life Adjustment for those in home care and in institutions, little can be inferred from the much greater quality of life of those at home (HUI = 0.797) compared with those in institutions (HUI = 0.120) because those with more severe conditions will be admitted and self-select to receive institutional care (Jones & Feeny, 2007). The Health Utility Index (HUI) captures changes in health status, such as depression, resulting from care responsibilities. The difficulty in attributing changes in HUI to care setting is compounded by the measures of the index which relies primarily on physical conditions in estimating quality of life. While it cannot ethically be applied to care recipients, the literature indicates that care responsibilities have an impact on the health of care providers (Mentzakis et al., 2011). This suggests there may be a role for Quality Adjusted Life Years as a measure of the costs of home care to the care provider. To include this measure, I compare the HUI, general life satisfaction, and level of stress between care providers and non-care providers. 47 Willingness to Pay/Willingness to Accept Two approaches are possible to estimate the value of the benefits of a program in terms of the patient’s willingness to pay for those benefits. First, a patient’s willingness to pay for a treatment can be inferred based on people’s actual choices, where the value of that good is reflected in a market price. One reference point for judging people’s willingness to pay based on actual behavior is the market for unsubsidized nursing care. If people purchase this care, it can be inferred that the market price is less than the value they place at the margin on receiving care. An alternate method for valuing benefits in cost-benefit analysis is contingent valuation, whereby patients and their families would be directly asked how they would behave in hypothetical situations. However, those in long-term care may lack the mental competency to be able to complete a contingent valuation questionnaire. This method also does not resolve the inconsistency between the impact of income on people’s willingness to pay and the principle that the allocation of heath resources should not depend on people’s incomes. The effect of income can be mitigated by asking how much they would be willing to accept to stay out of institutional care, rather than what they would be willing to pay to receive it. The data set did not provide any means of estimating willingness to pay but estimates were already discussed in the literature review section above. 48 Analysis This section explores the possible impacts of care responsibilities on the quality of life of the care provider. The majority (51.3%) of intensive care providers aged 45 to 64 find their life somewhat stressful (Table 2A). There are significantly (p<.01) higher rates of intensive care provision among those who found life somewhat stressful (3.4% in group provided) or very stressful (3.2% in group provided). This likely reflects a combination of the stress associated with having someone you care for unwell and the added stress resulting from care responsibilities. These differences are not enormously different from the popular average rate of provision of 3.1%. There was no significant relationship between life satisfaction and whether or not a respondent provided care (p>.1) (Table 2B). Together, these indicators do not suggest a clear utility burden on care providers resulting from their responsibilities, possibly because those who are socially integrated are more likely both to provide care and have lower baseline levels of stress and higher life satisfaction that could obfuscate the impact of care responsibilities. There was a weak relationship between personal income and care provision (p<.05) (Table 2C) with the highest rate of care provision (1.1% providing moderate and 3.7% providing intensive care) in the $15,000 to $29,999 wage range (below the Canadian average of 34,200 at the time of the survey). This suggests that the tax may be slightly progressive as a function of aggregate patterns of behavior, i.e., those with below average incomes are more likely to provide care, so the tax provides slightly greater benefits to the those with lower personal incomes. This relationship may exist because those with lower incomes have lower opportunity costs when providing care (as outlined in the model 49 above). However, there was no significant relationship between family (household) income and care provision (p>.1) so with the assumption of pooled resources this contradicts the proposition that families with lower abilities to pay would be more likely to claim the credit (Table 2D). Oddly, there was no significant difference in care provision between those receiving and not receiving employment insurance, despite the existence of Employment Insurance Compassionate Care Benefits, which should theoretically provide short-term relief to care givers unable to work due to their care burden at the end of the recipient’s life (Government of Canada, 2013) (Table 2E). Perhaps respondents did not regard these benefits as employment insurance income or the period of time for which it can be claimed had expired. The difference in health utilities between care providers and non-providers in the subsample is statistically insignificant (p>.05) although clinically meaningful (.008>.005) (Table 2F) (Jones & Feeny, 2007). Surprisingly, the health utility of intensive care providers is actually higher than that of non-providers. While this result can partially be explained by the greater ability of the healthy to provide care and as a statistical fluke, the absence of any significant or even negative relationship here has real world significance in that it implies that care responsibilities may not substantially impact the health of providers, and certainly does not provide a means of quantifying the burden of care. It is difficult to assign monetary values to the changes in life stress and satisfaction. This would be valuable because it would make it possible to estimate the change in income (created through the tax credit) that would leave the respondent just as well off, and determine the degree to which the credit is effective in compensating for that burden. Unfortunately, while greater care was associated with higher stress, so was higher (or very 50 low) income, so it we were to determine the change in income that would create a equivalent variation in stress (as a measure of well-being) the answer would be nonsensical negative, i.e., it would suggest care providers be hugely taxed to reduce their stress. Life satisfaction was negligibly lower for intensive care providers and slightly higher for moderate providers. As a rough estimate of the change in income that would create an equivalent variation in overall well-being, the .02 difference is about 26% of the difference between the$15,000 to $30,000 brackets overall well-being and that of the $30,000 to $50,000 well-being bracket. 26% of the difference in the middle values of these brackets is about $4,500. However, it would be problematic to look only at this indicator when the difference between means was not statistically significant and life stress as a measure of well-being would have provided such a different answer. Total household income (grouped) How stressful is life:12 Overall life satisfaction13 No income or loss Less than $15,000 $15,000 to $29,999 $30,000 to $49,999 $50,000 to $79,999 $80,000 or more Total 2.14 2.51 2.70 2.61 2.49 2.35 2.52 2.27 1.99 1.82 1.75 1.71 1.60 1.74 Intensity of Care Not a care provider 30 to 89 minutes per day 90 minutes or more per day Total 12 13 Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean How stressful is life Overall life satisfaction 2.55 1.75 2.27 1.67 2.30 1.77 2.54 1.75 Means of rating on a four point scale where lower values indicate higher stress Means of rating on a four point scale where lower values indicate higher satisfaction 51 An important guide to interpreting these results on the impact of care is the perception of care providers as to the impact of care responsibilities on their lives (Table 4a). For intensive personal care providers, the most common impact was that they had extra expenses (58.1%), changed their social life (54.9%), changed holiday plans (40.5%), suffered declines in health (30.7%), changed sleep patterns (29.9%), changed work patterns (28.9%), or reduced their hours of work (22.9%). Only 17.9% reported a reduction in income, which while significant suggests that the primary impact of care responsibilities is through additional expenditures and impacts on health and well-being rather than lost income. Future studies should inquire to the size of the additional expenditures necessary to provide care. Logistic Regression Model The purpose of the logistic regression model (Appendix 3) is to draw together demographic and income factors and show how they relate to intensive (90+ minutes /day) personal care provision among those aged 45 to 64, how strongly they are related, and the significance of this relationship. Specifically, the model includes age, gender, marital status, and personal income. Related measures, such as whether the person was employed, had to be excluded because the model’s statistical techniques assumes independence of predictors. The full model in included as Appendix 3. The overall model was highly significant based on the Chi-squared test (Chisquared = 196.788) which had a probability of less than 0.1% (p<0.001) of occurring if the null hypothesis was true, i.e., there was an effect of all the individual variables taken together on the dependent variable (Institute for Digital Research and Education, 2013). All 52 predictors were significant at the .05 level, i.e., there is a less than 5% chance that the observed difference would have occurred in the absence of a relationship between the predictor and care provision. A logistic regression model expresses the change in probability relative to a reference population, arbitrarily chosen here to be aged 45 to 54, male, living common law, and having a net income of zero or a loss. The odds ratio expresses the change in probability associated with a criterion being true, rather than belonging to the reference population. For example, the odds ratio associated with being female is 4.502 meaning that (all other factors being equal) women are 4.5 times as likely to be providing intensive care compared to men. Odds ratios greater than 1 indicate a higher probability of providing care than the reference population, while ratios less than 1 indicate a lower probability than the reference population. Criteria Age 45 to 5414 Age 55 to 64 Male15 Female Living common-law Married Widowed/Divorced/Separated Single (Never married) No personal income Personal Income Less than $15,000 Personal Income $15,000 to $29,999 Personal Income $30,000 to $49,999 Personal Income $50,000 to $79,999 Personal Income $80,000 or more 14 Significance of Predictor .027 .027 .000 .000 .024 .018 .012 .003 .046 .029 .004 .004 .002 .041 Odds Ratio Reference .782 Reference 4.502 Reference 1.922 2.074 2.568 Reference 1.697 2.000 1.968 2.186 1.862 This does not appear in the model output, it’s statistical significance is that of its binary opposite, belonging to the 55 to 64 age group. 15 This does not appear in the model output, it is only implied as the opposite of female. 53 The effects found here are not all consistent with those discussed in the statistical profile above because in the regression all variables are forced into the model at the same time so, for instance, the higher rates of care provision in the 55 to 64 age group seen in the cross tabulations might be explained by the greater number of women in the age group, and when the model controls for gender the effect could be reversed, as was the case here. Some changes in effect may also be due to random error, for instance it would be problematic to read too much into the double peaked rates of care provision by personal income; the difference between the $15,000 to $30,000 bracket and $30,000 to $50,000 bracket is negligible. Overall, care provision was now significantly (p<.05) higher in the younger 45 to 54 age group, meaning that when controlling for the other variables, belonging to the younger age group actually increased ones odds of providing care. Gender remained a highly significant predictor (p<.001) and the strongest one, with women being 4.5 times as likely to be providing intensive care compared to men. Whereas previously the highest rates of care provision were among the widowed, divorced and separated, the highest rate when controlling for other variables is among the single, suggesting that the greater number of widowed women may have been responsible for the higher rate of care provision in that group. All marital statuses were significant predictors (p<.05). Personal income was also a significant predictor (p<.05) of whether or not a respondent provided intensive care, with those in the middle income brackets ($15,000 to $80,000) being around twice as likely to provide care as those with no income or a loss, and having substantially higher rates of care provision than the $0 to $15,000 and over $80,000 brackets. This relationship between income and care provision suggests that those with incomes under $15,000 have difficulty 54 bearing the burden of care. The lower rate of care provision in the highest $80,000 and over bracket might be explained by the ability of these higher income respondents to afford private institutional care and home care workers and thus alleviate the personal burden of care. Conclusion This report provided an economic analysis of the impacts of the Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit on the care decision of care givers for elderly persons with severe longterm care needs. It focuses on three aspects of the impacts of the credit: efficiency, equity and effectiveness. This paper shows that the Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit could theoretically lead to efficiency gains (i.e., it could make families better off at lower cost), but is unlikely to be effective (i.e., its size is not substantial relative to the costs of longterm care). The data analysis here suggests that the credit is progressive (i.e., it provides greater benefits to those with lower incomes) above the personal income point at which $300 in taxes are owed but fairly neutral with respect to family income. The findings of this paper suggest that the Family Caregiver Amount Tax Credit has a design that should lead to efficiency and equity improvements. To maximize its equitability and efficiency, the credit should be made refundable and claimable only by the care provider. To be effective in actually creating improvements in efficiency and equity, the credit would need to be radically increased in size. 55 Works Consulted Data Source Statistics Canada. General Social Survey, Cycle 16, 2002 [Canada]: Ageing and Social Support, Main file [public use microdata file]. Ottawa, Ontario: Statistics Canada [producer and distributor]. Ottawa, Ontario: Data Liberation Initiative [distributor]. —. General Social Survey, Cycle 16, 2002 [Canada]: Ageing and Social Support, Care Giving by Respondent (45-64) [public use microdata file]. Ottawa, Ontario: Statistics Canada [producer and distributor]. Ottawa, Ontario: Data Liberation Initiative [distributor]. Academic Articles Abel, Emily K. “Informal care for the Disabled Elderly: A Critique of Recent Literature.” Research on Aging 12 no. 2. June 1990. http://journals2.scholarsportal.info.proxy.library.carleton.ca/tmp/970452500546290 9681.pdf [11 December 2012]. Blomqvist, Åke, and Colin Busby. "Long-Term Care for the Elderly: Challenges and Policy Options." C.D. Howe Institute Website. November 2012. http://www.cdhowe.org/pdf/Commentary_367.pdf [10 April 2013]. Branch, Laurence G. and Allan M. Jette. “A Prospective Study of Long-Term Care Institutionalization among the Aged.” American Journal of Public Health 72 no. 12. December 1962. http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC1650559/pdf/amjph00659-0063.pdf [11 December 2012]. Day, Christine. “Public Opinion Toward Costs and Benefits of Social Security and Medicare.” Research on Aging 15 no. 3. September 1993. http://journals2.scholarsportal.info.proxy.library.carleton.ca/details.xqy?uri=/01640 275/v15i0003/279_potcabossam.xml [11 December 2012]. denBerg, Bernard van et al. “Economic valuation of informal care: the contingent valuation method applied to informal caregiving.” Health Economics 14 no. 2. February 2005. http://journals1.scholarsportal.info.proxy.library.carleton.ca/details.xqy?uri=/10579 230/v14i0002/169_evoictvmatic.xml [11 December 2012]. 56 Dunham, Charlotte Chorn and Bernadette E. Dietz Bonsang. “’If I'm Not Allowed to Put My Family First’: Challenges Experienced by Women Who Are Caregiving for Family Members with Dementia.” Journal of Women & Aging 15 no. 1. February 2003. http://journals2.scholarsportal.info.proxy.library.carleton.ca/details.xqy?uri=/08952 841/v15i0001/55_inatpmcffmwd.xml [11 December 2012]. Faul, Mark et al. “Using a Cost-Benefit Analysis to Estimate Outcomes of a Clinical Treatment Guideline: Testing the Brain Trauma Foundation Guidelines for the Treatment of Severe Traumatic Brain Injury.” The Journal of Trauma Injury, Infection, and Critical Care 63 no. 6. May 2007. http://www.ghajar.net/downloads/TBI_CDC-BTF%20_07.pdf [11 December 2012]. Fevang et al. “Labor supply in the terminal stages of lone parents’ lives.” Journal of Population Economics 25 no 4. October 2012. http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007%2Fs00148-012-0402-3 [11 December 2012]. Grignon, Michel, and Nicole F. Bernier. "Financing Long-Term Care in Canada." Institute for Research on Public Policy Website. June 2012. http://www.irpp.org/pubs/IRPPstudy/IRPP_Study_no33.pdf. Hollander, Marcus J. "CIHR Team in Community Care and Health Human Resources." Unfinished Business: The Case for Chronic Home Care Services, A Policy Paper. August 2003. http://www.teamgrant.ca/MTHAC%20Greatest%20Hits/Bonus%20Tracks/Unfinished%20Business.pdf [28 April 2013]. Jones, Allyson, and David Feeny. "Health Status of Elderly Persons Living in the Community of in Long-Term Care Facilities." Institute for Health Economics. April 2007. http://www.ihe.ca/documents/2004-07paper.pdf [10 April 2013]. Jousten, Alain et al. “Long-term Care Insurance and Optimal Taxation for Altruistic Children.” Public Finance Analysis 61 no.1. January 2005. http://journals2.scholarsportal.info.proxy.library.carleton.ca/details.xqy?uri=/00152 218/v61H0001/1_lciaotfac.xml [11 December 2012]. Kuhn, Michael and Robert Nuscheler. “Optimal public provision of nursing homes and the role of information.” Journal of Health Economics 30 no. 4. July 2011. http://journals2.scholarsportal.info.proxy.library.carleton.ca/details.xqy?uri=/01676 296/v30i0004/795_opponhatroi.xml [11 December 2012]. 57 Lee, Myoung‐jae and Young‐sook Kim. Zero-inflated Endogenous Count in Censored Model: Effects of informal Family care on Formal Health Care. Health Economics 21 no. 9. May 2012. http://journals2.scholarsportal.info.proxy.library.carleton.ca/details.xqy?uri=/10579 230/v21H0009/1119_zecicmfcofhc.xml [11 December 2012]. Mentzakis, Emmanouil, Mandy Ryan, and Paul McNamee. "Using Desicrete Chice Experiements to Value Informal Care Tasks: Exploring Preference Heterogeneity." Health Economics 20, 2011: 930-944. Negera, Kebebew. An Informal Care Leave Arrangement – An Economic Evaluation. Norway: Ragnar Frisch Centre for Economic Research, 2009. http://www.frisch.uio.no/pdf/arbnot09_01.pdf [11 December 2012]. Pestieau, Pierre and Motohiro Satoz. “Long-Term Care: the State, the Market and the Family.” Economica 75. 2008. http://journals2.scholarsportal.info.proxy.library.carleton.ca/tmp/129402334377821 58534.pdf [11 December 2012]. Rodrigues, Ricardo and Andrea E. Schmidt. “Expenditures for Long-Term Care: At the Crossroads Between Family and State.” The Journal of Gerontopsychology and Geriatric Psychiatry 23 no. 4. December 2010. http://journals2.scholarsportal.info.proxy.library.carleton.ca/details.xqy?uri=/16629 647/v23i0004/183_eflcatcbfas.xml [11 December 2012]. Silverstein, Merril and Tonya Parrott. “Attitudes Toward Public Support of the Elderly: Does Early Involvement with Grandparents Moderate Generational Tensions?” Research on Aging 19 no. 1. March 1997. http://journals2.scholarsportal.info.proxy.library.carleton.ca/details.xqy?uri=/01640 275/v19i0001/108_atpsote.xml [11 December 2012]. Remler, Dahlia K. "Poor Smokers, Poor Quitters, and Cigarette Tax Regressivity." American Journal of Public Health 94(2), 2004: 225–229. Smith, Geoffrey C. "Residential separation and patterns of interaction between elderly parents and their adult children." Progress in Human Geography vol. 22 no. 3, 1998: 368-384. Smith, Kirsteen and Ken Wright. “Informal care and economic appraisal: A discussion of possible methodological approaches.” Health Economics 3 no.3. May 1994. http://journals1.scholarsportal.info.proxy.library.carleton.ca/details.xqy?uri=/10579 230/v03i0003/137_icaeaadopma.xml [11 December 2012]. 58 Walker, Donna-Jean et al. “Cost-Benefit Analysis of Neonatal Intensive Care for Infants Weighing Less Than 1,000 grams at Birth.” Pediatrics 74 no 1. July 1984. http://www.econ.brown.edu/fac/allan_feldman/AMF%20Significant%20Published %20Papers/CostBenefit%20Analysis%20of%20Neonatal%20Intensive%20Care%20for%20Infants %20Weighing%20Less%20than%201,000%20Grams%20at%20Birth.pdf [11 December 2012]. Wan, Thomas. “Evaluation Research in Long-Term Care: Scope and Methodology.” Research on Aging 8 no. 4. December 1986. http://journals2.scholarsportal.info.proxy.library.carleton.ca/details.xqy?uri=/01640 275/v08i0004/559_erilc.xml [11 December 2012]. Other Sources BBC. More than 230,000 Japanese centenarians 'missing'. September 10, 2010. http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-asia-pacific-11258071. Canada Revenue Agency. What you can deduct. January 3, 2013. http://www.craarc.gc.ca/tx/ndvdls/tpcs/ncm-tx/rtrn/cmpltng/ddctns/menu-eng.html. [10 April 2013]. —. Which medical expenses are eligible? January 3, 2013. http://www.craarc.gc.ca/tx/ndvdls/tpcs/ncm-tx/rtrn/cmpltng/ddctns/lns300-350/330/llwbl-eng.html. [28 April 2013]. Citizens for Tax Justice. Three States Focus on Eliminating Regressive Deduction to Raise Much Needed Revenue. February 27, 2009. http://www.ctj.org/taxjusticedigest/archive/2009/02/three_states_focus_on_eliminat .php#.UXxAs7Xvvzw [28 April 2013]. Field, Andy. Discovering Statistics Using SPSS 3rd Edition. London: SAGE Publications, 2009. Government of Canada. Employment Insurance Compassionate Care Benefits. April 2, 2013. http://www.servicecanada.gc.ca/eng/sc/ei/benefits/compassionate.shtml [28 April 2013]. Health Canada. Long-Term Facilities-Based Care. November 1, 2004. http://www.hcsc.gc.ca/hcs-sss/home-domicile/longdur/index-eng.php. [10 April 2013]. —. Improving Tax Support for Caregivers. 2012. http://actionplan.gc.ca/en/initiative/improving-tax-support-caregivers. 59 Institute for Digital Research and Education. "Annotated SPSS Output: Logistic Regression." UCLA. 2013. http://www.ats.ucla.edu/stat/spss/output/logistic.htm. [10 April 2013]. Intuit. What is the Family Caregiver Amount (FCA). January 9, 2013. http://support.intuit.ca/turbotax/en-ca/iq/Dependants/Family-caregiveramount/INF21867.html. [10 April 2013]. Martin, Daniel. "Children should be forced to care for parents and grandparents to repay them for 'free' childcare, says lawyer." Daily Mail. February 3, 2010. http://www.dailymail.co.uk/news/article-1247883/Children-forced-care-parentsgrandparents-repay-free-childcare.html [10 April 2013]. Ontario Association of Non-Profit Homes and Services for Seniors. "A Submission to the Ontario Standing Committee on Finance and Economic Affairs." Ontario Association of Non-Profit Homes and Services for Seniors Website. March 2013. http://www.oanhss.org/AM/AMTemplate.cfm?Section=Position_Papers_Submissio ns&TEMPLATE=/CM/ContentDisplay.cfm&CONTENTID=10823. [10 April 2013]. Ontario Home Care Association. "Home Care In Ontario - Fact and Figures." Ontario Home Care Association Website. 2012. http://www.homecareontario.ca/public/about/home-care/system/facts-andfigures.cfm. [10 April 2013]. Ontario Ministry of Health and Long-Term Care. "Care in Your Home." Ontario Ministry of Health and Long-Term Care Website. June 26, 2012.http://www.health.gov.on.ca/en/public/programs/ltc/8_home_comm_mn.aspx. [10 April 2013]. —. "Ontario Protecting Quality In Long-Term Care Homes." Ontario Ministry of Health and Long-Term Care. May 30, 2012. http://www.health.gov.on.ca/en/news/bulletin/2012/hb_20120530_1.aspx. [10 April 2013]. —. "Who do I Contact?" Ontario Ministry of Health and Long-Term Care Website. July 25, 2012. http://www.health.gov.on.ca/en/public/programs/ltc/6_ccac.aspx. [10 April 2013]. Ontario Ministry of the Attorney General. Power of Attorney and Living Wills. 2008. http://www.attorneygeneral.jus.gov.on.ca/english/family/pgt/incapacity/poa.asp [10 April 2013]. 60 Statistics Canada. "General Social Survey Cycle 16: Aging and Social Support (2002): User's Guide to the Public Use Microdata File." Ontario Data Documentation, Extraction Service and Infrastructure. Fall 2005. http://search2.odesi.ca/documentation/GSS16/12m0016-gpe.pdf. [10 April 2013]. Spencer, Charmaine. Provisions in several provincial laws that speak to some form of legal responsibility of adult children to their parents. 2011. http://www.canadianelderlaw.ca/Family%20Responsibility%20Laws.htm [10 April 2013]. West's Encyclopedia of American Law: Second Edition. Regressive Tax. 2008. http://legaldictionary.thefreedictionary.com/Regressive+taxation [10 April 2013]. Appendix A: Profile of Care givers and Comparison of Rate of Care Provision Across Groups This analysis was run on a merged dataset of the General Social Survey, Cycle 16, 2002 [Canada]: Ageing and Social Support, Main File and General Social Survey, Cycle 16, 2002 [Canada]: Ageing and Social Support, Care Giving by Respondent (45-64). The later data set is used to identify individuals proving moderate (30 to 89 mins/day personal care) and high (90+ mins/day personal care) intensity care. The data was weighted using the adjusted weight so as to compensate for the stratification of the sample geographically and by age without inflating statistical tests. The analysis below is run only for individuals ages 45 to 64 (N = 12167), as the care giving by respondent data set only covered this age range. The cross-tabulation below show the rate of care provision between groups (italicized and bold in the sample below) as well as the portion of care providers who belong to a particular group (underlined in the sample below). For example, in the sample below we can see that women were substantially more likely to provide care at both the moderate (1.3% compared with 0.3%) and intensive levels (4.8% compared with 1.1%) and that just over 80% of both types of care providers are women. Intensity of Care Count Male Not a care 30 to 89 90 minutes provider minutes per or more per day day 8118 22 89 % of men providing care of this Intensity 98.7% % of care providers of this gender 50.7% 0.3% 16.8% 1.1% 18.0% 7881 109 405 93.9% 1.3% 4.8% % of care providers of this gender 49.3% 83.2% 82.0% Count 15999 131 494 % Overall Providing Intensity of Care 96.2% 0.8% 3.0% Sex of Count respondent % of women providing care of this Female Total Intensity The Chi-Squared tables beneath each cross-tabulation show the statistical significance of the result, ie. The probability that a difference of this magnitude between groups would 62 occur by chance alone. In the case of this sample table, p<0.001 meaning that there is a less than 0.1% chance that men and women in fact provide equal amounts of moderate and intensive care and we can reject this hypothesis. 63 Table 1A: Age Distribution and Profile of Care Providers Intensity of Care Not a care 30 to 89 90 provider minutes minutes or per day more per day Count Age group of the 5138 42 160 45 to 49 % within group proving care of this intensity 96.2% 0.8% 3.0% % of care providers in this group 32.1% 32.1% 32.3% 4475 53 164 50 to 54 % within group proving care of this intensity 95.4% 1.1% 3.5% % of care providers in this group 28.0% 40.5% 33.1% 3591 18 105 55 to 59 % within group proving care of this intensity 96.7% 0.5% 2.8% % of care providers in this group 22.4% 13.7% 21.2% 2795 18 66 60 to 64 % within group proving care of this intensity 97.1% 0.6% 2.3% % of care providers in this group 17.5% 13.7% 13.3% Count 15999 131 495 % Overall Providing Intensity of Care 96.2% 0.8% 3.0% Count respondent: 5-year groups Count Count Total Chi-Square Tests Value df Asymp. Sig. (2-sided) Pearson Chi-Square 21.959a 6 .001 Likelihood Ratio 22.074 6 .001 Linear-by-Linear Association 5.300 1 .021 N of Valid Cases 16625 a. 0 cells (0.0%) have expected count less than 5. The minimum expected count is 22.69. 64 Table 1B: Gender Distribution and Profile of Care Providers Intensity of Care Not a care 30 to 89 90 minutes provider minutes per or more per day day Count Male Sex of 8118 22 89 % of men providing care of this Intensity 98.7% 0.3% 1.1% % of care providers of this gender 50.7% 16.8% 18.0% 7881 109 405 93.9% 1.3% 4.8% % of care providers of this gender 49.3% 83.2% 82.0% Count 15999 131 494 % Overall Providing Intensity of Care 96.2% 0.8% 3.0% Count respondent Female Total % of women providing care of this Intensity Chi-Square Tests Value df Asymp. Sig. (2-sided) Pearson Chi-Square 261.796 a 2 .000 Likelihood Ratio 283.726 2 .000 Linear-by-Linear Association 246.613 1 .000 N of Valid Cases 16624 a. 0 cells (0.0%) have expected count less than 5. The minimum expected count is 64.85. 65 Table 1C: Marital status Distribution and Profile of Care Providers Intensity of Care Not a 30 to 89 90 care minutes minutes provide per day or more r Marital Living Count common- % within group proving care of this intensity law % of care providers in this group Married status of per day 1036 7 16 97.8% 0.7% 1.5% 6.5% 5.3% 3.2% Count 11253 96 328 % within group proving care of this intensity 96.4% 0.8% 2.8% % of care providers in this group 70.5% 72.7% 66.3% 2532 26 106 the Widowed/ Count respondent Divorced/ % within group proving care of this intensity 95.0% 1.0% 4.0% Separated % of care providers in this group 15.9% 19.7% 21.4% Single Count 1147 3 45 (Never % within group proving care of this intensity 96.0% 0.3% 3.8% married) % of care providers in this group 7.2% 2.3% 9.1% Count 15968 132 495 % within Marital status group proving care of 96.2% 0.8% 3.0% Total this intensity Chi-Square Tests Value df Asymp. Sig. (2-sided) Pearson Chi-Square 26.784a 6 .000 Likelihood Ratio 29.064 6 .000 Linear-by-Linear Association 14.266 1 .000 N of Valid Cases 16595 a. 0 cells (0.0%) have expected count less than 5. The minimum expected count is 8.42. 66 Table 1D: Provincial Distribution of Care Providers Intensity of Care Non- 30 to 89 90 provider mins/day mins/day Newfoundland Count and Labrador % within province proving care of this intensity 294 6 14 93.6% 1.9% 4.5% 71 1 3 94.7% 1.3% 4.0% 491 10 26 93.2% 1.9% 4.9% 394 10 20 92.9% 2.4% 4.7% 4123 32 92 97.1% 0.8% 2.2% 6005 39 187 96.4% 0.6% 3.0% 538 2 25 95.2% 0.4% 4.4% 461 4 16 95.8% 0.8% 3.3% 1451 17 42 96.1% 1.1% 2.8% 2171 11 69 Prince Edward Count Island Nova Scotia Province of Count % within province proving care of this intensity New Count Brunswick % within province proving care of this intensity Quebec residence of the % within province proving care of this intensity Ontario respondent Manitoba Saskatchewan Alberta Count % within province proving care of this intensity Count % within province proving care of this intensity Count % within province proving care of this intensity Count % within province proving care of this intensity Count % within province proving care of this intensity British Count Columbia % within province proving care of this intensity 96.4% 0.5% 3.1% Count 15999 132 494 % overall proving care of this intensity 96.2% 0.8% 3.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% Total % of care providers in this group Chi-Square Tests Value df Asymp. Sig. (2-sided) Pearson Chi-Square 63.973 a 18 .000 Likelihood Ratio 54.687 18 .000 .859 1 .354 Linear-by-Linear Association N of Valid Cases 16625 a. 7 cells (23.3%) have expected count less than 5. The minimum expected count is .60. 67 Table 1E: Employment Distribution and Profile of Care Providers Intensity of Care Not a 30 to 89 90 care minutes minutes provider per day or more per day Count 11511 96 395 % of employed providing care of this intensity 95.9% 0.8% 3.3% wages/ salaries/ % of care providers in this group 73.8% 74.4% 80.8% commissions/ Count 4081 33 94 97.0% 0.8% 2.2% % of care providers in this group 26.2% 25.6% 19.2% Count 15592 129 489 % overall providing care of this intensity 96.2% 0.8% 3.0% Income from tips/ selfemployment Yes No Total % of unemployed providing care of this intensity Chi-Square Tests Value df Asymp. Sig. (2-sided) Pearson Chi-Square 11.928 a 2 .003 Likelihood Ratio 12.693 2 .002 Linear-by-Linear Association 11.405 1 .001 N of Valid Cases 16210 a. 0 cells (0.0%) have expected count less than 5. The minimum expected count is 33.49. 68 Table 1F: Highest Level of Education Distribution and Profile of Care Providers Intensity of Care <30 or 30 to 89 none Doctorate/ masters /bachelor's degree Highest level of education obtained by the respondent Count min/day min/day 3434 32 103 % of group who provided care of this intensity 96.2% 0.9% 2.9% % of care providers in this group 21.7% 24.8% 20.9% 4065 38 193 94.6% 0.9% 4.5% 25.7% 29.5% 39.1% 2169 32 67 Diploma/ Count certificate from % of group who provided care of this intensity community college or trade/ 90 % of care providers in this group technical school Some university/ Count community % of group who provided care of this intensity 95.6% 1.4% 3.0% college % of care providers in this group 13.7% 24.8% 13.6% 2615 12 64 % of group who provided care of this intensity 97.2% 0.4% 2.4% % of care providers in this group 16.5% 9.3% 13.0% 3550 15 67 High school diploma Count Some secondary/ Count elementary/ no % of group who provided care of this intensity 97.7% 0.4% 1.8% schooling % of care providers in this group 22.4% 11.6% 13.6% Count 15833 129 494 % within Highest level of education obtained 96.2% 0.8% 3.0% Total by the respondent Chi-Square Tests Value df Asymp. Sig. (2-sided) Pearson Chi-Square 76.817 a 8 .000 Likelihood Ratio 75.271 8 .000 Linear-by-Linear Association 29.737 1 .000 N of Valid Cases 16456 a. 0 cells (0.0%) have expected count less than 5. The minimum expected count is 17.78. 69 Table 1G: Country of Birth Distribution and Profile of Care Providers Intensity of Care Not a 30 to 90 care 89 minutes provider minutes or more per day per day Country of Canada 11964 118 387 % of native Canadians providing care of this 95.9% 0.9% 3.1% 75.2% 90.1% 78.2% 3936 13 108 intensity % of care providers in this group birth of the respondent Count Country Count outside % of immigrants proving care of this intensity 97.0% 0.3% 2.7% Canada % of care providers in this group 24.8% 9.9% 21.8% Count 15900 131 495 % within Country of birth of the respondent 96.2% 0.8% 3.0% Total Chi-Square Tests Value df Asymp. Sig. (2-sided) Pearson Chi-Square 17.484 a 2 .000 Likelihood Ratio 20.672 2 .000 Linear-by-Linear Association 5.662 1 .017 N of Valid Cases 16526 a. 0 cells (0.0%) have expected count less than 5. The minimum expected count is 32.16. 70 Appendix 2: Income and Utility Comparisons among (weighted, for those aged 45-54 with one living parent) Table 2A: Differences between Moderate and Intensive Personal Care Providers and the general population (45-64) in terms of Life Satisfaction Intensity of Care very stressful somewhat stressful How stressful is not very life stressful not at all stressful Not a 30 to 89 90 + care minutes mins/day provider per day Count 1999 28 66 % of group providing intensity of care 95.5% 1.3% 3.2% % of care intensity provided by group 13.1% 21.5% 13.4% Count 7082 50 253 % of group providing intensity of care 95.9% 0.7% 3.4% % of care intensity provided by group 46.5% 38.5% 51.3% Count 4291 41 132 % of group providing intensity of care 96.1% 0.9% 3.0% % of care intensity provided by group 28.2% 31.5% 26.8% Count 1784 11 42 % of group providing intensity of care 97.1% 0.6% 2.3% % of care intensity provided by group 11.7% 8.5% 8.5% 75 0 0 100.0% 0.0% 0.0% % of care intensity provided by group 0.5% 0.0% 0.0% Count 15231 130 493 % within How stressful is life 96.1% 0.8% 3.1% Count No opinion % of group providing intensity of care Total Chi-Square Tests Value Pearson Chi-Square df Asymp. Sig. (2-sided) 20.404a 8 .009 22.791 8 .004 Linear-by-Linear Association 7.325 1 .007 N of Valid Cases 15854 Likelihood Ratio a. 2 cells (13.3%) have expected count less than 5. The minimum expected count is .61. 71 Table 2B: Differences between Non-providers, Moderate and Intensive Personal Care Providers and the general population (45-64) in terms of Life Satisfaction Intensity of Care Not a 30 to 90 care 89 minutes provider minutes or more per day per day Count Very satisfied 4655 52 145 % of group providing intensity of care 95.9% 1.1% 3.0% % of care intensity provided by group 30.7% 40.3% 29.5% 9548 69 319 % of group providing intensity of care 96.1% 0.7% 3.2% % of care intensity provided by group 62.9% 53.5% 64.8% 703 7 21 % of group providing intensity of care 96.2% 1.0% 2.9% % of care intensity provided by group 4.6% 5.4% 4.3% 154 1 5 % of group providing intensity of care 96.3% 0.6% 3.1% % of care intensity provided by group 1.0% 0.8% 1.0% 122 0 2 % of group providing intensity of care 98.4% 0.0% 1.6% % of care intensity provided by group 0.8% 0.0% 0.4% Count 15182 129 492 % within Overall life satisfaction 96.1% 0.8% 3.1% Count Satisfied Count Overall life satisfaction Dissatisfied Count Very dissatisfied Count No Opinion Total Chi-Square Tests Value Pearson Chi-Square Likelihood Ratio Linear-by-Linear Association N of Valid Cases df Asymp. Sig. (2-sided) 8.605a 8 .377 9.557 8 .297 .363 1 .547 15803 a. 4 cells (26.7%) have expected count less than 5. The minimum expected count is 1.01. 72 Table 2C: Differences between Non-providers, Moderate and Intensive Personal Care Providers and the general population (45-64) in terms of Personal Income of Care Providers Intensity of Care Not a 30 to 90 care 89 minutes provider minutes or more per day per day Count No income Less than $15,000 Annual personal income of the respondent (grouped) $15,000 to $29,999 $30,000 to $49,999 $50,000 to $79,999 $80,000 or more Total 902 5 23 97.0% 0.5% 2.5% % of care providers in this group 7.0% 4.8% 5.7% Count 2282 18 83 % within group proving care of this intensity 95.8% 0.8% 3.5% % of care providers in this group 17.8% 17.3% 20.4% 2509 30 97 % within group proving care of this intensity 95.2% 1.1% 3.7% % of care providers in this group 19.5% 28.8% 23.8% 3363 22 107 % within group proving care of this intensity 96.3% 0.6% 3.1% % of care providers in this group 26.2% 21.2% 26.3% 2478 17 73 % within group proving care of this intensity 96.5% 0.7% 2.8% % of care providers in this group 19.3% 16.3% 17.9% 1300 12 24 % within group proving care of this intensity 97.3% 0.9% 1.8% % of care providers in this group 10.1% 11.5% 5.9% Count 12834 104 407 % overall proving care of this intensity 96.2% 0.8% 3.0% % within group proving care of this intensity Count Count Count Count Chi-Square Tests Value df Asymp. Sig. (2-sided) Pearson Chi-Square 20.507a 10 .025 Likelihood Ratio 21.133 10 .020 Linear-by-Linear Association 4.425 1 .035 N of Valid Cases 13345 a. 0 cells (0.0%) have expected count less than 5. The minimum expected count is 7.25. 73 Table 2D: Household Income Distribution and Profile of Care Providers Intensity of Care Non- 30 to 89 90 provide minutes minutes r per day or more per day No income or loss Less than $15,000 Total household income (grouped) $15,000 to $29,999 $30,000 to $49,999 $50,000 to $79,999 $80,000 or more Total Count 34 0 0 100.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.3% 0.0% 0.0% 783 7 24 96.2% 0.9% 2.9% % of care providers in this group 6.1% 6.5% 5.8% Count 1725 15 53 % within group proving care of this intensity 96.2% 0.8% 3.0% % of care providers in this group 13.4% 13.9% 12.8% 2879 21 106 % within group proving care of this intensity 95.8% 0.7% 3.5% % of care providers in this group 22.4% 19.4% 25.5% 3504 21 118 % within group proving care of this intensity 96.2% 0.6% 3.2% % of care providers in this group 27.3% 19.4% 28.4% 3925 44 114 % within group proving care of this intensity 96.1% 1.1% 2.8% % of care providers in this group 30.5% 40.7% 27.5% Count 12850 108 415 % overall proving care of this intensity 96.1% 0.8% 3.1% % within group proving care of this intensity % of care providers in this group Count % within group proving care of this intensity Count Count Count Chi-Square Tests Value df Asymp. Sig. (2-sided) Pearson Chi-Square 11.420 a 10 .326 Likelihood Ratio 12.657 10 .243 .049 1 .825 Linear-by-Linear Association N of Valid Cases 13373 a. 2 cells (11.1%) have expected count less than 5. The minimum expected count is .27. 74 Table 2E: Differences between Non-providers, Moderate and Intensive Personal Care Providers and the general population (45-64) in terms of Employment insurance Income Intensity of Care Not a 30 to 90 care 89 minutes provider minutes or more per day per day Count 1367 10 36 Yes % of group providing intensity of care 96.7% 0.7% 2.5% % of care intensity provided by group 8.8% 7.9% 7.4% 14168 116 452 No % of group providing intensity of care 96.1% 0.8% 3.1% % of care intensity provided by group 91.2% 92.1% 92.6% Count 15535 126 488 % within Income from Employment insurance 96.2% 0.8% 3.0% Income from Employment Count insurance Total Chi-Square Tests Value df Asymp. Sig. (2-sided) Pearson Chi-Square 1.304a 2 .521 Likelihood Ratio 1.366 2 .505 Linear-by-Linear Association 1.301 1 .254 N of Valid Cases 16149 a. 0 cells (0.0%) have expected count less than 5. The minimum expected count is 11.02. 75 Table 2F: Differences between Non-Providers and Intensive Personal Care Providers and the general population (45-64) in terms of Health Utility Index Group Statistics Intensity of Care Health utility index N 90 minutes or more per 493 day Not a care provider 15244 Mean .86326 Std. Deviation Std. Error Mean .195632 .008811 .85541 .209942 Independent Samples t-Test Levene's t-test for Equality of Means Test for Equality of Variances F Sig. t df Sig. Mean (2- Difference taile d) Equal variances Health assumed utility Equal index variances not assumed 3.401 .065 .819 15735 .413 .007850 .875 529.31 .382 .007850 6 .001700 Std. Error Differen ce 95% Confidence Interval of the Difference Lower Upper .009587 -.010942 .02664 2 .008973 -.009778 .02547 7 76 Appendix 3: Logistic Regression Model Logistic Regression Data Filter Weight General Social Survey Merged Data Set Individuals under 65 years of age Adjusted weight (Provided by StatsCan) Case Processing Summary Unweighted Cases Included in Analysis Selected Cases Missing Cases Total Total Dependent Variable Encoding Original Value Not intensive personal care Providing intensive personal care (90+ mins/day) N 9702 2465 12167 12167 Internal Value 0 1 Percent 79.7 20.3 100.0 100.0 77 Omnibus Test of Model Coefficients Chi-square df Sig. 196.788 10 Model Summary Step -2 Log likelihood Cox & Snell R Nagelkerke R Square Square 1 .015 3449.755a .000 .061 Variables in the Equation Aged 55 to 64 B S.E. Wald -.245 .111 4.903 Female 1.505 .132 130.173 1 Living common-law df 1 Sig. .027 Exp(B) .782 .000 4.502 .653 9.445 .276 5.613 3 1 .024 .018 1.922 Widowed/Divorced/Separated .730 .290 6.318 1 .012 2.074 Single (Never married) .943 .313 9.093 1 .003 2.568 Less than $15,000 .529 11.260 .242 4.784 5 1 .046 .029 1.697 $15,000 to $29,999 .693 .239 8.440 1 .004 2.000 $30,000 to $49,999 .677 .238 8.080 1 .004 1.968 $50,000 to $79,999 .782 .249 9.869 1 .002 2.186 $80,000 or more .622 .305 4.161 1 .041 1.862 Constant .367 235.990 1 5.631 .000 .004 Married No income 78 Appendix 4: Caregiver Perceptions of care burden Table 4A: Caregiver Perceptions of Impacts of Care Impact of Assisting Seniors % of those affected providing care of this intensity Changes in Yes % care providers of intensity affected your social % of those affected providing care of this intensity activities No % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity Changes in Yes % care providers of intensity affected your holiday % of those affected providing care of this intensity plans No % care providers of intensity affected Postponed Yes % of those affected providing care of this intensity % care providers of intensity affected educational/ training % of those affected providing care of this intensity No plans % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity Moved in Yes % care providers of intensity affected with care % of those affected providing care of this intensity recipient No % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity Yes Senior % care providers of intensity affected moved % of those affected providing care of this intensity closer to you No % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity Turned Yes % care providers of intensity affected down a job offer or a % of those affected providing care of this intensity No promotion % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity Changed Yes sleep % care providers of intensity affected patterns No % of those affected providing care of this intensity Duration of personal care (mins/day) Under 30 to 90+ 30 89 83.0% 4.1% 12.9% 30.7% 60.4% 54.9% 93.4% 1.4% 5.3% 69.3% 39.6% 45.1% 82.9% 4.2% 12.9% 22.7% 45.5% 40.5% 92.2% 1.6% 6.2% 77.3% 54.5% 59.5% 78.0% 6.4% 15.6% 3.4% 11.0% 7.8% 90.4% 2.1% 7.5% 96.6% 89.0% 92.2% 71.7% 10.1% 18.1% 2.5% 14.0% 7.2% 90.5% 2.0% 7.5% 97.5% 86.0% 92.8% 83.6% 4.5% 11.9% 8.0% 16.8% 13.0% 90.5% 2.1% 7.4% 92.0% 83.2% 87.0% 80.7% 3.5% 15.8% 2.3% 4.0% 5.2% 90.2% 2.2% 7.6% 97.7% 96.0% 94.8% 76.8% 7.2% 16.1% 12.4% 45.5% 29.9% 92.1% 1.5% 6.4% 79 Extra expenses Health affected Yes No Yes No Reduction in Yes hours of work No Yes Quit a job No Change your Yes work patterns No Reduction in income Yes No % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity % care providers of intensity affected % of those affected providing care of this intensity % care providers of intensity affected 87.6% 84.4% 36.3% 93.4% 63.7% 77.8% 12.0% 91.9% 88.0% 80.0% 11.0% 91.3% 89.0% 76.2% 1.2% 90.1% 98.8% 80.4% 14.5% 91.7% 85.5% 78.8% 7.4% 90.9% 92.6% 54.5% 70.1% 3.8% 11.8% 65.0% 58.1% 1.3% 5.3% 35.0% 41.9% 4.9% 17.3% 30.3% 30.7% 1.8% 6.3% 69.7% 69.3% 5.5% 14.5% 29.7% 22.9% 1.8% 6.9% 70.3% 77.1% 3.2% 20.6% 2.0% 3.8% 2.2% 7.6% 98.0% 96.2% 5.6% 14.0% 40.0% 28.9% 1.6% 6.6% 60.0% 71.1% 4.6% 16.6% 16.8% 17.9% 2.1% 7.0% 83.2% 82.1% Table 4b: Caregiver Perceptions of Government Role Intensity of Care (mins/day) 30 to 89 90+ % of those providing care of this 2.1% 10.2% Would the government take Yes intensity over assisting the long term receiver if you were unable % of those providing care of this 97.9% 89.8% No to do so? intensity 80 Table 5: Relationship between care provider and recipient (selected categories, not all possible responses included) Intensity of Total Care (minutes of personal care per day) 30 to 90 or 89 more % of caregivers with this relationship 18.2% 81.8% 100.0% Spouse/ partner % of those providing care of this intensity 1.5% 1.8% 1.8% % of caregivers with this relationship 28.8% 71.3% 100.0% Father % of those providing care of this intensity 17.6% 11.5% 12.8% The care % of caregivers with this relationship 23.0% 77.0% 100.0% recipient Mother % of those providing care of this intensity 39.7% 35.2% 36.2% is the care % of caregivers with this relationship 26.7% 73.3% 100.0% provider’s Father-inlaw % of those providing care of this intensity 3.1% 2.2% 2.4% […] 29.0% 71.0% 100.0% Mother-in- % of caregivers with this relationship law % of those providing care of this intensity 6.9% 4.5% 5.0% % of caregivers with this relationship 12.9% 87.1% 100.0% Close friend % of those providing care of this intensity 3.1% 5.5% 5.0% % of caregivers with this relationship 21.0% 79.0% 100.0% Total 100.0 100.0 100.0% % of those providing care of this intensity % %